E-government, economic growth and trade: a simultaneous equation approach.
Majeed, Muhammad Tariq ; Malik, Amna
E-government, economic growth and trade: a simultaneous equation approach.
Does e-government promote trade and economic growth? This paper
attempts to answer this question by employing simultaneous equation
estimation approach and using a cross-section data of 147 countries.
This is first study which has empirically estimated the bilateral
relationships between economic growth and e-government, trade and
e-government and trade and economic growth. The findings indicate that
e-government is a stimulant of both economic growth and trade. The
results predict the presence of a bilateral relationship between
e-government and economic growth, trade and e-government, and unilateral
causality exists from trade to growth.
JEL Classification: F14; H10; 040
Keywords: E-government; Economic Growth; Trade
1. INTRODUCTION
The study on economic growth is dated back from Adam Smith (1776)
discussed in his famous book "wealth of nation". There are
many theories of economic growth presented by different economists,
according to the situation that have been prevailed during that time
[Ricardo (1817); Harrod (1939); Domer (1946); Solow (1956)]. The pioneer
of theoretical framework of economic growth is Solow (1956) and his
model was employed by Barro (1991); Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992); and
Quah (1993, 1997).
Trade is an important topic that has been captured the attention of
policy makers since the start of previous century. The debate on trade
has been dated back from many decades but yet there is no consensus
about the positive consequences of trade on economic growth. The
positive influence of trade on economic growth is empirically supported
by [Edwards (1998); Wacziarg (2001); Greenaway, et al. (2002)] whereas
[Rodriguez and Rodrik (1999)] doubted the robustness of positive
relationship between trade and economic growth. In this study we
empirically check the association of trade with economic growth by
incorporating e-government. The trade and e-government have bilateral
relationship. Trade promotes e-government by diffusion of technologies
and on the other hand e-government promotes trade by overcoming non-
tariff barriers and asymmetric information.
E-government is referred to online availability of government to
provide quick and efficient services to masses of people. Von Haldenwang
(2004) defined e-government as a practice of information and
communication technology (1CT) in public administration. E-government
facilitates government in efficient provision of services to citizen by
employing ICT infrastructure [Tandon (2005); Chen, et al. (2009); and
Krishnan and Teo (2012)].
The theoretical studies on e-government emphasise its role in
enhancing the efficiency of public sector and public administration [Al
Kibsi, et al. (2001); Von Haldenwang (2004); and West (2004)] and
increasing the marginal productivity of labour by mitigating the
disguised unemployment [Grimes, Ren, and Steven (2012)]. In spite of its
importance the empirical research on e-government is on embryonic
stages. After reading vast literature we got insights about empirically
investigating its role in promoting trade and economic.
E-government contributes in economic growth through trade openness
by providing online availability of government and web connections.
Trade also significantly contributes in output growth by tapping full
potential of world resources that will help to mitigate poverty,
malnourishment, infant mortality rate, illiteracy, unemployment, and
inequality. The consensus about the positive relationship between trade
and economic growth is yet not achieved. The advocates of positive
relationship between trade and economic growth are [Rivera-Batiz and
Romer (1990); Grossman and Helpman (1991); Edwards (1998); Wacziarg
(2001); and Greenaway, et al. (2002)] whereas [Rodriguez and Rodrik
(1999)] questioned the robustness of positive association between trade
liberalisation and economic growth. Most of the studies empirically
confirm the positive association between trade and economic growth.
Thus, to reap full potential of trade we have to mitigate tariff and
non-tariff barriers. The hindrance in the way of trade openness is not
only tariffs but also non-tariff barriers such as asymmetric
information, transportation cost and low interaction between traders.
The non-tariff barriers in the way of liberalise economy can be
overwhelmed by e-government through cheap access to refine information
and interaction between traders. E-government can upsurge economic
development of country by facilitating trade. There are few studies
which have taken into account of internet role in facilitating trade
liberalisation [Choi and Hoon Yi (2009); Clarke and Wallsten (2006);
Freund and Weinhold (2004); Vemuri and Saddiqi (2009)]. These studies
predicted internet as a trade stimulant.
The impact of e-government on trade in empirical literature is
missing. We fill this gap by taking into account of bilateral
relationships between trade, e-government and economic growth by
employing simultaneous equation model. Our study empirically explores
e-government-trade, trade-economic growth and e-government-trade nexus.
By advocating the bilateral relationship between trade and economic
growth we are able to find the direct and indirect impact of trade on
economic growth through e-government.
The study is arranged as follows: Section 2 presents the literature
on economic growth, e-government and trade. Section 3 discusses the
empirical framework of our study. Section 4 describes data and its
statistical analysis. Section 5 presents and interprets empirical
findings of simultaneous equation model. Finally Section 6 concludes and
suggests policies.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
In this section we explore the literature on the relationships
between economic growth, e-government and trade.
2.1. E-government and Economic Growth
E-government provides efficient services to masses of people that
stimulate economic growth. The efficient provision of responsibilities
towards nation facilitates trade by providing cheap access to
information and efficient allocation of resources to those projects that
reap high returns, and facilitate interaction among investors. The
electronic government through information and communication
infrastructure enhances productive potential of economy. E-government
stimulates output growth of the country by disseminating information and
spilling over the knowledge and cutting down transaction and
transportation cost. Salvatore (1996) points out that East Asia
"miracle" was based on strong government support for domestic
industry while stimulating competition and efficiency among domestic
firms.
Summer (1999) illustrated the importance of software development in
setting up new information based modern economy. He demonstrated that
information technology is contributing significantly in output growth of
a country. Shamim (2007) empirically analysed the effect of
telecommunication technologies on output growth by taking data of 61
countries over the year of 1990 to 2001. She proposed that
telecommunication technologies provide refine information, mitigate the
data processing cost and asymmetric information, and facilitate
interaction between buyer and seller. The results indicated that
positive impact of financial development is mediated by e-government or
telecommunication technology.
Choi and Yi (2009) investigated empirically the effect of internet
on output growth using the panel data for 217 countries from 1991 to
2000. The findings indicate that 1 percent increase in internet
subscribers up surges growth about 0.05 percent. Krishnan, Teo, and Lim
(2013) argued that impact of e-government on growth is mediated by
control of corruption and environmental degradation. They use averaged
data over the period 2004-2008. Their finding inferred that direct
impact of e-government on economic prosperity is insignificant and its
impact on growth is intermediated by control of corruption and
environmental degradation.
According to Czemich, et al. (2011) broadband "fast speed
internet" has positive effect on output growth. They have
empirically investigated the impact of broadband on economic growth by
taking data of OECD countries over the years of 1996 to 2007. Their
results indicate that broadband upsurges growth up to 3.9 percent.
Mahyideen, et al. (2012) proposed that ICT upsurge economic development
by enhancing productivity and cutting down production cost. They
empirically explored the relationship between economic prosperity and
information and communication technologies (ICT) for ASEAN countries
from 1976 to 2010. The results of granger causality supported long run
relationship between ICT and economic growth.
2.2. Trade and Economic Growth
There is vast theoretical as well as empirical literature on the
impacts of trade liberalisation on economic growth but debate is yet not
settled. The contradiction in consequences of trade on growth in not
only lies between theoretical but also lies within empirical literature.
The positive impacts of trade liberalisation on output growth are
advocated by theoretical models of many economists [Grossman and Helpman
(1991); Rivera-Batiz and Romer (1990); and Devereux and Lapham (1994)]
and theoretical framework on negative implication of trade on economic
growth is proposed by Redding (2002). Likewise, empirical studies have
also polarised into positive and negative consequences of trade
liberalisation on economic growth. The positive impact of trade on
economic growth in empirical studies is advocated by [Edwards (1998);
Wacziarg (2001); and Greenaway, et al. (2002)] whereas Rodriguez and
Rodrik (1999) doubted the robustness of positive effect of trade on
output growth. The negative relationship between trade-growth nexus is
demonstrated by Clemens and Williamson (2000); and Vamvakidis (2002).
Winter (2004) doubted on robustness of positive impact of trade on
economic growth. He demonstrated that relationship between economic
growth and trade depends on omitted variables in regression. He proposed
that consequences of trade on economic growth can vary in the case of
inclusion of education, corruption, institutional strength, political
stability, and level of development of a country. Using a panel data for
42 countries, Parikh (2006) estimates the effect of trade liberalisation
on growth and growth on trade balance. The study finds out that trade
liberalisation promotes growth in most countries, but the growth itself
has a negative impact on trade balance.
Kneller, et al. (2008) empirically founded relationship between
trade liberalisation and economic growth is heterogonous in different
countries. He has taken panel data of 37 countries and introduced dummy
variable that is one for the time period when it starts to liberalise.
Their findings inferred that trade liberalisation has increased overall
growth rate of post-liberalisation period about 2.4 percent per annum
but out of 37, the growth rate of 20 countries has decease in after
liberalisation. Shachmurove and Spiegel (2010) analysed the welfare of
nations in a globalised economy. They point out less welfare effects in
a more globalised world.
2.3. E-government and Trade
The impediments of trade are not only tariffs but also non-tariff
barriers such as transaction cost and lack of information. Collier and
Gunning (1999) alleged that particular obstacle in the way of economic
growth in Africa is transaction cost. E-government through online
availability and web connection can fill this gap in the way of open
economy. E-government also accelerates trade by decreasing transaction
cost, facilitating interaction between traders, providing refine and
clear information on quality, demand and supply, markets, and prices of
different products.
Mattoo, Rathindran, and Subrama (2001) empirically investigated the
impact of liberalisation in service on economic growth of the country.
He argued that consequences of service liberalisation are different from
trade liberalisation. The empirically results of the study inferred that
telecommunication services and financial services have positive and
significant impact on output growth whereas impact of financial services
is stronger than telecommunication services. They conclude that the
economy having open telecom and financial services tends to grow 1.5
percent higher.
We cannot blame merely tariff as a resistance of trade
liberalisation but various transactions, communication, and fixed entry
costs also responsible for restricting smooth trade in the country.
Majeed and Ahmad (2006) in their study of determinants of exports in
developing countries enunciated the importance of communication
technologies in encouraging exports. They proposed that communication
technologies such as internet and mobile phones have significant impact
on exports of developing countries.
Clarke and Wallsten (2006) scrutinised the impact of internet on
trade for both developing and developed countries. The findings of their
study suggested that internet has positive impact on trade only in
developing countries. Meijers (2014) investigated growth-internet,
internet-trade, and trade-growth nexus by taking archive data of 162
countries over the time period 1990-2008. The result of simultaneous
equation model confirmed that the growth impact of internet is mediated
by trade whereas direct effect of internet on growth is insignificant.
Kurihara and Fukushima (2013) examined how internet facilitates
trade in 34 developed and 24 Asian countries for year 2005 and 2010 by
employing gravity trade model. Their findings indicate that internet has
stronger positive effect on trade in developing countries than developed
countries in 2005. Yadav (2014) studied the impact of internet on
exports and imports of 52 Asian and sub-Saharan African countries from
2006 to 2010. He proposed that internet has significant effect on export
and import of firms in extensive and intensive margin in Asian and
Sub-Saharan African countries. He mentioned that firm has to face fixed
information cost to enter into international market but internet save
firms from entry costs. Freund and Weinhold (2004) also supported that
internet is a trade stimulant in a sample of 56 developing countries.
The above literature shows that trade-growth nexus is empirically
investigated by economist, but the association of this nexus with
e-government is ignored. Furthermore, the existing literature focuses
different components of e-government such as internet to explain growth
but does not incorporate a comprehensive measure of e-government. The
present study fills these gaps in the literature. 3
3. SIMULTANEOUS EQUATION MODEL
E-government stimulates economic growth directly and also
indirectly by stimulating trade. Trade regulates e-government by
integrating different economies which facilitate diffusion and spillover
of knowledge whereas e-government enhances trade by facilitating
interaction between traders and foreign investors. The prevailing case
of interrelationship among three endogenous variables calls for a need
of simultaneous equations model. The empirical framework of our study is
based on three simultaneous equations to estimate direct and indirect
impacts of e-government on economic growth.
3.1. Equation of Economic Growth
The model of economic growth employed in our study is stemmed from
Solow (1956) which has CRS (constant returns to scale) and two inputs
y = f (A, K, L)
Mankiw, et al. (1992) extended the theoretical models of Solow
(1956) and Koopmans (1969) by relaxing the convergence condition.
According to absolute convergence theory the poor countries will catch
up the per-capita of rich countries due to high marginal productivity of
capital. In order to fulfil the convergence condition we have introduced
initial per-capita in our empirical growth model.
[y.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][y.sub.initial,i] +
[[beta].sub.2][A.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3][K.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.4][L.sub.i] + [e.sub.i] ... ... ... (1)
The advocates of endogenous growth model see divergence in
per-capita income due to divergence on technological potential of
country. The steady state growth rate of country varies due to
differences in technological progress and innovations [Barro (1991) and
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1991)]. Technological progress has proxied by
information and communication technology in different studies and
intuition behind using ICT "as a proxy for technology" is high
labour marginal productivity due to information and communication
technology [Jorgenson, et al. (2007); van Ark, et al. (2008); Oliner, et
al. (2008)]. Few studies emphasised on information technology (internet)
in order to measure the divergence in per-capita due to gaps in
technological potential [Clarke and Wallsten (2006); Meijers (2014)]. We
measure technology by e-government. The equation 1 is modified as
[y.sub.i] = [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][y.sub.initial,i] +
[[beta].sub.2]E[G.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3][K.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.4][L.sub.i] + [e.sub.i] ... ... ... (2)
The technological diffusion across the world can be driven by
economic integration of world. The economic integration will help in
diffusion and spill over knowledge and information and excite innovation
in the country. Acemoglu and Ventura (2002) proposed the model that
describes convergence in per-capita in terms of international trade. We
also address the impact of trade on economic growth following same
rationale. The left side variable is economic growth, K. is capital
stock, and L is labour force. The error term of equation is shown by
[e.sub.i].
[y.sub.i] - [[beta].sub.0] + [[beta].sub.1][y.sub.initial,i] +
[[beta].sub.2]E[G.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.3][K.sub.i] +
[[beta].sub.4][L.sub.i] + [[beta].sub.5][Trade.sub.i] + [e.sub.i] ...
(3)
3.2. Equation of Trade
The economic integration of world can be stimulated by e-government
through its information and telecommunication infrastructures, skilled
labour, and web connectivity. Different studies have explored merely
internet as a stimulant of trade liberalisation [Kurihara and Fukushima
(2013); Meijers (2014); and Yadav (2014)].
We are interested to explore reverse relationship between trade
liberalisation and economic growth. The equation three explains the
impact of trade on economic growth but in equation 4 we have
incorporated economic growth as a determinant of trade. Egovernment
stimulates trade by delivering cheap information and facilitating
interaction among traders.
Trade = [[alpha].sub.0] + [[alpha].sub.1][Trade.sub.initial,i] +
[[alpha].sub.2][y.sub.i] + [[alpha].sub.3]E[G.sub.i] +
[[alpha].sub.4]Tarif[f.sub.i] +
[[alpha].sub.5]Exchange[rate.sub.i]+[u.sub.i] ... ... ... ... ... ...
(4)
In order to determine the indirect impact of e-government on trade
we have introduced interactive term of economic growth and e-government.
The exchange rate is an important determinant of trade. Trade
liberalisation depends on protection level in a country. The tariff rate
is a measure of trade protection in a country and exerts a negative
influence on trade liberalisation.
[Trade.sub.i] = [[alpha].sub.0] +
[[alpha].sub.1][Trade.sub.initial,i] + [[alpha].sub.2][y.sub.i] +
[[alpha].sub.3]E[G.sub.i] + [[alpha].sub.4]Y x E[G.sub.i] +
[[alpha].sub.5]Exchange [rate.sub.i] + [[alpha].sub.6]Tarif [f.sub.i] +
[u.sub.i] ... ... ... (5)
3.3. Equation of E-government
The adoption of ICT tools by government for efficient provision of
its services depends on economic growth of the country. The installation
of latest technology in public sectors is regulated by economic
performance of the country. The latest technology is usually innovated
and adopted by developed countries because they have sufficient budgets
to shift public sector from primitive to modern public administration.
According to Comin and Hobjin (2004) famous technologies are first
embraced by most of the developed countries. Czemich, et al. (2011)
proposed that there is reverse causal relationship between e-government
and economic growth. The other possibility of impact of output growth on
e-government is state intervention. The installation and penetration of
ICT infrastructure in public sector is regulated by state intervention
in economic decisions of country and state intervention is regulated by
economic growth of the country [OECD (2009)].
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
The diffusion of technology is stirred by economic and social
integration of countries. Here we are going to address only trade as a
measure of economic integration, to find out that how it promotes
e-government. The equation 6 can be written as
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
According to Czernich, et al. (2011) access to broadband usually
comes from fixed telephones and TV-cables lines. The fixed telephone
lines regulate online presence of government. Anderson (2008) proposed
that according to UDT (urban density theory) internet subscription
depends on urban population because cost of internet decreases as share
of urban population increases because of knowledge spillover,
availability of other substitutes of internet such as broadband. For
these reasons we incorporated fixed-telephones line and share of urban
population as determinants of e-government
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
4. DATA DESCRIPTION
The secondary data of 147 countries for the years of 2003 to 2012
is employed in this study. We have supported our study through cross
sectional data by taking averages of dataset from 2003 to 2012. The main
reason behind the choice of cross sectional data is missing data of
e-government. The data on e-government is not continuous but have
missing values. So the best alternate was to take the multiyear averages
of data produce more efficient and robust results than single year data.
The cross sectional data of multiyear averages give less sensitive
results [Wiggins and Ruefli (2005)].
E-government index is weighted average of online service and web
connection, telecommunication infrastructure, and human capital that can
use the tools of information and communication technologies. All the
components of e-government have equal weight of 0.33. The data lies in
the range of 0 to 1: zero indicates worst e-government quality whereas
one indicates best e-government quality.
The measure of economic growth is natural log of per capita GDP (at
current U.S dollars) whereas 1990 is base year of initial per-capita
income, measure of tariff is tariff rate of weighted mean, measure of
physical capital is gross fixed capital formation (percentage of GDP),
and measure of trade liberalisation is export plus import (percentage of
GDP).The data source of these variables is WDI [World Development
Indicators (2014)]. The data of fixed telephone lines is derived from
ITU (International Communication Union).
Figures 1, 2 and 3 show a positive association of trade and
e-government with economic growth and with each other. The bar charts
(Figures 4 and 5) indicate that trade is high in countries having good
quality e-government (see Appendix).
Table 4.2 presents the summary statistics of data. The minimum
value of e-government is 0.087 that is the value for Niger. Niger has
poorest e-government quality and Denmark has best e-government quality.
United States has minimum trade to GDP ratio that is only 27 percent and
Luxembourg has highest trade to GDP ratio and per capita income. Burundi
has lowest per capita income. The country having lowest tariff rate is
Macao (China) and country having highest tariff rate is Liberia.
In order to avoid biased result it is necessary to check the
functional forms of specified equations. Linktest (1) serves to find
that whether functional form of the equation is correct or not. Table 4
presents the results of linktest which indicate that coefficients of hat
square are not significant in Equations 3 and 8 which is a signal of no
concern of specification error in the equations. Hat square is the
square of the independent variables in an auxiliary regression to check
leverage. The insignificance of hat square illustrates that the variance
in independent variables is not causing fluctuation in dependent
variables.
5. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
We have applied Seemingly Unrelated Regressions (SUR), Two Stage
Least Squares (2SLS), and Three Stage Least Squares (3SLS). (2) The SUR
model takes into account correlation among error terms of all the
equations. The empirical finding of SUR model indicates that there is a
positive and significant relationship between economic growth and
e-government. The coefficient of e-government in 1st column of Table 5.1
implies that 1 percent increase in e-government quality brings 3.67
percent increase in economic growth. The coefficient of trade in 1st
column of Table 5.1 is also positive and significant which implies that
1 percent increase in trade causes 0.35 percent increment in economic
growth. The coefficient of initial per capita income 1st column of Table
5.1 implies that 1 percent increase in initial income will upsurge
growth about 0.52 percent. (3)
The 2nd column of Table 5.1 presents the empirical finding of
equation 5. The results confirm that e-government is a trade stimulant.
The coefficient of economic growth in 2nd column of Table 5.1 implies
that 1 percent increase in economic growth will cause 0.10 percent
increment in trade. The findings indicate the reverse causal
relationship from economic growth to trade. The interactive impact of
"e-government and economic growth" on trade is negative and
significant. The net effect of e-government on trade is 2.07 (2.33-
0.26) whereas net effect of economic growth on trade is -0.16
(0.10-0.26). It indicates that high per capita income is not
strengthening the positive impact of e-government on trade, the likely
reason of this effect may be self-sufficiency of a country after certain
threshold level of high per capita income.
The high economic growth can make country self-sufficient that
probably has negative impact on trade due to cutting down imports and
exports (retaliation of foreign country due to decreasing theirs
exports). Our data also indicates that United States has lowest trade to
GDP ratio. Tokarick (2008) stated that rich countries use an array of
protectionism policies in agriculture sector in order to protect their
farm industry. They usually protect their agriculture sector by
employing import qoutas, tariff on imports, and subsidies. Stiglitz and
Charleton (2005) also stated that the spending on agriculture subsidies
in OECD countries is more than 300 billion US$ per annum. Exchange rate
has insignificant impact on trade liberalisation whereas initial trade
value of trade has positive significant impact on trade liberalisation.
The coefficient of tariff indicates that 1 percent increase in tariff
rate will decrease trade about 1 percent.
The findings of equation 8 are reported in 3rd column of Table 5.1.
The coefficients of trade and economic growth in 3rd column of Table 5.1
infer that 1 percent increase in trade and economic growth will improve
quality of e-government about 0.038 percent and 0.032 percent. The
initial urban population and fixed telephone lines have also positive
influence on e-government. The findings of SUR indicate that there is
bilateral relationship between per capita income and e-government, per
capita income and trade liberalisation, and trade and e-government.
Columns (4-6) of Table 5.1 present the results of 2SLS model. The
results show that there is a bilateral causality between
"e-government and trade" and "per capita income and
e-government". There is unilateral causality between trade and per
capita income from trade openness to per capita income. Initial urban
population and fixed telephones lines is positively influencing the
e-government quality. High per capita income is offsetting the positive
impact of e-government on trade due to certain threshold level of per
capita income when country adopts protection policy.
In 7th to 9th column of Table 5.1 the empirical findings of 3SLS
are discussed. The results of 3SLS indicate that there is a bilateral
relationship between e-government and per capita income and trade and
per capita income. However, there is one way causality between
e-government and trade that is from e-government to trade. The results
of SUR model, 2SLS and 3SLS are almost consistent. All the simultaneous
equation techniques confirm that e-government is a stimulant of trade
but high per capita income offset its positive impact on trade because
of protection in the form of subsidies to its sectors [Stiglitz and
Charleton (2005)].
Simultaneous equation econometric techniques is ideal to estimate
the simultaneous equation if all the equation are correctly specified.
If one of the equations is miss specified then estimation with
simultaneous equation approach will spread biasness in all the equation.
In that case OLS is recommended. In order to evade from biasness and for
sensitivity analysis we have applied Ordinary Least Square model. Table
5.2 presents the results of OLS which also infer that there is a two way
causality between e-government and trade liberalisation and e-government
and per capita income but unilateral causality between trade
liberalisation and per capita income that is from trade to per capita
income. The coefficient of e-government in 1st and 2nd column of table
5.2 indicates that 1 percent increase in e-government quality will
enhance per capita growth about 3.22 percent and trade about 2.188
percent, respectively. The coefficient of trade in 1st and 3rd column of
Table 5.2 denotes that 1 percent increase in trade increase per capita
growth about 0.247 percent and e-government quality about 0.034 percent,
respectively.
The positive sign of the coefficients of initial urban population
and fixed telephones lines is consistent with urban density theory (4)
and the study of Anderson (2008). Anderson proposed that online service
and broadband are usually delivered from fixed telephone lines and cable
TV lines. We have also controlled our result by introducing the control
of corruption (as a proxy of institution) in growth equation and our
results remain consistent (see Table A3 in Appendix).
6. CONCLUSION
E-government is an important tool that enhances trade. The online
service of e-government promotes frequent interactions among traders and
improves the quality of information regarding price, quality, and
demands of goods. It can serve as an efficient tool to increases
marginal productivity of labour and alleviate disguise unemployment in
country by increasing trade. E-government is an important tool to
mitigate non-tariff barriers lies in the way of liberalise and open
economy. It facilitates a country in tapping the full potential of world
resources.
We determine the relationships between economic growth and
e-government, trade and e-government and trade and economic growth
employing simultaneous equation estimation approach and a cross-section
data of 147 countries. The bilateral relationships between trade and
e-government are supported by SUR, OLS, and 2SLS whereas 3SLS model
support one way causality between trade and e-government from
e-government to trade openness.
Kim (2001) argued that main reason behind resistance in
e-government is insufficient allocation of budget in area of
e-government that will result into inappropriate usage of IT
infrastructure. The lack of modern education and training on usage of
information technology keep public servant unaware about usage of IT
tools and impede development of e-government. In order to tap full
potential of resources and trade liberalisation, the investment on
e-government may make mandatory.
APPENDIX
Table A 1
Summary of Variables of Interest and Their Data Sources
Variables Description Sources
Economic growth Natural log GDP per capita at [1]
current US $.
Initial per-capita Natural log of per-capita GDP in 1990 [1]
(measured in current U.S dollars.
E-govemment The extent of the online availability [2]
of the government, telecom
infrastructure, and human capital.
Initial level The year 2003 is taken as a initial [2]
of E-govememnt value of e-governemnt index.
Physical capital Gross fixed capital formation in [1]
percentage of GDP.
Labour supply Share of labour force participation [1]
total % of population.
Exchage rate Official Exchage rate measured as [1]
the average value of local currency
in terms of U.S dollars.
Trade Export plus import share of GDP. [1]
Inflation GDP deflator. [1]
Urban population Initial level of urban population [1]
(year 1990).
Fix_Telephone Fixed telephone lines per 100 [3]
inhabitants.
Tariff Weighted mean applied tariff is the [1]
average of effectively applied rates
weighted by the product import
shares corresponding to each partner
country.
[1] World development indicator (2014); [2] Global E-govemment
reports (2003-2012); [3] International telecommunication Unions (2014)
Table A 2
Correlation Matrix
Variables 1 2 3 4
1. Per capita 1.000
2. Trade 0.01 1.000
3. EG 0.733 0.075 1.000
4. Tariffs -0.4078 -0.1421 -0.6021 1.0000
5. Capital -0.062 0.226 -0.021 0.1421
6. Labour -0.015 -0.157 -0.267 0.2628
7. Urban_pop 0.568 0.0484 0.6814 -0.4035
8. Fix_Tele 0.788 0.0635 0.848 -0.4837
9. Exchange rate -0.1055 -0.1297 -0.0693 0.0629
Variables 5 6 7 8 9
1. Per capita
2. Trade
3. EG
4. Tariffs
5. Capital 1.000
6. Labour 0.0237
7. Urban_pop -0.0043 0.657 1.000
8. Fix_Tele -0.0344 0.7576 0.6447 1.000
9. Exchange rate 0.0665 0.0776 -0.0068 -0.0665 1.000
Table A3
SEM with Control Variables
SUR
(1) (2) (3)
Models (Eq3) (Eq5) (Eq8)
Variables Growth Trade E-gov
[Y.sub.initial] 0.542 ***
(0.0639)
Labour -0.253
(0.289)
Capital 0.324 **
(0.145)
E-govemment 3.716 *** 2.314 ***
(0.439) (0.816)
Trade 0.348 *** 0.0380 ***
(0.109) (0.00932)
Corruption -0.0394
Control (0.0852)
[Trade.sub. 0.550 ***
initial] (0.0456)
ln(per capita) 0.101 ** 0.0316 ***
(0.0479) (0.00479)
EG*Y -0.259 ***
(0.0825)
Exchange Rate 0.00705
(0.00988)
Tariff -0.0101 *
(0.00601)
[E-gov.sub. 0.520 ***
initial] (0.0349)
Urban 0.00992 ***
Population (0.00203)
Fix_Tele 0.00194 ***
(0.000404)
Constant 1.098 1.310 *** -0.373 ***
(1.540) (0.346) (0.0618)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared 0.880 0.622 0.956
2SLS
(4) (5) (6)
Models (Eq3) (Eq5) (Eq8)
Variables Growth Trade E-gov
[Y.sub.initial] 0.554 ***
(0.0694)
Labour -0.223
(0.315)
Capital 0.237
(0.159)
E-govemment 3.850 *** 3.023 **
(0.481) (1.357)
Trade 0.497 *** 0.0295 **
(0.148) (0.0149)
Corruption -0.0826
Control (0.0922)
[Trade.sub. 0.515 ***
initial] (0.0541)
ln(per capita) 0.193 ** 0.0453 ***
(0.0839) (0.00686)
EG*Y -0.376 ***
(0.141)
Exchange Rate 0.0100
(0.0109)
Tariff -0.0106
(0.00686)
[E-gov.sub. 0.489 ***
initial] (0.0405)
Urban 0.0105 ***
Population (0.00245)
Fix_Tele 0.00126 **
(0.000489)
Constant 0.442 0.829 -0.433 ***
(1.722) (0.539) (0.0834)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared 0.876 0.604 0.951
3SLS
(7) (8) (9)
Models (Eq3) (Eq5) (Eq8)
Variables Growth Trade E-gov
[Y.sub.initial] 0.316 ***
(0.0605)
Labour 0.0717
(0.257)
Capital 0.210
(0.131)
E-govemment 5.088 *** 2.027
(0.434) (1.288)
Trade 0.611 *** 0.0129
(0.142) (0.0142)
Corruption 0.0213
Control (0 0781)
[Trade.sub. 0.474 ***
initial] (0.0517)
ln(per capita) 0.268 *** 0.0605 ***
(0.0805) (0.00618)
EG*Y -0.337 **
(0.135)
Exchange Rate 0.0106
(0.00977)
Tariff -0.0112 *
(0.00608)
[E-gov.sub. 0.401 ***
initial] (00362)
Urban 0.00981 ***
Population (0.00224)
Fix_Tele 0.00107 **
(0.000426)
Constant 0.0299 0.672 -0.437 ***
(1.420) (0.518) (0.0779)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared 0.850 0.560 0.939
Standard errors in parentheses.
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Table A3
List of Countries
List of Under Developed, Developing, and Developed Countries Under
Develop Countries
Armenia, Bangladesh, Benin, Burkina Faso, Burundi, Central African
Republic, Chad, Comoros, Congo. Dem, Ethiopia, Gambia, Guiana,
Kenya, Kyrgyz Republic, Liberia, Malawi, Mali, Mozambique, Nepal,
Nigeria, Rwanda, Tajikistan, Togo, Uganda, Zimbabwe.
Developing Countries
Albania, Algeria, Angola, Argentina, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Belize,
Bhutan, Bolivia, Botswana, Bulgaria, Cape Verde, China, Cameroon ,
Columbia, Congo. Rep, Costa Rica, Cuba,
Djibouti, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Fiji,
Georgia, Ghana, Guatemala, Guyana, Honduras, Hungary, India,
Indonesia, Iran, Jamaica, Jordan, Kazakhstan. Lao PDR, Lebanon,
Lesotho, Macedonia. FYR, Malaysia, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mexico,
Moldova, Mongolia, Montenegro, Morocco, Namibia, Nicaragua, Niger,
Pakistan, Panama, Papua new Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, Philippine,
Romania, Senegal, Serbia, Solomon island, South Africa, Serbia, Sri
Lanka, St Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Suriname,
Swaziland, Syria, Thailand , Tonga, Tunisia, Turkey , Ukraine,
Uzbekistan , Vanuatu, Venezuela, Yemen.
Under Developed Countries
Australia, Austria, Bahamas, Bahrain, Barbados, Belgium , Brunei
Darussalam, Canada, Chile, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark,
Equatorial Guiana, Finland, France,
Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea.
Rep, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Macao SAR, China, Malta,
Netherland, New Zealand, Norway, Oman, Poland, Portugal, Russia,
Saudi Arabia, Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden ,
Switzerland, Trinidad and Tobago, United Kingdom, United States,
and Uruguay.
Muhammad Tariq Majeed <
[email protected],
[email protected]> is Assistant Professor, School of Economics,
Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad. Amna Malik
<
[email protected]> is Officer Grade 1, State Bank of Pakistan,
Karachi.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D. and J. Ventura (2002) The World Income Distribution.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, 659-694.
Al-Kibsi, G., K. De Boer, M. Mourshed, and N. P. Rea (2001) Putting
Citizens On-line, not In line. McKinsey Quarterly 2:SPI, 64-73.
Andersen, T. B. (2008) E'government as an Anticorruption Tool.
Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen.
Barro, R. J. (1991) Economic Growth in a Cross-section of Countries
(No. w3120). National Bureau of Economic Research.
Barro, R. J., X. Sala-i-Martin, O. J. Blanchard, and R.E. Hall
(1991) Convergence Across States and Regions. Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 1991:1, 107-182.
Chen, A. J., S. L. Pan, J. Zhang, W. W. Huang, and S. Zhu (2009)
Managing E-government Implementation in China: A Process Perspective.
Information and Management 46:4, 203-212.
Choi, C. and M. Hoon Yi (2009) The Effect of the Internet on
Economic Growth: Evidence from Cross-country Panel Data. Economics
Letters 105:1, 39-41.
Clarke, G. R. and S. J. Wallsten (2006) Has the Internet Increased
Trade? Developed and Developing Country Evidence. Economic Inquiry 44:3,
465-484.
Clemens, M. A. and J. G. Williamson (2000) Why Did the
Tariff-Growth Correlation Reverse after 1950? Washington, DC: National
Bureau of Economic Research. (Working Paper No. 9181).
Collier, Paul, and J. W. Gunning (1999) Why has Africa Grown
Slowly. Journal of Economic Perspectives 13:3, 3-22.
Comin, D. and B. Hobijn (2004) Cross-country Technology Adoption:
Making the Theories Face the facts. Journal of Monetary Economics 51:1,
39-83.
Czemich, N., O. Falck, T. Kretschmer, and L. Woessmann (2011)
Broadband Infrastructure and Economic Growth. The Economic Journal
121:552, 505-532.
Devereux, M. B. and B. J. Lapham (1994) The Stability of Economic
Integration and Endogenous Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 109:1,
299-308.
Domar, E. D. (1946) Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth, and
Employment. Econometrica, Journal of the Econometric Society 14:2,
137-147.
Edwards, S. (1998) Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We
Really Know? Economic Journal 108:447, 383-98.
Freund, C. L. and D. Weinhold (2004) The Effect of the Internet on
International Trade. Journal of International Economics 62:1, 171-189.
Greenaway, D., C. W. Morgan, and P. W. Wright (2002). Trade
Liberalisation and Growth: New Methods, New Evidence. Journal of
Development Economics 67:1, 229-44.
Grimes, A., C. Ren, and P. Stevens (2012) The Need for Speed:
Impacts of Internet Connectivity on Firm Productivity. Journal of
Productivity Analysis 37:2, 187-201.
Grossman, G. and E. Helpman (1991) Innovation and Growth in the
Global Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gujarati, D. N. (2003) Basic Econometrics. 4th. Tata McGraw-Hill
Education, Singapore.
Harrod, R. F. (1939) An Essay in Dynamic Theory. The Economic
Journal 49:193, 14-33.
Jorgenson, D., M. Ho, and K. Stiroh (2007) A Retrospective Look at
the US Productivity Growth Resurgence. (FRB of New York Staff Report,
277).
Kim, S. T. (2001) Leapfrogging from Traditional Government to
E-government. In The Human Society and the Internet Internet-Related
Socio-Economic Issues (pp. 273-284). Springer Berlin Heidelberg.
Kneller, R., C. W. Morgan, and S. Kanchanahatakij (2008) Trade
Liberalisation and Economic Growth. The World Economy 31:6, 701-719.
Koopmans, T. C. (1969) Objectives, Constraints, and Outcomes in
Optimal Growth Models (pp. 110-132). Springer Berlin Heidelberg.
Krishnan, S. and T. S. Teo (2012) Moderating Effects of Governance
on Information Infrastructure and E-government Development. Journal of
the American Society for Information Science and Technology 63:10,
1929-1946.
Krishnan, S., T. S. Teo, and V. K. Lim (2013) Examining the
Relationships Among e-government Maturity, Corruption, Economic
Prosperity and Environmental Degradation: A Cross-Country Analysis.
Information and Management 50:8, 638-649.
Kurihara, Y. and A. Fukushima (2013) Impact of the Prevailing
Internet on International Trade in Asia. Journal of Sustainable
Development Studies 3:1, 1-13.
Mahyideen, J. M., N. W. Ismail, and L. S. Hook (2012) A Pooled Mean
Group Estimation on ICT Infrastructure and Economic Growth in ASEAN-5
Countries 6:2, 360-378.
Majeed, T. and A. Ahmad (2006) Determinants of Exports in
Developing Countries. The Pakistan Development Review 45:4, 1265-1276.
Mankiw, N. G., D. Romer, and D. N. Weil (1992) A Contribution to
the Empirics of Economic Growth (No. w3541). National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Mattoo, A., R. Rathindran, and A. Subramanian (2001) Measuring
Services Trade Liberalisation and its Impact on Economic Growth: An
Illustration. World Bank Publications, (Vol. 2655).
Meijers, H. (2014) Does the Internet Generate Economic Growth,
International Trade, or Both? International Economics and Economic
Policy 11:1-2, 137-163.
Noh, Y. H. and K. Yoo (2008) Internet, Inequality and Growth.
Journal of Policy Modeling 30:6, 1005-1016.
OECD Communications Outlook (2009) Technical Report. Organisation
for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD), Directorate for
Science, Technology, and Industry, Committee for Information, Computer,
and Communications Policy.
Oliner, S. D., D. E. Sichel, and K. J. Stiroh (2008) Explaining a
Productive Decade. Journal of Policy Modeling 30:4, 633-673.
Parikh, A. (2006) Relationship between Trade Liberalisation,
Growth, and Balance of Payments in Developing Countries: An Econometric
Study. The International Trade Journal 20:4, 429-467.
Quah, D. (1993) Galton's Fallacy and Tests of the Convergence
Hypothesis. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 95:4, 427-443.
Quah, D. T. (1997) Empirics for Growth and Distribution:
Stratification, Polarisation, and Convergence Clubs. Journal of Economic
Growth 2:1, 27-59.
Redding, S. (2002) Path Dependence, Endogenous Innovation, and
Growth, International Economic Review A2 A, 1215--48.
Ricardo, D. (1817) Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. G.
Bell and Sons.
Rivera-Batiz, L. and P. M. Romer (1990) Economic Integration and
Endogenous Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:425, 531-555.
Rodriguez, F. and D. Rodrik (1999) Trade Policy and Economic
Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.
Washington, DC: National Bureau of Economic Research. (Working Paper No.
7081).
Salvatore, D. (1996) International Trade Policies,
Industrialisation, and Economic Development. The International Trade
Journal 10:1, 21-47.
Shachmurove, Y. and U. Spiegel (2010) The Welfare of Nations in a
Globalised Economy. The International Trade Journal 24:3, 230-260.
Shamim, F. (2007) The ICT Environment, Financial Sector and
Economic Growth: A Cross-country Analysis. Journal of Economic Studies
34:4, 352-370.
Smith, Adam (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the
Wealth of Nations. Edwin Cannan's Annotated Edition.
Solow, R. M. (1956) A Contribution to the Theory of Economic
Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70:1, 65-94.
Stiglitz, J. E. and A. Charlton (2005) Fair Trade for all: How
Trade can Promote Development (pp. 11-46). New York: Oxford University
Press.
Summers, L. H. (1999) Distinguished Lecture on Economics in
Government: Reflections on Managing Global Integration (Digest Summary).
Journal of Economic Perspectives 13:2, 3-18.
Tandon, H. (2005) E-govemance: An Indian Perspective. Policy and
Society 24:3, 142-169.
Tokarick, S. (2008) Dispelling some Misconceptions about
Agricultural Trade Liberalisation. The Journal of Economic Perspectives
22:1, 199-216.
Vamvakidis, A. (2002) How Robust is the Growth-Openness Connection?
Historical Evidence. Journal of Economic Growth 7:1, 57-80.
Van Ark, B., M. O'Mahony, and M. P. Timmer (2008) The
Productivity Gap between Europe and the United States: Trends and
Causes. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 22:1, 25-44.
Vemuri, V. K. and S. Siddiqi (2009) Impact of Commercialisation of
the Internet on International Trade: A Panel Study Using the Extended
Gravity Model. The International Trade Journal 23:4, 458-484.
Von Haldenwang, C. (2004) Electronic Government (e-government) and
Development. The European Journal of Development Research 16:2, 411-432.
Wacziarg, R. (2001) Measuring the Dynamic Gains from Trade. World
Bank Economic Review 15:3,393-429.
West, D. M. (2004) E-Govemment and the Transformation of Service
Delivery and Citizen Attitudes. Public Administration Review 64:1,
15-27.
Wiggins, R. R. and T. W. Ruefli (2005) Schumpeter's Ghost: Is
Hypercompetition Making the Best of Times Shorter? Strategic Management
Journal 26:10, 887-911.
Winters, L. A. (2004) Trade Liberalisation and Economic
Performance: An Overview. Economic Journal 114:493, F4-F21.
Yadav, N. (2014) The Role of Internet Use on International Trade:
Evidence from Asian and Sub-Saharan African Enterprises. Global Economy
Journal 14:2, 189-214.
(1) Specification error in model occurs when one or more irrelevant
variables are incorporated or one or more relevant variables are omitted
in the specified equation. When relevant variables are excluded from the
model or irrelevant variables are included in the model, the common
variance they share with excluded/included variables may be wrongly
attributed to those variables. In the case of such specification errors,
the error term tends to inflate and creates biased results.
Specification error in any equation leads to biasness in all the
results. Prior to estimate the model we have checked the specification
of our model by employing the linktest. The test generates two
variables, predicted independent variable (_hat), square of predicted
variable (_hatsq). The model is then re-estimated using these two
variables as predictors. If model is free from specification error then
hatsq should not have much prediction power. Table 4.3 indicates that
hatsq has not explanatory power and our all equations are free from
specification error.
(2) There is significant systematic difference between OLS and SUR
model, OLS and 2SLS, OLS and 3SLS according to Hausman Test. The
variance-covariance matrix of error terms indicates correlation between
the error terms of Equation 3, equation5, and equation8. The correlation
between error terms of equation3 and equation5 is 0.13, equation3 and
equation8 is 0.172. and equation 5 and equation 8 is 0.105 that is
significant and greater than 10 percent. 3SLS technique takes into
account of both endogeniety and correlation among error terms. 2SLS only
takes into account of endogeniety, and SUR model takes merely into
account of correlation between error terms. In order to check the
robustness of results we have employed all the techniques of
Simultaneous equation model. All equations in simultaneous equation
model are identified according to order condition because the number of
endogenous variables included in equation less one (M-l) is less than
the number of exogenous variables excluded in equation [Gujrati (2003)].
The internal instruments are used to tackle endogeniety. The instruments
are initial quality of e-government, physical capital, labour force,
fixed telephone lines, initial urban population, initial per capita
income, exchange rate, and tariffs.
(3) The sign of initial per-capita income can be positive in the
case of poor or developing economies because they will likely to grow
rapidly The hypothesis of "catching per-capita of rich economies by
poor economies is consistent with convergence theory that is supported
by Solow (1956).
Caption: Fig. 1. Relationship between Growth and E-government
Caption: Fig. 2. Relationship between Trade and Growth
Caption: Fig. 3. Relationship between E-governemnt (EG) and Growth
Caption: Fig. 4. E-government (EG) and Share of Trade in GDP in
Different Geographical Regions
Table 4.1
Dimensions of E-government
Description of E-government Dimensions
Online Service and It measures the extant of online and web content
Web Connections availability and focused on growing web
connection and online presence which improves
the accessibility of information by utilisation
of multimedia which facilitates online delivery
of transactional services and communication
between government and citizens.
Telecommunication The telecommunication infrastructure is founded
Infrastructure on five indicators: internet users, personal
computers, fix-telephones lines, mobile phone
subscription, and broadband subscription (all
the indicators are in per 100 inhabitants).
Human Capital Human capital is based on four indicators that
are adult literacy rate, gross secondary
enrolment, gross secondary enrolment, and gross
tertiary enrolment.
Table 4.2
Summary Statistics of Data
Variable Observation Mean Min Max
Y 147 11692.31 179.401 94654.22
[Y.sub.initial] 145 5342.72 182.797 36337.09
Capital 147 23.4887 9.85652 68.78322
Labour 147 63.29 41.42 86.63
E-govemment 147 0.44781 0.08738 0 .87
Exchange Rate 133 675.99 0.344 25000
[EG.sub.initial] 145 0.40274 0.0000 0 .92706
Trade 147 89.4306 27.0795 303.446
[Trade.sub.initiai] 142 73.24068 14.56329 210.161
Urban population 147 1.39e+07 21606 3.00e+08
Fix_Telephone 147 19.6930 0 .04629 65.9294
Tariff 146 6.616705 4.839402 21.42
Table 4.3
Linktest Results
Dependent Variable: Natural log of per-capita GDP
Variables Coef Std. Err T P>[absolute
value of t]
_hat 1.374505 0.316188 4.35 0.000
_hatsq -0.022062 0.018553 -1.19 0.236
_cons -1.542248 1.318649 -1.17 0.244
Dependent Variable: Trade liberalisation
_hat 1.318894 1.333089 0.99 0.324
_hatsq -0.0367583 0.153453 -0.24 0.811
_cons -0.6875192 2.886441 -0.24 0.812
Dependent Variable: E-government
_hat 0.96947 0.091681 10.57 0.000
_hatsq 0.031816 0.093483 0.34 0.734
_cons .0062143 0.020458 0.30 0.762
Table 5.1
Empirical Results of Simultaneous Equations Model
Empirical Findings of Simultaneous Equation Model
SUR Model 2SLS
(1) (2) (3)
Independent (Eq3) (Eq5) (Eq8)
Variables Growth Trade E-gov
[Trade.sub.iniiiai] 0.55 ***
(0.045)
EG*Y -0.26 ***
(0.0824)
Exchange Rate 0.00715
(0.0099)
Tariff -0.0101 *
(0.0060)
ln(per capita) 0.101 ** 0.032 ***
(0.0478) (0.00479)
E-gov 3.67 *** 2.33 ***
(0.416) (0.815)
[Y.sub.initial] 0.53 ***
(0.055)
Capital 0.319 **
(0.145)
Labour -0.281
(0.282)
Trade 0.35 *** 0.038 ***
(0.109) (0.00932)
Urban pop 0.010 ***
(0.00203)
[E-gov.sub.initial] 0.519 ***
(0.0349)
Fix Tele 0.002 ***
(0.00040)
Constant 1.364 1.30 *** -0.376 ***
(1.427) (0.345) (0.0617)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared
Observation 0.880 0.622 0.956
F-stat 127 127 127
Chi-Square 959.11 217.22 2846.20
2SLS
(4) (5) (6)
Independent (Eq3) (Eq5) (Eq8)
Variables Growth Trade E-gov
[Trade.sub.iniiiai] 0.53 ***
(0.057)
EG*Y -0.321 *
(0.169)
Exchange Rate 0.00876
(0.0110)
Tariff -0.0108
(00068)
ln(per capita) 0.159 0 046 ***
(0.102) (0.00701)
E-gov 3.67 *** 2.601 *
(0.451) (1.526)
[Y.sub.initial] 0.53 ***
(0.059)
Capital 0.242
(0.158)
Labour -0.311
(0.304)
Trade 0.46 *** 0.0309 **
(0.148) (0.0151)
Urban pop 0.011 ***
(0.00248)
[E-gov.sub.initial] 0.484 ***
(0.0411)
Fix Tele 0 0012 **
(0.00049)
Constant 1.242 1.040 -0.450 ***
(1.591) (0.645) (0.0857)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared
Observation 0.877 0.613 0.951
F-stat 127 127 127
Chi-Square 177.23 31.73 474.64
3SLS
(7) (8) (9)
Independent (Eq3) (Eq5) (Eq8)
Variables Growth Trade E-gov
[Trade.sub.iniiiai] 0.51 ***
(0.055)
EG*Y -0.209
(0.161)
Exchange Rate 0.00778
(0.0099)
Tariff -0.0119 *
(0.0061)
ln(per capita) 0.175 * 0.062 ***
(0.0978) (0.00627)
E-gov 5.08 *** 1.140
(0.411) (1 449)
[Y.sub.initial] 0.33 ***
(0.053)
Capital 0.242 *
(0.131)
Labour 0.0125
(0.259)
Trade 0.55 *** 0.0138
(0.143) (0.0143)
Urban pop 0.010 ***
(0.00221)
[E-gov.sub.initial] 0.397 ***
(0.0365)
Fix Tele 0.0010 **
(0.00042)
Constant 0.344 1.190 * -0.447 ***
(1.366) (0.619) (0.0785)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared
Observation 0.854 0.592 0.937
F-stat 127 127 127
Chi-Square 912.74 197.42 2468.93
Standard errors in parentheses.
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Table 5.2
Empirical Findings of Ordinary Least Squares
Empirical Findings of OLS
Ordinary Least Square Technique
(Equation 3) (Equation 5) (Equation 8)
Variables Economic Growth Trade E-gov
[Trade.sub.initial] 0.560 ***
(0.0473)
EG*per Capita -0.231 ***
(0.0858)
Exchange Rate 0.00519
(0.0103)
Tariff -0.00952
(0.00628)
In (per capita) 0.0669 0.0254 ***
(0.0497) (0.00497)
E-govemment 3.215 *** 2.188 **
(0.431) (0.849)
[Y.sub.initial] 0.581 ***
(0.0572)
Capital 0.314 **
(0.152)
Labour -0.437
(0.295)
Trade 0.247 ** 0.0344 ***
(0.112) (0.00961)
Urban Population 0.00937 ***
(0.00212)
[EG.sub.initial] 0.554 ***
(0.0364)
Fix_Tele 0.00208 ***
(0.000423)
Constant 2.261 1.496 *** -0.314 ***
(1.494) (0.359) (0.0641)
Observations 127 127 127
R-squared 0.882 0.624 0.957
F-stat 180.63 33.20 540.65
Observation 127 127 127
Standard errors in parentheses.
*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1.
Fig. 5. E-government and Share of Trade in GDP in Developing,
Developed and Under Developed Countries
Average of E-government and share of Trade in GDP
Trade EG
Under developed countries 0.67 0.23
Developing countries 0.9 0.4
Develop countries 0.1 0.64
Note: Table made from bar graph.
COPYRIGHT 2016 Reproduced with permission of the Publications Division, Pakistan Institute of Development Economies, Islamabad, Pakistan.
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2016 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.