Setting the minimum: Ontario's employment standards in the postwar years, 1944-1968.
Thomas, Mark
Setting the minimum: Ontario's employment standards in the postwar years, 1944-1968.
MINIMUM LABOUR STANDARDS are legally established standards that
apply to most employers and employees, and include minimum wages,
maximum hours of work, overtime, and paid time off. The regulation of
minimum standards in Ontario was consolidated within the Ontario
Employment Standards Act in 1968. While the provincial minimum standards
of the late 19th and early 20th century have been well documented, the
regulation of minimum standards during the postwar period has received
little scholarly attention. This paper explores the development of
minimum standards legislation in Ontario from the immediate postwar
years up to the enactment of the Employment Standards Act. The paper
argues that social forces both internal and external to the state
pressured for the enactment of comprehensive legislation to provide some
statutory protection for the most vulnerable workers in the province.
However, the ways in which the state negotiated the tensions associated
with providing social protection for non-unionized workers, while at the
same time minimizing interference in the market, severely compromised
the capacity for the legislation to provide protection for the
"pockets of exploitation" they were intended for. Further,
this approach to minimum standards supported and reproduced patterns of
gendered and racialized segmentation within a labour market that was
built around the norm of the Standard Employment Relationship, and
thereby ensured standards of a secondary status for workers with the
least bargaining power.
PAR DES NORMES D'EMPLOI MINIMALES on entend les normes
legalement etablies qui s'appliquent a la plupart des employeurs et
des employes et qui comprennent les salaires minimums, les heures de
travail maximales, les heures supplementaires et les conges payes. La
reglementation sur les normes minimales en Ontario a ete consolidee en
1968 par l'adoption de la Loi sur les normes d'emploi de
l'Ontario. Bien que les normes minimales provinciales de la fin du
19e siecle et du debut du 20e siecle aient ete bien documentees, la
reglementation des normes minimales pendant la periode
d'apres-guerre n'a recu que peu d'attention de la part
des specialistes. Cet article explore l'elaboration de la loi sur
les normes de travail en Ontario de l'apres-guerre jusqu'a la
promulgation de la loi en 1968. Il pretend que les forces sociales,
internes et externes, ont exerce des pressions sur l'Etat en vu du
passage d'une loi exhaustive donnant une protection statutaire a la
plupart des travailleuses et travailleurs les plus vulnerables de la
province. Toutefois, les facons dont l'Etat avait negocie les
tensions generes par les debats politiques sur la protection sociale des
ouvriers non-syndiques, meme si elles minimisent l'interference sur
le marche, ont sape severement la capacite de la loi a proteger les
<< poches d'exploitatiom >> auxquelles elie
s'adressait. De plus, cette approche fondee sur des normes
minimales a soutenu et reproduit des tendances a la segmentation par le
genre et la race sur un marche du travail qui a ete construit autour des
relations normales de travail. Elle a finalement assure une position
secondaire aux travailleuses et aux travailleurs possedant le pouvoir de
negociation le plus faible.
**********
IN 1965, AN ONTARIO DEPARTMENT OF LABOUR report entitled Labour
Standards And Poverty stated that "[l]abour standards legislation
attempts to deal with various aspects of poverty by raising wages,
improving working conditions, and opening up employment
opportunities.... [T]he legislation is widely accepted as necessary for
the maintenance of minimum levels of living among low paid
workers...." (1) The report was published as the Ontario provincial
government was undertaking a thorough review of its existing minimum
standards regime and contemplating the development of a comprehensive
new labour standards code. By the mid-1960s, the government was facing
growing pressure from the labour movement to enact stronger legislative
protections for workers who did not have the benefit of unionization,
and to legislate reduced working time in order to protect against the
threat of unemployment created by technological innovation. The
government was also aware that its existing approach to the regulation
of minimum standards, which at that time included several separate
pieces of legislation that set standards in the areas of hours of work,
vacations with pay, minimum wages, and equal pay for equal work, was
increasingly insufficient. The standards lagged behind those of other
jurisdictions, and as indicated in departmental reports on both minimum
wages and hours of work, there remained "pockets of
exploitation" within the province's workforce that required
stronger legislative protection. (2)
In 1968, the provincial government enacted the Ontario Employment
Standards Act. The Act was an amalgamation of existing minimum standards
legislation, along with some new standards, including a legislated
overtime premium. But was the Act capable of dealing with "pockets
of exploitation" and substantially improving the employment
conditions of low-wage workers? While the Minister of Labour Dalton Bales expressed his concerns about the conditions of work of low-wage
workers, he also cautioned in an address to the provincial legislature
that "when it comes down to considering improvements in standards
of employment, we must improve but also maintain a balance that will
help us to keep industry and to attract new industries to the
province." (3) In other words, the government' s new labour
code should not undermine economic prerogatives with the socially
desirable goals of protecting vulnerable workers.
This article explores the development of Ontario's postwar
minimum standards through to the enactment of the 1968 Ontario
Employment Standards Act. The origins of provincial minimum standards in
the late 19th and early 20th centuries have been well documented. (4) So
too has the legislative framework of the postwar settlement that set the
parameters for postwar industrial relations. (5) However, the
development of minimum standards legislation has received relatively
little scholarly attention. (6) A case study of Ontario's
legislated standards provides the means to explore the ways in which the
postwar state negotiated the tension between addressing "pockets of
exploitation" and, as was stated in a federal Department of Labour
report on minimum standards, "that which was economically
practicable." (7) Conceived more broadly, how did the state
regulate employment conditions of non-unionized workers during the years
of the postwar settlement and what were the social forces that shaped
regulatory strategies? Further, given the explicitly gendered legacy of
early minimum standards legislation, which was premised upon supporting
gendered divisions of labour and male breadwinner norms, to what extent
did the standards of the postwar period depart from this earlier
approach? While postwar employment standards legislation contained
formally gender-neutral standards and did not advance the explicitly
gendered approach of early minimum standards, did it constitute a new
regulatory approach that could counter longstanding gendered divisions
in labour law and in the labour market?
The State, Labour Market Regulation, and Minimum Standards
This analysis of the regulation of postwar employment standards
draws from longstanding debates within state theory and seeks to
integrate several approaches to construct a conceptual framework that
accounts for interrelationships between the state and external social
forces, as well as institutional autonomy, and internal conflict. Few
would argue that theoretical frameworks that present the state as either
a purely autonomous social formation, or as a captive instrument of
dominant classes, are able to capture the complexity of social,
economic, and political relations between the state and external social
forces, as well as social relations within the state itself. As it
implies, the autonomous model posits that the state retains
institutional autonomy from other sectors of society, including the
economy. Conversely, the captive state model constructs a view of the
state as an instrument of class rule that is used solely by the dominant
class(es) to further their interests against the dominated class(es).
While the autonomous model has been critiqued for overlooking the
complex interrelationships that are formed between the state and other
social institutions, relations, and practices, the captive state model
is unable to conceptualize the existence of any form of autonomy between
the institutions of the state and the dominant class(es). (8)
Relative autonomy models, for example, those developed by Ralph
Miliband and Nicos Poulantzas, attempt to overcome some of these
limitations by theorizing the ways in which the state is tied to
capitalist interests, yet is able to maintain some degree of autonomy in
the ways in which it supports and legitimates the basic principles of
the capitalist system. (9) Relative autonomy models move state theory
beyond the absolutist positions of the captive and autonomous models.
Both have been critiqued, however, Miliband for not fully accounting for
the various forms of articulation between the state and economic
relations, and Poulantzas for at times denying the state any
independence from the objective structures of the economic base. (10)
Bob Jessop's "strategic-relational" theory of the
capitalist state provides the basis to develop a more nuanced approach
to understanding the role of the state in capitalist society. Jessop
argued that the capitalist state maintains the long-term interests of
the dominant class(es) and secures the long-term conditions required for
capital accumulation. But the captive state approach is rejected, as
competing or conflicting interests may shape the actions of the state,
and thereby produce contradictory actions and outcomes. Jessop's
model situates the state in the context of its "wider social
environment" by arguing that state interventions are shaped by the
"changing balance of forces" both internal and external to the
state. (11) While state interventions act in the long-term interests of
capital, the specific nature of specific interventions (for example,
labour market policies) are subject to the changing balance of social
forces within and around the state. Due to its sensitivity to the
influence of social forces, and its attention to contradiction and
conflict even within the state, this approach provides a more useful
starting point in theorizing the role of the state in regulating the
labour market.
Theories of capitalist hegemony provide further insight into how
the state may support the interests of private enterprise, while at the
same time conceding some demands to subordinate social groups. Antonio
Gramsci defined hegemony as "intellectual and moral
leadership" that takes into account "the interests and
tendencies of the groups over which hegemony is exercised" through
compromises that do not ultimately threaten the rule of the dominant
group. (12) Analyses of the role of hegemony in relation to the
capitalist state provide a multidimensional framework through which to
conceptualize the operation of state power, in particular in ensuring
the legitimation of capitalist relations of production by securing
consent through public policies that are based, in part, on concessions
to popular demands. This approach has been widely applied in analyses of
postwar-era systems of labour law in industrialized economies, which
have been described as "post-war political-economic
settlements." (13) The specificities of such arrangements varied
between national boundaries; however, the principles were similar:
unions gained organizational stability, union members gained regular
wage increases and stable employment, and employers were ensured
"responsible" unionism through regular collective bargaining,
which minimized workplace disruption)4 The hegemonic character of
postwar industrial relations is based upon interconnected compromises
made by unions and employers that limit the capacity for unionized
workers to challenge the capitalist order, but at the same time meet
some of the demands of union members. Michael Burawoy argues that this
form of state intervention constitutes an important component of a
"hegemonic regime" as it seeks to secure workers' consent
to capitalist control of production through forms of state intervention
that provide social welfare, restrict management discretion, and allow
for the. (15) bureaucratic regulation of the workplace through high
levels of unionization.
Returning to the question of employment standards, while the
framework of capitalist hegemony is useful in the analysis of postwar
labour relations, the dynamics of labour market regulation are somewhat
different when viewed from the perspective of minimum standards. First,
the concept of hegemony, with its dual components of coercion and
consent, cannot be applied so easily to the regulation of minimum
standards. Unorganized workers were not drawn into a web of industrial
legality in the manner that organized labour was in the years of the
postwar settlement. Second, the regulation of minimum standards was not
established simply by groups of workers pushing the state for
concessions, and the state responding in a partial or provisional
manner. While this perspective on the state contributes to an analysis
of dynamics of labour market regulation and union activism in the
postwar years and, as will be shown, partly explains the approach of the
labour movement to minimum standards legislation, this conceptual
framework cannot on its own explain the role of the state in the
regulation of minimum standards.
The limitations of this approach to understanding minimum standards
are made further apparent when feminist theories of the state are
considered. Feminist theorists critique Marxist and non-Marxist theories
of the state for overlooking the ways in which the capitalist state is
also a gendered set of institutions and relations. (16) With respect to
labour market regulation, the state has been identified as a site
involved in organizing the social relations not only of economic
production, but also of social reproduction. For example, state
intervention in the labour market through various forms of labour
legislation has been identified as supporting gendered divisions of
labour, and according male and female workers with different levels of
social protections. (17) Feminist analyses of labour market regulation
have demonstrated that postwar labour legislation constructed a gendered
hegemony that excluded women workers. Further, gender has been
identified as a central social relation in the regulation of
contemporary employment standards legislation, earning such legislation
the title "labour law's little sister." (18) Thus, an
analysis of the regulation of minimum standards in the postwar years
requires an analysis of their gendered character.
In addition to feminist perspectives on the state, labour market
segmentation theory provides a useful analytic frame to understand
gendered, as well as other social divisions within the labour market.
(19) Segmentation theorists have sought to explore the ways in which
divisions in capitalist labour markets are created by job
characteristics, the social organization of work relations, the role of
class struggle, the ascribed characteristics of workers, the sphere of
reproduction, and the influences of institutions such as the state and
trade unions. (20) In particular, feminist political economists have
drawn attention to the ways in which interconnections between
institutions of labour regulation (the state, trade unions) and the
relations of social reproduction create forms of gendered segmentation.
(21) Using an intersectional approach, feminist political economy has
sought to integrate anti-racist analyses into this framework as well,
indicating that processes of racialization intersect with relations of
class and gender to shape patterns of labour market regulation. (22)
Building upon the insights discussed above, the study of the
regulation of minimum standards requires consideration of the ways in
which the state contributes to the reproduction of capitalist relations
of production, as well as contradictory and conflicting relations that
may shape state interventions, including those that result from social
forces external and internal to the state. As well, the gendered and
racialized character of state interventions must be accounted for. Drawn
together, these insights frame an analysis of the social relations of
the regulation of minimum standards during the postwar years.
Early Origins of Ontario's Minimum Standards
Models of labour regulation are often rooted in historical patterns
and relations. (23) Early minimum standards in Ontario, which date back
to the late 19th and early 20th centuries, set the framework for future
legislative strategies. During the late 19th century, labour and
employment law in Canada was shaped by the principles of "liberal
voluntarism"--minimal state regulation of the employment
relationship, both with respect to unionization and minimum standards.
(24) Most of the conditions of employment were left to individual
employment contracts and the "free" operation of the labour
market, as the state was largely unwilling to interfere with the
business imperatives of the emerging industrial capitalist economy. (25)
By the early 20th century, legislated minimum standards were being
developed as a means to protect the most "vulnerable"
employees in a labour market. Understood through the Victorian,
patriarchal ideals of the time, this referred to the growing numbers of
women and children entering the growing industrial workforce.
The legislative foundations for Ontario's postwar minimum
standards lay in the Factories Act of 1884 and the Minimum Wage Act of
1920.26 Both reflected principles of minimal government interference in
the regulation of the workplace, and the gendered norms of the
patriarchal household headed by a male breadwinner. The Ontario
Factories Act of 1884 set maximum hours of work at ten hours per day and
60 hours per week for women, girls (14-18), and boys (12-14), and made
it illegal to employ boys under the age of 12 and girls under the age of
14. (27) The 1920 Minimum Wage Act established a provincial board to
determine weekly minimum wages for most female employees, with the
exception of domestic servants and farm workers. (28) In enacting
protective legislation for women and children working in industrial
workplaces, the state was responding to pressures from both organized
labour and middle-class social reformers to improve the conditions of
work experienced by these workers. (29)
The Factories Act and the Minimum Wage Act marked the inception of
several central tendencies in the regulation of minimum standards. They
signified a recognition on the part of the state that it should have a
role to play in establishing basic minimum standards for workers who
could be defined as the most "vulnerable" and the least likely
to have union representation. However, this pattern of state
intervention simultaneously attempted to minimize the impact of
legislated standards on employer power. In describing the impact of the
Factories Act, legal historian Eric Tucker states that it sought to
regulate class conflict "through relatively minor legislative
concessions that were administered compatibly with the industrial
capitalist order." (30) In other words, while the state accepted a
role in regulating workplace standards, this role was very much
circumscribed by the imperatives of capitalist profitability. (31) The
Minimum Wage Act constructed a similar model, characterized by
exemptions, ineffective enforcement, and an individualized complaints-based process, with the effect that did not significantly
alter the power dynamics of the workplaces of industrial capitalism.
(32)
The class dynamics of these Acts cannot be separated from their
gendered character. By regulating the hours of work for women on the
basis of concerns related to social reproduction, the Factories Act
accepted and promoted a gendered division of labour that existed within
both the emerging industrial economy and the labour organizations of the
time, and that was premised on the ideals of the patriarchal family.
Women were not considered to be permanent members of the labour force.
They required protective legislation not only because they were not
likely to benefit from union membership, but also in order to protect
their role in the process of social reproduction. In the area of minimum
wages, the state accepted the need for a women's minimum wage
because of the predominance of women in low-wage industries, and the low
levels of women's unionization. Low wages for women workers could
undermine the social norm of the male breadwinner. But women's
minimum wages did not need to approximate male wages as it was assumed
that women were not sole-supporters of dependents; rather, they were
assumed to be earning a supplemental income, or holding a temporary
position. (33) As Bob Russell notes, minimum wages were "designed
only to cover the 'transitory anomalies' (that is, temporary,
single female wage earners), which fell outside the scope of the
patriarchal household." (34) The racialized dimensions to the Act
were also apparent in the explicit exclusion of domestic workers, a
common form of employment for black women. (35) The intersection of
these social relations through early minimum standards legislation
ensured that minimum standards had minimal impact on employer power, and
simultaneously reinforced gendered and racialized segmentation within
the labour market.
Aside from specific legislation, another central aspect of the
regulation of minimum standards that was established prior to the
post-World War II period was that of provincial jurisdiction over
minimum standards legislation for most workers. In order to resolve
jurisdictional disputes over the regulation of working time, in 1925 the
Supreme Court of Canada confirmed that the regulation of hours of work
fell within provincial jurisdiction, with the exception of
"servants of the Dominion Government" or "those parts of
Canada which are not within the boundaries of the province." (36)
Jurisdictional tensions between the federal and provincial governments
over labour standards re-emerged in the late 1930s. A 1937 report of the
Royal Commission on Dominion-Provincial Relations highlighted the lack
of uniformity in standards between the provinces, and recommended that
the federal government be given jurisdiction to set standards for
minimum wages, maximum hours, and minimum age of employment. (37) The
commission also argued that the implementation of international
conventions, which were developed through the International Labour
Organization (ILO), could also promote uniformity of labour standards.
(38) However, a 1937 Privy Council Decision, which confirmed that
legislation to implement any ILO convention was to be left to the
appropriate jurisdiction (federal or provincial), once again confirmed
provincial jurisdiction over minimum standards. (39)
The Depression Era: Fair Wages, the ISA, and a Male Minimum Wage
The years of the Great Depression prompted both the federal and
provincial governments to consider social and economic policy reforms to
dampen the effects of free market capitalism. Following the failure of
Prime Minister R.B. Bennett's proposed New Deal policies, the
reforms process took place primarily at the level of the provinces and
municipalities. (40) Ontario was no exception, as the province, led by
Mitch Hepburn's Liberal government, sought to address growing
concerns about a "sweatshop crisis" characterized by
increasing hours of work and declining wages. (41) Yet, while new
regulatory strategies emerged during the years of the Great Depression,
intervention remained highly provisional. As labour historian Bryan
Palmer notes, "the interwar years are noteworthy as ones in which
the state failed to integrate itself into the emerging Fordist regime of
accumulation" that developed in this period. (42) Further, lobbying
by national and provincial labour bodies failed to produce a Canadian
version of the Wagner Act at either the federal or provincial levels.
(43) In terms of the regulation of minimum standards, the minimal and
explicitly gendered framework of the early 20th century remained intact.
The years of the Depression are significant nonetheless, as while
comprehensive minimum standards for male and female workers were not
forthcoming, it was becoming apparent that a shift away from this
formally gendered framework was emerging. For example, following a model
established by the federal government, (44) "fair wages" and
the eight hour day were established for workers employed on Ontario
government construction contracts. (45) This model was not extended to
the private sector, however. In the private sector, an alternative to
legislated general minimum standards came in the form of the Industrial
Standards Act (ISA) of 1935. The provincial government did not set
minimum standards through the ISA; rather, the legislation simply
established a process though which employers and employees could
negotiate industry-wide standards. According to Arthur Roebuck, the
Ontario Minister of Labour at the time, "[w]ere the Government to
attempt to legislate for industry by a general minimum wage or to set
the hours that men can work in an arbitrary way, it would not be
successful and it would probably do more harm that good." (46) By
1937, only 65,000 of the province's 650,000 non-agricultural wage
labourers were covered by standards negotiated through the Act and 80
per cent of the ISA schedules were in industries that had been
previously unionized. (47) As the development and enforcement of ISA
standards was dependent upon the efforts of employers and workers, the
legislation offered little to workers who were not organized into trade
unions. (48) Though formally gender neutral, neither fair wages
legislation, nor the ISA addressed the general inadequacies of existing
minimum standards legislation, or offered a comprehensive minimum
standards framework for non-unionized workers in the province.
A third option explored in this period was the male minimum wage.
Following a 1926 resolution in federal parliament by J.S. Woodsworth
calling for a male minimum wage, organized labour took up the call for
provincial legislatures to pass legislation to provide for a minimum
wage for all male workers, "such minima to be not less than that
set out in the Labour Gazette as necessary to maintain a family in a
decent standard of living, the wage to be based on an eight-hour
day." (49) Employers' associations, such as the Toronto Board
of Trade, the Retail Merchant's Association, and the Ontario
Restaurant Owners' Association, all wrote to Deputy Minister of
Labour J.F. Marsh to indicate their support for a male minimum wage in
hopes that it would increase consumer spending power and combat
competitive pressures that, without a legislated minimum, continued to
drive wages to lower and lower levels. (50) However, employer support
for the male minimum was premised upon the assumption that minimum wage
legislation would not become Fair Wages legislation. Employers also
sought assurances that any hours regulations would only establish the
maximum number of hours to which the weekly minimum wage could be
applied, rather than constitute absolute weekly hours maximums. (51)
By 1937, 438,500 of the 650,000 non-agricultural wage labourers in
the province were male workers with no wage protection. Many were
married, with dependents, and had an average wage of less than $12.50
per week, which was the rate set by the Minimum Wage Board for a single
women working in the city of Toronto. Further, the provincial government
noted that these workers "have no degree of bargaining power with
their employers, because there is an ample supply of labour of this type
at the present time and there is no prospect that this reservoir will be
drained in the future." (52) In light of the growing concern over
low male wages, and in response to growing public support for a male
minimum wage, a new Minimum Wage Act was implemented in 1937. The new
Industry and Labour Board created by the Act was empowered to set
minimum wage rates for both men and women, and to set rates across
either industries or regional zones. (53) David Croll, Minister of
Labour, stated that the government's position was that the
legislation was not intended to establish minimum rates in highly
unionized industries, but rather to improve the living standards "of those who have found it impossible to bargain collectively or
to organize for the purpose of improving their wages and working
conditions." (54) However, while the Board was able to set minimum
wages for men, it issued only one order to that effect. For most male
workers outside those on government contracts, the new Act was of little
consequence.
In the development of early minimum standards legislation, from the
Factories Act of the late 19th century to the amended Minimum Wage Act
of 1937, the state slowly responded to concerns from organized labour
and social reformers by attempting to ameliorate some of the harshest
conditions of industrial employment. However, state interventions in the
regulation of minimum standards generally remained well within the
boundaries of the principles of voluntarism. Any shift away from
voluntarism was provisional, applying only to specific categories of
workers, often included explicitly gendered regulations, and did little
to alter the secondary status of non-organized workers. Workers without
unions were left to rely on only a patchwork of employment laws to
establish minimum conditions for their employment. Further, existing
legislation was primarily designated for women workers, who were
presumed to be unorganizable, and this legislation was premised upon
highly gendered conceptions of what should constitute women's
employment norms. These patterns of segmentation within both the labour
market and state policies comprised the antecedent to the minimum
standards legislation that was introduced in the postwar years.
Setting The Postwar Minimum
The 1944 Ontario Speech from the Throne indicated that the
provincial government planned substantial changes to labour and
employment legislation. New legislation would include a general
limitation on hours of work, an annual holiday with pay, and the
adoption of the wartime labour relations legislation. (55) This
commitment was made in a context of growing labour unrest, the emergence
of the federal welfare state, and the regulation of the former by the
later through the labour relations legislation of the postwar
settlement.
The Canadian welfare state developed as a result of a range of
social pressures, including labour unrest and the socialist-oriented
policies of the Co-operative Commonwealth Federation (CCF), and was also
influenced by the legacy of the Depression years, all of which
encouraged the adoption of a Keynesian approach to social and economic
policy. (56) At the federal level, the Mackenzie King government
announced a commitment to a number of measures of social security reform
in the early 1940s. The liberal welfare state that developed in Canada
during the postwar period was premised upon a general policy commitment
to promote full male employment, and to provide social security for
Canadian citizens, within the context of an economic system of private
enterprise. (57) From this framework evolved policies and funding for
unemployment insurance, family allowances, welfare and social
assistance, old age pensions, job creation and job training programs,
and public health care. As implied by the liberal welfare state model,
the implementation of Keynesianism in Canada was limited in all of these
areas, as the policy program of the postwar federal government was
designed to ensure a political and economic climate that respected the
private interests of capital. (58)
Following the war, business leaders sought to ensure that the state
did not undertake excessive levels of intervention. A 1943 Canadian
Manufacturers' Association (CMA) brief to the Special Senate
Committee on Economic Re-Establishment and Social Security stressed the
need to "encourage individual initiative, effort, and thrift, as
opposed to the various forms of completely planned economy under State
control." (59) Postwar planning should be the responsibility of
individual private firms, and private industry should be given priority
to determine postwar employment. Governments should only become involved
with emergency or first-aid programs. The CMA also wamed against both
the continuation of wartime methods of central planning and government
cooperation with organized labour in postwar policy development. (60)
The business community was particularly concerned with organized
labour's involvement in the construction of postwar labour
legislation, specifically a national labour code. Business leaders, and
organizations such as the CMA, were primarily concerned with ensuring
that postwar labour relations legislation would guarantee that unions
would be made to act "responsibly."
Organized labour's policy vision for postwar reconstruction included a national labour code, the legal enshrinement of collective
bargaining rights, full employment, and wage programs geared towards
poverty elimination. (61) The postwar policy programs of the Ontario
federations of both the newly formed Canadian Congress of Labour (CCL)
and the Trades and Labour Congress (TLC) included demands for a 40-hour
work week in order to increase employment opportunities and
workers' leisure time. (62) Other policy demands included time and
a half for overtime over 40 hours, two weeks paid vacation, payment for
statutory holidays, and an increase to the minimum wage rates. As well,
by the early 1940s, both the TLC and the CCL expressed support for the
principle of equal pay for equal work. (63)
When the strike wave of the mid-1940s hit, it was over issues such
as union security, wages, and the 40-hour work week. It was organized at
the level of the workplace, although there were political connections
through relations with the CCF. (64) The state's response was the
postwar labour legislation that instituted the regime of industrial
pluralism and secured the process of collective bargaining as the
primary means through which organized workers could improve their
workplace standards. (65) The 1948 federal collective bargaining
legislation embodied in the Industrial Disputes and Investigation Act
provided a model for the provinces, as provincial jurisdiction over
labour relations returned in the late 1940s. (66)
The implementation of this legislation facilitated the unionization
of the mass production industries, with their largely male, blue-collar
workforce. (67) This process further channelled union activities towards
seeking improvements to workplace standards through collective
bargaining, and did little to encourage the unionization of the
secondary labour market. The effect of this was to further ingrain divisions between the working conditions of unionized workers and those
in the secondary sector, who relied upon minimum standards legislation.
As labour historian Peter McInnis, notes, "[i]mplicit with the
attainment of official recognition was the reality that many
working-class Canadians would be excluded from the advantages won
through private contractual arrangement." (68)
While the emerging labour relations framework took shape in the
context of both labour militancy and the development of the welfare
state, as indicated in its 1944 Throne Speech, the Ontario provincial
government was also developing new minimum standards legislation. In the
summer of 1944, the province introduced the Hours of Work and Vacations
with Pay Act (HWVPA), which not only reduced hours of work standards to
eight per day and 48 per week, but, as it applied to both male and
female employees in industrial undertakings, also ended the explicitly
gendered nature of the regulation of working time. The Act also
introduced the right to refuse overtime and an annual paid vacation of
one week per year. (69) A memo to the Ontario Legislative Assembly
indicated that these standards were established at levels that were
considered to reflect the prevailing industrial conditions at the time,
as "the effect of this legislation has been to make permanent for
everyone working in industry in Ontario the basic conditions which
generally prevailed." (70) Further, the maximum hours provisions
were introduced to "spread employment over a greater number of
employees and also to prohibit an employer from requiring his employees
to work excessive hours." (71)
While expanding the scope of minimum standards, the provincial
government also intended to respect the imperatives of private
enterprise. Even though large industrialists were primarily intent on
preventing organized labour from securing increased power through new
labour relations legislation, they also pressured the state to exercise
caution with improvements to minimum standards legislation. In response
to the Hours of Work and Vacations with Pay Act, the Hamilton-Brantford
branch of the CMA called upon the government to delay the changes until
the end of the war out of fear that reduced hours of work would
exacerbate labour shortages. (72) When the legislation was enacted, in
addition to exempting all war-time industries, a number of other
exceptions and special provisions were built into the Act, ensuring that
employers could exceed the new hours standards. (73) Writing four
decades later, the Ontario Task Force on Hours of Work and Overtime
described the contradictory nature of the Act, stating "the greater
stringency of the vastly extended coverage and the more stringent
maximums at eight hours per day and 48 per week were offset, in part at
least, by greater flexibility through extensive exemptions and by
downplaying the eight hour-per-day maximum where longer hours were the
custom." (74) Exemptions and exceptions to ensure
"flexibility"--better understood as relief from the legislated
standards--were both a legacy of past minimum standards legislation and
a central feature of the state's approach to minimum standards for
the remainder of the 20th century.
In the years to follow, this approach to minimum standards received
strong criticism from organized labour. For example, the Ontario
Federation of Labour complained that employers were able to "almost
willy-nilly get permits to exceed the maximum." (75) The Industry
and Labour Board focused most of its enforcement attention to the
weekly, rather than the daily maximum, resulting in complaints from
unions that daily maximums were exceeded without employee consent. (76)
The ease with which permits were granted, combined with weak enforcement
practices and a lack of reinstatement provisions for workers who were
fired for refusing to work overtime, drastically reduced the impact of
the maximum hours regulations.
The regulation of minimum wages was restructured in the immediate
postwar years as well. In 1947, all minimum wage orders established
through the Minimum Wage Act were revoked. The province was divided into
three zones, based on population size, and new orders were issued on a
regional zones basis. (77) General minimum weekly wages based on a
48-hour work week were set for women workers in each of these zones. If
a worker worked fewer hours in a week, the weekly wages were to be
pro-rated. While the 1937 Minimum Wage Act allowed the Industry and
Labour Board to set minimum wage rates for men, the new orders continued
to leave men's rates unregulated. (78)
While the system of industrial pluralism constructed a hegemonic
approach to relations between employers, unions, and the state, (79) the
segmented nature of this hegemony becomes evident when viewed in
relation to postwar employment standards legislation. The labour
relations legislation of the postwar settlement secured the means by
which unionized workers could improve their standards (through
compulsory collective bargaining), while non-unionized workers relied
upon minimum standards for statutory protection. (80) Further, while the
regulation of minimum standards took on a more generalized character,
the broader policy approach developing within the postwar system of
labour market regulation remained premised upon the designation of
minimum standards as legislation primarily applicable to those workers
in supplemental and/or transitory forms of employment. As Judy Fudge and
Leah Vosko suggest, the implications of this segmented approach to
postwar labour market regulation were profound. It contributed to the
normalization of the Standard Employment Relationship (full-time,
continuous employment) within the unionized mass production industries,
providing these workers with full-time, stable, well-paying jobs, and
thereby entrenching a distinct pattern of segmentation between primary
and secondary labour markets. (81) Employment relationships within the
secondary labour market, those regulated by minimum standards, were
characterized by job insecurity, part-time hours, low-pay, and little
opportunity for advancement. The segmented nature of labour market
regulation supported this segmented labour market structure.
The primary beneficiaries of industrial pluralism were largely
white, male, blue-collar workers. (82) Many workers, particularly women,
as well as many workers of colour, including the growing numbers of
non-British immigrant workers, did not secure unionization as a result
of the postwar settlement. (83) These workers were left with minimum
standards legislation, which did not construct standards comparable to
those negotiated through collective bargaining, (84) to set the basic
standards in their workplaces. Further, despite the acknowledgment that
women workers were particularly reliant on minimum standards
legislation, (85) the state's postwar legislative strategy was not
premised on the need to create standards to make up for gendered
differences in working conditions; thus, this segmented approach to
labour market regulation continued to support male breadwinner norms.
(86) The new legislation replaced the explicitly gendered application of
minimum standards (to women workers) with a more general provision of a
"safety net" for those with "limited bargaining
power." (87) But due to connections to the aforementioned patterns
of labour market segmentation, minimum standards legislation took on an
implicitly gendered character. Further, while minimum standards
legislation had never held explicitly racialized provisions, due to the
marginalization of many racialized groups within the labour market, and
hence their reliance on minimum standards, the regulation of minimum
standards remained racialized as well.
As McInnis argues, the framework of industrial pluralism directed
unions towards collective bargaining, thus further entrenching this
segmented approach to labour market regulation. Organized labour's
response to these tendencies was not homogenous, however. In the years
immediately following the enactment of the HWVPA, organized labour
engaged in intense debates over the merits of general minimum standards
legislation. Older, craft-based unions were in favour of improving
workplace standards through collective bargaining, while the newer
industrial unions were open to the use of a combination of legislative
and workplace strategies. (88) At its annual convention in 1947, the
Trades and Labour Congress resolved to follow a plan of action based on
"the securing of concessions asked for by direct negotiation rather
than legislation." (89) Conversely, at the CCL annual convention in
1947, delegates called for uniformity of labour legislation across the
country and the adoption of ILO conventions, both of which should be
accomplished through regular federal and provincial conferences.
Further, the CCL's traditional demand of the eight-hour day and the
40-hour work week was to be achieved through the combination of both
legislation and collective bargaining.
This debate played out at the provincial level. At the annual
meeting of the Ontario Provincial Federation of Labour (AFL-TLC) in
1951, delegates expressed concern over "too much legislation."
One delegate typified this sentiment, stating that "[t]his business
of trying to legislate improvements just shows the lack of intestinal
fortitude on the part of some unions and their failure to fight for what
they want." (90) Another delegate feared that unions were
"drifting altogether too far into the field of asking the
government to do everything for them." These sentiments were
reflected in a recommendation of non-concurrence on a resolution calling
for a legislated five-day, 40 hour work week for motormen and
conductors. Union officials expressed opposition to minimum wages for
male workers as, based on the experience of women workers, it was feared
that the legislated minimum would become the maximum wage rate for the
industry. Moreover, union officials asserted that legislation would be
of little value without unions present to enforce legislated standards,
and advocated unionization to improve the wages of non-unionized men,
rather than look to the state for protection. (91)
The Ontario provincial government was aware of these tensions
within organized labour, and exploited this lack of consensus over the
merits of minimum standards when defending its opposition to
improvements to existing legislation. In 1951, the CCF presented bills
that were intended to reduce maximum hours of work from 48 to 40,
preserve the eight hour day with no reduction in take home pay,
establish an overtime premium at time-and-a-half, and provide two weeks
of paid vacation with vacation pay at 4 per cent of a worker's
annual salary. (92) In response, the Minister of Labour expressed the
government's opposition to the bills, stating "I think that
the members of this House will agree that the proposals contained in the
various Bills offered by the members opposite to amend the Hours of Work
and Vacations with Pay Act are the type which members of the Ontario
Provincial Federation of Labour think should be left to collective
bargaining." (93)
The provincial government also used small business opposition to
improvements in minimum standards legislation as a rationale to resist
the same proposals. In opposing the CCF amendments, the Minister of
Labour stated "there are many small businesses and many employers
who employ one or two employees would could not sustain the burdens
which this type of legislation seeks to impose." (94)
Elements within the labour movement that supported the further
development of minimum standards legislation, combined with the general
militancy of the 1940s, contributed to the increased social pressure
placed on the state to improve the existing minimum standards
legislation. Overall, however, the lack of strong, coordinated pressure
limited the potential for legislative gains. (95) The effect of the
divisions within organized labour was to reinforce the strategy of
collective bargaining of unionized workers as the primary means through
which working conditions would be improved. Due to the bias of existing
labour relations legislation towards large, industrial workplaces with
predominantly male employment, this contributed directly to the
aforementioned patterns of segmentation within the labour market.
While standards in the areas of hours of work and minimum wages had
longstanding legislative roots, another key component of the postwar
minimum standards regime--equal pay for male and female workers--was not
developed until after the war. Prior to World War II, there was no
general legislation against women workers receiving wages below the
level of male workers when performing the same work. (96) Following the
war, and in the context of dramatic increases in women's
participation in the labour market, (97) pressure on the state to
address the disparity of wages between women and men workers escalated.
This wage gap drew the attention of women's organizations such as
the National Council of Women and the Federation of Business and
Professional Women's Clubs. These organizations called on the state
to enact equal pay legislation in order to address the moral and
economic injustice of the lack of equal pay for equal work. Within the
labour movement, women activists pushed for legislative action not only
for equal pay, but also for equal opportunity of employment. (98) Male
unionists were also willing to support the principle of pay equity,
partly fearing that lower wages for women could undermine both male
employment (through the replacement of men with women), and "the
wage rates and standards won by the trade unions over a long period of
time." (99)
Ontario was the first Canadian province to enact equal pay
legislation. In 1951, the provincial government passed the Fair
Remuneration to Female Employees Act, which came into effect on 1
January 1952. The Act was designed to "ensure that a woman who is
doing the same job as a man is paid at the same wage rate." (l00)
Employers were prohibited from discriminating between male and female
employees by paying a lower rate to a woman for "the same work in
the same establishment." (101) By the end of the decade, equal pay
laws covered approximately 67 per cent of women in the Canadian labour
force. (102)
The Act was immediately criticized, as it applied only to the same
work, and therefore did not take into account work of equal value.
Employers were able to continue to pay differential wages to men and
women workers through practices of occupational segregation. (l03) The
CCF attempted, with no success, to expand the Act to cover work of
"comparative character or on comparable operations or where
comparable skills are involved." A report produced by the federal
government at the end of the decade found that the practice of paying
women less than men for the same work remained widespread, in part due
to the assumption of the need to maintain a male breadwinner wage. (104)
As well, a complaints process that placed the onus on the individual
worker to report a violation held the clear potential to act as a
deterrence to the registering of complaints. The Act could certainly be
seen as a "cautious and narrow solution to women's
demands." (105)
From the mid-1940s through the 1950s, the regulation of minimum
standards shifted from an explicit orientation towards protecting women
workers to a general commitment to constructing a set of standards for
all vulnerable (non-unionized) workers, male and female. Employment
standards legislation sought to promote a degree of decommodification
through general minimum standards that provided these workers some
protection from market forces; however, as Judy Fudge and Eric Tucker
note, "[m]inimum entitlement could not depart too markedly from
market norms." (106) While the postwar state sought to buffer the
effects of the market, as in the pre-World War n years, the manner in
which minimum standards were regulated ensured that employers had some
"flexibility" to exceed the legally established minimums.
Further, while explicitly gendered standards were replaced with this
formally gender neutral framework, the standards remained implicitly
gendered. Joan Sangster describes Ontario's postwar employment and
welfare policies as grounded in a "dichotomous understanding of
women (occasional workers) and men (permanent workers)." (107) This
gendered conception of employment certainly persisted through the
transition of employment standards from protective legislation
explicitly designated for women workers to general minimum standards
legislation designed for all vulnerable (non-unionized) workers,
primarily through the parallel dichotomy created between minimum
standards and labour relations legislation, and the ways in which this
segmented regulatory framework shaped the social organization of the
labour market. In addition, the hegemonic character of postwar labour
relations legislation drew organized labour further away from those
outside the bounds of industrial pluralism. The lack of a strong,
unified labour movement organizing around demands for improved minimum
standards legislation further reinforced the state's segmented
approach to labour market regulation.
The Ontario Employment Standards Act, 1968
The final phase in the development of Ontario's postwar
minimum standards regime took place in the 1960s, amidst a social
context of growing labour unrest, in particular from young workers and
militant and unionized elements within public sector workforces. As well
the federal government had embarked on a nation wide "war on
poverty," which included strategies to re-regulate minimum
standards. As stated by the federal Task Force on Industrial Relations,
which was struck in response to labour militancy, labour standards
legislation may be "part of an anti-poverty program to ensure
workers a minimum standard of living without being exploited by having
to work unduly long hours." (l08) Within the provincial government
itself, Ministry of Labour officials were increasingly aware of the
inadequacy of existing minimum standards legislation, and of the need to
develop a new solution to the continued economic marginalization of low
wage workers in the province, as "a portion of the labour force had
difficulty in maintaining even a subsistence standard of living."
(109) Thus, by the mid-1960s, the Ontario Department of Labour was in
the process of developing a comprehensive labour standards code that
would bring together existing legislation in the areas of minimum wages,
hours of work, and equal pay. (110)
While a coming shift was taking shape, internal debates within the
government over the minimum wage indicate that there was no clear
consensus. In 1960, a provincial government committee was appointed to
explore the possibility of creating a legislated male minimum wage.
(111) In a memorandum to the Minister of Labour, the Industry and Labour
Board expressed concern that the introduction of a male minimum wage
could create economic and political problems within the province. There
were the competing concerns that an increased minimum wage could
generate unemployment, while at the same time a minimum wage rate that
was too low would generate further criticism from opponents. (112) After
several meetings between December 1960 and February 196 l, the committee
concluded that a legislated weekly minimum wage for men was not
necessary because the existing Minimum Wage Act permitted the
establishment of male minimum wage rates through minimum wage orders.
While the possibility of an hourly minimum was assessed, the committee
concluded that it could not recommend a minimum wage for men without
further study.
Nonetheless, the general concern within the government over the
economic marginalization of low wage workers, combined with union
pressure for a general minimum wage, pushed forward a new approach to
the regulation of minimum wages. (113) In disagreement with the minimum
wage committee, the Ontario Minister of Labour took the position that a
male minimum wage of $1.00 per hour would be both politically and
economically feasible, even in the event of some short-term
unemployment. (114) The practice of setting a minimum wage for only
women workers was finally abandoned in 1963 with a general rate phased
in across each of the existing minimum wage zones. (115) A general
minimum wage of $1.00 for male and female workers in the province ($1.25
for construction workers) was reached across the province on 27 December
1965. (116) This new minimum wage legislation followed the pattern set
by other postwar minimum standards legislation by constructing a minimum
social safety net, in part a response to increased pressure from
organized labour. (117) At the same time, the phase-in approach was
meant to take into account concern raised within the business community,
which had indicated cautious support so long as the rates did not
increase to the point where they could have a detrimental impact upon
marginal industries that employed large numbers of unskilled labourers.
(118) Further, its gendered character was apparent in the fact that the
majority of workers who were affected by the new minimum were women.
(119)
The lack of consensus within the government over the specifics of
the minimum wage paled in comparison to the tensions that developed
between the province and the federal Department of Labour over the issue
of general labour standards. These tensions were apparent in the
reactions of provincial officials to the development of the Canada
Labour (Standards) Code, itself a product of the social context of
labour militancy and the "war on poverty." The Code was
implemented in July 1965, and set labour standards for all industries
under federal jurisdiction, including an eight hour day and 40 hour
week, with an overtime rate of time-and-a-half for hours over 40. (120)
Both employers and the Ontario provincial government voiced opposition
to the Code. Employers, particularly those in the trucking industry,
feared that the hours of work restrictions could have a detrimental
impact on work scheduling. (121) Ontario Minister of Labour H.L.
Rowntree agreed, arguing that the federal labour code could create an
unequal level of competition, as some companies in grey area
jurisdictions (trucking and highway transport) were covered by the
federal code, while others remained under provincial jurisdiction with
different hours of work regulations. In a more general sense, the new
code was criticized in a memo produced by the Ontario Department of
Labour for taking a "leading edge" approach to legislated
standards by exceeding standards set through collective bargaining. This
leading edge approach was very different than the approach favored by
the province of Ontario, where "labour standards are established by
Governments as floor levels to prevent exploitation," and were not
to constitute an alternative to collective bargaining. (122)
The Ontario government was particularly concerned about the federal
government's desire to promote a harmonization of labour standards
across the provinces. It made clear that such an initiative would not be
supported in Ontario. In a letter to Ottawa, Ontario Labour Minister
H.L. Rowntree stated that "it is unrealistic to expect all economic
regions across Canada to be capable of supporting a minimum wage of
$1.25 or a 40-hour week or many other of the Code's
provisions." (123)
The new federal code was met with mixed reactions from the Canadian
Labour Congress, which offered qualified support for the new standards.
(124) Within Ontario, however, the Ontario Federation of Labour used the
standards set by the federal labour code as a rationale to push for
improvements to provincial labour standards legislation. The OFL's
strategy reflected a growing conviction within the labour movement that
unionization and collective bargaining needed to be supplemented with
legislative action. This was particularly the case in light of the
increasing economic shift towards a service economy, as these jobs were
"the hardest to organize and are the lowest paid." (125) The
new federal Code, combined with the broader "war on poverty,"
provided the organization with an opportunity to push for stronger
provincial standards. Specifically, the OFL called on the province to
match the federal hours of work standards of 40 hours per week and the
overtime rate of time-and-one-half, as these standards greatly exceeded
the existing provincial standards of the 48-hour work week with no
overtime premium. In the words of the Federation, "[s]urely the
highly industrial province of Ontario should at least conform to the
Federal standards." (126) The OFL argued that reduced work time,
through legislation, could create employment opportunities for larger
numbers of workers, and that an increase to the minimum wage from $1.00
to $2.00 per hour was a necessary first step to the reduction of poverty
rates in the province.
Women's organizations supported further improvements to the
legislated standards as well. The Congress of Canadian Women called for
an increase in the minimum wage from $1.00 to $2.00 per hour at its 1967
Annual Convention. Such a raise was needed to reflect the realities of
women's wage labour in the 1960s. Paid employment was not a
temporary phase in a woman's life, as many women workers remained
in the labour force until retirement, and the existing minimum wage rate
was insufficient to meet the needs of women who were the "sole
breadwinners" of their families. (127) The Business and
Professional Women's Clubs in Ontario called for amendments to the
equal pay legislation through the 1960s, as women were receiving as
little as 75 per cent of the salary paid to men for comparable work.
(128)
In direct contrast to these positions, both large and small
employers expressed a preference for standards to be set through
workplace-level bargaining. (129) The CMA pressured for exemptions for
employers with unionized workforces so that minimum standards
legislation would not directly impact upon collective bargaining. In
response to potential changes to the regulation of hours of work, small
businesses sought greater flexibility in the scheduling of hours of
work, and opposed proposals for a required half-hour break after five
hours of work. Such legislation, it was claimed, would "create a
very definite hardship" on workers employed in continuous shift
operations, as well as on consumers and entire industries. Instead of
legislated standards, "mutually satisfactory working
conditions" that are negotiated between employers and employees
were deemed more appropriate as they are "more conducive to good
labour relations than legislated working conditions." (130)
Within the provincial government, the prevailing ideology regarding
the role of minimum standards was tied to the goal to provide protection
against exploitation in the labour market in order to address poverty.
Minimum standards were necessary due to differences in bargaining power
between organized and unorganized workers. A government report on Labour
Standards and Poverty in Ontario suggested that, as "a portion of
the labour force had difficulty in maintaining even a subsistence
standard of living," minimum labour standards could play an
important role in addressing the poverty that may result from low wages,
long hours, and unfair competition. (131) For example, a 1968 memorandum
indicated that the role of the minimum wage was "to ensure that
employees with little or no bargaining power are paid an hourly rate
that gives them sufficient income to obtain the necessities of
life." (132) In the area of hours of work, despite the legislated
maximum of 48 hours, the province was aware that between thirteen and
sixteen per cent of workers were working hours in excess of the maximum,
(133) creating pockets of exploitation in relation to existing community
standards. The province was also aware that its legislated hours
standards exceeded both the ILO conventions, and legislated maximums in
many other jurisdictions (British Columbia, Alberta, Saskatchewan,
Manitoba, and federal jurisdictions in Canada and the United States).
(134) These concerns within the government not only created internal
support for a new labour code, but also created a political space for
those outside the state pushing for better standards, such as the OFL.
Yet, the same report on Labour Standards and Poverty in Ontario
indicated that these considerations were to be accomplished without
creating undue hardships for employers. (135) A subsequent memorandum in
1968 echoed this sentiment, stating that minimum wages themselves were
not considered to be a means to eliminate poverty; rather they were to
provide a "socially and economically acceptable" floor. (136)
Consistent with previous minimum standards initiatives, any new minimum
standards legislation should not be used to develop leading edge
standards that would exceed standards negotiated through collective
bargaining. For example, in response to an OFL demand to increase paid
vacation to two weeks per year in 1968, the Minister of Labour Dalton
Bales recommended against this to the Ontario Cabinet. Given that many
collective agreements did not yet have two weeks paid vacation,
"[i]f unions can't get two weeks after one year via collective
bargaining, the law is going to be rather hard on the economies of some
employers if it imposes the requirements." (137) Further, the
province was certainly not prepared to follow the federal standard of
the 40-hour work week. In response to business concerns over the
possibility of a legislated 40-hour work week in 1965, E.G. Gibb, a
Department of Labour official, stated it was "doubtful if any
amendment along this line would be introduced by the Government at this
Session." (138) A memorandum in 1968 clarified this position,
stating "to limit hours to 40 would not only hobble industry, but
would also limit workers' opportunities to earn overtime pay, which
would reduce their incomes." (139) Thus, while the Canada Labour
Code provided a model in terms of its comprehensive approach to labour
standards, provincial opposition to the levels of the standards within
the code indicated that the Ontario government intended to maintain
provincial autonomy in developing its own code, (140) and that while
efforts would be made to address poverty through minimum standards
improvements, these efforts would be delimited by the province's
interpretation of its economic interests.
Ontario's own comprehensive labour standards code--the Ontario
Employment Standards Act (ESA)--was enacted in 1968 and came into effect
on 1 January 1969. (141) At the time, there were some 2,800,000
employees in the province, with approximately 728,000 organized in trade
unions. The legislation was primarily designed for those without
collective agreements, particularly those in low-income employment.
(142) A Ministry of Labour notice to employers and employees in the
province described the ESA as a means to "safeguard workers against
exploitation and to protect employers against unfair competition based
on lower standards." (143) Consistent with the previously existing
approach to minimum standards, the ESA was designed to provide socially
acceptable minimum standards without impeding business interests in the
province. The principles of minimum standards, as indicated in a summary
report in the 1967 Labour Gazette, were already well established:
"The social and economic implications of minimum standards are
inter-related, and must be largely determined by that which is
economically practicable." (144)
The ESA established standards for minimum wages, hours of work,
overtime, vacations with pay, and equal pay for equal work for most
workers in the province. The general minimum wage was increased to $1.30
for all workers covered by the Act (the construction rate was increased
to $1.55). Hours of work maximums remained at eight hours per day and 48
hours per week, with an overtime premium rate of time-and-one-half for
work over 48 hours. Holiday pay was set at time-and-a-half for seven
statutory holidays. (145) An annual paid vacation of two weeks was to be
compensated at a rate of four per cent of a worker's annual salary.
As well, the Act established a new process for the collection of unpaid
wages up to $1,000, and incorporated the equal pay legislation into its
framework. (146)
As with previous minimum standards legislation, the Act included
exemptions and special provisions designed to provide employers with the
capacity to operate outside its standards. (147) For example, R.M
Warren, Executive Director of Manpower Services described the overtime
provisions as a "flexible deterrent to excessively long
hours." (148) The overtime premium was to provide a deterrent,
while flexibility was gained through the possibility to average overtime
hours over multiple weeks, subject to the Director's approval.
Further, the right to refuse overtime did not apply in cases where an
employer had established a normal work day in excess of eight hours in a
work week of 48 hours or less. Hours in excess of the weekly maximum
were permitted through a permits system, which was administered by the
Director, to a maximum of 100 hours of overtime per year.
Organized labour was highly critical of the new legislation,
stating that "[t]he new minimums will do very little to help the
unorganized workers participate in the prosperity they help to
create." (149) The 48-hour work week was unrealistic as industry
standards were moving towards a 40-hour work week. The minimum wage
levels, which were well below the poverty line established by the
Economic Council of Canada for a family of four in 1969, were widely
criticized by organized labour, the provincial New Democratic Party, and
in the print media. (150)
Despite the flexibilities contained in the Act, employer
associations also registered a number of concerns in the first year of
the its implementation. (151) While the Canadian Manufacturers'
Association was consulted prior to the Act receiving Royal Assent, the
Association wrote to Labour Minister Dalton Bales to inform him of their
perception that the concerns of employers had not been addressed in the
drafting of the regulations. (152) At their Annual General Meeting in
1969, the association submitted that the ESA created many practical
problems for employers. (153) Along with other employer associations,
the CMA'S position at the time was that the Act should not apply to
an employer with a collective agreement, as it undermined the process of
free collective bargaining. The Ontario Chamber of Commerce requested
that employees in service industries be exempted from holiday pay
provisions as "there is little justification for providing
legislative authority which requires that such continuous operations as
hospitals, hotels and communications enterprises should be required to
pay above normal rates for maintaining normal service." (154)
Employers continued to favour (individual and collective) workplace
bargaining over legislated standards. (155)
The government's response to its critics of the minimum wage
levels is illustrative of its perception of the role of the minimum wage
specifically, and of minimum standards more generally. In response to
claims that the minimum wage was too low, the government stated that the
minimum wage levels were assumed to be a general floor below which wage
rates cannot go, rather than a fair or living wage. This floor was
assumed to have income raising potential, as increases to the minimum
rates would lead to general increases in wage rates across the province.
(156) In addition, the minimum wage was itself only part of a package of
income-raising devices that included collective bargaining, the
Industrial Standards Act, fair wage schedules for government contracts,
and premium pay for overtime and statutory holidays. (157) But the
standards also had to take business interests into account. The
government was not prepared to meet demands from the OFL and NDP for a
minimum wage of $2.2 5 per hour. A memorandum to the Minister of Labour
suggested that this rate "probably would have too heavy an impact
on low-wage industries." (158) Further, it was not considered
reasonable for the government to set the minimum wage at a level that
would ensure an income above the poverty line, as employees' family
responsibilities and marital status were not to be considered in the
determination of wage rates. Finally, competitive pressures required
that the minimum wage be kept at a level in line with economic
realities, lest companies decide to relocate to lower-wage
jurisdictions. Thus, while the state exhibited some autonomy from the
business community in setting minimum standards, that autonomy was
clearly delimited by the prerogative to support private enterprise by
minimizing the impact of the legislated minimums.
Conclusion
In the postwar years, collective bargaining and unionization
provided some groups of workers with the means to secure stable incomes,
benefits, and job security. Workers of the secondary labour market were
accorded a secondary form of legislative workplace protections through
minimum standards. In Ontario, government officials accepted the need
for some minimum level of legislative protection for non-unionized
workers. However, the policy framework that was adopted was clearly
constrained by the state's support for private enterprise, for
example, through the low level of the standards, and the various special
provisions that allowed employers to circumvent the legislation.
The explicitly gendered legacy of Ontario's early minimum
standards legislation continued to shape the regulation of minimum
standards in the postwar years. While postwar minimum standards
legislation, including the 1968 Ontario Employment Standards Act, was
free of the explicitly gendered provisions of early minimum standards
legislation, it nonetheless constructed a highly gendered set of
standards as it remained premised upon the norms of the male breadwinner
model, and was much more likely to apply to women workers. This approach
to minimum standards supported and reproduced patterns of not only
gendered, but also racialized segmentation, as workers of colour and
recent immigrant workers of largely non-British origins were also more
likely to be reliant on the legislated standards, which were clearly set
below conditions that were established by collective bargaining. The
state's approach to minimum standards thereby ensured standards of
a secondary status for workers with the least bargaining power, and thus
reinforced and reproduced patterns of segmentation within a labour
market that was built around the norm of the Standard Employment
Relationship. Thus, in the post-war years, the regulation of minimum
standards took on a broader scope than it had previously held. However,
due to the ways in which the state negotiated the tensions associated
with providing social protection for vulnerable workers, while at the
same time minimizing interference in the market, the capacity for
Ontario's postwar minimum standards to provide protection for the
"pockets of exploitation" they were intended for was severely
compromised.
I would like to thank the members of the Toronto Labour Studies
Research Group and the anonymous reviewers for their comments and
assistance in revising this paper.
(1) Archives of Ontario (hereafter AO) RG 7-1, Ministry of Labour,
Minister, Correspondence (hereafter MLMC), File 7-1-0-1178, box 37,
Labour Standards and Poverty in Ontario, Ontario Department of Labour,
22 November 1965.
(2) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1181, box 37, Legislative Proposal
Respecting The Hours of Work and Vacations with Pay Act; AO MLMC, File
7-1-0-1407.3, box 47, The Labour Standards
Mark Thomas, "Setting the Minimum: Ontario's Employment
Standards in the Postwar Years, 1944-1968," Labour/Le Travail, 54
(Fall 2004), 49-82.
Act, Background Memorandum, 25 January 1968, 2; AO MLMC, File
7-1-0-731, box 19, Statement by the Honorable H.L. Rowntree, Minister of
Labour, on the Government's Minimum Wage Policy, 1-2.
(3) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.2, box 47, Notes for an Address by the
Hon. Dalton Bales, Q.C., Minister of Labour for Ontario, During 2nd
reading of: The Employment Standards Act, 1968, 31 May 1968.
(4) See Margaret E. McCallum, "Keeping Women in their Place:
The Minimum Wage in Canada, 1910-25," Labour/Le Travail, 17 (Spring
1986), 29-56; Eric Tucker, "Making the Workplace 'Safe'
in Capitalism: The Enforcement of Factory Legislation in
Nineteenth-Century Ontario," Labour/Le Travail, 21 (Spring 1988),
45-85; Jane Ursel, Private Lives, Public Policy: 100 Years of State
Intervention in the Family (Toronto 1992).
(5) For example, see Leo Panitch and Donald Swartz, From Consent to
Coercion: The Assault on Trade Union Freedoms (Toronto 2003); Bob
Russell, Back to Work." Labour, State and Industrial Relations in
Canada (Scarborough 1990).
(6) Judy Fudge, "Reconceiving Employment Standards
Legislation: Labour Law's Little Sister and the Feminization of
Labour," Journal of Law and Social Policy, 7 (Spring 1991), 73-89;
Roy J. Adams, "Employment Standards in Ontario: An Industrial
Relations Systems Analysis," Relations Industrielles/Industrial
Relations, 42 (Winter 1987), 46-64.
(7) Canada Department of Labour, "Minimum Standards
Legislation and Economic Policy," The Labour Gazette, 67 (September
1967), 567.
(8) See Bob Jessop, State Theory: Putting Capitalist States in
their Place (University Park, PA 1990), 25-47. See also, Andrew Yarmie,
"The State and Employers' Associations in British Columbia:
1900-1932," Labour/Le Travail, 45 (Spring 2000), 53-59.
(9) Ralph Miliband, The State in Capitalist Society: An Analysis of
the Western System of Power (London 1969); Nicos Poulantzas, Political
Power and Social Classes, Trans. T. O'Hagan (London 1978). Miliband
tied the operation of state power to the social composition of the
state, arguing that those who hold leadership positions in the
institutions of the state system, in other words, the "state
elite," wield state power. According to this approach, in advanced
capitalist societies, the members of the state elite are themselves
members of the middle and upper classes. Thus, the interests of the
dominant classes are represented by the state because members of those
classes hold state power. The state establishes some autonomy from
business interests through a certain degree of variability in the
specific political programs advanced by the parties and leaders who hold
office. This autonomy is relative, however, as all state programs in the
advanced capitalist nations nonetheless defend the basic principles of
the capitalist system. In contrast, Poulantzas considered the question
of the state's relative autonomy in more structuralist terms,
arguing that while the state ensures the reproduction of capitalist
relations of production and the interests of the dominant class, it
maintains a degree of autonomy from the other "regional
structures" of the capitalist mode of production, and is dominated
only "in the last instance" by the economic level.
(10) See Jessop, State Theory, 25-47.
(11) Jessop, State Theory, 353. See pages 9-11 for a general
overview of the "strate(12) gic-relational" approach.
(12) Antonio Gramsci, Selections from the Prison Notebooks, Trans.
Q. Hoare and G.N. Smith (New York 1971), 57, 161.
(13) Richard Hyman, "Economic Restructuring, Market Liberalism
and the Future of National Industrial Relations Systems," in R.
Hyman and A. Femer, eds., New Frontiers in European Industrial Relations
(Oxford 1994), 5.
(14) Greg Albo and Chris Roberts, "European Industrial
Relations: Impasse or Model?" in E. Meiksins Wood, P. Meiksins, and
Michael Yates, eds., Rising from theAshes? Labour in the Age of
'Global" Capitalism (New York 1998), 164-179; Aaron McCrorie,
"PC 1003: Labour, Capital, and the State," in C. Gonick, P.
Phillips, and J. Vorst, eds., Labour Gains, Labour Pains: 50 Years of PC
1003 (Halifax 1995), 15-38; Paul Phillips, "Labour In the New
Canadian Political Economy," in W. Clement, ed., Understanding
Canada: Building on the New Canadian Political Economy (Montreal &
Kingston 1997), 64-84; Russell, Back To Work.
(15) Michael Burawoy, The Politics of Production: Factory Regimes
Under Capitalism and Socialism (London & New York 1985).
(16) For examples of feminist analyses of the Canadian state see
Isabella Bakker and Katherine Scott, "From the Postwar to the
Post-Liberal Keynesian Welfare State," in W. Clement, ed.,
Understanding Canada, 286-310; Wendy McKeen and Ann Porter,
"Politics and Transformation: Welfare State Restructuring in
Canada," in W. Clement and L. Vosko, eds., Changing Canada:
Political Economy as Transformation (Montreal and Kingston 2003),
109-134; Ursel, Private Lives, Public Policy.
(17) Ann Forrest, "A View from Outside the Whale: The
Treatment of Women and Unions in Industrial Relations," in L.
Briskin and P. McDermott, eds., Women Challenging Unions: Feminism,
Democracy and Militancy (Toronto 1993), 325-41; Judy Fudge, "The
Gendered Dimension of Labour Law: Why Women Need Inclusive Unionism and
Broader-based Bargaining," in L. Briskin and P. McDermott, eds.,
Women Challenging Unions, 231-48.
(18) Judy udge, Labour Law's Little Sister: The Employment
Standards Act and the Feminization of Labour (Ottawa 1991).
(19) Labour market segmentation theories posit that capitalist
labour markets are constructed through the intersection of social,
institutional, economic, and technological forces, and that they are
divided into sub-markets, each of which may regulate labour market
actors in different ways. See Jamie Peck, Work-Place: The Social
Regulation of Labour Markets (New York 1996).
(20) Judy Fudge and Eric Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation?
The Twentieth-Century Employment Law Regime in Canada," Labour/Le
Travail, 46 (Fall 2000), 251-306.
(21) Judy Fudge and Leah Vosko, "Gender Paradoxes and the Rise
of Contingent Work," in W. Clement and L. Vosko, eds., Changing
Canada, 183-212.
(22) Daiva Stasiulis, "The Political Economy of Race,
Ethnicity, and Migration," in W. Clement, ed., Understanding
Canada, 141-171; Leah F. Vosko, "The Pasts (and Futures) of
Feminist Political Economy in Canada: Reviving the Debate," Studies
in Political Economy, 68 (Summer 2002), 55-83.
(23) P.K. Edwards, "A Comparison of National Regimes of Labor
Regulation and the Problem of the Workplace," in P. Edwards, J.
Belanger, and Larry Haiven, eds., Workplace Industrial Relations and the
Global Challenge (Ithaca, NY 1994), 23-42.
(24) Judy Fudge and Eric Tucker, Labour Before the Law: The
Regulation of Workers' Collective Action in Canada, 1900-1948 (Don
Mills 2001).
(25) Fudge and Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation," 252.
Prior to the 1880s, the Lord's Day Act was the only legislation
governing what are today considered to be minimum employment standards.
Canada Department of Labour, "Sunday Shopping in Canada--Some of
its Legal Aspects," The Labour Gazette, 2 (January 1902), 415.
(26) For a detailed discussion of the Factories Act see Tucker,
"Keeping the Workplace Safe" and Lorna F. Hurl
"Restricting Child Factory Labour in Late Nineteenth Century
Ontario," Labour/Le Travail, 21 (Spring 1988), 87-121 For the
Minimum Wage Act see McCallum, "Keeping Women in their Place."
While the Factories Act was the first of its kind in Canada, by the time
of the enactment of the Minimum Wage Act, the provinces of Alberta,
Manitoba, British Columbia, Saskatchewan, and Quebec had all established
some form of minimum wage legislation.
(27) Legislation similar to that of the Factories Act was extended
to shops (1888), mines (1890), and bake shops (1895), Canada Department
of Labour, "Legislation with Regard to Child and Female Labour in
Canada," The Labour Gazette, 8 (March 1908), 1100-1120.
(28) Canada Department of Labour, "Minimum Wage Rates for
Women in Ontario in 1928," The Labour Gazette, 29 (August 1929),
885-6; McCallum, "Keeping Women in their Place." In 1922, the
Act was amended to permit the Board to establish a maximum number of
hours to which the minimum weekly wage could be applied, and to
establish overtime rates.
(29) As early as 1881, the first Canadian local of the Knights of
Labor called for the abolition of employment of children under fourteen
years of age in factories, as did the Trades and Labor Congress at its
founding convention in 1883. Hurl "Restricting Child Factory Labour
in Late Nineteenth Century Ontario."; Robert McIntosh,
"Sweated Labour: Female Needleworkers in Industrializing
Canada," Labour/Le Travail, 32 (Fall 1993), 105-38. Social
reformers sought to protect women and children from the threats posed by
the industrial workplace to both their physical health and morality, and
in particular to protect women's role in the process of social
reproduction. Tucker, "Making the Workplace Safe"; Ursel,
Private Lives, Public Policy.
(30) Tucker, "Making the Workplace Safe," 83-4.
(31) For example, the Factories Act contained
"loop-holes" and exemptions that allowed employers to
circumvent the restrictions on hours of work, as well as significant
enforcement problems. See Hurl, "Restricting Child Factory
Labour," and Tucker, "Making the Workplace Safe."
(32) As well, the Minimum Wage Board showed a tendency to be more
cooperative with employers than with labour representatives, first in a
reluctance to prosecute employers who violated the Act and, second, by
developing wage rates primarily in consultation with employers. See
McCallum, "Keeping Women in their Place," and McIntosh,
"Sweated Labour."
(33) Canada Department of Labour, "Recent Developments in
Canadian Labour Legislation," The Labour Gazette, 24 (July 1924),
556.
(34) Bob Russell, "A Fair or a Minimum Wage? Women Workers,
the State, and the Origins in Wage Regulation in Western Canada,"
Labour/Le Travail, 28 (Fall 1991), 59-88.
(35) Dione Brand, No Burden To Carry: Narratives of Black Working
Women in Ontario, 1920s to 1950s (Toronto 1991).
(36) Canada Department of Labour, "Labour Measures At Late
Session of Parliament of Canada," The Labour Gazette, 24 (July
1924), 574-82. This decision led Prime Minister Mackenzie King to
advocate for uniform labour laws across the provinces, since "if
there is not uniformity it very often happens that the particular
province that has higher standards in labour ultimately loses in
consequence of the lower standards that exist in other provinces."
Canada Department of Labour, "Notes on Current Matters of
Industrial Interest--Benefit of Uniform Labour Laws," The Labour
Gazette, 26 (April 1926), 305.
(37) Canada Department of Labour, "Royal Commission on
Dominion-Provincial Relations: Recommendations Concerning Unemployment
Insurance, Labour Legislation, etc.--Demarcation of Jurisdiction in
Social Services," The Labour Gazette, 40 (June 1940), 545-554. The
mandate of the commission was to "re-examine the economic and
financial basis of Confederation and the distribution of legislative
powers in the light of the economic and social developments of the last
70 years." The commission made wide-ranging recommendations in the
areas of unemployment insurance, employment services, provincial
welfare, old age pensions, health insurance, worker's compensation,
and labour legislation.
(38) Canada Department of Labour, Royal Commission on
Dominion-Provincial Relations, 551. The federal government had ratified conventions regarding the eight-hour day, weekly rest periods, and
minimum wage-fixing machinery in 1935. See Allan J. Torobin, "The
Labour Program and the International Labour Organization: Looking Back,
Looking Ahead," Workplace Gazette: An Industrial Relations
Quarterly, 3 (Winter 2000), 85-91. However, the ILO conventions ratified
by the federal government had no legal power within the provinces, as
labour legislation fell under provincial jurisdiction. The primary
significance of the ILO standards for Canadian workers was that such
standards provided an international principle against which to measure
Canadian standards when Canadian labour organizations sought to pressure
provincial governments for improvements to minimum standards
legislation.
(39) Torobin, "The Labour Program and the International Labour
Organization." Between 1938 and 1959, ten of the eleven conventions
ratified by the federal government covered matters of federal
jurisdiction.
(40) Marcus Klee, "Fighting the Sweatshop in Depression
Ontario: Capital, Labour and the Industrial Standards Act," Labour
/ Le Travail, 45 (Spring 2000), 14-15.
(41) Klee notes that some within the business community also
favoured some form of state regulation to "protect them from the
dangers of the free market" during this period. Klee,
"Fighting the Sweatshop in Depression Ontario," 14-15.
(42) Bryan D. Palmer, Working Class Experience: Rethinking the
History of Canadian Labour, 1800 - 1991 (Toronto 1992), 260.
(43) See Craig Heron, The Canadian Labour Movement: A Short History
(Toronto 1996); Nor man Penner, From Protest to Power: Social Democracy
in Canada 1900-Present (Toronto 1992), 66.
(44) The eight-hour day was legislated for workers under federal
jurisdiction in 1930 with the Fair Wages and Eight-Hour Day Act. In
1935, this was replaced with the Fair Wages and Hours of Labour Act,
which established the eight-hour day and 44-hour week for federal
employees. Geoffrey Brennan, "Minimum Wages and Working Time During
the Last Century," Workplace Gazette--Centennial Issue, 3 (Ottawa
2000), 61-73.
(45) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-69, box 2, The Fair Wages and Eight-Hour
Day Act, 1934, 2nd Draft. The 1934 Fair Wages and Eight Hour Day Act
applied to contracts of all departments of the Public Service, the Hydro
Electric Power Commission, and all other provincial commissions
"and like bodies."
(46) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-154, box 5, Report of a Conference Between
Members of the Canadian Manufacturers' Association and Hon. A.W.
Roebuck, K.C., Minister of Labour for the Province of Ontario, 30
January 1935.
(47) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-130, box 4, Memorandum, Re: Minimum Wage,
26 February 1937; Fudge and Tucker, Labour Before the Law.
(48) Klee, "Fighting the Sweatshop in Depression
Ontario," 48.
(49) Canada Department of Labour, "Labour Subjects at Recent
Session of Dominion Parliament," The Labour Gazette, 26 (July
1926), 651-5. But while it adapted convention resolutions that called
for a male minimum wage, organized labour continued to hold concerns
that a male minimum wage could also become a maximum wage. Instead of a
male minimum wage, the province enacted legislation that would provide
workers with "the legal right to organize into a Trade Union of
their own choosing." AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-130, box 4, Letter,
Toronto District Labor Council; Canada Department of Labour,
"Ontario Executive of Trades and Labour Congress Presents
Legislative Program to Provincial Government," The Labour Gazette,
35 (February 1935), 160-1; Canada Department of Labour, "Trades and
Labour Congress of Canada--Summary of the Proceedings of the 42nd Annual
Convention," The Labour Gazette, 26 (October 1926), 971-2.
(50) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-130, box 4, Memorandum, Re: Minimum Wage,
26 February 1937; AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-130, box 4, Letter, From The Board
of Trade of the City of Toronto, 17 March 1937; AO R.G. 7-14, Ministry
of Labour, Legislation and Regulation Files (hereafter MLLR), File
7-14-0-130, box 3, Letter, From Canadian Manufacturers'
Association, To J.F. Marsh, Deputy Minister of Labour, 13 March 1937;
Mayors of Ontario municipalities also called upon the provincial
government to enact a male minimum wage.
(51) When it became clear that minimum wage legislation would not
be used to establish absolute hours restrictions, the CMA too expressed
tentative support for a legislated male minimum wage. AO MLMC, File
7-1-0-154, box 5, Report of the Executive Committee of the Toronto
Branch of the Canadian Manufacturers' Association to the Annual
Meeting of the Branch, Toronto, 28 April 1938.
(52) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-130, box 4, Memorandum, Re: Minimum Wage,
26 February 1937.
(53) Canada Department of Labour, "Notes on Current Matters of
Industrial Interest--Ontario Bill Provides Minimum Wages for Men,"
The Labour Gazette, 37 (March 1937), 264.
(54) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-130, box 4, Letter, David Croll, Minister
of Labour to Toronto District Labour Council, 22 March 1937.
(55) Canada Department of Labour, "Notes on Current Matters of
Industrial Interest--Ontario Bill Provides Minimum Wages for Men,"
The Labour Gazette, 37 (March 1937), 264.
(56) Heron, The Canadian Labour Movement; Stephen McBride and John
Shields, Dismantling a Nation: The Transition to Corporate Rule in
Canada (Halifax 1997).
(57) For typology of welfare state models that developed during the
postwar period see Gosta Esping-Andersen, The Three Worlds of Welfare
Capitalism (Princeton 1990).
(58) Peter S. McInnis, Harnessing Labour Confrontation: Shaping the
Postwar Settlement in Canada, 1943-1950 (Toronto 2002). See also McBride
and Shields, Dismantling a Nation, Chapter Two.
(59) Canadian Manufacturers' Association, The War and After:
Plans, Organization and Work of the Canadian Manufacturers
'Association in Connection with the War and in Preparation for
Conditions after the War (Toronto 1944).
(60) McInnis, Harnessing Labour Confrontation.
(61) McInnis, Harnessing Labour Confrontation.
(62) Canada Department of Labour, "Legislative Proposals of
Labour Organizations," The Labour Gazette, 49 (May 1949), 552-75.
(63) Canada Department of Labour, "Dominion Legislative
Proposals of Canadian Congress of Labour," The Labour Gazette, 42
(March 1942), 291-95; Canada Department of Labour, "Annual
Convention of the Trades and Labour Congress of Canada," The Labour
Gazette, 42 (September 1942), 1040-44.
(64) McInnis, Harnessing Labour Confrontation.
(65) See Fudge and Tucker, Labour Before the Law, 3-4 for a
definition of the legal regime of "industrial pluralism."
(66) See Fudge and Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation,"
275-79, for a discussion of legislative developments in the area of
labour relations during this period.
(67) Fudge, "The Gendered Dimension of Labour Law."
(68) McInnis, Harnessing Labour Confrontation, 185.
(69) Canada Department of Labour, "Labour Legislation in
Ontario and Saskatchewan in 1944," The Labour Gazette, 44 (July
1944); Canada Department of Labour, "Recent Regulations under
Dominion and Provincial Legislation," The Labour Gazette, 44
(September 1944), 1177-81.
(70) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-90, box 3, Ontario Legislative Assembly,
14 February 1951, 3. In the early 1940s, approximately 40 per cent of
male employees and 50 per cent of female employees in Ontario worked 48
hours per week or less. A one week annual vacation with pay was a
generally accepted standard. AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-93, box 3, An Act
Respecting Hour of Work and Vacations with Pay in Industrial
Undertakings, August 1944.
(71) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-854, The Hours of Work and Vacations with
Pay Act, 1964.
(72) Canadian Manufacturers' Association, "Annual
Meetings of Divisions and Provincial and City Branches," Industrial
Canada, 45 (June 1944).
(73) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-93, box 3, Regulations Under The Hours of
Work and Vacations With Pay Act, 1944, 6 July 1944.
(74) Ontario Ministry of Labour, Working Times: The Report of the
Ontario Task Force on Hours of Work and Overtime (Toronto 1987), 25.
(75) Canada Department of Labour, "Annual Conventions of the
Ontario and Quebec Federation of Labour," The Labour Gazette, 68
(February 1968), 78.
(76) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-447, box 10, Memorandum to all Members of
Cabinet Committee, T.M. Eberlee, 1961.
(77) The three zones were as follows: Zone One--Toronto, Hamilton,
Windsor, Ottawa, London, and surrounding municipalities; Zone
Two--municipalities with populations of 3000 and over; and Zone
Three--municipalities with populations under 3000. AO MLLR, File
7-14-0-130, box 3, The Minimum Wage Act, Order No. 2 made by the
Industry and Labour Board under the Act, 1947.
(78) Frank Whittingham, Minimum Wages in Ontario: Analysis and
Measurement Problems (Kingston 1970).
(79) See Panitch and Swartz, Consent to Coercion, Chapter 2.
(80) Judy Fudge and Leah F. Vosko, "Gender, Segmentation and
the Standard Employment Relationship in Canadian Labour Law, Legislation
and Policy," Economic and Industrial Democracy, 22 (May 2001),
271-310.
(81) Fudge and Vosko, "Gender, Segmentation and the Standard
Employment Relationship."
(82) Women workers in the public sector would benefit from the
legislation once public sector workplaces began to unionize. Fudge and
Vosko, "Gender, Segmentation and the Standard Employment
Relationship"; Alan Sears, "The 'Lean' State and
Capitalist Restructuring: Towards a Theoretical Account," Studies
in Political Economy, 59 (Summer 1999), 91-114.
(83) Bryan Palmer notes that over two million immigrants arrived in
Canada between the years of 1946 and 1961, and that these new Canadians
accounted for a significant portion of labour market growth during this
period. Further, many were from eastern and southern Europe, rather than
of British origin, and were predominantly employed in low-wage labour.
See Palmer, Working Class Experience, 305-7. See also Fudge and Tucker,
"Pluralism or Fragmentation," 280-81.
(84) Heron, The Canadian Labour Movement, 78.
(85) For example, a 1960 federal Department of Labour report
recognized that, where women workers were concerned, "[t]he
conditions of work that are offered may be largely determined by the
legal minimum standard." Canada Department of Labour,
"Legislation Affecting Women's Work," The Labour Gazette,
60 (July 1960), 672-74.
(86) Fudge and Vosko, "Gender, Segmentation and the Standard
Employment Relationship."
(87) Ontario, Working Times, 26.
(88) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-90, box 3, Globe and Mail, "Labour
Delegates Clash on Official Coddling," 13 January 1951.
(89) Canada Department of Labour, "Conventions of Labour
Organizations," The Labour Gazette, 47 (November 1947), 1574.
(90) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-90, box 3, Globe and Mail, "Labour
Delegates Clash on Official Coddling," 13 January 1951.
(91) These sentiments were also expressed in debates over the
question of equal pay for women workers at the end of the 1950s. While
some unionists favored equal pay legislation, others saw the
unionization of women workers and the securing of equal pay through
collective bargaining as a more effective solution. Canada Department of
Labour, "Equal Pay for Equal Work," The Labour Gazette, 59
(September 1959), 903-5.
(92) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-90, box 3, Ontario Legislative Assembly,
14 February 1951.
(93) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-90, box 3, Ontario Legislative Assembly,
14 February 1951, 3-4.
(94) AO MLLR, File 7-14-0-90, box 3, Ontario Legislative Assembly,
14 February 1951, 4.
(95) Fudge and Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation?" 282.
(96) Canada Department of Labour, "Equal Pay for Equal
Work," The Labour Gazette, 59 (September 1959), 903-5.
(97) Between 1941 and 1971, women's labour force participation
rate doubled from 20 to 40 per cent. However, this was not uniform
across the labour market. Building on early patterns of gendered
segmentation, this participation was characterized by a concentration of
women in specific occupations (secretarial, service, health) that were
associated with women's "natural" abilities (caring,
cleaning, cooking). Pat Armstrong and Hugh Armstrong, The Double Ghetto:
Canadian Women and their Segregated Work (Toronto 1994). Moreover, at
this point women's rates of unionization remained low relative to
that of men.
(98) Canada Department of Labour, "The 12th Annual Convention
of the Canadian Congress of Labour," The Labour Gazette, 52
(October 1952), 1312-28.
(99) Canada Department of Labour, "Equal Pay for Equal
Work," The Labour Gazette, 59 (September 1959), 904. Along with
pressuring for legislation, unions also attempted to secure equal pay
through collective bargaining, although at the time equal pay provisions
were "not frequent."
(100) Canada Department of Labour, "Equal Pay Legislation in
Canada," The Labour Gazette, 58 (Ottawa 1958), 1227-29.
(101) Canada Department of Labour, "Notes of Current
Interest--Fair Employment Practices and Equal Pay Bills in
Ontario," The Labour Gazette, 51 (April 1951), 443; AO MLMC, File
7-1-0-447, box 10, Memorandum to all Members of Cabinet Committee, T.M.
Eberlee, 1961.
(l02) During the 1950s, similar legislation was enacted in
Saskatchewan, British Columbia, Manitoba, Nova Scotia, Alberta, and at
the federal level. For a discussion of the various provisions of these
acts see Canada Department of Labour, "Labour Legislation of the
Past Decade--III," The Labour Gazette, 61 (February 1961), 140-44.
(103) Fudge and Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation,"
281-82.
(l04) Canada Department of Labour, "Equal Pay for Equal
Work," 903-5.
(l05) See Joan Sangster, "Women Workers, Employment Policy and
the State: The Establishment of the Ontario Women's Bureau,
1963-1970," Labour/Le Travail, 36 (Fall 1995), 133. For a detailed
analysis of pay equity legislation, see Jan Kainer, Cashing In On Pay
Equity? Supermarket Restructuring and Gender Equality (Toronto 2002).
(106) Fudge and Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation?"
277.
(107) Sangster, "Women Workers, Employment Policy and the
State," 131.
(108) H.D. Woods, Canadian Industrial Relations: The Report of the
Task Force on Labour Relations (Ottawa 1968), 35. The Task Force
recommended that future labour standards legislation include minimum
wages set at levels "consistent with a minimum standard of
living," the establishment of a "uniform living wage"
across the country, the extension of wage rates established through
collective bargaining across entire industries, and the introduction of
premium pay for hours worked over 40. See 202-4. For an overview of
labour militancy in the 1960s, see Heron, The Canadian Labour Movement,
92-8, and Palmer Working Class Experience, 320-5. For a discussion of
the "war on poverty" see Palmer, Working Class Experience,
276, 337. See Fudge and Tucker, "Pluralism or Fragmentation?"
283-89 for general developments in labour and employment law in the
context of this heightened militancy.
(l09) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1178, box 37, Labour Standards and
Poverty in Ontario, Ontario Department of Labour, 22 November 1965, 5.
(110) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1182, box 37, Memorandum, to H.L.
Rowntree, Minister of Labour, Re: Proposed Provincial Labour Code, 17
October 1966.
(111) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-447, box 10, Memorandum Re: Meetings of
Cabinet Committee Appointed to Consider a Minimum Wage for Men, 1961.
(112) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-475, box 11, Memorandum, Minimum Wage for
Men, Industry and Labour Board, 1961.
(l13) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-731, box 19, Statement by the Honorable
H.L. Rowntree, Minister of Labour, on the Government's Minimum Wage
Policy, 1-2.
(114) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-447, box 10, Memorandum to all Members of
Cabinet Committee, T.M. Eberlee, 1961, 2
(115) Ursel, Private Lives, Public Policy.
(116) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1189, box 37, Circular #24, The Minimum
Wage Act, Labour Standards Branch, Department of Labour, 1 March 1966.
See also, Whittingon, Minimum Wages in Ontario.
(117) By the early 1960s, the OFL was calling for a general minimum
wage of $1.25 for male and female workers. AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-730, box
19, Legislative Proposals, 1963, To the Prime Minister and Other Members
of the Government of Ontario, Submitted by Ontario Federation of Labour
CLC, 22 February 1963.
(118) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-653, box 16, Report of the Ontario
Division Executive Committee to the 44th Annual Meeting of the Ontario
Division, the Canadian Manufacturers' Association, 2 May 1963.
(119) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-897, box 25, Poverty in Ontario 1965,
Ontario Federation of Labour, 1964. At the time there were over 132,000
workers who were receiving wages below $1.00 per hour. The vast majority
(over 100,000) was in services and trade, and over half were women.
(120) The standards within the Code also included a minimum wage of
$1.25 per hour for both men and women, two weeks of paid vacation per
year, and eight statutory holidays for workers in the federal
jurisdiction. Canada Department of Labour, Canada Labour (Standards)
Code, The Labour Gazette, 64 (December 1964), 1058-63; Human Resources
Development Canada, Workplace Gazette--Centennial Issue, 3 (Winter
2000).
(121) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-992, box 30, Notes for Statement by Hon.
Allan J. MacEachen, Minister of Labour on resumption of debate in the
House of Commons on Bill C-126, The Canada Labour (Standards) Code, 16
February 1965.
(122) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-992, box 30, Bill C-126--Canada Labour
Standards Code, (produced by Ontario Department of Labour), 11 February
1965, 2.
(123) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-992, box 30, Letter, To W.M. McIntyre,
Deputy Minister, Department of the Prime Minister, From H.L. Rowntree,
Minister of Labour, 28 April 1965.
(124) According to the Canadian Labour Congress, the Code's
minimum wage of $1.25 per hour was too low. But while the new labour
code was not perfect, it "seems at least to meet the CLC's
longtime demand for a minimum wage, maximum hours of work, and other
working standards legislation" Canada Department of Labour,
"Annual Briefs to Government," The Labour Gazette, 65 (April
1965), 318-25.
(125) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1322, box 43, Ontario Federation of
Labour Legislative Proposals to the Prime Minister and Other Members of
the Government of Ontario, 1967.
(126) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1322, box 43, Submission of the Ontario
Federation of Labour to Hon. Dalton Bales, Minister of Labour, January
1967.
(127) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1435, box 49, Brief on Women's
Minimum Wage Rates, Submitted by The Congress of Canadian Women, 28
February 1968.
(128) Specifically, they proposed that the legislation be amended
to cover "work of a comparable character done in the same
establishment." AO MLMC, File 7- 1-0-1181, box 37, Report on
Proposed Amendments to the Ontario Human Rights Code.
(129) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1532.3, box 54, Summary of
Representations Made by Associations in regard to the Employment
Standards Act 1968, 1969.
(130) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-872, box 24, Letter, From Building
Products Ltd., To Hon. H.L. Rowntree, Minister of Labour, 9 March 1964.
(131) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1178, box 37, Labour Standards and
Poverty in Ontario, Ontario Department of Labour, 22 November 1965, 5.
(132) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.1, box 47, Minimum Wage Regulations,
1968.
(133) By the mid-1960s, the hours of work for most workers in the
province were well below 48, with the majority working a standard work
week of 40 hours or less. AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.3, box 47, Labour
Standards Act, 1968, Background Memorandum, 25 January 1968.
(134) Ontario was one of the weakest jurisdictions in North America in providing holiday pay or overtime pay. By that time, other provincial
jurisdictions, including Manitoba, Saskatchewan, Alberta, and British
Columbia had two weeks of paid vacation, as compared to one in Ontario.
AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-447, box 10, Memorandum to all Members of Cabinet
Committee, T.M. Eberlee, 1961.
(135) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1178, box 37, Labour Standards and
Poverty in Ontario, Ontario Department of Labour, 22 November 1965.
(136) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.3, box 47, The Labour Standards Act,
Background Memorandum, 25 January 1968.
(137) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1385.1, box 46, Memorandum to: W.M.
McIntyre, Esq., Secretary of the Cabinet, Parliament Buildings, From
Dalton Bales, Minister of Labour, 25 March 1968.
(138) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1021, box 31, "Longer Hours Unlikely
for Lumber Dealers," The Globe and Mail, 27 March 1965; AO MLMC,
File 7-1-0-1021, box 31, Memorandum, From E.G. Gibb, Re: Globe and Mail
Article, 29 March 1965.
(139) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.2, box 47, Memorandum Re: Employment
Standards Act.
(140) A major change that was considered was the introduction of an
overtime premium rate. This was considered preferable to the existing
permits system as it would discourage excess hours of work and provide
protection for workers against unpaid overtime, while still permitting
the scheduling of extra hours. AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1156, box 36,
Memorandum, To Hon. H.L. Rowntree, Minister of Labour, From T.M.
Eberlee, Deputy Minister, 21 October 1966.
(141) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.1, box 47, Employment Standards Act,
1968, 1969. The Act received Cabinet approval on 13 May 1968. It was
given First Reading on 27 May and received Royal Assent on 13 June.
(142) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.2, box 47, Bales' New Labour
Code Includes 1 1/2 overtime
(143) CA' Ontario Department of Labour Information Release, 27
May 1968. O MLMC, File 7-1-0-1532.1, box 54, Notice to Employers and
Employees, 1969.
(144) Canada Department of Labour, "Minimum Standards
Legislation and Economic Policy," The Labour Gazette, 67 (September
1967), 567.
(145) These were New Year's Day, Good Friday, Victoria Day,
Dominion Day, Labour Day, Thanksgiving Day, and Christmas Day.
(146) Ontario, Working Times; Canada Department of Labour,
"News Briefs--Ontario Ups Minimum Wage, Passes New Standards
Act," The Labour Gazette, 69 (January 1969), 27.
(147) Canada Department of Labour, "Recent Regulations Under
Provincial Legislation," The Labour Gazette, 69 (February 1969),
108-10; Canada Department of Labour, "Labour Legislation in
1968-69," The Labour Gazette, 69 (December 1969), 736-45. For
example, different hours of work maximums were established for certain
industries.
(148) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1533.1, box 54, Memorandum, From R.M.
Warren, Executive Director, Manpower Services, 3 February 1969. Canada
Department of Labour, "Labour Standards Legislation in
1967-68," The Labour Gazette, 69 (January 1969), 19-24.
(149) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1581, Legislative Proposals to the
Government of Ontario, 1969, 1. AO MLMC, File 1505.1, box 53,
Legislative Proposals to the Government of Ontario, 1969, Submitted
by--Ontario Federation of Labour.
(150) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1532.2, box 54, "The Minimum Wage
Must be a Living Wage," Toronto Daily Star, 10 July 1969; AO MLMC,
File 7-1-0-1533.1, box 54, "Employment Standards Act Comes Under
Fire as Well," The Oshawa Times, 18 October 1968.
(151) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1532.3, box 54, Summary of
Representations Made by Associations in regard to the Employment
Standards Act 1968, 1969.
(152) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.1, box 47, Letter, to Honorable
Dalton Bales, Minister of Labour, 23 August 1968.
(153) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1506, box 53, Industry '69--Shaping
the '70s, Canadian Manufacturers' Association 98th Annual
General Meeting, June 1969, 30; AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1408.2, Letter, To
Hon. D. A. Bales, 13 September 1968.
(154) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1408.2, Letter, To Hon. D. A. Bales, 13
September 1968.
(155) In a letter to Dalton Bales, the Ontario Chamber of Commerce
stated that "union representatives are quite capable of protecting
the best interests of their members concerning wages, hours of work,
overtime and vacations." AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1408.2, Letter, To
Hon. D. A. Bales, 13 September 1968.
(156) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1407.1, box 47, Notes on Minimum Wage and
Employment Standards Policy.
(157) To indicate the significance of the increase to $1.30, the
government argued that at the time there were 150,000 workers who
received a raise with the implementation of the ESA. AO MLMC, File
7-1-0-1505.1, box 53, Memorandum to Hon. J.P. Robarts, From Dalton
Bales, Minister of Labour, 18 March 1969.
(158) AO MLMC, File 7-1-0-1581, Memorandum to the Minister Re: OFL
Brief, 19 March 1969.
COPYRIGHT 2004 Canadian Committee on Labour History
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2004 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.