首页    期刊浏览 2024年11月30日 星期六
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Determinants of Housing Demand in Urban Areas of Pakistan: Evidence from the PSLM.
  • 作者:Ahmed, Ayaz ; Iqbal, Nasir ; Siddiqui, Rehana
  • 期刊名称:Pakistan Development Review
  • 印刷版ISSN:0030-9729
  • 出版年度:2018
  • 期号:March
  • 出版社:Pakistan Institute of Development Economics
  • 摘要:The study attempts to investigate the determinants of housing demand in urban areas of Pakistan. The empirical analysis is carried out using the Pakistan Social and Living Standard Measurement (PSLM) survey 2004-05 and 2010-11. The hedonic price model is used for the estimation of house prices. In order to control the selectivity bias between the tenure choice and the quantity of housing services demanded, Heckman's two-step selection procedure is used. The empirical analysis shows that housing price and income (temporary and permanent) play an important role in the determination of the housing units' demand. An increase in houses' prices causes decrease in demand for the housing units while the housing demand increases when the permanent income increases. On the face of change or increase in the transitory income, the demand for housing units remains static, since people do not desire to make long-term decisions based on volatile income. To manage rising housing demand, government should focus on developing effective and enforced price control mechanisms.
  • 关键词:Urban Housing Demand, PSLM, Pakistan

Determinants of Housing Demand in Urban Areas of Pakistan: Evidence from the PSLM.


Ahmed, Ayaz ; Iqbal, Nasir ; Siddiqui, Rehana 等


Determinants of Housing Demand in Urban Areas of Pakistan: Evidence from the PSLM.

The study attempts to investigate the determinants of housing demand in urban areas of Pakistan. The empirical analysis is carried out using the Pakistan Social and Living Standard Measurement (PSLM) survey 2004-05 and 2010-11. The hedonic price model is used for the estimation of house prices. In order to control the selectivity bias between the tenure choice and the quantity of housing services demanded, Heckman's two-step selection procedure is used. The empirical analysis shows that housing price and income (temporary and permanent) play an important role in the determination of the housing units' demand. An increase in houses' prices causes decrease in demand for the housing units while the housing demand increases when the permanent income increases. On the face of change or increase in the transitory income, the demand for housing units remains static, since people do not desire to make long-term decisions based on volatile income. To manage rising housing demand, government should focus on developing effective and enforced price control mechanisms.

Keywords: Urban Housing Demand, PSLM, Pakistan

1. INTRODUCTION

Housing is a basic human need and millions of people struggle to have a roof over their heads. In the face of unprecedented urbanisation and population growth many cities have accrued huge housing shortages, especially in developing and emerging economies. Estimates show that in 2010 around 980 million urban households lacked decent housing, as will another 600 million between 2010 and 2030. One billion new homes will be required worldwide by 2025, costing an estimated amount of $650 billion per year [UN-Habitat (2016)]. Although hundreds of new housing colonies have been established, the problem of finding a suitable accommodation in big cities persists. In 2014, more than 30 percent of urban population resided in slums in developing countries. Since every household is not able to build a house for itself, there is always a demand for rental houses. Housing, therefore, as a basic need became a challenging outlay of rapid urbanisation in most of the developing countries [UN-Habitat (2016)].

Housing demand is simply a housing need, which is backed up by the ability and willingness to pay. It depends on the different forms of behaviour of individuals, that how various households spend their limited resources, to fulfil their needs of housing units as well as their need for goods and services. The need of urban housing is affected by a number of factors, such as: rural to urban migration, increasing population, low investment in housing development, low purchasing power of household, poor urban infrastructure and geography [Fontenla, Gonzalez, and Navarro (2009); Oktay, Karaaslan, Alkan, and Kemal Celik (2014); Saiz (2010)].

Pakistan is a developing country that accommodates the world's sixth largest population. The housing situation has remained under pressure in Pakistan. Pakistan has been confronting housing issues in both qualitative and quantitative terms. Pakistan is faced with a severe shortage of housing, particularly for low and middle-income groups. Estimates disclosed that there is a shortage of about 7.5 million housing units [SBP (2013)]. The gap between supply and demand is increasing by more than 0.35 million. This issue is more critical in urban regions, where accessibility of sufficient residences at affordable rents is getting scarcer by the day. Population growth, rising urbanisation and economic development have created huge housing backlog, especially in big cities. This has not only increased the need for new housing units, but has also created a huge burden on the existing housing units. The existing work on housing in Pakistan by Pasha and Ghaus (1990), Lodhi and Pasha (1991), Ahmed (1994) and Pasha and Butt (1996), represents the first few attempts at determining factors that affect housing demand. Very few studies have ventured into determining the housing demand across income groups [Shefer (1990) and Tiwari and Parikh (1998)].

Given this background, the prime objective of this study is to analyse the housing demand in urban areas of Pakistan. This study attempts to determine empirically, how the factors such as wealth, income and house prices influence the ability to own a house differently for low, middle and high-income groups. This study compares the influence of socio-economic factors on the housing demand for two different time periods i.e. 2004-05 and 2010-11. In 2004-05, the housing market boomed while in 2010-11 the housing market was faced with recession.

This study makes a significant contribution to literature in various contexts. First, the study identifies all the possible factors, affecting the housing demand at national, provincial and income groups' levels. Second, this study compares the influence of socioeconomic factors on housing demand for two different time periods i.e. 2004-05 and 2010-11. In 2004-05, the housing market was at its boom while in 2010-11 housing market was faced with recession. Both periods, therefore, have different implications for housing demand. This comparison helps in designing appropriate policies according to the contemporary state of the housing market. Different factors contribute differently towards housing demand on the face of two contrast economic cycles.

Following the conventional housing studies, this study determines a house price by employing the hedonic price model. Unlike most studies on developing countries, this study quantified the relationship between the housing demand and its covariates, by using an econometric framework, augmented by Heckman's two-step selection procedure that controls selectivity bias between the tenure choice and quantity of housing services demanded. Margins for probability of house ownership are calculated by using the Probit model. Permanent and Transitory income is also estimated according to the permanent income hypothesis. Another aspect, not commonly found in studies for developing countries, including Pakistan, is determining the separate effect of permanent and more importantly transitory income on housing demand. The log-linear model is estimated using the Ordinary Least Square (OLS) technique.

The rest of the paper is organised as follows: section 2 presents the state of housing in Pakistan with special focus on National Housing Policy; section 3 layouts the conceptual framework of the study, describes data and estimation methodology; section 4 explains the results and last section concludes the discussion with policy suggestions.

2. STATE OF HOUSING IN PAKISTAN

According to Population Census 1998, the stock of housing units was 19.2 million in 1998. Figure 1 represents the distribution of housing units across the provinces. Figure 1 indicates that in 1998, 55 percent housing units were in Punjab, 26 percent in Sindh, 11.5 percent in KPK and 5.1 percent in Balochistan. The stock of housing units was 12.5 million in 1981.

The housing units, as a percentage of the total population remained almost the same across provinces. The housing units as a percentage of the total population have declined from 14.6 percent in 1981 to 12.5 percent in 1998 in KPK. The housing units as a percentage of the total population have declined from 15.9 percent in 1981 to 14.3 percent in 1998 in Punjab. On the other hand, the housing units as a percentage of the total population has increased from 14.6 percent in 1981 to 16.5 percent in 1998 in Sindh and from 13.6 percent in 1981 to 14.8 percent in 1998 in Balochistan. The increase in housing units was primarily observed in rural areas of Sindh and Balochistan during that period. But, on the other hand, decline has been recorded in urban areas of Sindh and Balochistan during this period (Table 1).

Table 2 presents the "nature of tenure" at national level across the rural and urban areas. The nature of tenure was measured using three categories, including "owned house", "rented house" and "rent free house". The data uncovered that the owned dwellings have increased from 78.4 percent in 1981 to 81.2 percent in 1998. There was no significant change in the ratio of owned houses from 1998 to 2012-13. The statistics have established that around 86 percent dwellings are owner occupied (Table 2). Similar patterns have been observed across rural and urban areas of Pakistan. There was not a huge change across rural and urban areas in the ratio of owned houses from 1981 to 1998 (Table 2)

Various indicators are used to examine the level of congestions within the housing unit. In this context we use persons per housing unit, person per room, single room housing units, two rooms housing units and three to four rooms housing units. Census of 1981 and 1998 established that in Pakistan persons per housing unit were 6.70 and 6.80 percent in 1981 and in 1998 respectively and the number of persons per room was 3.50 and 3.13. On the other hand, it was noticed that 51.54 and 38.11 percent people were living in one room, whereas 44.83 and 30.54 percent, 3.63 and 24.43percent, 6.70 and 6.92 percent people were living in two rooms, three to four rooms and five or more rooms respectively (Table 3 and Table 4).

The gap between supply and demand for housing is persistently rising in Pakistan. The previous section clearly indicates that per annum housing demand is around 0.35 million. The unavailability of new housing unit increases the congestion and homeless people in the country. This calls for governmental intervention to provide decent accommodation to every household. Pakistan had no housing policy at national and even provincial level till 1992. First National Housing Policy was developed in 1992, which was revised in 1994. This policy proposed various innovative methods for increasing housing stock and improving the quality of existing housing units. The government, nevertheless, failed in implementing this policy. Later on, the government of Pakistan had formulated a National Housing Policy (NHP) in 2001.

The NHP 2001 covers all major issues related to housing market, such as land issues, housing finance, construction service sector, low cost rural housing, building material, infrastructure development, zoning regulations and institutional arrangements. The NHP 2001 highlights key challenges to housing sector and proposes some strategies to resolve those issues and challenges and spells out the aims with key objectives. Following are the key problems and issues that were highlighted in the NHP 2001:

(i) The housing related issues are mainly generated by huge population growth.

(ii) The per annum housing requirement is 0.57 million.

(iii) The unchecked growth of squatter settlements, Katchi Abadis, encroachment of state and vacant land is held responsible for housing shortages.

(iv) Scarcity of suitable land for housing, particularly in and around the urban centres.

(v) Affordability issues, especially for low-income group.

(vi) The housing stock is rapidly aging.

(vii) Shortage of affordable housing finance to be major obstacle in housing production.

(viii) Tremendous rise in price of housing material because of inflationary pressure,

(ix) Lack of the use of technology.

To overcome these issues and meet the future housing requirements, with low cost and high quality, the proposed NHP 2001 was intended to achieve the following aims and objectives:

(i) To propose an enabling strategy for capacity building and institutional arrangements.

(ii) Empowering all stakeholders, including public as well as private sector for housing market development.

(iii) To propose a strategy for easing housing finance and home improvement credits which are compatible with affordability, especially for low-income group.

(iv) Strategy to improve the housing conditions through development, capacity building and initiation of innovative ideas.

(v) Strategy to upgrade the existing cities with better planning through the improvement of infrastructure.

(vi) Encourage research and development activities to design low cost houses.

(vii) Provision of safeguard against malpractices and resource mobilisation.

(viii) Provision of incentives through tax rationalisation.

(ix) A countrywide program of developing small and medium size towns having growth potential.

3. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK, DATA AND ESTIMATION METHODOLOGY

3.1. Conceptual Framework

To put the above discussion in a framework, we followed the work of Goodman (1998), Zabal (2004) and Fontenla and Gonzalez (2009). These studies have used the utility maximisation approach as a framework to understand the housing demand dynamics. Let individual i's utility function in market j depends on two goods: (i) non-housing composite consumption, denoted by [C.sub.ij] and (ii) the amount of housing units, denoted by [q.sub.ij]. We also assume that households have the same utility function but differ in their socio-demographic characteristics. These socio-demographic characteristics are denoted by [z.sub.i]. The vector z includes variables such as age of the head of the household, gender and education, social status and migration. The utility function of the household can be written as follows:

[U.sub.ij] = U([C.sub.ij] [q.sub.ij] [z.sub.i]) (1)

Assuming a static setting, the objective of an individual is to maximise the utility, given the budget constraints. An individual chooses how to allocate his/her income to non-housing composite consumption ([C.sub.ij]) and the housing services ([q.sub.ij]). The budget constraint of an individual can be defined as follows:

[C.sub.ij] = [p.sub.i][q.sub.ij] = [m.sub.ij] (2)

Where m is the household's income, p is the price of housing services and the price of non-housing consumption is normalised to one. We allow housing prices to be different across markets.

The household's utility maximisation problem is defined as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (3)

Solving the budget constraint for [C.sub.ij] and substituting into the utility function gives the indirect utility function. The budget constraint can be written as follows:

[C.sub.ij] = [m.sub.ij] - [p.sub.i][q.sub.ij] (4)

Now substituting Equation 4 in the utility function, we get the following indirect utility function

[V.sub.ij] = [Max.sub.qij] U([m.sub.ij] - [p.sub.i][q.sub.ij], [q.sub.ij], [z.sub.i]) (5)

Solving Equation (5) yields the (implicit) housing demand equation

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (6)

Providing a specific form for the utility function (1), will give rise to an explicit housing demand equation. While many utility functions result in non-linear demand equations, typically a log-linear housing demand equation is specified

ln [q.sub.ij] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1] ln p + [[beta].sub.2] ln [z.sub.i] (7)

This equation can be assumed to be an approximation to the underlying (nonlinear) housing demand equation. We analysed the housing demand in Pakistan with the use of this model. Estimating the implicit parameters of Equation (7) is the main purpose. We usually observe the value of the housing unit rather than the quantity. Thus, [q.sub.ij] has to be estimated in order to obtain Equation (7). An important feature of the housing market is that the physical and surrounding characteristics of the housing units are important, yet they vary widely across the housing units.

Define [H.sub.n] as the vector that represents housing characteristics for housing unit n. Similarly, [[beta].sub.j] is defined as the parameter vector, which is allowed to vary across markets, for each of the housing unit characteristics in [H.sub.n]. Thus the value y of a housing unit n in market j, consumed by household i, is given by the following expression:

[V.sup.i.sub.nj] = V([H.sub.n]; [[beta].sub.j]) ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (8)

If the characteristics [H.sub.n] and the value [v.sup.i.sub.n,j] of each housing unit are known, then it is possible to estimate [[beta].sub.j], using a hedonic price model. In addition, defining [H.sup.*.sub.n] as the standard unit we can compute the price index [p.sub.j] as follows:

[p.sub.j] = v([H.sup.*.sub.n]; [[beta].sub.j])/v([H.sup.*.sub.n]; [[beta].sub.1]) ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (9)

The value of the housing unit n in market j, consumed by the household i can be expressed as [v.sup.i.sub.n,j] = [q.sub.iy] x [p.sub.j]. The quantity, therefore, of housing is obtained as follows:

[q.sub.ij] = [v.sup.i.sub.nj]/[p.sub.j] ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (10)

Once we know the [q.sub.ij], we can estimate the Equation 7.

3.2. Data

To estimate the demand for housing, data of various social and economic indicators is taken from Pakistan Social and Living Standards Measurement Survey (PSLM) and Household Integrated Economic Survey (HIES), conducted by Pakistan Bureau of Statistics (PBS). In this study, PSLM survey data for the year 2004-05 and 2010-11 is taken.

We are using a set of population based social indicators for 16341 households from PSLM/HIES national level data. The data on household information covers education, health, employment and income as well as ownership of assets, household details, immunisation, married women, facilities and services. Additionally, it offers data on household consumption expenditures (including consumption on durable items owned/sold), transfer received and paid out and buildings and land owned. Population of all the four provinces is considered as the universal sample. Under the framework of PSLM/HIES each city/town was sub divided into enumeration blocks. Urban areas were divided into 26698 blocks and rural areas comprised of 50588 blocks. Each urban block was categorised on the basis of income groups. The selection of Primary Sample Units (PSU) and Secondary Sample Units (SSUs) data from urban and rural areas of each province has been discussed in Table 5.

Table 5 indicates that the entire sample of households has been drawn from 1045 Primary Sample Units (PSUs) in 2004-05, out of which 486 are urban and 559 are rural and 1180 Primary Sample Units (PSUs) in 2010-11, out of which 564 are urban and 616 are rural. The total sample is 14777 in 2004-05 and 16341 in 2010-11. This sample size has been considered sufficient to produce estimates of key variables at national and provincial levels [Pakistan (2012)].

3.3. Estimation Methodology

In this study, we seek to determine the factors that impact the demand for housing and its services across income groups. Additionally, welfare impact across income groups is also determined for 2004-05 and 2010-11, that will clarify whether the housing units owned by the income-based groups are better off or worse off. For the purpose of analysis, this model includes m = 1 ... M urban areas. In each urban area there are i = 1 ... [I.sub.m] individual household heads and j = 1 ... [J.sub.m] housing units. The analysis, therefore, considers each city as a separate entity across income groups.

3.3.1. Housing Demand Model

The model explained in previous section indicates that various socio-economic variables explain the housing demand. These factors include different physical and community attributes, such as number of rooms, dummy variable for owner occupied or rented unit as well as the availability of housing services, including pipe-water, motors, hand pumps or others. The community attributes include whether a housing unit is located in a city, number of earners and educated members in the household. Moreover, attributes related to head of the household are age, gender, education, marital status, employment status and occupation. In this study, we consider the household head as a special case. Thus demand for housing can be represented as a function of personal characteristic of the household head, background of the household and price of housing. The functional form of housing demand highlighted in Equation 7 at maximum utility level is given below:

q(z) = f([X.sub.1],Y,C,[P.sub.j](z)) ... ... ... ... ... ... (11)

For each housing characteristic "[z.sub.ij]" the q(z) presents the quantity of individual housing unit, which is to be estimated. [X.sub.1] refers to the household characteristics such as family size, income group it belongs to and the number of earners. Income of household is represented by Y which is the sum of permanent income and transitory income. Characteristics of the head of the household is represented by C, including education of the household head, age of the household head, occupation, marital status and gender. Finally, [p.sub.j](z) denotes the price of the individual household which is not available for household data. A proxy, therefore, is used to capture the price of the house estimated, using hedonic price model. In order to estimate the demand for housing, we first need to calculate the quantity of housing unit (q (2)), house price ([p.sub.j](z)), permanent income ([T.sub.P]) and transitory income ([Y.sub.T]). Thus the demand for housing is determined as

[Y.sub.i] = [x'.sub.i][beta] + [e.sub.i] ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (12)

In Equation (12), [Y.sub.i] represents the housing quantity and [x'.sub.i] is a vector with dimensions 1 x M, representing all exogenous variables included in the model, [beta] is a vector of parameters with M x 1 dimensions. The following Ordinary Least Square (OLS) regression equation specifications used for housing demand in log-linear form is given as:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (13)

Where, [beta] is the coefficient of exogenous variables and [delta] is the coefficient used for dummies. The interpretation of the variables is as: q(z) is the quantity of housing unit (defined in equation 10), [Y.sub.P] is the permanent income of the household, [Y.sub.T] represents the transitory income, [p.sub.j](z) is the price of housing unit, [A.sub.R/Y] is the affordability of the individual household head, A is the age of the household head, [E.sub.r] represents the number of earners in a household, [E.sub.d] is the education of the household head, [F.sub.s] is the family size (children and adults), male is the dummy, representing the gender of the household head (=1 if male; = 0 if female), M is the marital status (=1 if married; =0 otherwise), [Y.sub.M] is the dummy for middle-income group (=1 if middle-income group; = 0 otherwise), [Y.sub.H] is the dummy for high-income group (=1 if high-income group; = 0 otherwise), Ct represents the dummy for the 14 urban cities of Pakistan selected in this study and [e.sub.i] is the error term. Moreover, all the variables used are in its log form for reducing changes including extreme values in parametric estimation. Additionally, it also reduces the heteroscedasticity in data.

3.3.2. Housing Quality

In order to estimate the housing demand, dependent variable i.e. quality of housing units is first calculated following Dusansky and Koc (2007).

Standardized Housing unit (q(z)) = (owner occupied housing value)/house price per unit [p.sub.j] (14)

The market value of the house is used as a proxy to measure the owner-occupied housing value, which refers to the price of the house acceptable if he wishes to sell his property. The housing price per unit represents the hedonic price [P.sub.j](z). Some studies also used rent (rent equivalent) instead of owner-occupied housing value for the calculation of housing units [Hernandez and Garcia (2006); Garabato and Sarasola (2011)]. The demanded quantity of housing calculated in Equation (14) is used to calculate the factors that affect housing demand.

3.3.3. Permanent and Transitory Income

There are many views regarding the modelling of the unobservable variables, such as permanent income and transitory income. Friedman (1957) states that the consumption is the function of permanent income, but his point of view was criticised as the consumption decision of the household are forward-looking. It was looked at as a poor determinant to measure the permanent income. Though, permanent income cannot be measured directly, it is estimated using physical and human resources, such as education, property and experience, which contribute in generating income. Singh, et al. (1986) states that the determinants of permanent income are the household characteristics, physical assets, education, community and environmental attributes. It was, nonetheless, argued that the physical assets are a weak determinant of permanent income, as physical assets may underline a different level of permanent income in different countries. Because of the environmental and economic factors, the price of physical assets is distorted and it represents different proportion of ownerships, thus the level of permanent income. Many different approaches are discussed in literature to measure permanent income, Townsend, et al. (1985). Some used qualitative approach while others used rapid rural appraisal (RRA) approach [Takasaki, et al. (2000)]. Shefer (1990), Ahmed (1994) and Ballesteros (2001) used the expenditures on consumption as a proxy to measure permanent income.

There are some studies, nevertheless, that used a set of different individual characteristics such as education, age, skills, wages, bonus, pension, on job training capital gain, inheritance and savings [Goodman and Kawai (1984); Ahmed (1994); Wang (1995); Goodman (2002)]. Thus, following Goodman and Kawai (1984) and Goodman (2002), we expressed permanent income as a function of human and non-human wealth:

[Y.sub.P] = f(H,N) ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (15)

Where, H is the human wealth and N represents the non-human wealth. The human wealth demands the expected future income such as bonus and increments (annual increase in income on constant rate) and the current income, which depends on the individual household characteristics such as age, education, gender, marital status, occupation, employment status, number of earners in a household and family size. Nonhuman wealth accounts for the income received from other resources, such as remittances and income from commercial or non- agricultural property.

Thus, the permanent income measure represents the potential lifetime earnings and by regressing the real observed total income on the independent variables, provides the permanent income as fitted value of the regression and transitory income as residual. Observed total income is indicated as the sum of permanent and transitory income is highlighted in Equation (16) as:

Y = [Y.sub.p](H, N) + [Y.sub.T] ... ... ... ... ... ... (16)

Linear regression model is represented as:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (17)

Where, [beta] is the coefficient of exogenous variables and [delta] is the coefficient used for dummies. Y represents the observed total income, A is the age of the household head, [E.sub.r] represents the number of earners in a household, [E.sub.d] is the education of the household head, [F.sub.s] is the family size (children and adults), [R.sub.m] is the remittances, male is the dummy representing the gender of the household head (=1 if male; = 0 if female), M is the marital status (=1 if married; = 0 otherwise), [E.sub.p] is the dummy for employment status (=1 if employed; = 0 otherwise), [O.sub.c] represents the occupancy: whether the housing unit is owner occupied, rented, subsidised rent or rent free, [Y.sub.M] is the dummy for middle-income group (=1 if middle-income group; = 0 otherwise), [Y.sub.H] is the dummy for high-income group (=1 if high-income group; = 0 otherwise), Ct represents the dummy for the cities and [e.sub.i] is the error term. Thus the predicted income is the required permanent income ([Y.sub.P]) and the residual is saved as transitory income ([Y.sub.T]).

Various income measures can be estimated using different sets of explanatory variables, but the best fitted regression model for which the standard error is minimum, is chosen for the analysis.

3.3.4. House Price

Since house prices are not available in the data set of PSLM, it is estimated using the hedonic price model. The price of the house is determined by the internal characteristics as well as the external factors. There are other underlying issues that cause difficulties towards calculating the price of unobserved variables. Firstly, price of the property is not the same in each period; the house price varies because of the supply and demand factors that determine the price. Thus, the price is not same for two consecutive periods. Secondly, such as many other products, properties of house traded in market are not identical. The price changes, therefore, because of the characteristics of property (number of rooms, appearance, source of water, availability of gas, electricity, telephone, means of sewage), location attributes (close to market area, office, school, hospital, neighbourhood and others) and environmental attributes (urban, rural, industrial area, air or water pollution) [Herath and Maier (2010)]. Thus, these attributes cannot be ignored while calculating the house price.

The household survey data provides information about the expected value of the house/property, if it is put up for sale and is reported as the owner-occupied housing value. Owner-occupied housing value represents the product of housing price per unit and standardised housing unit. The value of the housing price is extracted from the owner-occupied housing value using hedonic regression. Following Goodman and Kawai (1984) and Goodman (2002), house price per unit can be calculated using hedonic price model, which is a more sophisticated form of mix adjustment. The hedonic regression, in terms of set of features that contributes to the value of house is as follows:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (18)

Where, P is the owner-occupied housing value, number of rooms is used as a proxy to measure the house size and is represented by [H.sub.S], [T.sub.H] is the house tax, [W.sub.P] is the dummy for piped water (= 1 if piped water; = 0 otherwise), [W.sub.HP] is the dummy for water from hand pump (= 1 if water from hand pump; = O otherwise), [W.sub.M] represents the dummy for water availability from motor (= 1 if water from motor; = 0 otherwise), [G.sub.AS] is the dummy for availability of gas (= 1 if gas is available; = 0 otherwise), TS denotes the time (in minutes) required to reach a grocery shop, TPT represents the time (in minutes) required to reach a public transport, TPS characterises the time (in minutes) required to reach a primary school, TMS represents the time (in minutes) required to reach a middle school, 77/5 represents the time (in minutes) required to reach a high school, THP symbolises the time (in minutes) required to reach a hospital, [Y.sub.M] is the dummy for middle-income group (=1 if middle-income group; = 0 otherwise), [Y.sub.H] is the dummy for high-income group (=1 if high-income group; = 0 otherwise), Ct represents the dummy for the 14 urban cities and e is the error term, [beta] is the coefficient of exogenous variables and O is the coefficient used for dummies. Taking logs of the variables are considered to ensure that the prices are non-negative. This regression model used values of the above mentioned features to predict the price of housing unit during a particular period. The fitted values generated from the hedonic regression are the required prices per house for the standardised housing units. Dusansky and Koc (2007) are of the view that prices generated from the hedonic method represent the prices of the same sized house across cities. Hedonic price modelling is commonly used in real estate for sales comparison. Thus, allow the comparison between prices of constant quality housing across cities over a particular time period.

3.3.5. Imputed Rent

For the calculation of standardised unit of housing, we also need to estimate affordability. In literature, affordability is defined as the ratio of rent to total income [Tiwari and Parikh (1998)]. Housing expense is commonly measured through rent. Malpezzi and Mayo (1985) considered rent as the product of unit price and quantity consumed, depending on the housing services. It varies for individual household, depending on the shelter, type of construction, dwelling and neighbourhood. The conventional hedonic regression model can also be used to measure imputed rent. The hedonic equation for house rent is specified as:

R = f([R.sub.T],[W.sub.T],[G.sub.AS],[T.sub.F],W) ... ... ... ... ... ... (19)

The house rent is measured against the set of characteristics of the housing unit, which are specified as follows: [R.sub.T] is the type of roof, it may be made of rcc/rbc, wood/bamboo, steel/cement or other; [G.sub.AS] represent the dummy for availability of gas, [T.sub.F] represents the toilet facility (outdoor, flush, pit/latrine or others), W represents the water availability (piped, hand pump, motor or other) and [W.sub.T] refers to type of walls i.e. brick, cement, stone, wood, bamboo or mud. After the hedonic regress, fitted value of the imputed rent is generated for the sample of housing units [Malpezzi (2003)]. Imputed rent is used only for owner-occupied housing unit for which only market value of housing is available.

Following Greene (2003) and Wooldridge (2006), we applied Heckman's twostep model [Heckman (1979)] of sample selection. In order to select sample, two equations are used, first is the equation that determines the outcome variable. Second equation only uses selected samples and mechanisms determining the selection process. The dependent variable, standardised housing unit, is only observed for those household heads that are the owners of their houses and are not observed for those rented units. Regressing an OLS model on the standardised housing unit will cause sensitivity bias. Thus, the model will estimate biased and incontinent value of [beta]. In order to deal with the problem of non-random selection and to control the sensitivity bias between household quantity of service demand and tenure, the Heckman two-step selection model was applied.

For data generation, the Heckman model applies the moments of incidentally reduced by variant normal distribution. The basic Heckman model equation is specified as:

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (20)

The basic demand equation is

[mathematical expression not reproducible] (21)

[z.sup.*.sub.1] refer to those households who own their houses and is 0 for rented households, [w.sub.i] is the lxk row vector for the selected exogenous variables used in Heckman model and in the demand equation, [gamma] is the parameter to be estimated with kxl dimensions. As a special case, if the error terms of both equations are correlated then the problem of selectivity arises and additional assumptions are imposed:

[u.sub.i] ~ N(0,1) [[epsilon].sub.i] ~ N(0, [[sigma].sup.2]) corr([u.sub.i], [[epsilon].sub.i]) = [rho] ... ... ... ... ... ... ... (22)

Here we assume normal distribution with mean zero and correlation[rho]. Following Goodman (1988), Ahmad (1994) and Dusansky and Koc (2007) the selectivity biasness was removed through Heckman process.

4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

4.1. Housing Demand Analysis

The housing demand was estimated using 2-step Heckman model, whose results are presented below in Tables 6 to 8. The housing demand during 2004-05 indicates that the coefficients of permanent income are insignificant, whereas during 2010-11 the permanent income elasticity of 0.04, negatively yet significantly affected the housing demand. Whereas, the transitory income elasticity 0.033 (2004-05) and 0.039(2010-11) was found to be positive and significant. It was found to be relatively smaller as compared to the income elasticity range i.e. 0.6 to 0.8 found in literature for developing countries [Mayo (1981)]. The results are in line with the findings of Malpezzi and Mayo (1987), Lodhi and Pasha (1991) and Garabato and Sarasola (2011) and they indicate that additional factors are needed to improve the housing demand. The results in Table 5.1, nonetheless, present a static relationship between transitory income and housing demand.

The difference in the results of income elasticity may have stemmed from different income measures [Mayo (1981)]. Ahmad (1994) used the permanent income, predicted from the income regression. Shefer (1990) and Ballesteros (2001) used monthly household expenditures as an indicator for permanent income. Arimah (1992) and Tiwari and Parikh (1998) used total annual income as a proxy for permanent income. Moreover, because of the difference in the data sample the results uncovered the variations.

The fitted house price was statistically significant and it highlighted a negative relationship between house price and demand for both data sets. It indicated that with an increase in house price, keeping other factors constant, the overall demand in housing market will decrease. The reported price elasticity ranges 0.027and 0.042 for 2004-05 and 2010-11, respectively. Results suggest that the demand for house price was inelastic. The range of price elasticity observed in literature was from -0.1 to -0.9. The less elastic demand, nonetheless, could be caused by limited supply of houses in markets. Consequently, the household head was bound to pay the asking price of housing. Results imply a downward sloping demand for housing service with no gain in housing demand market.

Rent to income ratio, used as proxy for afford ability, derived positive and significant results for the housing demand. With an increase in affordability, which may have been triggered by the increase in income or decrease in rent, the house demand had increased by 18.5 percent and 0.8 percent in 2004-05 and 2010-11, respectively. It implies that household head was willing to buy a housing unit in order to avoid the large housing expense.

All the demographic factors are found to be insignificant for 2004-05, whereas except gender all the demographic factors are statistically significant for 2010-11. Household head's age implies that the need for housing increases with the increase in age. With an additional year in the age of household head, increases the housing demand by 0.1 percent, nonetheless, after a certain age, as the children move out, the demand for housing decreases (2010-11). It also implies that with an increase in house demand because of age, there appears a change in the taste of the individual [Goodman (1988); Fontenla, et al. (2009)].

The coefficients for number of earners in a household were also positive and significant. The value of earners coefficient indicates that with an addition of one earning member, the housing demand increased by 0:2 percent (2010-11). Similar results were also reported by studies in Pakistan, such as Pasha and Ghaus (1990) and Nazli and Malik (2003). It shows that 'a aingle earner (household head) cannot save enough because of high consumption'expenses, therefore, with an increase in number of earning members, the saving level increases, which ultimately increases the demand for housing.

Highly significant results are reported about the effect of education on housing demand. With an additional year in education, the housing demand increased by 4.5 percent, which discovered that the income of the household was in control. Such household could demand a new housing unit with a change in its taste (2010-11). Additionally, with an increase of one member in family, the demand for housing increased, as the number of rooms was already assigned to the existing members of the household. Thus, with an additional member, 0.3 percent increase was recorded. For a household that belonged to middle-income group, the demand increase was recorded as 2.4 percent and for a high-income group, an increase of 8.4 percent in demand was reported (2010-11), as shown in Table (5.3). Mixed results were reported in the previous literature regarding the effect of demographic factors on housing demand.

The LAMBDA coefficient indicates that the choice for housing was made by considering the housing units consumption. The LAMBDA coefficient was positive and significant for only 2010-11. In case of Pakistan, this study established that a major increase in housing demand was caused by the education factor.

4.2. Housing Demand Analysis at Disaggregated Level

This study estimated the housing demand, based on income groups for owned housing and is reported in Table (9). The permanent income elasticity was found positive and significant for low-income group and high-income group, whereas the elasticity for middle-income group was found inelastic (2004-05). The elasticity of 0.06 (low-income group) and 0.07 (high-income group) reported were higher than the results at the national level but it still indicated that the housing demand was inelastic. During 2010-2011, permanent income elasticity (0.04) was negatively significant only for middle-income group. Transitory income represents a positive and significant effect on the housing demand across all income levels and for both data sets. With the increase in income level, the housing demand became less elastic, as high-income group represented an elasticity of 0.02.

Increase in house price negatively affect the housing demand for all income groups. These results are highly significant for low-income groups and the credibility decreases as we move from low-income group to high-income group for both data sets. An increase of 36 percent was observed in housing demand with the increase in affordability in low-income group (2004-05). As we moved from low to high-income group, affordability ratio decreased because of high-income and fixed rent cost and, therefore, housing demand was less affected by the affordability (2004-05, 2010-11). Moreover, during 2010-11 attribute of affordability was insignificant for housing demand.

The coefficient of age of the household head was found to be insignificant during 2004-05, across all income groups. The age factor caused housing demand to change slightly by 0.1 percent for income groups (2010-11). As seen in the results at the national level, age, number or earners, household size (family members), education, gender and marital status are statistically insignificant during 2004-05, except the household size related to high-income group, which negatively and significantly causes house demand to decrease by 0.5 percent.

Increase in the earning members of a household, positively affected the house demand by 0.1 percent (low-income group) and 0.4 percent (middle-income group), nevertheless, for a high-income group, the housing demand decreases by 0.2 percent (2010-11). For middle-income group, the increase in housing demand because of an additional year of education was reported as 5.1 per cent higher as compared to other groups. No significant impact of education, nonetheless, for high-income group was found on the housing demand. For most of the time families living in low-income groups and middle-income groups view housing as an indicator for Social, Economic and Personal Security.

A logical increase in house demand was recorded with the increase in family size for all income groups. Household head, being male, negatively affect the housing demand in low-income group, whereas its effect was statistically insignificant for other income levels. For a married household, the house demand increased by 1.5 percent for a low-income group, while results are insignificant for middle and high-income groups. The results demonstrated a change in the attributes of housing demand across income groups over the year. The housing attributes for low-income groups highlighted that demand was more sensitive to the change. Therefore, high proportion of income was spent on the improvement and consolidation of housing units in low-income group.

In an attempt to explain the differences of regional housing demand, this study used the log-linear regression model for a province-wise analysis of houses in urban Pakistan. The results are presented in Table (10). The empirical results suggest that household income was the significant factor, causing housing demand to vary among province. The permanent income elasticity of 0.03 (2004-05) and 0.04 (2010-11) was highly significant and positive for Sindh. Similarly, positive statistically significant and permanent income elasticity was also reported for Punjab (2004-05) and Balochistan (2010-11) on housing demand. Whereas, in case of KPK (2004-05) and Balochistan (2004-05), the housing demand was negatively related to change in permanent income, but the results are insignificant for Balochistan only (2004-05). The results indicate that the demand for housing was inelastic for all provinces.

Transitory income elasticity is positive and statistically significant for four provinces, for both data sets, except for KPK (2010-11). Moreover, the coefficient of transitory income presented inelastic demand for housing across all regions. House price negatively and significantly cause the demand for housing to decrease for all regions except for KPK (2004-05) and Balochistan (2004-05). The result implies that the housing demand was inelastic and relatively small for all regions. The housing price was elastic for Balochistan (2010-11) and was reported to be 0.8. It indicates that the sectorial and regional difference should also be considered using aggregate parameters, while estimating housing demands. These differences are not reflected in the housing demand at national level.

Interesting results were reported regarding the affordability of a household head across regions. Results indicated that households in Punjab, Sindh and Balochistan depend on affordability (rent to income ratio) for housing demand but, for KPK results were found insignificant. With an increase in affordability ratio, the housing demand increased by 15 percent and 4 percent for Punjab; 19 percent and 0.4 percent for Sindh and 12 percent and 14 percent for Balochistan for both data sets, respectively. It indicates that individuals depend less on affordability for housing demand. A decrease, therefore, in housing demand was observed over the period for Punjab and Sindh. The dependence on income, nevertheless, for house demand increased over the period for Balochistan.

As discussed in the previous literature, the demographic factors uncovered mixed results. With an increase in age, a significant change in demand was recorded to the extent of Punjab (2010-11) and Balochistan (2004-05). An increase in number of earners negatively and significantly caused the decrease in demand by 0.9 percent for Sindh (2010-2011) and insignificant for all the other regions. With an increase in education, the demand for housing increased by 0.9 percent and 0.1 percent in Punjab; 1.1 percent in Sindh (2010-11) and 5.8 percent for Balochistan (2004-05). Household size negatively affected the demand by 0.3 percent for Sindh (2010-11) and its impact was insignificant for other regions. Similarly, gender and marital status were found irrelevant as a result of regional demand analysis.

5. CONCLUSION AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS

The study has attempted to investigate the determinants of housing demand in urban areas of Pakistan. The empirical analysis is carried out using Pakistan Social and Living Standard Measurement (PSLM) survey 2004-05 and 2010-11. The hedonic price model is used for the estimation of house prices. In order to control the selectivity bias between the tenure choice and the quantity of housing services demanded, Heckman's two-step selection procedure is used.

The empirical analysis shows that housing price and income (temporary and permanent) play an important role in the determination of the housing units' demand. An increase in houses' prices causes decrease in demand for the housing units, while the housing demand increases when the permanent income increases. It was found that the transitory income has positive effect on the housing demand among all three groups, but its impact was relatively stronger in case of middle-income. Escalation of price was negatively related to demand, as the housing demand decreases with the increase in the prices of housing units. The affordability has the same effect on low and middle-income groups, but for high-income group it was positive, yet reflects a lesser value in terms of its coefficient. The demand for housing at national level has positively impacted permanent income, as people with more permanent income caused an increase in demand for houses. The scenario changed in 2010-11 when people with more permanent income had a negative impact on the demand for housing.

To manage rising housing demand, following policy implications emerged from the empirical analysis:

(a) Analysis indicates that housing price has a negative impact on housing demand. This finding suggests that government should focus on developing effective and enforced price control mechanism. This will help to control housing market hence reduce burden on city development.

(b) The economic development is one of the major determinants of housing demand, as measured by income. Empirical analysis reveals that rising income has a significant impact on new housing markets. To meet the future demands with rising income, it is suggested that government in collaboration with the private sector should develop new low cost housing societies to cater future needs. Along with the economic development, increasing urbanisation and population growth put pressure on the housing sector. Government of Pakistan should devise national housing policy on priority basis to address future housing demand in the light of Vision 2025. This framework should address not only future demands but also quality issues of housing sector, especially in mega cities.

(c) Affordability is another important policy dimension of the housing sector. The positive association between affordability and housing demand implies that household prefers to purchase new housing unit to manage housing expenses. A well functional rental market may help to reduce housing pressure with innovative housing units. The government should regulate rent market to manage rising demands.

In essence, government should design and implement new housing policy to cater future need. The policy should consider future development, house prices and affordability dimensions in its design. The policy should also look into the institutional arrangement of this sector to manage rental market and development of new societies, especially in mega cities. The on-going census 2017 will provide a golden opportunity to assess the demand and supply conditions of housing market, in finalising the new housing policy. The Benazir Income Support Programme (BISP) has also collected data on housing condition across Pakistan, using National Socio-Economic Registry (NSER). This data can also be used to understand the current housing situation in Pakistan. A detailed study may be conducted using NSER and PSLM 2014-15 datasets to review and suggest policy framework, keeping in view development, housing price and affordability dimensions.

Appendix
Appendix Table 1
List of Explanatory Variables

Variables                   Description

Standardised housing unit   Dependent variable
Permanent Income            Monthly income, remittances or
                            wealth effect
Transitory Income           Unexpected income, bonus
Remittances                 Total remittance was the sum of domestic
                            and foreign remittance
Market Value of House       Price of owner occupied housing unit
Low-income Group            Low income group
                            (as identified under PSU)
Middle-income Group         Middle income group
                            (as identified under PSU)
High-income Group           High income group
                            (as identified under PSU)
Affordability               Affordability was defined as
                            Rent to Income Ratio
Household Head's Age        Age of household head in year
Household Head's
Education                   Education of household head in year
Gender                      = 1 if Male; = 0 if female
Marital Status              = 1 if married; = 0 otherwise
Occupation                  Post currently working on
Employment Status           = 1 if employed; = 0 otherwise
Industry                    Industry in which households
                            head was working
Number of Earners           Number of earners in a house hold
Family Size                 Number of members in a house hold
Household size              Number of Rooms
Owner Occupied House        = 1 if owner occupied, = 1 otherwise
Housing Expenditure
(rent)                      Rent in rupees
Imputed rent                imputed rent was used for the missing
                            values of house rent
Type of roof                It refers to the material used in roof
Type of walls               It refers to the material used in
                            making walls
Water Facility              water availability in house, piped,
                            motor water or other
City                        urban cities are chosen for analysis

Source: Author's own work.

Appendix Table 2

Means of Variables (2004-05)

Variables                    National   Low-income

Standardised housing unit      1.00        1.00
Permanent Income              11.92       11.56
Transitory Income              0.00        0.00
Remittances                   11026        5089
Market Value of House        1386344      661429
Affordability                  0.85        0.83
Household Head's Age          46.24       44.71
Household Head's Education     9.84        8.65
Gender                         0.93        0.95
Marital Status                 0.89        0.91
Number of Earners              1.72        1.84
Household size                 6.49        6.89
Owner Occupied House           0.71        0.69
Observation                    2752        820

Variables                    Middle-income   High-income

Standardised housing unit        1.00           1.00
Permanent Income                 11.88          12.58
Transitory Income                0.00           0.00
Remittances                      8808           26069
Market Value of House           922390         3735204
Affordability                    0.85           0.87
Household Head's Age             45.93          49.43
Household Head's Education       9.60           11.63
Gender                           0.94           0.90
Marital Status                   0.89           0.87
Number of Earners                1.68           1.63
Household size                   6.48           5.91
Owner Occupied House             0.70           0.74
Observation                      1402            430

Source: Author's own Calculations.

Appendix Table 3
Means of Variables (2010-11)

Variables                    National   Low-income

Standardised Housing Unit      1.00        1.00
Permanent Income              12.37       12.08
Transitory Income              0.00        0.00
Remittances                   15712        8320
Market Value of House        2637309     1112030
Affordability                  0.29        0.27
Household Head's Age          47.18       46.04
Household Head's Education    10.63        8.72
Gender                         0.93        0.93
Marital Status                 0.89        0.89
Number of Earners              1.70        1.78
Household Size                 6.14        6.36
Owner Occupied House           0.68        0.70
Observation                    3053        944

Variables                    Middle-income   High-income

Standardised Housing Unit        1.00           1.00
Permanent Income                 12.32          12.93
Transitory Income                0.00           0.00
Remittances                      15381          27683
Market Value of House           2033660        6454766
Affordability                    0.28           0.33
Household Head's Age             46.89          49.58
Household Head's Education       10.39          13.15
Gender                           0.93           0.92
Marital Status                   0.88           0.89
Number of Earners                1.73           1.51
Household Size                   6.14           5.83
Owner Occupied House             0.68           0.66
Observation                      1485            624

Source: Author's own Calculations.


Ayaz Ahmed, Nasir Iqbal, and Rehana Siddiqui

Ayaz Ahmed <[email protected]> is Senior Research Economist, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. Nasir Iqbal <[email protected]> is Director Research, Benazir Income Support Programme (BISP), Islamabad. Rehana Siddiqui <[email protected]> is Head, Department of Environmental Economics, Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.

REFERENCES

Ahmed, I. (1994) Up to the Waist in Mud: Earth-based Architecture of Rural Bangladesh. Dhaka: University Press Limited.

Arimah, B. C. (1992) An Empirical Analysis of the Demand for Housing Attributes in a Third World Country. Land Economics 68:4, 366-379.

Ballesteros, Marife M. (2001) The Dynamics of Housing Demand in the Philippines: Income and Lifecycle Effects. Philippine Institute for Development Studies. (Discussion Papers DP 2001-15).

Dusansky, R. and C. Koc (2007) The Capital Gains Effect in the Demand for Housing. Journal of Urban Economics 61:2, 287-298.

Fontenla, M. and F. Gonzalez (2009) Housing Demand in Mexico. Journal of Housing Economics 18:1, 1-12.

Friedman, M. (1957) The Permanent Income Hypothesis: Theory of Consumption Function. National Bureau of Economic Research 20-37.

Garabato, N. and M. R. Sarasola (2011) Are Uruguayan Housing Policies Reaching the Poor? An Assessment of Housing Deficit, Housing Informality and Usage of Housing Programs in Uruguay. Inter-American Development Bank.

Goodman, A. C. (1988) An Econometric Model of Housing Price, Permanent Income, Tenure Choice and Housing Demand. Journal of Urban Economics 20, 327-353.

Goodman, A. C. (1998) Andrew Court and Invention of Hedonic Prices. Journal of Urban Economics 44, 291-298.

Goodman, A. C. (2002) Estimating Equilibrium Housing Demand for Stayers. Journal of Urban Economics, 1-24.

Goodman, A. C. and M. Kawai (1984) Replicative Evidence of the Demand for Owner-occupied and Rental Housing. Southern Economic Journal 50:4, 1036-1057.

Greene, W. (2003) Simulated Maximum Likelihood Estimation of the Normal-Gamma Stochastic Frontier Model. Journal of Productivity Analysis 19:2, 179-190.

Heckman, J. (1979) Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica 47:1, 153-161.

Herath, Shanaka, and Gunther Maier (2010) The Hedonic Price Method in Real Estate and Housing Market Research. A Review of the Literature. WU Vienna University of Economics and Business, Vienna. (SRE-Discussion Papers, 2010/03).

Lodhi, A. and H. A. Pasha (1991) Housing Demand in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Karachi in Pakistan. Urban Studie 28,623-634.

Malpezzi, S. and S. K. Mayo (1987a) The Demand for Housing in Developing Countries. Economic Development and Cultural Change 35, 687-721.

Malpezzi, S. and S. K. Mayo (1987b) User Cost and Housing Tenure in Developing Countries. Journal of Development Economics 25, 197-220.

Malpezzi, S. and S. Mayo (1985) Housing Demand in Developing Countries. The World Bank, Washington, DC.

Mayo, S. K. (1981) Theory and Estimation in the Economics of Housing Demand. Journal of Urban Economics 10:1, 95-116.

Nazli, H. and Sohail J. Malik (2003) Housing: Opportunity, Security, and Empowerment for the Poor. The Pakistan Development Review 42:4, 893-908.

Oktay, E., A. Karaaslan, O. Alkan, and A. Kemal Celik (2014) Determinants of Housing Demand in the Erzurum Province, Turkey. International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis 7:4, 586-602.

Pakistan, Government of (1981 and 1998) Population and Housing Census of Pakistan. Islamabad: Pakistan Bureau of Statistics

Pakistan, Government of (2004-2005) Pakistan Social and Living Standard Measurement Survey. Islamabad: Pakistan Bureau of Statistics.

Pakistan, Government of (2010-2011) Pakistan Social and Living Standard Measurement Survey. Islamabad: Pakistan Bureau of Statistics.

State Bank of Pakistan (SBP) (2013) Annual Report of State Bank of Pakistan (SBP). Karachi: State Bank of Pakistan.

Pasha, H. A. and A. Ghaus (1990) Magnitude of Housing Shortage in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 29:2, 137-153.

Pasha, H. A. and M. S. Butt (1996) Demand for Housing Attributes in Developing Countries: A Study of Pakistan. Urban Studies 33:7, 1141-1154.

Saiz, A. (2010) The Geographic Determinants of Housing Supply. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125:3, 1253-1296.

Shefer, D. (1990) The Demand for Housing and Permanent Income in Indonesia. Urban Studies 21, 259-272.

Singh, I., L. Squire, and J. Strauss (1986) Agricultural Household Models: Extensions, Applications and Policy. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

Takasaki, Y., B. Barham, and O. Goomes (2000) Rapid-rural Appraisal in Humid Tropical Forests: An Asset Possession-based Approach and Validation Methods for Wealth Assessment Among Forest Peasant Households. World Development 28:11, 1961-1977.

Tiwari, P. and J. Parik (1998) Affordability, Housing Demand and Housing Policy in Urban India. Urban Studies 35:11, 2111-2129.

Townsend, P. (1985) A Sociological Approach to the Measurement of Poverty: A Rejoinder to Professor Amartya Sen. Oxford Economic Papers 37, 659-668.

UN-Habitat (2016) World Cities Report 2016: Urbanisation and Development Emerging Futures. United Nations Human Settlements Programme (UN-Habitat), Nairobi, Kenya.

Wang, Y. P. (1995) Public Sector Housing in Urban China since 1949: The Case of Xian. Housing Studies 10:1, 57-82.

Wooldridge, J. M. (2006) CLuster-Sample Methods in Applied Econometrics. Cluster-Sample Methods in Applied Econometrics: An Extended Analysis.

Zabal, J. E. (2004) The Demand for Housing Services. Journal of Housing Economics 13:1, 16-35.
Table 1
Housing Units (TrendAnalysis)

               All Areas         Rural           Urban

Region        1981    1998    1981    1998    1981    1998

Housing units (million)

Pakistan      12.51   19.21   9.01    13.18   3.50    6.03
KPK           1.61    2.21    1.38    1.84    0.23    0.37
Punjab        7.53    10.54   5.57    7.34    1.96    3.20
Sindh         2.78    5.02    1.56    2.85    1.22    2.17
Balochistan   0.59    0.97    0.50    0.78    0.09    0.20

Housing units as percent of total across the rural urban

Pakistan      100.0   100.0   72.0    68.6    28.0    31.4
KPK           100.0   100.0   85.7    83.3    14.3    16.7
Punjab        100.0   100.0   74.0    69.6    26.0    30.4
Sindh         100.0   100.0   56.1    56.8    43.9    43.2
Balochistan   100.0   100.0   84.7    79.9    15.3    20.1

Housing units as percent of total across the provinces

Pakistan      100.0   100.0   100.0   100.0   100.0   100.0
KPK           12.9    11.5    15.3    14.0     6.6     6.1
Punjab        60.2    54.8    61.8    55.7    56.0    53.1
Sindh         22.2    26.1    17.3    21.6    34.9    36.0
Balochistan    4.7     5.1     5.5     5.9     2.6     3.2

Persons per housing unit

Pakistan      6.73    6.89    6.70    6.78    6.83    7.14
KPK           6.87    8.03    6.81    8.01    7.39    8.08
Punjab        6.28    6.98    6.16    6.89    6.63    7.19
Sindh         6.84    6.06    5.26    5.47    8.85    6.84
Balochistan   7.32    6.76    7.40    6.40    7.78    7.85

Source: Population Census (1981, 1998).

Table 2
Nature of Tenure (Percentages) by Rural/Urban Areas

                           1981                    1998

                    All    Rural   Urban    All    Rural   Urban
Nature of Tenure   Areas                   Areas

All Types           100     100     100     100     100     100
Owned              78.4    82.6    67.7    81.2    86.8    68.9
Rented              7.7     2.2    21.9     8.6     2.2    22.7
Rent Free          13.9    15.2    10.5    10.2    11.0     8.4

                          2004-05                 2010-11

                    All    Rural   Urban    All    Rural   Urban
Nature of Tenure   Areas                   Areas

All Types           100     100     100     100     100     100
Owned              86.6    92.8    78.4    85.9    91.2    75.7
Rented              8.1     1.5    16.8     8.1     2.0    19.9
Rent Free           5.3     5.7     4.8     6.0     6.8     4.4

Source: Population Census (1981, 1998);
PSLM (2004-05 and 2010-11).

Table 3
Congestion of Housing Units

                                                1981

Indicators                           Pakistan    KPK    Punjab

Persons per Housing Unit               6.70     7.00     6.50
Persons per Room                       3.50     3.60     3.30
Single Room Housing Units (%)         51.54     50.00   48.00
Two Rooms Housing Units (%)           44.83     4.00    48.00
3-4 Rooms Housing Units (%)            3.63     46.00    4.00
5 and more Rooms Housing Units (%)     6.70     7.00     6.50

                                                1998

Persons per Housing Unit               6.80     8.00     6.90
Persons per Room                       3.13     3.34     3.04
Single Room Housing Units (%)         38.11     27.71   31.97
Two Rooms Housing Units (%)           30.54     34.50   33.54
3-4 Rooms Housing Units (%)           24.43     29.11   27.12.
5 and more Rooms Housing Units (%)     6.92     8.67     7.36

                                          1981

Indicators                           Sindh   Balochistan

Persons per Housing Unit             7.10       7.60
Persons per Room                     4.00       4.20
Single Room Housing Units (%)        61.00      60.00
Two Rooms Housing Units (%)          36.00      36.00
3-4 Rooms Housing Units (%)          3.00       4.00
5 and more Rooms Housing Units (%)   7.10       7.60

                                          1998

Persons per Housing Unit             6.00       6.70
Persons per Room                     3.37       3.07
Single Room Housing Units (%)        56.93      42.77
Two Rooms Housing Units (%)          23.87      25.18
3-4 Rooms Housing Units (%)          17.00      22.69
5 and more Rooms Housing Units (%)   3.56       9.36

Source: Population Census (1981 and 1998).

Table 4
Congestion of Housing Units

                                               2004-05

Indicators                           Pakistan    KPK    Punjab

Persons per Housing Unit               6.75     7.71     6.55
Single Room Housing Units (%)         24.20     18.35    24.75
2-4 Rooms Housing Units (%)           68.71     69.90    68.69
5 and more Rooms Housing Units (%)     7.09     11.75    6.56

                                               2010-11

Persons per Housing Unit               6.38     7.17     6.16
Single Room Housing Units (%)         24.83     19.03    26.09
2-4 Rooms Housing units (%)           69.33     72.62    67.49
5 and more Rooms Housing units (%)     5.84     8.32     6.43

                                         2004-05

Indicators                           Sindh   Balochistan

Persons per Housing Unit             6.71       6.88
Single Room Housing Units (%)        30.76      14.79
2-4 Rooms Housing Units (%)          65.00      75.78
5 and more Rooms Housing Units (%)   4.24       9.43

                                         2010-11

Persons per Housing Unit             6.39       7.08
Single Room Housing Units (%)        25.67      20.89
2-4 Rooms Housing units (%)          70.94      75.02
5 and more Rooms Housing units (%)   3.39       4.09

Source: PSLM (2004-05 and 2010-11).

Table 5
Profile of the Sample of PSLM Survey (2004-05 and 2010-11)

                          Sample PSUs             Sample SSUs

Province/Area        Urban   Rural   Total   Urban   Rural   Total

                            2010-11

Punjab                256     256     512    2935    4019    6954
Sindh                 152     144     296    1802    2296    4098
Khyber Pakhtunkhwa    88      120     208    1041    1913    2954
Balochistan           68      96      164     811    1524    2335
Total                 564     616    1180    6589    9752    16341

                            2004-05

Punjab                210     226     436    2511    3607    6118
Sindh                 125     125     250    1497    1980    3477
Khyber Pakhtunkhwa    91      118     209    1088    1878    2966
Balochistan           60      90      150     713    1434    2147
Total                 486     559    1045    5809    8899    14708

Source: PSLM/HIES (2004-05 and 2010-11).

Table 6
Tenure Choice Regression 2004-05 (Income Group Wise)

                              Low-income

Variables             Coefficient   Margin effect

Permanent Income        13.030          3.246
                      (1.01) ***     (0.30) ***
Transitory Income       -0.150         -0.037
                        (0.18)         (0.05)
House Price              0.823          0.205
                       (0.33) **      (0.08) **
Affordability            5.162          1.286
                      (1.53) ***     (0.39) ***
Age                     -0.089         -0.022
                      (0.01) ***     (0.00) ***
Number of Earners       -1.180         -0.294
                      (0.11) ***     (0.03) ***
Head's Education        -5.826         -0.893
                      (0.46) ***     (0.03) ***
Household Size          -0.436         -0.109
                      (0.04) ***     (0.01) ***
Gender                   1.340          0.468
                      (0.39) ***     (0.15) ***
Marital Status          -1.113         -0.168
                      (0.33) ***     (0.03) ***
Intercept              -152.635
                      (11.49) ***
City Dummies              Yes            Yes
No. of Observations       784            784

                            Middle-income

Variables             Coefficient   Margin effect

Permanent Income         8.211          2.405
                      (0.53) ***     (0.17) ***
Transitory Income       -0.244         -0.071
                       (0.10) **      (0.03) **
House Price              0.962          0.282
                      (0.19) ***     (0.05) ***
Affordability            4.087          1.197
                      (1.10) ***     (0.32) ***
Age                     -0.048         -0.014
                      (0.01) ***     (0.00) ***
Number of Earners       -0.708         -0.207
                      (0.06) ***     (0.02) ***
Head's Education        -3.709         -0.541
                      (0.26) ***     (0.03) ***
Household Size          -0.271         -0.079
                      (0.03) ***     (0.01) ***
Gender                   0.730          0.257
                      (0.22) ***     (0.09) ***
Marital Status          -0.064         -0.018
                        (0.16)         (0.05)
Intercept              -106.222
                      (6.16) ***
City Dummies              Yes            Yes
No. of Observations      1,402          1,402

                             High-income

Variables             Coefficient   Margin effect

Permanent Income         6.450          1.659
                      (0.77) ***     (0.22) ***
Transitory Income       -0.241         -0.062
                       (0.14) *       (0.04) *
House Price              1.571          0.404
                      (0.27) ***     (0.06) ***
Affordability            2.162          0.556
                        (1.55)         (0.40)
Age                     -0.034         -0.009
                      (0.01) ***     (0.00) ***
Number of Earners       -0.569         -0.146
                      (0.11) ***     (0.03) ***
Head's Education        -2.993         -0.243
                      (0.46) ***     (0.03) ***
Household Size          -0.293         -0.075
                      (0.05) ***     (0.01) ***
Gender                   0.832          0.273
                       (0.37) **      (0.14) *
Marital Status          -0.702         -0.137
                       (0.36) **     (0.05) ***
Intercept               -99.540
                      (9.58) ***
City Dummies
No. of Observations       485            485

Note: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1, Figures
in parenthesis are robust standard errors.

Table 7
Tenure Choice Regression 2010-2011 (Income Group Wise)

                              Low-income

Variables             Coefficient   Margin Effect

Permanent Income         1.264          0.405
                      (0.47) ***     (0.15) ***
Transitory Income       -0.396         -0.127
                      (0.13) ***     (0.04) ***
House Price              1.781          0.570
                      (0.25) ***     (0.08) ***
Affordability            0.638          0.204
                       (0.32) **      (0.10) **
Age                     -0.001         -0.000
                        (0.01)         (0.00)
Number of Earners       -0.196         -0.063
                      (0.07) ***     (0.02) ***
Head's Education        -0.717         -0.213
                      (0.24) ***     (0.07) ***
Household Size          -0.079         -0.025
                       (0.03) **      (0.01) **
Gender                   0.784          0.290
                      (0.26) ***     (0.10) ***
Marital Status          -0.632         -0.166
                      (0.22) ***     (0.05) ***
Intercept               -38.854
                      (5.81) ***
City Dummies              Yes            Yes
No. of Observations       944            944

                            Middle-income

Variables             Coefficient   Margin Effect

Permanent Income         1.391          0.465
                      (0.41) ***     (0.14) ***
Transitory Income       -0.176         -0.059
                       (0.09) **      (0.03) **
House Price              1.175          0.393
                      (0.17) ***     (0.06) ***
Affordability            1.435          0.480
                      (0.28) ***     (0.09) ***
Age                      0.003          0.001
                        (0.00)         (0.00)
Number of Earners       -0.253         -0.085
                      (0.05) ***     (0.02) ***
Head's Education        -0.888         -0.251
                      (0.21) ***     (0.05) ***
Household Size          -0.016         -0.005
                        (0.03)         (0.01)
Gender                   0.474          0.174
                       (0.19) **      (0.07) **
Marital Status          -0.337         -0.103
                       (0.15) **      (0.04) **
Intercept               -33.092
                      (4.85) ***
City Dummies              Yes            Yes
No. of Observations      1,484          1,484

                             High-income

Variables             Coefficient   Margin Effect

Permanent Income         3.546          1.142
                      (0.71) ***     (0.24) ***
Transitory Income       -0.206         -0.066
                       (0.12) *       (0.04) *
House Price              2.113          0.681
                      (0.24) ***     (0.07) ***
Affordability            0.730          0.235
                      (0.21) ***     (0.07) ***
Age                     -0.008         -0.002
                        (0.01)         (0.00)
Number of Earners       -0.475         -0.153
                      (0.10) ***     (0.03) ***
Head's Education        -2.362         -0.340
                      (0.41) ***     (0.03) ***
Household Size          -0.137         -0.044
                      (0.05) ***     (0.02) ***
Gender                   0.361          0.126
                        (0.30)         (0.11)
Marital Status          -0.415         -0.118
                        (0.27)        (0.07) *
Intercept               -74.003
                      (9.19) ***
City Dummies              Yes            Yes
No. of Observations       624            624

Note: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1, Figures
in parenthesis are robust standard errors.

Table 8
Housing Demand at National Level (Dependent Variable Housing Units)

Variable                  2004-05      2010-11

Permanent Income           0.0190      -0.0430
                          (0.0200)    (0.01) ***
Transitory Income          0.0330       0.0390
                         (0.00) ***   (0.00) ***
House Price               -0.0270      -0.0420
                         (0.00) ***   (0.01) ***
Affordability              0.1850       0.0080
                         (0.02) ***   (0.00) ***
Age                        0.0000       0.0010
                           0.0000     (0.00) ***
Number of Earners         -0.0010       0.0020
                           0.0000     (0.00) ***
Head's Education           0.0080       0.0450
                          (0.0100)    (0.01) ***
Household Size            -0.0010       0.0030
                           0.0000     (0.00) ***
Gender                    -0.0070      -0.0070
                          (0.0100)      (0.01)
Marital Status             0.0000       0.0060
                           0.0000     (0.00) ***
Middle-income Group        0.0030       0.0240
                          (0.0100)    (0.01) ***
High-income Group          0.0110       0.0840
                          (0.0200)    (0.02) ***
Lambda                    -0.0020      -0.0180
                           0.0000      (0.01) *
Intercept                  0.9820       2.0370
                         (0.23) ***   (0.23) ***
City Dummies                Yes          Yes
Number of Observations      2752        3,040
R-squared                  0.107        0.119

Note: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1, Figures
in parenthesis are robust standard errors.

Table 9
Housing Demand by Income Group (Dependent Variable Housing Unit)

                                      2004-05

Variables             Low-income   Middle-income   High-income

Permanent Income        0.0600        0.0240         0.0780
                       (0.04) *      (0.0300)       (0.04) *
Transitory Income       0.0360        0.0270         0.0280
                      (0.01) ***    (0.00) ***     (0.01) ***
House Price            -0.0450        -0.0270        -0.0100
                      (0.01) ***    (0.01) ***      (0.0100)
Affordability           0.3620        0.1510         0.2410
                      (0.04) ***    (0.04) ***     (0.06) ***
Age                     0.0000        0.0000         0.0000
                       (0.000)        (0.000)        (0.000)
Number of Earners      -0.0060        -0.0030        0.0010
                       (0.000)        (0.000)        (0.000)
Head's Education       (0.0090)       0.0050        (0.0200)
                       (0.0200)      (0.0100)       (0.0200)
Household Size         -0.0010        0.0000         -0.0050
                        0.0000        0.0000        (0.00) **
Gender                 (0.0110)       0.0070        (0.0110)
                       (0.0100)      (0.0100)       (0.0100)
Marital Status         (0.0040)      (0.0020)       (0.0080)
                       (0.0100)      (0.0100)       (0.0100)
Lambda                  0.0050       (0.0040)        0.0310
                       (0.0100)      (0.0100)       (0.01) **
Intercept               0.6310        0.9640         0.0240
                       (0.4100)     (0.32) ***      (0.5800)
City                     yes            Yes            yes
No. of Observations      784           1402            485
R-squared               0.2390        0.0980         0.2640

                                     2010-2011

Variables             Low-income   Middle-income   High-income

Permanent Income       (0.0240)       -0.049         -0.009
                       (0.0200)     (0.02) ***       (0.04)
Transitory Income       0.0320         0.042          0.02
                      (0.00) ***    (0.00) ***     (0.00) ***
House Price            -0.0410        -0.054         -0.019
                      (0.01) ***    (0.01) ***      (0.01) *
Affordability           0.0040         0.004          0.01
                      (0.00) ***    (0.00) ***       (0.01)
Age                     0.0010         0.000          0.001
                      (0.00) ***    (0.00) ***     (0.00) ***
Number of Earners       0.0010         0.004         -0.002
                      (0.00) ***    (0.00) ***     (0.00) ***
Head's Education        0.0310         0.051          0.028
                      (0.01) ***    (0.01) ***       (0.02)
Household Size          0.0010         0.002          0.002
                      (0.00) ***     (0.00) **     (0.00) ***
Gender                 -0.0210        -0.002         -0.012
                      (0.01) **       (0.01)         (0.01)
Marital Status          0.0150         0.002          0.011
                       (0.01) *       (0.01)         (0.01)
Lambda                 (0.0250)       -0.045          0.028
                       (0.01) *     (0.01) ***      (0.01) **
Intercept               1.8210         2.333          1.307
                      (0.32) ***    (0.25) ***      (0.57) **
City                     yes            Yes            Yes
No. of Observations    944.0000        1,484           612
R-squared               0.2030         0.16           0.297

Note: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1, Figures

Table 10
Housing Demand: A Provincial Comparison (Dependent Variable Housing
Unit)

                              Punjab                     Sindh

Variables              2004-05      2010-11      2004-05      2010-11

Permanent Income        0.014        0.000        0.038        0.044
                       (0.01) *      (0.01)     (0.01) ***   (0.01) ***
Transitory Income       0.025        0.031        0.045        0.047
                      (0.00) ***   (0.00) ***   (0.00) ***   (0.00) ***
House Price             -0.021       -0.017       -0.017       -0.011
                      (0.00) ***   (0.00) ***   (0.01) ***   (0.00) **
Affordability           0.152        0.044        0.199        0.004
                      (0.03) ***   (0.01) ***   (0.05) ***    (0.00) *
Age                     0.000        0.000        -0.000       0.000
                        (0.00)      (0.00) *      (0.00)       (0.00)
No. of Earners          0.000        -0.000       -0.002       -0.009
                        (0.00)       (0.00)       (0.00)     (0.00) ***
Head's Education        0.009        0.014        0.004        0.011
                       (0.00) *    (0.00) ***     (0.01)      (0.01) *
Household Size          -0.000       0.001        -0.001       -0.003
                        (0.00)       (0.00)       (0.00)     (0.00) ***
Gender                  -0.009       0.001        -0.003       -0.005
                        (0.01)       (0.01)       (0.01)       (0.01)
Marital Status           0003        -0.001       -0.004       0.001
                        (0.01)       (0.00)       (0.01)       (0.01)
Intercept                0988        1.200        0.614        0.636
                      (0.05) ***   (0.05) ***   (0.07) ***   (0.07) ***
No. of Observations     1,385        1,542         971         1,089
R-squared               0.066        0.106        0.144        0.247

                               KPK                  Balochistan

Variables              2004-05     2010-11      2004-05      2010-11

Permanent Income       -0.047       0.023        -0.035       0.074
                      (0.02)**      (0.02)       (0.03)     (0.03) **
Transitory Income       0.017       0.008        0.033        0.063
                      (0.01)**      (0.01)     (0.01) ***   (0.01) ***
House Price             0.002       -0.030       -0.014       -0.087
                       (0.01)     (0.01) **      (0.02)     (0.01) ***
Affordability           0.071       -0.005       0.124        0.144
                       (0.10)       (0.01)      (0.07) *    (0.04) ***
Age                     0.000       0.000        0.001        0.000
                       (0.00)       (0.00)     (0.00) **      (0.00)
No. of Earners         -0.001       -0.005       0.003        -0.008
                       (0.00)       (0.00)       (0.01)       (0.01)
Head's Education        0.023       -0.008       0.058        0.017
                       (0.01)       (0.01)     (0.01) ***     (0.02)
Household Size          0.001       0.001        -0.001       -0.001
                       (0.00)       (0.00)       (0.00)       (0.00)
Gender                 -0.011       0.022        0.034        0.061
                       (0.02)       (0.02)       (0.03)       (0.05)
Marital Status          0.016       -0.019       -0.016       -0.016
                       (0.02)       (0.01)       (0.02)       (0.02)
Intercept               1.451       1.127        1.394        1.218
                      (0.15)***   (0.18) ***   (0.21) ***   (0.27) ***
No. of Observations      234         231          162          178
R-squared               0.126       0.078        0.263        0.391

Note: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 level of
significance and standard errors are
highlighted in parentheses.

Fig. 1. Distribution of Housing Units across Provinces

KPK;           11.5
Punjab;        54.8
Sindh;         26.1
Balochistan;    5.1

Source: Authors' own calculation base on the "Population Census
1998".

Note: Table made from bar graph.
COPYRIGHT 2018 Reproduced with permission of the Publications Division, Pakistan Institute of Development Economies, Islamabad, Pakistan.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.

联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有