首页    期刊浏览 2025年03月02日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Capital Beyond Borders: States and Firms in the Auto Industry, 1960-1994
  • 作者:Arbix, Glauco
  • 期刊名称:Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs
  • 印刷版ISSN:0022-1937
  • 出版年度:1999
  • 卷号:Fall 1999
  • 出版社:Wiley-Blackwell Publishing, Inc.

Capital Beyond Borders: States and Firms in the Auto Industry, 1960-1994

Arbix, Glauco

Thomas, Kenneth P. Capital Beyond Borders: States and Firms in the Auto Industry, 1960-1994. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1997. Tables, map, notes, bibliography, index, 191 pp.; hardcover $55.

Multinational companies are growing stronger over time. They move confidently around a borderless world as purveyors of capital, technology, and the promise of good jobs. In the perspective of most of the world's states, these multinationals offer developing countries a cloak of modernity. The stimulus they receive to develop their factories often includes mega-incentives and official benefits. Few governments, whether democratic or authoritarian, neoliberal or socialist, refuse to participate in the inevitable conflict with rival states to attract these investors. It is not surprising, then, that the investments of multinationals have become the most desired objects among national states at the end of the twentieth century.

Kenneth Thomas's book reminds us that the multinationals' capacity to fix and alter the location of their productive capital grants them enormous advantages in their negotiations with national states and with their own workers. As Thomas argues, the growing mobility of the multinationals erodes the power of states, diminishing their capacity to maintain leverage in negotiations at the federal, municipal, and international levels.

Capital mobility must not be confused with "movement of capital." Many economists conflate these concepts as the ability of capital to travel the planet in search of higher rates of return. The central question, however, should be how negotiations between states and multinational firms focus on the goal of locking in benefits for foreign capital in ways that are always geared to protecting monopolistic-oligopolistic competition and not the more open kind. Thomas tries to explain the mobility of capital; that is, the power to transfer, coordinate, and install capital investment geographically. It is the power to move capital and not the actual movement of capital that causes markets to change and constrains government choices.

Thomas's arguments are based on studies of the automobile industry in the United States, Great Britain, and Canada. As an oligopolistic sector par excellence, the auto industry has a long history of flexing its economic muscles in negotiations with states. The sector's bargaining power remains enormous, as the industry employs millions of workers who work directly for assemblers or autoparts suppliers. According to an estimate published in Fortune in 1995, 13 of the 50 largest firms in the world are auto multinationals. And although it is one hundred years old, the industry continues to develop advanced technology and employ the most modem organizational techniques.

Over the last 30 years, competition has increased in the auto sector, but states have granted more generous incentives to attract multinational investments in the industry. Governments have proceeded with such incentives knowing that the multinationals will always side with their subsidiaries in disputes with states. The multinationals remain much more preoccupied with their global standing than with the economic development of the countries in which they are installed. These firms will simply move to other countries when domestic markets shrink, or they will cease to invest during downturns. The latter occurred in Argentina in the 1980s, with negative consequences. Despite these threats, governments in the developing world still do not hesitate to grant incentives to the automakers.

In attempting to explain this paradox, Thomas describes the current international political economy as one of disequilibria, in which the mobility of capital grants the multinationals several kinds of leverage over states. It increases the range of strategic options for firms. It allows the multinationals to exercise credible threats not to invest or to pull out if their demands are not met. It diminishes the power of state sanctions over firms. It externalizes the provision of certain goods (infrastructure, finance, equipment) and, in the context of competitive incentive schemes across national and subnational governments, it forces these governments to provide those goods or lose the investment.

Capital mobility allows multinationals to move to areas of the world with weak unions so that they might hold labor costs down. One infamous case in the United States is General Motors' "southern strategy." Finally, capital mobility helps multinationals practice transfer pricing in intrafirm trade-sales within the firm across borders to avoid paying taxes and to facilitate the expatriation or repatriation of capital. Thomas argues that the latter is no marginal phenomenon. In the United States alone, intrafirm trade composed 33 percent of total exports and 37 percent of total imports between 1977 and 1994. In global commerce, intrafirm trade accounted for 20 percent of trade in 1990.

These capacities are the root causes of what Thomas sees as a secular shift toward more generous official incentives by governments over the last 35 years. Even in developing countries such as Brazil, Argentina, and India, there is much evidence that these trends persist (see Humphrey et al. 1998). In many of these cases, the terms of agreements between multinational firms and governments have come to public light only after judicial proceedings; the vast majority remain secret.

The reality of multinational leverage over states affects all the Latin American countries that seek the investments of multinational auto firms. This situation contrasts sharply with that of the 1950s and 1960s, when the first major wave of transnational automotive companies flocked to Mexico, Brazil, and Argentina. That first wave of investment relied on much more than the construction of factories and the creation of industrial employment; it involved the wholesale restructuring of industrial relations. It provided the first real impetus for union movements in industry to grow sophisticated.

The expansion of the automobile industry in Latin America required significant commitments of capital and technology and profound changes in the role of the state, which was charged with nothing less than creating a new model of capital accumulation. Back then, developmentalist states negotiated directly with the multinationals. The central state played the role of chief articulator of how the firms' investments would affect the economy, but the main goal was to promote the overall development of the domestic industrial market.

The current situation is very different. In 1995, the Brazilian government prepared a series of incentives for foreign automobile companies. Brazil sought to beat out its rivals in Asia, particularly China; but also its neighbors, particularly Argentina, which in 1991 succeeded in using incentives to expand its automaking sector. Argentina's actions motivated Brazil to follow suit, but under the Mercosur trading regime, multinationals in Argentina were also motivated to provide and import parts produced in the Brazilian market.

The administration of Fernando Henrique Cardoso paid more attention after the Mexican peso crisis affected the Southern Cone economies in 1995, and when Brazil began running large current-account deficits spurred by automobile imports that year. In December 1995, Cardoso launched a protective regime for the automakers that was sharply distinct from the way the autoparts companies were left open to foreign competition. The protective regime, combined with incentives for export within the Mercosur block, stimulated commercial and industrial integration within the multinationals based in Brazil and Argentina. As part of the downsizing and simplification of their own production, the American, European, and Asian multinationals proceeded to allocate a large segment of their global commitments to Brazil.

In Brazil itself, competition between state and municipal governments for multinational investment expanded to an unprecedented degree. Fifteen new factories are to be built through the year 2000, with investments totaling $20 billion. Nine Brazilian states and more than 100 municipal governments, some separated by as many as 2,000 kilometers of distance, have produced cooperative programs to attract the auto multinationals.

Without a doubt, Capital Beyond Borders contributes to the scholarship on processes like these. Capital mobility remains the most important variable in the bargaining between states and firms that underlies the restructuring of investment patterns in Latin America. In the context of global shifts in the leverage that international investors have over states and the erosion of industrial policy and welfare states, Thomas's book sheds light on the dangerous relations between states and multinationals. It asks a timely question: who is regulating whom?

Glauco Arbix

Universidade de Sao Paulo

REFERENCE

Humphrey, John, Glauco Arbix, A. Mukherjee, and M. Zilbovicious. 1998. Globalization, FDI, and the Restructuring of Supplier Networks: The Motor Industry in Brazil and India. In Learning, Liberalization, and Economic Adjustment, ed. Michael J. Piore, John Humphrey, and Mitsuhiro Kagami. Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economies.

Copyright Journal of Interamerican Studies Fall 1999
Provided by ProQuest Information and Learning Company. All rights Reserved

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有