Whose preferences are revealed in hours of work?
Pencavel, John
Whose preferences are revealed in hours of work?
I. THE SETTING
When observations on the hours worked by individuals in labor
markets are related to observations on their hourly earnings, what is
the appropriate interpretation of the fitted relationship? This paper
asks this question of the research that measures this relationship. This
research is best understood in the context of a conceptual framework
and, for what follows, I outline this framework briefly. I shall not
take issue with this framework but I do have concerns with the manner in
which it has been applied. The theory I sketch is conventional and it is
the simplest of many variants, some of which may be important in certain
circumstances.
First, consider hours of work from the perspective of the
consumer-worker who has well-behaved preferences over his consumption of
commodities, Q, and his hours of market work, H: U= U(Q, H). He sells
his hours to an employer and thereby becomes an employee. His choices
are assumed to be constrained by a linear budget constraint: p x Q = w x
H + y where p stands for the prices of commodities he consumes, w is
take-home hourly earnings, and y is nonlabor income. In this simple
model, p, w, and y are given to the consumer-worker. Selecting Q and H
so that he does the best he can given his constraints results in
commodity demand and labor supply equations, the latter being
(1) H =f (p, w, y).
This equation describes the employee's budget-constrained
working hours choices. The effect of higher wages on the employee's
choice of hours decomposes into opposite-signed substitution and income
effects and empirical research aims to determine which of these two
effects dominates. Higher nonlabor income is expected to reduce his
preferred working hours.
Second, consider hours of work per worker, H, from the perspective
of an owner-manager. Her demand for hours per worker (and her choice of
the number of workers, N, and of other inputs, Z) results from her
maximization of net revenues: [PI] = q x X (H, N, Z) - wHN - vN - rZ
where q is the price of each unit of output X produced, r is the price
per unit of Z, and v are the costs associated with employing each worker
(such as the costs of hiring and training new workers) and are
independent of H. (1) Assume the production function X(H, N, Z) is
strictly concave and that q, w, v, and r are given to the owner-manager.
The demand equation for hours per worker is
(2) H = g (q, w, v, r).
Under the conditions given, the demand for hours falls when w
rises. (2)
When economists use observations on the working hours and hourly
wages (and perhaps other variables) of individuals or groups, are they
estimating Equation (1) or (2) or some mixture of the two? The exclusion
restrictions should help to discriminate between the two equations: the
demand for hours equation implies that increases in a worker's
nonwage income do not depress hours of work; the supply of hours
equation implies that increases in the price of the output that workers
help to make do not increase work hours. The decision-makers in Equation
(1) are workers while the decision-makers in Equation (2) are
manager-owners.
This paper takes up this question of identification. (3) In so
doing, I survey (very selectively) the research in economics over the
previous 60 years on the hours that individuals devote to market work.
Also, at some places below, I illustrate my points with the use of
observations close at hand on hours and wages. Given the relevance of
income tax revenue to finance government activities, the issue of hours
of work is salient to many questions in public finance and, given the
importance of working hours to workers and employers alike, the topic of
hours of work is pertinent to economists concerned with production and
distribution in a market economy. Research on this topic proceeds at
such a pace that surveys (more thorough than this) are published every
few years. (4)
II. THE ORTHODOXY IS LAUNCHED
Figure 1 traces annual observations from 1890 to 1930 in average
weekly hours of work and average real compensation of production workers
in U.S. manufacturing industry. (5) For much of the period, real wages
rose and hours worked fell. A scatter diagram of the combinations of
annual values of wage rates and weekly hours between 1890 and 1930 is
drawn in Figure 2.
A. Lewis in 1957
In 1957, H. Gregg Lewis offered an explanation for this decline in
the length of the working week until the 1930s. (6) He reasoned as
follows: "To a first approximation," the typical employer
cares about the aggregate hours worked by the firm's entire work
force but, at the given wage, the employer allows each worker to set his
or her own work hours according to the worker's income-leisure
preferences. Expressed differently, in a figure with the real hourly
wage measured on the vertical axis and the average weekly hours worked
on the horizontal axis, the typical employer's demand for an
individual worker's work hours is a horizontal line. This
horizontal demand curve for a worker's hours shifted up over time
as the economy grew and as the derived demand for labor rose.
Assume that the labor supply curve remained unchanged; as Lewis
expressed it, "tastes for leisure are very stable in the long
run." Because hours of work fell as wages rose, this must mean the
worker's labor supply curve is negatively sloped implying the
income effect of wage increases exceeded the substitution effect. (7)
The typical worker chose to respond to wage increases by working fewer
hours. According to Lewis (1957, 72), "employers' preferences
have played only a minor role in the long-run trend of hours of work in
this country." (8) Figure 3 illustrates Lewis' rationalization
of the hours-wages pattern in U.S. manufacturing industry. The parsimony
of Lewis' explanation is appealing: variations in real wages and in
hours worked trace out the typical worker's preferences, a labor
supply curve.
It is not surprising that, within a few years, a Ph.D. thesis at
the University of Chicago (Lewis' academic home at the time) was
written using Lewis' framework to describe variations among
individual workers in their hours of work. I write "not
surprising" because, by many accounts, Lewis was a demanding but
very engaged and generous advisor of graduate students. (9) This
dissertation was written by Marvin Kosters (1966) who used observations
on individual workers from the 1960 Census of Population to relate the
working hours (per week and per year) of married men aged 50-64 years to
their nonlabor income and to their hourly earnings. In this way,
Lewis' proposed explanation for changes in average working hours
over time was converted to an explanation of differences in working
hours among individuals at a given moment.
Representative of Kosters' estimated equations is the
following where H is hours worked of 8,467 husbands in the week
preceding the Census, w is average hourly earnings, and y is nonlabor
income:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
where the dots stand for nine other regressors in the equation
(such as regional dummy variables, demographic indicators, and some
occupational and industry dummy variables). Estimated standard errors
are in parentheses beneath their estimated coefficients.
In the many fitted equations that Kosters reported, the estimate of
the uncompensated wage effect is routinely negative suggesting the
income effect exceeded the substitution effect just as Lewis had
conjectured in his explanation for the decline in average hours between
1890 and 1930 in manufacturing industry. As for the estimated
coefficient on nonlabor income, y, Kosters (1966) wrote, the estimates
"... were very often positive and small when negative" (35).
In fact, "only those regressions for which the sign of the
estimated income coefficient was non-positive were reported ..."
(27).
In many respects, the approach and findings of Kosters'
dissertation typify much of the subsequent cross-section research on the
hours of work of men: the estimated coefficient on hourly earnings
tended to be negative and the estimated coefficient on nonlabor income
was often imprecisely estimated and, on a number of occasions, it was
positive rather than negative. These findings--that [partial
derivative]H/[partial derivative]w < 0 and [partial
derivative]H/[partial derivative]y [greater than or equal to] 0--imply a
nonpositive substitution effect which some would find a cause for
concern for the interpretation of the hours-wage observations as a
conventional labor supply function. (10) Nevertheless, Lewis'
(1957) model for understanding movements in and differences in hours of
work became the norm, usually unquestioned, even though Lewis himself
amended his earlier model to allow for a role for employers to play in
the determination of hours. (11)
B. Lewis in 1969
Lewis' amendment appears in an article published in a
Spanish-language journal in 1969. An English-language version titled
"Employer Interests in Employee Hours of Work" has circulated
for over 40 years. In this later paper, Lewis distinguished between two
types of labor costs: "fixed" costs that varied with the
number of workers such as the costs of searching for, hiring, and
training a worker (12); and costs that varied with hours of work such as
the earnings that increased with hours worked. To economize on the fixed
costs of employment, an employer is inclined to extend the hours of her
work force inducing workers to accept these longer hours with higher
hourly wages. In this 1969 paper, Lewis posited a market wage curve (the
"market equalizing wage curve") whose slope depended on the
underlying preferences of workers and employers. (13) An optimizing
employer selects a wage-hours combination on this market curve.
Similarly, a worker chooses a wage-hours bundle from this "market
equalizing wage curve." According to Lewis' revised model,
normally, observations on hours and wages in a labor market trace out
neither the typical employer's demand function for hours nor the
typical employee's supply function for hours, but the wage-hour
packages that each worker and each employer optimize against. [14]
Lewis' second model was influential, but not in accounting for
differences in hours of work. The model was used by Sherwin Rosen (1974)
in an important paper providing a framework for understanding
"hedonics." This literature addresses the fact that consumer
goods and jobs have attributes and characteristics that are tied to
their prices: one car may have more desirable features than another and
one job may have different nonpecuniary components from another.
Rosen's market hedonic price function in which the price of a
product varies with the quantity of its attribute was formally identical
(as Rosen fully acknowledged) to Lewis' market equalizing wage
curve where employers and workers take as given the market relation
between wages and hours of work. It also figures prominently in
Rosen's (1986) masterful survey on the research on equalizing wage
differentials.
Although Lewis' second model became the paradigm in the
hedonics literature, it had negligible impact on labor supply research
which followed (usually unacknowledged and uncontested) Lewis'
earlier framework and Kosters' application: the dominant line of
research consisted of using cross-section observations (or a time-series
of cross-section observations) to regress the working hours of
individuals on their hourly earnings and other variables with the
estimated parameters interpreted as structural parameters of the typical
worker's preferences. (15)
There were certainly important contributions in this line of
research such as the extension of the model to account for age-related
hours of work choices (Heckman and MaCurdy 1980; MaCurdy 1981), the
coupling of skill acquisition to intertemporal labor supply decisions
(Heckman 1976; Imai and Keane 2004), the explicit conjunction of
consumer demand analysis and labor supply decisions (Abbott and
Ashenfelter 1976), the appropriate treatment of corner solutions to the
worker's optimizing work decision (Heckman 1974), the incorporation
of risk and uncertainty in consumer-workers' decisions (Pistaferri
2003), and the development of so-called collective models of household
decision-making (Browning, Chiappori, and Weiss 2014). In recent years,
much research effort has been devoted to the treatment of nonlinear and,
indeed, nonconvex budget sets, an evident complication if hours of work
reflect the preferences of workers and if workers respond to post-tax
and post-transfer wages and income.
Should economists be confident that the measured relationship
between wages and hours maps the preferences of workers, that is, a
labor supply function? Examine, first, the role of hours in the
production function and, second, the specification of the hours-wage
relationship.
III. HOURS OF WORK IN THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION
Lewis' (1957) solution to the problem of identification was to
posit that the wage-taking employer's demand function for an
employee's hours of work was infinitely elastic with respect to
hours. A horizontal demand function implies a marginal product of hours,
[partial derivative]X/[partial derivative]H, that is independent of
hours. Writing this as [partial derivative]X/[partial derivative]H =
F(Z) where Z stands for inputs other than hours, then, upon integration,
Lewis is assuming X = F(Z)[H.sup.[beta]] where [beta] is unity. (16)
Such a production function might pose problems for a well-defined
interior solution for the canonical price-taking profit-maximizing
production unit which requires the law of diminishing returns to operate
in the neighborhood of the optimum. Nevertheless, is there empirical
support for an exponent on H of unity?
In some research on the estimation of production functions, the
input of labor is measured by the number of workers only; hours of work
are neglected. More frequently, the input of labor is defined as
worker-hours, the product of the number of workers and average hours of
work implying that employment and hours per worker are completely
substitutable. In a small number of cases, average hours of work enter
the production function as a separate input from the number of workers.
One early example of this distinction is Feldstein's (1967) study
of a cross section of British industries. He used a Cobb-Douglas
expression and estimated remarkably (implausibly?) high elasticities of
output with respect to weekly hours worked. (17)
Leslie and Wise (1980) revisited the issue with a time-series of a
cross section of industries. With fixed industry effects, they estimated
more believable output-hours elasticities and, indeed, their preferred
estimate of the output-hours elasticity was significantly less than
unity. Also, they could not reject the hypothesis that the output-hours
elasticity was no different from the output-employment elasticity, a
finding that justified the use of worker-hours as measuring the input of
labor services.
IV. IDENTIFICATION THROUGH PRICES AND WAGES
Consider the following linear-in-the-logarithms annual hours of
work equation fitted to 27 conventionally owned plywood mills in the
state of Washington between 1968 and 1986. There are 134 mill-year
observations. Annual work hours across mills and over time, [H.sub.it]
are regressed on hourly wages [w.sub.it], the price of plywood output
[q.sub.it], and the price of raw material logs [r.sub.it] and fixed mill
effects (expressed by [[mu].sub.i]):
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
Cobb-Douglas production functions with an explicit role for hours
are estimated by DeBeaumont and Singell (1999). Using annual
observations within 20 four-digit manufacturing industries over time
(from 1958 to 1994), they report an estimated coefficient on hours that
is significantly less than unity in 16 of the 20 industries, a result
implying that the marginal product of hours falls as hours increase. A
falling marginal product of hours is consistent with research suggesting
that long hours of work damage workers' health and work
performance. (18) Work fatigue and stress may be more relevant today
than it was a few decades ago in view of the fact that, between 1980 and
2005, the fraction of men working more than 48 hours per week rose from
16.6% to 24.3 %. (19) This increase has been greater for college
graduates and professional workers. Moreover, for some groups of
workers--nurses, medical interns, police officers, truck drivers,
merchant seamen, flight attendants, and aircraft pilots--there are
specific studies into the link between long working hours and fatigue
(sometimes measured by accidents). (20)
Heteroskedastic-robust estimated standard errors are in parentheses
beneath their estimated coefficients. The point estimates of this
equation are consistent with a conventional input demand equation for a
price-taking profit-maximizing firm. Indeed, without imposing the
restriction, these estimates exhibit the zero homogeneity property of
such input demand functions. The negative sign on the logarithm of
hourly earnings is also consistent with a negatively sloped labor supply
curve in which the income effect of higher wages outweighs the
substitution effect, but it requires an ingenious mind to reconcile with
a labor supply function the positive effect of increases in plywood
prices on hours and the negative effect of increases in the price of
logs on hours worked notwithstanding the imprecision of the estimates.
(21)
Unfortunately information on the nonlabor income of the workers is
not available. If it were, it would be informative to add it to the
right-hand side of the hours equation above to test the hypothesis that
the sign of its estimated coefficient is not negative. Each worker in a
given mill in a given year worked the same number of hours as all other
workers. They started and ended work at the same time of day, patterns
that might signal the influence of an employer. (22)
If the regression equation of working hours yielded the result
that, other things equal, workers with greater nonlabor income worked
fewer hours, this might permit the interpretation of this equation as a
labor supply equation. However, if the nonlabor income of these plywood
mill workers were available and the variable were added to the hours
equation above, I suspect (from the evidence of many investigations into
working hours) the estimated coefficient on nonlabor income would be
positive or trivially different from zero as Kosters discovered. (23)
This "perverse" finding is usually attributed to error in
measuring income independent of labor market activity or to its joint
determination with hours in a life cycle context. The frequency with
which it has been necessary to resort to such explanations might have
caused some to question the orthodoxy, but it is understandable for a
researcher to pull back from such a judgment out of concern that others
would not question the orthodoxy but question the researcher's
skills.
One might think that a situation in which an individual received
unexpectedly an inheritance would provide a neat opportunity to measure
the effect of nonlabor income on hours of market work. In fact, the
effect of surprise inheritances on hours of work appears to be mixed
(24) (see Joulfaian and Wilhelm 1994). Somewhat similar to the research
on the effects of unexpected gifts on the work hours of beneficiaries is
the impact of legislated amendments to Social Security benefits that had
the consequence of changing the wealth of particular cohorts. In such an
analysis, Krueger and Pischke (1992) report an undetectable effect of
such changes on the weeks worked of these cohorts.
V. THE CHANGING TEXTBOOKS
Section II opened with Lewis' (1957) explanation for the
decline in hours of work in manufacturing industry from the end of the
nineteenth century to 1930. It may be difficult today to appreciate the
radical change in economists' thinking about working hours that
Lewis' paper brought about. One grasps an inkling of this by
comparing the dominant textbooks before Lewis with the popular textbooks
of today. Textbooks provide a window on prevailing ideas and attitudes
and the labor economics textbooks before 1957 offer explanations for the
decline in work hours that make no mention of competing income and
substitution effects. (25) The contrast with labor economics texts of
today is extraordinary. Contemporary textbooks use the words
"working hours" and "supply of labor" as synonyms.
The notion that working hours is a quantity and the wage rate is a price
so that the interpretation of observations on quantities and prices
requires attention to an identification problem--something that Lewis
explicitly addressed in his work--is not even entertained!
These early texts attributed the decline in hours to trade union
activity and "union-sponsored legislation," explanations that
barely appear in present-day textbooks. (26) If these explanations are
irrelevant, should not those who explicitly or implicitly assume that an
employer's marginal product of working hours is independent of
hours address the historical record of employers resisting workers'
demands for shorter hours? There have been major confrontations between
workers and their employers over the length of the work day and of the
work week. If "employers are completely indifferent with respect to
the hours of work schedules of their employees" (Lewis 1957,
198-99), why did employers oppose so resolutely workers' calls for
shorter hours? (27)
In their discussion of working hours, the earlier generation of
labor economists did consider how hours enter production with one
writing "... reductions in the length of the working day generally
increase the hourly output of workers and may, depending on the
circumstances, cause no decline in total daily output" (Lester
1946, 356). Some years later, this argument was adopted by Edward
Denison (1962) in his well-known study of the contribution of different
factors to U.S. economic growth. In his research on the effects of the
reduction in hours of work, Denison alleged that, in 1929 when average
weekly hours were 49, a reduction in hours would leave output unchanged
whereas in 1957 when hours per week averaged 40, a 10% reduction in
hours would reduce output by only 6%. The results by Pencavel (2014) may
be interpreted as support for Denison's estimates.
Another older text mentioned fatigue as a factor in the setting of
working hours and drew the nonlinear production function that is
reproduced in Figure 4 (Reynolds 1954, 254). In today's textbooks,
in their treatment of hours of work, it is unusual (28) for fatigue and
stress to receive even footnote attention notwithstanding contemporary
evidence that it remains highly relevant for some workers where the
incidence of injuries and illness is associated with long working hours
(Dembe et al. 2005; Ricci et al. 2007).
The older texts provided a historical perspective on reductions in
working hours and suggested patterns that appear to be overlooked in
modern texts. For instance, although the quality of earlier data on
working hours permit only tentative inferences, it does appear as if,
from the first half of the nineteenth century, reductions in the length
of the working day and week came about discontinuously, being unchanged
for a number of years before a discrete and marked decrease. (29) Viewed
from this perspective, the movements in average real wages and average
weekly hours of work in U.S. manufacturing industry from the close of
the Second World War to the late 1970s appear not to be at variance with
this pattern; while real wages reveal a clear modest upward trend over
these years, weekly hours of work are trendless (see Figure 5). Flours
of work are cyclically sensitive but their value at the end of these 30
years is little different from that at the beginning of this period.
(30) Is this combination of rising wages and constant (cycle removed)
hours consistent with "very stable" preferences of workers?
VI. SELF-EMPLOYMENT
The beginning of this paper presented an equation of the hours of
market work from the perspective of an employee, Equation (1), and
second hours of work equation from the perspective of the owner-manager.
Equation (2). This paper has been addressed to the issue (largely
neglected to date) of distinguishing between these two equations in
empirical research. As most workers in the market are employees, the
attention to this class of workers would appear appropriate.
However, there is another class of workers who resemble both the
employee and the employer: the self-employed. If a group of
self-employed collaborate, the resulting arrangement is called a
partnership or a worker co-op or a producer co-op. Either working
individually or in collaboration with others, self-employed workers
interact directly with the consumer without the presence of an
intermediary, the employer.
One natural extension of the earlier reasoning might suggest that a
self-employed worker selects his work hours (H) and the level of
co-operating inputs (Z) to maximize his wellbeing U(Q, H) given his
income-expenditure constraint: p x Q = qX(H, Z) + y - r x Z where X
denotes the amount of commodity or services produced and sold to the
consumer at a price of q per unit. The per unit price of the
co-operating input is r. Any income from the ownership of assets is y.
The worker's strictly concave production function is X(H, Z) and
the unit price of consumption goods is p. Assume, as before, owned and
managed by the workers who worked in them. For over 60 years, these
worker co-ops were the largest and most durable expression of such
organizations in U.S. manufacturing industry. Using 55 mill-year
observations on 11 of these co-ops in the years between 1968 and 1986 in
the state of Washington, an abridged least-squares equation fitted to
the observations on hours per worker and prices yields the following
estimates:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
that the lower-case variables are parametric. The consequence of
this constrained choice of Z and work hours (and, therefore of
consumption goods, Q) can be expressed in equations that, in the case of
work hours, may be written:
(3) H = [phi] (p, q, r, y).
This equation is a mixture of Equations (1) and (2) which is to be
expected now that the intermediary, the employer, has been renounced.
For an application to a group of self-employed workers, return to
the study of plywood manufacturing in the Pacific Northwest from 1968 to
1986 where between one-third and one-half of the plywood produced came
from mills that were where j denotes a given mill and t identifies the
year and where heteroskedastic-robust standard errors are beneath their
relevant coefficients. This is an abridged version of Equation (3)
because observations on y, the flow of income from the mill's
reserves (or the nonlabor income of the individual workers), are
lacking. Subject to this important omission, the estimated equation
resembles a firm's output supply function: hours of work are
positively associated with the price of output and negatively associated
with the price of the cooperating input. The equation is also
homogeneous of degree zero in p, q, and r.
There is no hourly wage rate in this specification; it is jointly
determined with the choice of hours of work. However, a wage rate was
paid to each of these workers and it was equal to [[N x (H).sup.-1]
[qX(H, Z) r x Z - C] where N stands for the number of member-workers and
C measures fixed costs such as the payment of interest on debt or the
addition to reserves. (31) It appears to be the case that when the
hourly wage is defined in this way, it is negatively associated with
hours of work but the association is weak and, over the central tendency
of hours, hours vary little with hourly wages. (32) With other
self-employed workers, the association between hourly wages and work
hours will depend on how hourly wages vary with the prices of output and
of cooperating inputs and this association is likely to vary from one
activity to another.
VII. TWO CLASSES OF RESEARCH THAT RECOGNIZE THE DEMAND FOR HOURS
A. Hours and Business Cycles
A role for employers' preferences in the determination of
hours of market work that appears to be widely acknowledged concerns
business cycle movements in hours. A well-established pattern is that
hours are pro-cyclical and, moreover, that movements in hours precede
turning points in business activity (production, sales, and new orders).
(33) A cut in the working hours of employees tends to be among
employers' first reactions to the over-accumulation of inventories
and to the weakening of new orders. Because the reductions in hours in a
contraction tend to affect lower wage unskilled workers more than the
higher wage skilled workers, the observed hours-wage pattern in a cross
section may well differ according to the stage of the cycle to which the
cross section relates and to the skills of the workers.
This may also affect micro-economic research exploiting panel data
such as is common in applications of life cycle models. Indeed, in one
specification of Frisch's substitution elasticity, MaCurdy (1981)
adds calendar year dummy variables (ostensibly to account for variations
in the rate of interest but which may be interpreted as absorbing the
effects of the business cycle). The consequence of this for his first
differenced hours of work equation is to render the point estimate on
wage changes to be smaller than its estimated standard error. In this
instance, the hypothesis that there is no intertemporal substitution of
hours as individuals' age cannot be rejected by conventional
criteria. (34)
B. Minimum Wage Effects on Hours
The literature on the association between hourly earnings and hours
of work includes the effect of changes or differences in statutory
minimum wages on the hours worked of affected employees. This class of
research usually frames the issue without reference to labor demand or
to labor supply. There are some instances in which it is assumed the
impact of a higher minimum wage must reflect the reaction of an
employer, but this assumption is often not used to place a restriction
on the set of other variables in the hours of work equation. A variety
of different regressors--the logic for which is not always clear--are
included when measuring the association between working hours and hourly
(minimum) wages. As a consequence of this variety perhaps, there is an
assortment of findings on the effects on hours of minimum wages ranging
from negative effects to no discernible effects. (35) Would this range
be narrowed if a behavioral model were drawn upon to discipline the
choice of regressors?
VIII. EMPLOYERS' CONSTRAINTS ON EMPLOYEES' HOURS CHOICES
Recognizing a role for the influence of employers' preferences
on working hours not only may help to reconcile existing divergent
results, but the literature on "rationing" in hours can be
provided with a conventional theoretical underpinning. That is, some
researchers have expressed discomfort with the assumption that the
association between working hours and wage rates reflects the
preferences of workers and of workers only. These scholars have
speculated that some employees' work preferences are constrained by
employers such that employees work more or fewer hours than they prefer
at their observed wage rates. (36) Indeed, when asked whether they would
choose different hours (at the same hourly wage rate) from those they
are currently working, many respond they would choose more or fewer
hours (Golden and Gebreselassie 2007; Stewart and Swaffield 1997).
Notwithstanding the plausibility of these employer mandates,
testing for these constraints has been frustrated by the difficulty of
specifying where these hours constraints come from and, consequently,
from the fact that differences and variations in the extent of rationing
are unobserved. A natural postulate is that variations in
employers' mandates come from variations in their product prices
(or marginal revenues), in the prices of their nonlabor inputs, and in
their input-output technology.
Expressed differently, employers' effects on hours of work are
not capricious or inexplicable but are systematic and related to their
production and price environments. In this way, the literature on
employer restrictions on work hours does not need to abandon the
conventional labor supply model as a characterization of the hours'
preferences of workers. It is the application of the labor supply model
that is wanting. The conventional model of labor supply needs to be
married to conventional models of employers' preferences to derive
a meaningful explanation of the variations in hours of work and wages
before it is possible to assess the empirical performance of the
neoclassical approach to hours of work.
IX. WHAT IS TYPICALLY ESTIMATED-THE HYBRID EQUATION?
The argument above has tended to present the issue as one in which
the hours-wage observations correspond either to a demand for hours
function or to a supply of hours function. In circumstances in which the
work setting might provide a strong a priori case for one or the other,
such an unambiguous determination might be appropriate. Typically,
however, researchers report little about the work environment of
employees and they put together samples of large numbers of workers in
many different workplaces and, subject to certain demographic
characteristics such as gender, age, and marital status, a single
equation is fitted to a disparate set of observations. In many cases, I
suspect, the fitted equation is neither a supply of hours equation that
embodies the work-income preferences of workers nor a demand for hours
equation that connotes the constrained objectives of employers, but some
mixture of the two.
A simple expression of this hybrid equation assumes conveniently
log-linear hours-wage relationships. Suppose, as is typical, a large
number of workers are observed and the demand for hours equation of
these workers takes the form of
log [H.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1] log [w.sub.i] +
[[alpha].sub.2] [X.sup.D.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sup.D.sub.i]
where [[alpha].sub.1], < 0. [X.sup.D.sub.i] represents
predetermined variables such as the prices of output and inputs and firm
or industry specific effects that shift the demand for hours function.
The effects of the production technology on hours worked are also
embedded in [X.sup.D.sub.i]. Analogously let the supply of hours
equation for these workers be
log [H.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] log [w.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.2] [X.sup.S.sub.i] + [[epsilon].sup.S.sub.i]
where [[beta].sub.1] may be positive or negative. [X.sup.S.sub.i]
are predetermined variables such as nonlabor income that shift the
supply of hours function in addition to variables believed to be
associated with differences across workers in preferences. Omitted
stochastic elements are represented by [[epsilon].sup.D.sub.i] and
[[epsilon].sup.S.sub.i].
Suppose [lambda] is the fraction of these workers whose hours
conform to the demand function leaving the remaining fraction 1 -
[lambda] of workers who work the hours that satisfy their constrained
preferences. Multiplying the demand for hours equation by [lambda],
multiplying the supply of hours equation by 1 - [lambda], and adding the
resulting two equations yields (4)
log [H.sub.i] = [[gamma].sub.0] + [delta] log [w.sub.i] +
[[gamma].sub.1] [X.sup.D.sub.i] + [[gamma].sub.2] [X.sup.S.sub.i] +
[u.sub.i]
where [delta] = [[lambda] [[alpha].sub.1] (l - [lambda]])
[[beta].sub.1] and [u.sub.i] incorporates both [[epsilon].sup.D.sub.i]
and [[epsilon].sub.S.sub.i]. [delta] may be positive or negative. If it
is interpreted as the elasticity of hours with respect to wages in a
supply of hours of work function, then [delta] underestimates the key
parameter of employees' preferences, [[beta].sub.1], unless
[lambda] is zero. Unfortunately, the value of [lambda] is unknown though
it would be audacious to maintain it is zero.
If scholars are fitting Equation (4), then differences and
variations in [lambda] may be related not to differences in the
work-earnings preferences of employees (i.e., [[beta].sub.1]) as many
researchers assume but to differences and variations in [lambda]. To
pursue this possibility, perhaps the most consistent result in this
literature is that [delta] is positive for women and that [delta] is
less, perhaps negative, for men. This could mean that [[beta].sub.1]
differs between women and men or it could mean that preferences are the
same but [lambda] is smaller for women than for men. It is difficult to
know if this is the case without some knowledge or guesses about the
magnitudes of [lambda] for men and women.
Perhaps workplaces where workers are highly interdependent and
complementary for one another and where starting and ending times for
work are the same for all employees might signal a situation in which
employers unilaterally specify the hours that their employees work. In
such workplaces, employees work with high levels of physical capital and
the costs of using the machinery are greater when employees are not
working together at the same time. An assembly line in a manufacturing
plant may come close to the prototype of this workplace.
There remain noticeable differences between men and women in the
industries and occupations in which they work and possibly these are, in
turn, related to X. For instance, about 17% of all employed men work in
"production, transportation, and material moving occupations";
only 5% of employed women work in these occupations. About 14% of all
employed men work in manufacturing industry compared with 6% of all
women. A sector in which women employees outnumber men is work in
non-profit organizations, workplaces that, I conjecture, are more
amenable to accommodating individuals' hours of work preferences.
These are guesses of workplaces where the estimate of [delta] in
Equation (4) may reflect the value of X rather than that of
[[beta].sub.1]. In short, the positive values of [delta] often estimated
for women workers imply that women work in activities in which their
work preferences are accommodated by their employers.
Several scholars have reported that, for women, the hours-wage
partial correlation has weakened in recent decades. (37) Does this mean
that the work-income preferences of women are altering or that the value
of [lambda] is changing such that an increasing fraction of women are
working in jobs where employers' preferences over hours dominate?
One research study that recognizes the relevance of employers'
preferences for hours is Blundell, Brewer, and Francesconi (2008) who
examine the working hours responses of unmarried women to shocks in the
monetary returns to their market work. In this case, over a 2-year
period, about one-fifth of the women altered their working hours by
changing their employer whereas "there is little evidence of
systematic labor supply induced movements within jobs" (2008, 450);
that is, following shocks to their budget constraints, 80% of these
women did not switch employers and their working hours did not change.
If their work preferences were satisfied before the changes in their
budget constraints, are they now working at an undesirable number of
hours? Or are the labor supply functions of 80% of these women totally
inelastic with respect to their net returns to market work?
X. CONCLUSION
In this selective review of research since the 1970s on what has
become known as "labor supply," I opened with Gregg
Lewis' explanation for the decline in working hours since the end
of the nineteenth century to 1930. I did not do so because I disagree
with his explanation. The notion that, in the nineteenth and early
twentieth centuries, American workers took some of their real wage
increases in the form not of higher consumption but in the form of
shorter hours of work is appealing provided the various ways in which
the expression of this choice are recognized. That is, I do not view the
demands by trade unions for lower working hours and the statutory
restrictions on hours as alternative explanations but as highly
complementary explanations. Union pressure and legislative mandates were
manifestations of workers' preferences.
By contrast, Lewis did express his argument in a form in which
union activity and statutory restrictions on hours were alternative
explanations. One might see his presentation as preferable on the
grounds that trade union activity and government legislation are
unnecessary components of an explanation. Or one may view union activity
and legislation as providing a richer explanation by providing the
mechanism by which workers' preferences were put into action. (38)
The reason that Lewis' argument has occupied an important role
in this review is because his simple model has provided the intellectual
justification for a vast amount of research on the issue of the relation
between hours of work, hourly earnings, and other variables--even
though, in later work, Lewis himself put forward a very different
characterization of the labor market. However, the appeal of Lewis'
earlier, simple, model has proved irresistible to a whole generation of
researchers who have forgotten the need to address the fundamental
identification problem that Lewis recognized.
This paper has been concerned with whether the association between
hours of work and wages reflects the preferences of workers or the
preferences of employers or some mixture of the two. This is not a new
issue. For instance, it was raised explicitly by Martin Feldstein (1968)
and by Sherwin Rosen (1969) almost 50 years ago. Abbott and Ashenfelter
(1976) may have been the last study of hours of work that referred to
the issue.
Feldstein (1968) reasoned that, if observations on hours and wages
were restricted to a single labor market in which differences among
workers' supply curves were small compared with the differences in
employers' demand curves, the supply function would be identified.
He proceeded to use observations on workers in a single occupation in a
single industry in a single region. He admitted that his subsequent
estimates allowed for the interpretation that "the identification
problem persists" (1968, 78).
Using observations on industries, Rosen (1969) specified demand and
supply equations for hours per worker using familiar omitted variable
restrictions to distinguish the two equations. For example, the fraction
of workers covered by collective bargaining agreements is assumed to
affect the demand for hours and not the supply whereas workers'
nonwage income appears in the supply equation but not the demand. Both
the demand for hours and the supply of hours were negatively related to
the hourly wage although demand was more wage-responsive than supply.
Once again, variations in nonwage income were uncorrelated with hours
per worker. "Demand seems to fit the data better than supply"
wrote Rosen (1969, 269).
If the issue of distinguishing between the supply of work hours and
the demand for work hours was worthy of attention in the late 1960s and
1970s, why did it disappear over the next 40 years? The character of the
research became one of measuring the parameters of a presumed
relationship, not of testing hypotheses that the relationship described
one structural equation and not the other. Was this a safer line of
inquiry than one that questioned the interpretation of the estimated
relationship?
I am not suggesting that the vast quantity of research on hours and
wages that is presumed to map the preferences of workers is worthless;
much of it is both plausible and appealing as a description of the
supply of labor. I am proposing that research on hours of work would be
enriched if some effort were directed to confirming that the fitted
equations describe one set of preferences or the other. If a regression
of hours of work on wages and nonwage income yields a positive or zero
coefficient on nonwage income, the researcher needs to question the
interpretation of the relationship as a labor supply equation. If,
moreover, the hours of work of individuals appear to be associated with
the prices of inputs and output at their workplaces, the case
strengthens for this hours-wage relationship as a demand for labor
equation. It would be an advance if a fitted hours-wage relation were
not presented as a labor supply function as a matter of faith but if its
interpretation as a mapping of employees' working hours'
preferences were corroborated with some empirical tests.
Once the presumption that the hours-wage relation represents the
preferences of workers only is discarded, the question of the relevant
control variables in the hours equation can be reconsidered. The usual
procedure has been to draw upon large data sets on individual workers
such as the Current Population Survey or the Census of Population and to
permit gender, age, and marital status differences in the hours-wage
relation, but little more. But for their age, gender, marital status,
and wage rates, are the work preferences of agricultural workers in
California really the same as those of university teachers in
Massachusetts? Rarely are such assumptions tested.
When a role for the demand for hours is accepted, the practice of
ignoring types of workplaces and work environments becomes less tenable.
Behind the demand for hours lies the production technology and the
objectives of the employer so that knowledge of the institutional
setting becomes relevant to a description of differences in hours across
workers. Some of the most effective and plausible research on working
hours has been undertaken on workers where the nature of the work, the
character of the workplace, and the types of workers are carefully
spelled out and where a persuasive case can be made for the homogeneity
of the agents' preferences. (39)
Moreover, refocusing on working hours from the perspective of the
employer may offer other insights. For instance, it has become customary
to allow for fixed costs of employment (as contained in Equation (2)
above): these labor costs vary with the number of workers but do not
vary with their hours. (40) There are also labor costs that vary with
hours but do not vary with employment. These include not only premium
hourly earnings for overtime hours but also the ancillary costs of
heating, ventilating, and lighting buildings for longer, operating
machines for longer, and paying supervisory workers higher earnings for
their longer work hours. Furthermore, the cost of accidents, injuries,
and errors tends to rise with hours, a link recognized in earlier texts.
There is much more to be done on hours of work. Economists should
cease calling hours-wage regressions "labor supply" research.
Do not imitate the economist surveying research in 1986 on the hours,
work, and wages of men who titled his paper "Labor Supply of
Men." Unless the identification problem is addressed, let the title
be "Hours of Work and Wages of Men" or "Market Work
Behavior of Men and Their Wages"!
doi: 10.1111/ecin.12276
REFERENCES
Abbott, M., and O. Ashenfelter. "Labour Supply, Commodity
Demand, and the Allocation of Time." Review of Economic Studies,
43(3), 1976, 389-411.
Altonji, J. G., and C. H. Paxson. "Labor Supply Preferences,
Hours Constraints, and Hours-Wage Trade-Offs." Journal of Labor
Economics, 6, 1988, 254-76.
Ashenfelter, O., K. Doran, and B. Schaller. "A Shred of
Credible Evidence on the Long-Run Elasticity of Labour Supply."
Economica, 77(308), 2010, 637-50.
Bargain, O., K. Orsini, and A. Peichl. "Comparing Labor Supply
Elasticities in Europe and the United States." Journal of Human
Resources, 49(3), 2014, 723-838. Becker, G. S. Human Capital. New York:
Columbia University Press, 1964.
Bell, L. A. "Differences in Work Hours and Hours Preferences
by Race in the U.S." Review of Social Economy, 56(4), 1998,
481-500.
Biddle, J. E. "H. Gregg Lewis," in American Economists of
the Late Twentieth Century, edited by W. J. Samuels. Cheltenham: Edward
Elgar, 1996, 174-93.
Bienefeld, M. A. "Working Hours in British Industry: An
Economic History." L.S.E. Research Monographs, Weidenfeld and
Nicolson, London, 1972.
Bishop, K., B. Heim, and K. Mihaly. "Single Women's Labor
Supply Elasticities: Trends and Policy Implications." Industrial
and Labor Relations Review, 63(1), 2009, 146-68.
Blau, F. D., and L. M. Kahn. "Changes in the Labor Supply
Behavior of Married Women: 1980-2000." Journal of Labor Economics,
25(3), 2007, 393-438.
Blundell, R., and T. MaCurdy "Labor Supply: A Review of
Alternative Approaches, " in Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3A,
edited by O. Ashenfelter and D. Card. Amsterdam, The Netherlands:
North-Holland Elsevier, 1999, 1559-695.
Blundell, R., and I. Walker. "Modelling the Joint
Determination of Household Labour Supplies and Commodity Demands."
The Economic Journal, 92(366), 1982, 351-64.
Blundell, R., M. Brewer, and M. Francesconi. "Job Changes and
Hours Changes: Understanding the Path of Labor Supply Adjustment."
Journal of Labor Economics, 26(3), 2008, 421-53.
Brown, j. R., C. C. Code, and S. J. Weisbenner. "The Effect of
Inheritance Receipt on Retirement." Review of Economics and
Statistics, 92(2), 2010, 425-34.
Browning, M., A. Deaton, and M. Irish. "A Profitable Approach
to Labor Supply and Commodity Demands over the Life-Cycle."
Econometrica, 53(3), 1985, 503-44.
Browning, M., P.-A. Chiappori, and Y. Weiss. Economics of the
Family. New York: Cambridge University Press, 2014.
Bry, G. "The Average Workweek as an Economic Indicator."
National Bureau of Economic Research Occasional Paper 69, New York,
1959.
Cahill, M. C. Shorter Hours. New York: Columbia University Press,
1932.
Cahuc, P., S. Carcillo, and A. Zylberberg. Labor Economics. 2nd ed.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2014.
Card, D. "Labor Supply with a Minimum Hours Threshold."
Camegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 33, 1990, 169-92.
Connolly, S., and M. Gregory. "The National Minimum Wage and
Hours of Work: Implications for Low Paid Women." Oxford Bulletin of
Economics and Statistics, 64, 2002, 607-31.
Couch, K. A., and D. C. Wittenberg. "The Response of Hours of
Work to Increases in the Minimum Wage." Southern Economic Journal,
68(1), 2001, 171-77.
Craig, B., and J. Pencavel. "The Behavior of Worker
Cooperatives: The Plywood Companies of the Pacific Northwest."
American Economic Review, 82(5), 1992, 1083-105.
DeBeaumont, R., and L. D. Singell Jr. "The Return to Hours and
Workers in U.S. Manufacturing: Evidence on Aggregation Bias."
Southern Economic Journal, 66(2), 1999, 336-52.
Dembe, A. E., J. B. Erickson, R. G. Delbos, and S. M. Banks.
"The Impact of Overtime and Long Work Hours on Occupational
Injuries and Illnesses: New Evidence from the United States."
Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine, 62(9), 2005, 588-97.
Denison, E. F. The Sources of Economic Growth in the United States
and the Alternatives Before Us. New York: Committee for Economic
Development, 1962.
Dickens, W. T, and S. J. Lundberg. "Hours Restrictions and
Labor Supply." International Economic Review, 34(1), 1993, 169-92.
Douglas, P. H. Real Wages in the United States, 1890-1926. Boston:
Houghton Mifflin, 1930.
--. The Theory of Wages. New York: Macmillan, 1934,
Ehrenberg, R. G. Fringe Benefits and Overtime Behavior. Lexington,
KY: D.C. Heath and Co., 1971.
Farber, H. S. "Is Tomorrow Another Day? The Labor Supply of
New York City Cab Drivers." Journal of Political Economy, 113(1),
2005, 46-82.
Feldstein, M. S. "Specification of the Labour Input in the
Aggregate Production Function." Review of Economic Studies, 34(4),
1967, 375-86.
--. "Estimating the Supply Curve of Working Hours."
Oxford Economic Papers, 20(1), 1968, 74-80.
Golden, L. "The Effects of Working Time on Productivity and
Firm Performance: A Research Synthesis Paper." Conditions of Work
and Employment Branch, Series No. 33, International Labour Office,
Geneva, 2012.
Golden, L., and T. Gebreselassie. "Overemployment Mismatches:
The Preference for Fewer Work Hours." Monthly Labor Review, April,
2007, 18-37.
Hamermesh, D. S. Labor Demand. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 1993.
Heckman, J. J. "Shadow Prices, Market Wages, and Labor
Supply." Econometrica, 42(4), 1974, 679-94.
--. "A Life-Cycle Model of Earnings, Learning, and
Consumption." Journal of Political Economy, 84(4), 1976, S11-44.
Heckman, J. J., and T. E. MaCurdy. "A Life Cycle Model of
Female Labor Supply." Review of Economic Studies, 47(1), 1980,
47-74.
Heim, B. T. "The Incredible Shrinking Elasticities:Married
Female Labor Supply, 1978-2002." Journal of Human Resources, 42(4),
2007, 881-918.
van der Hulst, M. "Long Workhours and Health."
Scandinavian Journal of Work, Environment & Health, 29(3), 2003,
171-88.
Imai, S., and M. P. Keane. "Intertemporal Labor Supply and
Human Capital Accumulation." International Economic Review, 45(2),
2004, 601-41.
Jones, E. B. "New Estimates of Hours of Work Per Week and
Hourly Earnings, 1900-1957." Review of Economics and Statistics,
45(4), 1963, 374-85.
Joulfaian, D., and M. Wilhelm. "Inheritance and Labor
Supply." Journal of Human Resources, 29(4), 1994, 1205-34.
Kahn, S., and K. Lang. "The Effect of Hours Constraints on
Labor Supply Estimates." Review of Economics and Statistics, 93,
1991, 605-11.
Keane, M. P. "Labor Supply and Taxes: A Survey." Journal
of Economic Literature, 59(4), 2011, 961-1075.
Kinoshita, T. "Working Hours and Hedonic Wages in the Market
Equilibrium." Journal of Political Economy, 95(6), 1987, 1262-77.
Kosters, M. H. Income and Substitution Effects in a Family Labor
Supply Model P-3339. Santa Monica, CA: The Rand Corporation, 1966.
Krueger, A. B., and J.-S. Pischke. "The Effect of Social
Security on Labor Supply: A Cohort Analysis of the Notch
Generation." Journal of Labor Economics, 10(4), 1992, 412-37.
Kuhn, P., and F. Lozano. "The Expanding Workweek?
Understanding Trends in Long Work Hours among U.S. Men, 1979-2006."
Journal of Labor Economics, 26(2), 2008, 311-43.
Leslie, D., and J. Wise. "The Productivity of Hours in U.K.
Manufacturing and Production Industries." The Economic Journal,
90(357), 1980, 74-84.
Lester, R. Economics of Labor. 2nd ed. New York: Macmillan, 1946.
Lewis, H. G. "Hours of Work and Hours of Leisure," Paper
presented at the Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Meeting of the
Industrial Relations Research Association, Madison, WI, 1957, 196-206.
--. "Employer Interests in Employee Hours of Work."
Cuadernos de Economia, 6(18), 1969, 38-54.
MaCurdy, T. E. "An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a
Life-Cycle Setting." Journal of Political Economy, 89(6), 1981,
1059-85.
Manning, A. "Labour Supply, Search and Taxes." Journal of
Public Economics, 80(3), 2001,409-34.
McClelland, R., and S. Mok. "A Review of Recent Research on
Labor Supply Elasticities." Working Paper No. 2012-12,
Congressional Budget Office, Washington, DC, 2012.
Meghir, C., and D. Phillips "Labour Supply and Taxes," in
Dimensions of Tax Design: The Mirrlees Review, edited by S. Adam, T.
Besley, R. Blundell, S. Bond, R. Chote, M. Gammie, P. Johnson, G. Myles,
and J. Poterba. Oxford and London: Oxford University Press, 2010,
202-74.
Moffitt, R. "The Tobit Model, Hours of Work and Institutional
Constraints." Review of Economics and Statistics, 64, 1982, 510-15.
Neumark, D., M. Schweitzer, and W. Wascher. "Minimum Wage
Effects throughout the Wage Distribution." Journal of Human
Resources, 39(2), 2004, 425-50.
Officer, L. H. Two Centuries of Compensation for U.S. Production
Workers in Manufacturing. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2009.
Oi, W. Y. "Labor As a Quasi-Fixed Factor." Journal of
Political Economy, 70(6), 1962, 538-55.
Pencavel, J. "Labor Supply of Men: A Survey," in Handbook
of Labor Economics, Vol. I, edited by O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard.
Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland, 1986, 3-102.
--. "The Productivity of Working Hours." The Economic
Journal, 2014, Oct. 9. [Epub ahead of print]. DOI: 10.1111/ecoj.12166.
--. "The Labor Supply of Self-Employed Workers: The Choice of
Working Hours in Worker Co-Ops." Journal of Comparative Economics,
Forthcoming.
Pencavel, J., and B. Craig. "The Empirical Performance of
Orthodox Models of the Firm: Conventional Firms and Worker
Cooperatives." Journal of Political Economy, 102(4), 1994, 718-44.
Pistaferri, L. "Anticipated and Unanticipated Wage Changes,
Wage Risk, and Intertemporal Labor Supply." Journal of Labor
Economics, 21(3), 2003, 729-54.
Rebitzer, J. B., and L. J. Taylor. "Do Labor Markets Provide
Enough Short-Hour Jobs? An Analysis of Work Hours and Work
Incentives." Economic Inquiry, 33(2), 1995, 257-73.
Rees, A. "H. Gregg Lewis and the Development of Analytical
Labor Economics." Journal of Political Economy, 84(4), 1976, S3-S8.
Reynolds, L. G. Labor Economics and Labor Relations. 2nd ed. New
York: Prentice-Hall, 1954.
Ricci, J. A., E. Chee, A. L. Lorandeau, and J. Berger.
"Fatigue in the U.S. Workforce: Prevalence and Implications for
Lost Productive Work Time." Journal of Occupational and
Environmental Medicine, 49(1), 2007, 1-10.
Rosen, S. "On the Interindustry Wage and Hours
Structure." Journal of Political Economy, 77(2), 1969, 249-73.
--. "Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product
Differentiation in Pure Competition." Journal of Political Economy,
82(1), 1974, 34-5.
-. "The Theory of Equalizing Differences," in Handbook of
Labor Economics, Vol. I, edited by O. Ashenfelter and R. Layard.
Amsterdam, The Netherlands: North-Holland, 1986, 641-92.
--. "H. Gregg Lewis and Modern Labor Economics." Journal
of Labor Economics, 12(1), 1994, 139-43.
Saez, E., J. Slemrod, and S. Giertz. "The Elasticity of
Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates." Journal of
Economic Literature, 50(1), 2012, 3-50.
Shiells, M. "Hours of Work and Shiftwork in the Early
Industrial Labor Markets of Great Britain, the United States and
Japan." Ph.D. dissertation, University of Michigan, 1985.
Stewart, M. B., and J. K. Swaffield. "Constraints on the
Desired Hours of Work of British Men." The Economic Journal,
107(441), 1997, 520-35.
--. "The Other Margin: Do Minimum Wages Cause Working Hours
Adjustments for Low-Wage Workers?" Economica, 75(297), 2008,
148-67.
Weiss, Y. "Synchronization of Work Schedules."
International Economic Review, 37(1), 1996, 157-79.
Working, E. J. "What Do Statistical 'Demand Curves'
Show?" Quarterly Journal of Economics, 41(2), 1927, 212-35.
Working. H. "The Statistical Determination of Demand
Curves." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 39(4), 1925, 503-43.
Wright, P. G. "Review of Henry Schultz: Statistical Laws of
Demand and Supply." Journal of the American Statistical
Association, 24(166), 1929, 207-15.
Zavodny, M. "The Effect of the Minimum Wage on Employment and
Hours." Labour Economics, 7, 2000, 729-50.
(1.) Because observations on v are often lacking, occupational
variables are used as surrogates faute de mieux. See Rosen (1969) for an
example. If the firm is not a price-taker in the product market,
variables such as consumers' incomes or the prices of substitutable
or complementary products replace q.
(2.) For a fuller discussion of the demand for hours, see Hamermesh
(1993).
(3.) Lest I am characterized as a Johnny-come-lately (pun intended)
on this matter, I wrote 30 years ago, "In an econometric exercise
associating quantities (hours of work) and prices (wage rates), prior to
estimation it is appropriate to enquire whether what is being estimated
is a supply function, a demand function, or some hybrid." (Pencavel
(1986, 59). In fact, it is rare for a researcher to so enquire.
(4.) In the last 15 years, surveys include Blundell and MaCurdy
(1999), Meghir and Phillips (2010), Keane (2011), McClelland and Mok
(2012), Saez, Slemrod, and Giertz (2012), and Bargain, Orsini, and
Peichl (2014). Keane's (2011) authoritative survey lists 117
references.
(5.) This series on working hours (based on material put together
by Paul A. Douglas 1930) conceals important differences among classes of
workers and industrial groups both in levels and the timing of changes.
For example, hours in iron and steel were consistently higher than these
figures and changes in iron and steel came later than other
manufacturing industries. See Shiells (1985).
(6.) Lewis' teacher, Paul Douglas (1934), had devoted a
chapter of his The Theory of Wages to the association between weekly
hours of work and hourly earnings using both cross-section (across
industries in given years) and time series (across years within given
industries) observations. His consistent finding was that the two
variables were negatively correlated. Even though identification issues
had been addressed for some years by scholars such as Working (1925),
Working (1927), and Wright (1929), unlike Lewis, Douglas does not
address the identification problem and simply assumes his estimates
describe the preferences of the typical worker.
(7.) If the annual observations in Figure 2 are used in a
least-squares regression of the logarithm of weekly hours on the
logarithm of real hourly compensation for the years 1890-1930, the
estimated coefficient on hourly earnings is -0.269 with an estimated
standard error of 0.016.
(8.) Lewis (1957, 73) recognized that "periods of substantial
unemployment or effective legislation affecting hours of work per
head" would interfere with the identification of the average
worker's supply of work hours curve from observations on wages and
hours of work. This is why observations from the 1930s and the Second
World War are omitted from Figures 1 and 2.
(9.) Read the depictions of Lewis by Rees (1976) and Rosen (1994)
in the essays written by his colleagues and students. Also see Biddle
(1996).
(10.) Even with a positive value of the uncompensated wage effect,
a positive substitution effect may not be implied if the effect of
nonlabor income on hours if sufficiently positive.
(11.) Ehrenberg (1971) also demurred. He assumed that a typical
firm faced an infinitely elastic supply of hours per worker at the going
wage.
(12.) Lewis cited Walter Oi's (1962) "quasi-fixed"
labor costs and Gary Becker's (1964) "specific on-the-job
human investment" costs as examples of these costs.
(13.) Lewis wrote, "... the sign of the slope of the [market
equalizing] curve, to say nothing of the sign of the second derivative,
cannot be derived from the economic theory of hours of work choices by
employees and employers I have presented."
(14.) The claim that the "average" consumer-worker's
preferences for work hours and hourly earnings can be inferred from
situations where "persons choose their hours of work by selecting
across employers offering different wage packages" (Blundell and
MaCurdy 1999,1588) is not consistent with this model. The different
hours-wage bundles that define each worker's opportunity set
depend, in part, on what employers find to be optimal so the observed
hours-wage relationship maps out a mix of employers' preferences
and consumer-workers' preferences. The wage rate is not a
sufficient statistic to determine an employee's hours of work.
(15.) The only empirical research on working hours that draws on
Lewis' (1969) model I am aware of is that by Rosen (1969).
Kinoshita (1987) provides a clear exposition of the model.
(16.) This is also derived in Manning (2001).
(17.) Feldstein's point estimates of the elasticity of output
with respect to hours were often not merely greater than unity but, in
some instances, greater than two. They were imprecisely estimated,
however, with values neither significantly different (by conventional
criteria) from zero nor from unity.
(18.) On hours and health, among many articles, see van der Hulst
(2003) and on hours and work performance see the references in Golden
(2012).
(19.) These numbers come from Kuhn and Lozano (2008).
(20.) Many studies may be found in the Journal of Occupational and
Environmental Medicine.
(21.) It is entirely plausible for these mills to be characterized
as price-takers in input and output markets. The wage was set at
multiemployer collective bargaining agreements that permitted pay
differentials across mills and that allowed owner-managers to adjust
inputs in response to these given wages. Logs were purchased in markets
where selling prices were determined by auction and the price of plywood
was set in international markets. More information about these data and
this industry may be found in Pencavel and Craig (1994).
(22.) Weiss (1996) considers how synchronized work schedules
deriving from the importance of communication in production may even
override differences in work preferences.
(23.) Kosters' admission that he did not report results where
the coefficient on nonlabor income was nonpositive is laudable. How many
researchers have been less forthcoming and have not mentioned such
findings?
(24.) To be clear, such surprise bequest is sometimes correlated
with labor force withdrawals, but rarely with movements in work hours
among those at market work. As Brown et al. (2010, 425) write, "...
the few studies that have attempted to isolate the effect of a wealth
shock on labor supply [sic] have found collectively ambiguous
results." Using information from the Health and Retirement Study,
they provide evidence of the inheritance of assets affecting retirement
behavior. Effects on working hours among those remaining at work are not
reported.
(25.) See, for instance, Lester (1946) and Reynolds (1954).
(26.) Lewis (1957) mentioned these explanations but argued they
were relevant in only some special cases (such as in the railroad
industry).
(27.) Of course, in Lewis' (1969) model, employer resistance
to workers' demands for shorter hours is understandable because
there are costs to employing more workers that could be used to offset
the decline in hours. In his 1957 model, there is no such hindrance to
replacing shorter hours per worker with more workers.
(28.) "Unusual" but not "never." See Cahuc,
Carrillo, and Zylberberg (2014, 105).
(29.) I infer this from Bienefeld (1972) and Shiells (1985), among
others.
(30.) Weekly working hours averaged 40.4 over the 5 years from 1949
to 1953 and averaged 40.1 in the 5 years from 1975 to 1979. From 1979 to
2006, average real hourly compensation of production workers in
manufacturing industry grew little while average weekly work hours
changed little.
(31.) N was ignored in the formulation of the model above because,
in year-to-year decisions, the employment of member-workers in these
worker co-ops changed little and changes in the labor input were
effected principally through variations in hours per worker. All workers
worked the same number of hours and each worker received the same hourly
pay. See Craig and Pencavel (1992).
(32.) See Pencavel (forthcoming).
(33.) This finding goes back at least to Bry (1959).
(34.) The life cycle results of Browning, Deaton, and Irish (1985)
are also sensitive to the presence or absence of calendar year dummy
variables.
(35.) Negative effects are reported in Couch and Wittenberg (2001),
Neumark, Schweitzer, and Wascher (2004), and Stewart and Swaffield
(2008) and no "significant" effects in Connolly and Gregory
(2002) and Zavodny (2000).
(36.) Among many papers on this, see Altonji and Paxson (1988),
Bell (1998), Blundell and Walker (1982), Card (1990), Dickens and
Lundberg (1993), Kahn and Lang (1991), Moffitt (1982), Rebitzer and
Taylor (1995), and Stewart and Swaffield (1997).
(37.) See, for instance, Blau and Kahn (2007), Heim (2007) and
Bishop, Heim, and Mihaly (2009).
(38.) Marion Cahill's (1932) account of reductions in working
hours since the Civil War identifies three mechanisms by which hours
were cut: legislative action, trade union action, and voluntary action
by employers. Although she recognizes difficulties in categorizing some
hours reductions, she determines that "the reduction in hours by
pioneer employers has been less common than that brought about by
legislative or trade-union action" (1932, 27).
(39.) See, for instance, the research of Ashenfelter, Doran, and
Schaller (2010) and Farber (2005) on New York City cab drivers.
(40.) These costs are often expressed as linear in the number of
employees although one may conjecture there are economies of scale in
these hiring, training, and separation costs.
JOHN PENCAVEL, This manuscript formed the basis of my Presidential
address "Supply and Demand: Herd Behavior among Economists?"
at the meetings of the Western Economic Association International in
Honolulu in June 2015. I have benefitted from comments on an earlier
draft from William Boal, Jed DeVaro, Luigi Pistaferri, Frank Wolak, and
two anonymous referees of this journal. I thank Monica Bhole for her
capable research assistance.
Pencavel: Levin Professor of Economics, Department of Economics,
Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305-6072. Phone 650-723-3981, Fax
650-725-5702, E-mail
[email protected]
COPYRIGHT 2016 Western Economic Association International
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2016 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.