Household inequality and the consumption response to aggregate real shocks.
Amromin, Gene ; De Nardi, Mariacristina ; Schulze, Karl 等
Household inequality and the consumption response to aggregate real shocks.
Introduction and summary
The drop in output and consumption that occurred during the Great
Recession has been large and prolonged. Figure 1 displays per capita
U.S. real gross domestic product (GDP) and personal consumption
expenditures (PCE) between 1985 and 2016 and highlights the large drop
in both consumption and output that occurred starting in 2007 and its
parallel shift compared with the previous trend. In this article, we ask
why consumption has dropped so much and has been recovering so slowly.
We also ask to what extent household inequality before and after the
Great Recession interacted with the recession itself to generate such a
large and persistent drop in consumption. (1)
To reach our goal, we first review two key papers, Krusell and
Smith (1998) and Krueger, Mitman, and Petri (2016), and summarize what
we understand from quantitative macro models with aggregate uncertainty
about wealth inequality, borrowing-constrained households with
heterogeneous marginal propensities to consume (MPCs), and the response
of aggregate consumption to an aggregate shock. The key message from
macroeconomic theory is that the extent to which households are
borrowing constrained (which in these models means how many people have
low wealth holdings) and how that changes both over time and with
aggregate shocks are crucial to explaining the aggregate economy's
response and the speed of its recovery. That is, versions of these
models with a realistic fraction of poor people can generate larger
consumption drops in response to a total factor productivity (TFP) shock
than models with fewer poor people. Hence, inequality does affect
aggregate consumption dynamics in response to shocks in an important
way.
While these two papers, Krusell and Smith (KS) and Krueger, Mitman,
and Perri (KMP), provide very important lessons and are much more
realistic than previous models, we argue that these newer models still
abstract from important changes that happened during the Great Recession
and are thus likely to understate the size (and potentially the
persistence) of the consumption drop that occurred and the role of
household inequality in generating it.
First, they do not incorporate the large wealth losses (due to
drops in house prices and stock market values) that occurred during the
Great Recession and have depressed aggregate consumption due to a
negative wealth effect. Second, they take the view that there is only
one asset and that borrowing-constrained people are largely people with
low amounts of this composite asset. However, the composition of a
household's portfolio is important to determine the extent to which
the household is borrowing constrained. For instance, in a model with
liquid and illiquid assets that are subject to adjustment costs, people
might have significant holdings of illiquid wealth and still be
borrowing constrained (Kaplan and Violante, 2014). Thus, these models
understate the fraction of households that are borrowing constrained
and, hence, the size of the associated consumption drop. Third, these
models assume that financial frictions are constant, including during a
large downturn. In contrast, credit standards tightened considerably
during the Great Recession, which also tends to reduce consumption
(Guerrieri and Lorenzoni, 2017). Fourth, these models assume that only
unemployment risk changes over the cycle, while there is significant
evidence that earnings risk conditional on being employed is asymmetric:
Large earnings drops are much more likely than large earnings increases,
and this asymmetry becomes more pronounced during recessions (Guvenen,
Ozkan, and Song, 2014). If a household perceives higher earnings risk
during a recession, it would likely cut consumption and increase
savings, thus generating an even larger drop in aggregate consumption.
Thus, all four of these factors likely increase the size of the
consumption drop that is related to household inequality, because they
increase the fraction of borrowing-constrained households that have high
marginal propensities to consume and whose consumption reacts more
strongly to a negative aggregate shock.
Interestingly, these factors do not apply symmetrically to all
households. For instance, the wealth drop is more important for
households in the top half of the wealth distribution, while credit
market access plays a larger role for low-wealth households who lack
alternative means of smoothing consumption. Accounting for these factors
can thus improve the ability of the current models to match
cross-sectional patterns of consumption responses.
One important implication of the four features that are missing in
these macro benchmark models is that we should think more carefully how
to best measure the fraction of households that are borrowing
constrained and how this fraction changes over time and the business
cycle. It is important to stress that the fraction of households that
are borrowing constrained is not just the fraction of low-wealth
households, but also depends on their portfolio composition, exposure to
earnings risk, and, potentially, on what nondiscretionary expenses they
expect (Campbell and Hercowitz, 2018). We thus need a better measure of
borrowing-constrained households.
To help shed light on these important issues, we use the Panel
Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) and credit bureau panel data (Equifax)
to examine the interaction between consumption, wealth inequality, and
borrowing constraints during the Great Recession. We find that,
consistent with the models' implications, the poor and
borrowing-constrained households have a larger consumption expenditure
rate as a fraction of their income and that their expenditure rate
dropped by more during the Great Recession. We then use various measures
of borrowing constraints to get a sense of how the fraction of
constrained households has changed over time. We document that, for all
of the measures that we consider, the fraction of households that are
borrowing constrained has drastically increased since the onset of the
Great Recession and remained high, or even increased, all the way to
2012, the last year for which we currently have PSID data. Thus, it is
not surprising that aggregate consumption has experienced such a large
drop and remained depressed for a long time. Before we turn to our data
analysis, we discuss what we know from macroeconomic theory in more
detail.
Krusell and Smith (1998)
In Krusell and Smith's (KS) model, the consumers are
infinitely lived, provide labor inelastically, and optimally choose how
much to save and consume. They are ex-ante identical but get hit by an
unemployment shock. Markets are incomplete: There is only one asset,
aggregate capital, and consumers cannot borrow. The model induces
endogenous wealth inequality: Although households face the same
stochastic process for an endowment shock, they receive different
sequences of the unemployment shock and are thus ex-post heterogeneous
in their wealth holdings.
There is an aggregate shock that affects total factor productivity
of both capital and labor (TFP) in the aggregate production function and
the aggregate unemployment rate. A recession in this framework is thus
characterized by lower aggregate wages and higher unemployment. The
equilibrium interest rate is the marginal product of capital. The
equilibrium wage is the marginal product of labor. Due to the aggregate
shocks, both the interest rate and the wage fluctuate over time. Thus,
because of aggregate uncertainty, consumers have to forecast future
prices (both the wage and the interest rate). In principle, the whole
distribution of wealth, together with the aggregate shock, is a state
variable to forecast future prices.
We learn two main lessons from this paper. The first one is that
today's average capital, or net worth, is enough to forecast future
prices for a given aggregate shock, and that we therefore need to keep
track of only one moment of the wealth distribution. The second main
lesson from this paper is that the first result can still imply that the
response of the aggregate time series depends on the distribution of
wealth and the fraction of people that are constrained. In fact, the
second moments of the aggregate time series in models with incomplete
markets are different from those with a representative agent. Especially
in models with more realistic wealth inequality, there is a larger
correlation between consumption and income.
The key insight in these models with incomplete markets is that
different saving (and consumption) propensities are associated with low
levels of wealth. As wealth increases, the marginal propensity to save
converges to one (permanent income behavior) and thus aggregates up
across agents. Because the agents with lowest and most heterogeneous
propensity to save (and highest propensity to consume) are associated
with low wealth levels, they have very little effect on aggregate
capital and prices, as opposed to the high-wealth agents whose policy
functions aggregate. In contrast, because the poor have a high marginal
propensity to consume, they account for a significant amount of
aggregate consumption. Moreover, because they have little wealth to
insulate their consumption from aggregate shocks affecting wages and
income, they also have the largest consumption fluctuations over the
cycle.
Krueger, Mitman, and Perri (2016)
Krueger, Mitman, and Perri (KMP) extend the KS framework with
preference heterogeneity to include a stylized life-cycle structure with
constant probabilities of aging or dying in each subperiod (working
period and retirement), labor productivity shocks conditional on
employment, and unemployment insurance.
Their key finding is that, in these economies, the decline in
aggregate consumption in response to an aggregate shock is larger in an
economy populated by more wealth-poor households because their
consumption responds more strongly to aggregate shocks, which are
characterized by a reduction in TFP and increased unemployment risk.
Figure 2 displays the consumption functions (plotted against
individual wealth on the x-axis) and the pre-recession wealth
distributions for the original KS economy (left-hand side) and the KMP
economy (both graphs are from KMP). The lines represent the consumption
functions of the employed in an expansion, the employed in a recession,
and the unemployed in a recession. Thus, for a given wealth level, the
vertical difference between the consumption functions for the employed
in the good aggregate state and the employed in the bad aggregate state
gives the consumption drop in a large recession, conditional on the
aggregate state switching but on not losing a job. In the same way, the
vertical difference between the consumption function of the employed in
an expansion and the consumption function of the unemployed in a
recession shows the consumption drop for a household that experiences a
recession and unemployment at the same time.
The figure reveals several interesting features. First, for a given
level of wealth, the drop in consumption is larger in the original KS
economy and especially so for households with little to no assets.
Second, while there are almost no people in this situation in the
original KS economy, there are many more households in those wealth
quantiles in the KMP economy. It should be noted that average wealth is
the same in the two economies. As it turns out, the KMP economy displays
a larger consumption drop than the KS economy precisely because there
are more people with low wealth holdings. Figure 3 (also from KMP)
highlights this result.
Results from the models, a discussion leading to our data analysis
These two papers stress the importance of modeling heterogeneity
and constrained households in understanding aggregate consumption and
output dynamics. However, these models abstract from features of the
Great Recession that are likely important in helping us to understand
the behavior of aggregate consumption during and after that recession.
For example, while the additional heterogeneity in KMP deepens the
initial consumption drop, it recovers at the same rate as the KS model.
The richer dimensions of heterogeneity we document could potentially
help future models match both the steep initial decline and the slow
recovery in consumption we observed in the Great Recession.
The features we consider include, first, changes in the value of
wealth holdings (and thus the fraction of poor households) due to drops
in house prices and financial asset valuation. Second, we study the
implications of the observation that the asset structure is much richer
than just one asset. A household's portfolio allocation and its
liquidity can have crucial implications for who is constrained (the
wealthy-hand-to-mouth). Third, changes in credit constraints that
occurred, due to changes in credit conditions during the downturn, are
likely important. Fourth, we examine changes in earnings risk for the
employed in recessions and expansions. We know that the distribution of
earnings displays more negative skewness in recessions, for instance. It
is also possible that the persistence of earnings might depend on the
status of the aggregate economy and one's earning level.
We now turn to discussing key aspects of the data and the strengths
and weaknesses of the models in explaining empirical consumption
dynamics after large shocks.
Data
Panel Study of Income Dynamics
We utilize the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID) to analyze the
relationship between household inequality and consumption dynamics. The
PSID has two important advantages from the standpoint of the questions
that we are asking. First, it provides information on earnings, income,
consumption, and wealth for a sample that is representative of the U.S.
population. Second, it has a panel dimension that allows us to track
households over time in addition to performing cross-sectional
investigations. Thus, we can examine how wealth and consumption have
changed for the same households.
We use data from the 2001 to 2013 PSID waves (covering the years
2000 to 2012), with particular focus on 2004, 2006, and 2010. Our
baseline sample in these years consists of families with household heads
aged 25 to 60. We exclude a few households whose total annual
consumption is implausibly small, less than $1,000 in 2006 dollars. Our
wealth quintiles are defined over this working-age sample. When
analyzing changes over time, we make these restrictions only in the base
year. Much of our analysis focuses on three variables: total income,
consumption expenditures, and net worth. All dollar values are deflated
to 2006 using the Consumer Price Index, unless stated otherwise.
Total income includes all pre-tax sources of household income from
all family members, including Social Security income and other
transfers, as well as a family's income from assets and businesses.
Transfer income includes unemployment compensation, transfers from other
family members, and welfare benefits, among others. Total income also
includes retirement and pension income. Net worth is composed of net
housing equity, net value of other real estate, net value of farm or
business, net value of vehicles, value of annuities and retirement
accounts, value of nonretirement investments and savings, and the net
value of other assets less the value of other liabilities. After 2010,
the value of other liabilities is subdivided into credit card debt,
student loans, medical bills, legal bills, and other family loan debt.
In the analysis that considers illiquid housing wealth, we only look at
the net equity in the primary home and other real estate. Net worth does
not include the present value of defined-benefit pension income.
While the PSID harmonizes the variables for total family income and
net worth, we must construct consumption expenditures using disparate
expenditure categories. These are: expenditures on transportation,
vehicles purchased in the current year, food, clothing, education, child
care, entertainment, recreation, vacation, utilities, rent, imputed
rents for homeowners, property taxes, household repairs, household
durables, homeowners' insurance, out-of-pocket medical care, and
health insurance premiums. As in KMP, we impute the rental value for
homeowners by multiplying the total value of a household's home by
an interest rate of 4 percent.
This definition of consumption is only available for 2004 onward as
expenditures on clothing, entertainment, recreation, vacation, household
durables, and household repairs were not collected prior to this. We
adjust all expenditure variables to an annual frequency. (2)
Equifax
We also make use of the Equifax-FRBNY Consumer Credit Panel (CCP),
which is a longitudinal data set containing quarterly credit bureau
records for a nationally representative 5 percent random sample of
individual borrowers. The CCP database also includes records of all
household members of the primary sample borrower. These data include
information on all aspects of individual- and household-level credit and
debt, which includes credit cards, auto loans, and student debt, as well
as first- and second-lien mortgages. The data also include individual
credit scores and the number of credit applications, which allow us to
track household creditworthiness and demand for credit over time. (3)
Important dimensions of heterogeneity in the PSID
We begin by discussing several key empirical facts from the PSID.
(4) Table 1 reports the marginal distributions of earnings, income,
consumption expenditures, and net worth in 2006, on the eve of the
recession. All of these measures of household well-being are very
unevenly distributed, but some more so than others.
For the moment, we will take net worth as a measure of household
constraints, since less wealthy households are likely less able to
respond to shocks. How much do wealth-poor households contribute to
aggregate consumption? To answer this question, table 2 reports the
distribution of several variables, conditional on wealth quintile in
2006. It reveals that asset-poor households make up a sizable measure of
aggregate consumption expenditures. In fact, the bottom two wealth
quintiles account for 30 percent of expenditures in 2006. Not
surprisingly, households in these quintiles spend much higher shares of
their total income on consumption (expenditure rates).
Table 3 shows that the low-wealth quintiles are populated by
households that are younger, less educated, have low propensities to own
homes or financial assets, and are less likely to hold full-time
employment throughout the year, as evidenced both by the number of hours
worked and prevalence of unemployment spells. The data in these tables
corroborate the essential ingredients of KMP: l) a large fraction of
households have no assets but account for a significant part of
aggregate consumption; and 2) these households are vulnerable to shocks,
as their low asset positions are compounded by lower levels of human
capital, whether acquired through schooling or work experience.
How did these household groups respond to the Great Recession?
Table 4 reports annualized nominal changes in select variables before
and during the Great Recession, conditional on initial wealth quintile.
These changes are computed holding the initial quintile composition
fixed. For instance, to compute the change in consumption expenditures
for households in the bottom wealth quintile between 2004 and 2006, we
take all households in that quintile in 2004 and compute their mean
consumption expenditures in 2004 and 2006. The annualized change in
these means is reported in the table. Changes in expenditure rates are
constructed similarly but are reported as percentage point differences.
The top row of table 4 shows aggregate growth rates that tell a
familiar tale of the Great Recession. (5) After expanding at a pace of
14.1 percent during the boom years, aggregate net worth declined at an
annual rate of 3.4 percent between 2006 and 2010. The growth rate of
aggregate total income also slowed down from 2.6 percent to only 0.8
percent per year. However, the slowdown in aggregate consumption proved
to be much faster: After increasing at an average rate of 5.5 percent
per year, consumption fell at an average rate of 0.8 percent between
2006 and 2010. These relative movements in growth rates of income and
consumption are reflected in absolute declines in the aggregate
expenditure rate.
A convenient metric for measuring the effect of the Great Recession
is the change in nominal growth rates between the 2004-06 and 2006-10
periods. The Great Recession depressed total income growth for all
wealth groups but in a non-monotonic fashion. Households in the middle
of the wealth distribution (quintiles 3 and 4) experienced the greatest
slowdown, while for those at the lowest quintile total income growth
decelerated much less (-0.6 percent per year). Consumption growth rates
also decreased for all wealth groups, with the slowdown again being most
severe in the middle of the wealth distribution.
Low-wealth households experienced a slowdown in consumption growth
that was barely above those in the highest-wealth quintile and well
below those in quintiles 3 and 4. This finding is consistent with
results in Meyer and Sullivan (2013), which documents a decline in
consumption inequality during the Great Recession. They show that the
fall in asset prices (both housing and financial) had a disproportionate
effect on households with higher ex-ante consumption levels.
Importantly, slowdowns in consumption growth were larger than drops
in income growth for all wealth groups. As a result, the share of income
spent on consumption (expenditure share) declined for all wealth groups,
but the poorest households experienced the largest decline. This
empirical fact is consistent with the main intuition of the KMP model:
When unemployment risk rises, low-wealth households cut back consumption
because they fail to accumulate wealth that can be used to smooth
consumption fluctuations. This happens whether they actually become
unemployed or not. In the latter case, they cut consumption to build up
their precautionary savings given the heightened unemployment risk
during a recession.
Matching heterogeneous patterns in the data
As shown in figure 3, the KMP model delivers a larger response to
an aggregate recession shock than a model with a smaller wealth
dispersion. It thus matches important aspects of the data and shows that
an economy with borrowing-constrained agents can generate larger drops
in aggregate consumption. As shown in table 5, the KMP model does well
in matching heterogeneity in declines in disposable income, which drops
less in recessions for low-wealth households (Q1-Q2) than high-wealth
households in both the model and the data. The model also captures the
qualitative ordering of recession-driven changes in expenditure rates.
In particular, the drops in expenditures of the two lowest-wealth
quintiles are smaller than the drops in expenditures of the
highest-wealth quintiles.
However, the Great Recession was associated with large wealth
losses, tightening of borrowing constraints, and increased earnings
uncertainty. These forces would take the model even closer to the data.
They could further reduce aggregate consumption growth and amplify the
consumption response relative to income drops. They could also further
contribute to a slow recovery in consumption. Because wealth losses fall
unevenly across the distribution, the implied reductions in consumption
growth rates would be heterogeneous.
Additional elements of the Great Recession
Shocks to wealth
Unlike the baseline model, the Great Recession was characterized by
substantial declines in household wealth. Figure 4 demonstrates the
leftward shift in distribution of household wealth between the 2006 and
2010 PSID surveys. The share of households with negative net worth
jumped from 16 percent to 24 percent, and mean household net worth
plummeted from $324,973 to $197,780 in 2006 dollars. In the context of
the KMP model, this drop in household net worth could reinforce the
negative consumption dynamics by altering the wealth distribution in
figure 2. Put differently, a recession that brings about a sizable
leftward shift in the wealth distribution elicits an additional
consumption response, especially among households who bear the brunt of
this shock.
We can get some additional insight into these consumption dynamics
by exploiting the panel structure of the PSID and linking changes in
wealth with changes in consumption at the household level. Table 6
presents the shift in the distribution of household wealth between 2006
and 2010 as transitions across fixed net worth quintiles, defined by
their 2006 threshold values. Each row of the table shows the
distribution of households in a given wealth quintile in 2006 across
wealth groupings in 2010. For example, 43.8 percent of households in the
middle quintile of the 2006 net worth distribution remained in the same
group by 2010. However, more than one-third of households in this
quintile (12.5% + 22.9%) had lost enough wealth by 2010 to drop into the
bottom two quintiles. For example, 12.5 percent of households in the
middle 20 percent of net worth in 2006 dropped to the bottom 20 percent
in 2010. This group had an average nominal net worth of $73,900 in 2006
and dropped to a 2010 mean of-$33,100. Similarly, for those who
transitioned from the third to the second quintile, 22.9 percent of
households dropped from an average wealth level of $73,000 to an average
of $20,800.
The table also captures the consumption growth rates for each of
these groups, located in the brackets below the transition
probabilities. Looking at households that moved from the middle quintile
in 2006 to the bottom quintiles in 2010 shows that the deterioration in
their wealth position was accompanied by massive reductions in
consumption of about 3 percent per year. Table 6 shows that, in general,
downward movements in wealth (the lower diagonal part of the transition
matrix) are associated with negative consumption growth rates, shown in
bold. The total row of the table again underscores the shift in the
wealth distribution: the bottom quintile in 2006 (< $2,500 in net
worth) by construction accounted for 20 percent of households, but 23.7
percent of households found themselves with less than $2,500 in net
worth in 2010.
Shocks to composition of wealth
Housing equity represents the single-largest wealth component for
the majority of households, although it is illiquid. During the run-up
to the Great Recession, financial innovations made it much easier for
households to use housing equity to support consumption, either by
extracting it directly or by borrowing against it (Bhutta and Keys,
2016). Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2013) estimate propensities to
consume out of different types of wealth by analyzing changes in per
capita consumption expenditures, income, financial wealth, and housing
wealth in a quarterly panel of U.S. states spanning 1975 to 2012. They
find much higher elasticities of consumption for housing than for
financial wealth and attribute this result to changes in tax laws and
the above-mentioned financial innovations. Thus, a drop in house values
could further contribute to the drop in consumption.
In figure 5. we again exploit the panel structure of PSID to show
the distribution of individual changes in real housing wealth between
2006 and 2010, expressed in annualized, real percentage terms. The
smaller figures show the unconditional distribution in each 2006 wealth
quintile, while the top figure shows the overall distribution, which is
the sum of the smaller histograms. The overall distribution of housing
wealth changes (top panel) was strongly asymmetric as many households
experienced losses in real terms. On average, housing wealth declined by
an average of 6.4 percent per year over this period, and as many as 17.8
percent of PSID homeowners lost all of their housing wealth, whether
through foreclosure (the -100% group) or by owing more than their house
was worth (the "'underwater" or <-100% group). The
rest of the panels show the unconditional distributions of changes for
each of the 2006 wealth groups. In these panels, non-homeowners and
those with little housing wealth in 2006 are omitted and thus the sum
over all the bins in each panel will roughly equal the homeownership
rate for that quintile.
Consequently, the histograms for the bottom two wealth quintiles
suggest that housing losses there were limited because of low ownership
rates. However, the rest of the wealth distribution was hit hard. In the
middle quintile, complete loss of all housing equity represented the
likeliest outcome. Although foreclosures were not nearly as common in
the top wealth deciles, the share of households facing losses was even
greater.
Changes in credit accessibility
Figure 5 describes the erosion in housing wealth, which is commonly
used as collateral. However, in addition to experiencing negative wealth
shocks, households were also faced with a more adverse credit
environment with the onset of the Great Recession. Lenders tightened
their credit standards for home mortgages and other credit products.
Moreover, as delinquency rates rose across credit markets, household
credit scores deteriorated, which further contributed to difficulties in
accessing credit.
To get some sense of the magnitude of the shock to credit access,
we turn to the Equifax panel data. Figure 6 shows the distribution of
credit risk scores (6) in a representative sample of households in 2006
and for the same sample in 2010. Unlike household wealth, the
distribution of credit scores did not shift uniformly to the left.
Rather, by 2010, the credit score distribution became much thinner in
the middle range of creditworthiness (690-790) and more concentrated at
the very top. On net, the fraction of households that remained above the
informal midpoint of the prime credit score range (credit score = 720)
was nearly unchanged.
Instead, it was the tightening of minimum credit standards, shown
by the dashed vertical lines, that pushed a large fraction of households
out of credit markets. As shown in figure 7, according to
mortgage-servicing data from McDash Analytics, a credit score of 720
roughly corresponded to the median score of a borrower approved for a
home mortgage by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac prior to the Great Recession.
Over this period, households with credit scores between 680 and 780--the
'"prime" group in figure 8--experienced a success rate
above 80 percent in getting their credit applications approved. Applying
a credit score of 720 as a notional cutoff for ready credit access to
the distribution in figure 6 places 47 percent of households in this
category. However, by 2010, the same criteria for ready credit
access--obtaining mortgage credit from the GSEs or having undiminished
success rates for credit applications--required a credit score of about
780. This shift in credit requirements, shown by the red dashed line,
shrank the fraction of households with easy credit access to just under
30 percent.
Evidence of credit tightening during the Great Recession can be
seen in the mortgage-servicing data on median credit scores for newly
originated mortgages depicted in figure 7. Stricter credit requirements
are apparent both for mortgages backed by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac and
for mortgages for first-time homebuyers explicitly guaranteed by the
U.S. government through the Federal Housing Agency (FHA) or the Veterans
Administration (VA). The same phenomenon is illustrated by a sizable dip
in success rates of credit applications in figure 8, which includes not
only mortgages but also auto loans and credit cards. This decline is
especially pronounced for the lowest-credit-risk-score borrowers, who
tend to be young and/or have low incomes. Altogether, this negative
shock to the accessibility of credit likely contributed to the observed
patterns of substantial slowdowns in consumption growth and expenditure
rates, especially at the bottom of the wealth distribution.
The persistence of various measures of credit tightening mirrors
changes in household constraints, as shown in figure 9 for several
metrics. The top-left panel presents absolute measures of household
wealth below a certain threshold. The top-right panel depicts measures
of household wealth relative to earnings or income. The bottom panel
captures the share of households whose credit scores are below the
threshold commonly employed by mainstream financial institutions. All of
these measures paint the same picture and tell us that the share of
constrained households increased dramatically with the onset of the
Great Recession and showed no signs of decline through 2012. Since
current models do not explain the slow recovery of consumption with
simply a large fraction of poor households, the persistence of these
constraints means that this channel could hold particular promise in
bringing existing models in line with realistic consumption dynamics.
Changes in earnings risk
Table 7 discusses changes in some statistics of the labor market by
net worth quintiles. First, it shows that unemployment increased during
the Great Recession and especially so for those in the bottom wealth
quintile. Second, it highlights that there were also large changes in
hours and the fraction of people working and that both are U-shaped in
wealth quintiles. In the baseline models, unemployment is the only labor
market dynamic that changes (exogenously) during the cycle and does so
independently of one's wealth level. Thus, the labor market
dynamics of the model abstract from important features of labor supply.
Other studies have also found that earnings conditional on
employment exhibit different dynamics over the business cycle. For
instance, Guvenen, Ozkan, and Song (2014) find that the left-skewness of
earnings shocks is strongly countercyclical: During recessions, large
upward earnings movements become less likely, whereas large drops in
earnings become more likely. KS and KMP do not account for these
important dynamics. The fact that negative earnings shocks become more
likely in a recession is another force reducing consumption and
increasing savings and might help bring the consumption response to
aggregate shocks in the model more in line with the data.
This asymmetric increase in negative earnings risk during downturns
holds promise in explaining the persistently languid consumption growth
after the Great Recession, particularly among the poorest households, in
addition to the initially steep decline. For example, Pistaferri (2016)
runs regressions on changes in wealth and disposable income using
pre-2008 aggregate data to predict consumption responses and then
extrapolates these for the post-2008 period. He finds that consumption
has recovered significantly more slowly than would be expected based on
the historical data (a finding corroborated in our figure 1), but that
accounting for household leverage and consumer confidence appears to
explain the entire gap between observed and extrapolated trends. While
the influence of the deleveraging process on reduced consumption has
probably softened, Pistaferri finds that factors influencing consumer
confidence have not. In particular, pessimism is strongest amongst the
lowest quartile of the income distribution who report worse expectations
and increased uncertainty concerning financial conditions. These
households also exhibit a permanent rise in the expected probability of
job loss, not unlike the long-lasting aversion to financial risk
documented among households who experienced the macroeconomic shock of
the Great Depression (Malmendier and Nagel, 2011). This indicates that
the recession could be seen as being characterized by both permanent
negative shocks to income and persistent increases in income uncertainty
(De Nardi, French, and Benson, 2012). The prevalence of this pessimism
among the poorest households underscores the importance of accounting
for earnings dynamics in models of household heterogeneity.
Conclusion
This article highlights a number of theoretical and empirical
reasons established by earlier literature for the importance of
household heterogeneity in understanding macroeconomic responses to
shocks. In particular, we focus on identifying households who are
constrained in their consumption choices. These households typically
have a high marginal propensity to consume. Their prevalence in the
economy and the nature of their constraints have a sizable impact on
consumption dynamics.
While incorporating a realistic degree of wealth heterogeneity is
crucial for generating plausible consumption responses, we argue that
the role of constraints cannot be adequately captured by only having a
large share of households with no wealth before a recession. This is
particularly true in the case of slowdowns like the Great Recession,
which delivered a strong negative shock not just to earnings, but also
to wealth itself. We show that accounting for shocks to different types
of wealth may also help explain consumption responses in the middle of
the wealth distribution. Also, it is important to take into account
supply-side changes in the availability of credit, which may further
amplify the magnitude of the consumption response, especially among
younger and less wealthy households. Finally, changes in the nature of
earnings risks during booms and expansions should be taken into account.
NOTES
(1) We recently published short summaries of this work in the
Chicago Fed Letter (available online,
https://www.chicagofed.org/publications/chicago-fed-letter/2018/392) and
on VoxEU.org (available online,
https://voxeu.org/article/household-inequality-and-consumption-response-shocks).
(2) We calculate similar results to KMP. See their paper for a
comparison between aggregates in the PSID and National Income and
Product Accounts.
(3) These are restricted-use data. See Lee and van der Klaauw
(2010).
(4) Tables 1, 2. and 4 are calculated by the authors from the PSID
following the computations by KMP.
(5) Recall that these statistics are derived from a representative
panel of working-age households. Thus, they will differ from
population-wide estimates that comprise NIPA data.
(6) Credit score refers to the Equifax 3.0 Risk Score. The Equifax
3.0 model score ranges from 280 to 850. As with FICO scores, higher
score values are associated with lower expected likelihood of default.
Additional details are available online.
https://help.equifax.com/app/answers/detail/a_id/244/noIntercept/.
REFERENCES
Bhutta, Neil, and Benjamin J. Keys, 2016, ''Interest
rates and equity extraction during the housing boom," American
Economic Review, Vol. 106, No. 7, July, pp. 1742-1774. Crossref,
https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20140040
Campbell, Jeffrey R., and Zvi Hercowitz, 2018, "Liquidity
constraints of the middle class," Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago,
working paper, No. 2009-20, revised February 2018, available online,
https://www.chicagofed.org/publications/working-papers/2009/wp-20.
Case, Karl E., John M. Quigley, and Robert J. Shiller, 2013,
"Wealth effects revisited 1975-2012," Critical Finance Review,
Vol. 2, No. 1, pp. 101-128. Crossref,
http://dx.doi.org/10.1561/104.00000009
De Nardi, Mariacristina, Eric French, and David Benson, 2012,
"Consumption and the Great Recession," Economic Perspectives,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Vol. 36, No. 1, pp. 1-16, available
online, https://www.chicagofed.org/publications/economic-perspectives/2012/lq-denardi-french-benson.
Guerrieri, Veronica, and Guido Lorenzoni, 2017, "Credit
crises, precautionary savings, and the liquidity trap," Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 132, No. 3, August, pp. 1427-1467. Crossref,
https://d0i.0rg/l 0.1093/qje/qjx005
Guvenen, Fatih, Serdar Ozkan, and Jae Song, 2014, "The nature
of countercyclical income risk," Journal of Political Economy, Vol.
122, No. 3, June, pp. 621-660. Crossref, https://doi.org/10.1086/675535
Kaplan, Greg, and Giovanni L. Violante, 2014, "A model of the
consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments," Econometrica,
Vol. 82, No. 4, July, pp. 1199-1239. Crossref,
https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA10528
Krueger, Dirk, Kurt Mitman, and Fabrizio Perri, 2016,
'"Macroeconomics and household heterogeneity," in
Handbook of Macroeconomics, John B. Taylor and Harald Uhlig (eds.), Vol.
2, Amsterdam: Elsevier B. V./North-Holland, pp. 843-921. Crossref,
https://doi.org/10.1016/bs.hesmac.2016.04.003
Krusell, Per, and Anthony A. Smith, Jr., 1998, "Income and
wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy," Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 106, No. 5, October, pp. 867-896. Crossref,
https://doi.org/10.1086/250034
Lee, Donghoon, and Wilbert van der Klaauw, 2010, "An
introduction to the FRBNY consumer credit panel," Federal Reserve
Bank of New York, staff report, No. 479, November. Crossref,
https://dx.d0i.0rg/10.2139/ssrn.1719116
Malmendier, Ulrike, and Stefan Nagel, 2011, "Depression
babies: Do macroeconomic experiences affect risk taking?,"
Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 126, No. 1, February, pp. 373-416.
Crossref, https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjq004
Meyer, Bruce D., and James X. Sullivan, 2013, "Consumption and
income inequality and the Great Recession," American Economic
Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 103, No. 3, May, pp. 178-183.
Crossref, https://d0i.0rg/l0.1257/aer. 103.3.178
Pistaferri, Luigi, 2016, "Why has consumption remained
moderate after the Great Recession?," Stanford University, working
paper, October.
University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Survey
Research Center, 2017, Panel Study of Income Dynamics, public use data
set, Ann Arbor, MI, available online, https://psidonline.isr.umich.edu/.
Gene Amromin is a vice president and the director of financial
research, Mariacristina De Nardi is a senior economist and research
advisor, and Karl Schulze is a senior research assistant in the Economic
Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. De Nardi is
also a faculty ivsearch fellow at the National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER). The authors are grateful to Dirk Krueger, Fabrizio
Perri, and Kurt Mitman for providing some of their graphs, some of their
codes for comparison, and for helpful discussions. They thank Francisco
Buera, Spencer Krone, and Marcelo Veracierto for insightful comments and
suggestions. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do
not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
or the NBER.
[c] 2018 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Economic Perspectives is published by the Economic Research
Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. The views expressed
are the authors' and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago or the Federal Reserve System.
Charles L. Evans, President; Daniel G. Sullivan, Executive Vice
President and Director of Research: Anna L. Paulson, Senior Vice
President and Associate Director of Research; Spencer Krane, Senior Vice
President and Senior Research Advisor; Daniel Aaronson, lice President,
microeconomic policy research; Jonas D. M. Fisher, Vice President,
macroeconomic policy research; Robert Cox, Vice President, markets team;
Gene Amromin, lice President, finance team; William A. Testa, Vice
President, regional programs; Marcelo Veracierto, Senior Economist and
Economics Editor; Helen Koshy and Han Y. Choi, Editors; Julia Baker,
Production Editor; Sheila A. Mangier, Editorial Assistant.
Economic Perspectives articles may be reproduced in whole or in
part, provided the articles are not reproduced or distributed for
commercial gain and provided the source is appropriately credited. Prior
written permission must be obtained for any other reproduction,
distribution, republication, or creation of derivative works of Economic
Perspectives articles. To request permission, please contact Helen
Koshy, senior editor, at 312-322-5830 or email
[email protected].
ISSN 0164-0682
https://doi.org/10.21033/ep-2018-1
TABLE 1
Means and marginal distributions in 2006
Consumption
Labor earnings Total income expenditures Net worth
Mean (2006) 66,425 80,277 47,526 324,973
Q1 2.1 4.4 6.1 -1.5
Q2 9.8 10.9 12.2 1.2
Q3 16.2 16.3 17.2 6.0
Q4 24.9 23.4 23.4 14.7
Q5 47.1 45.0 41.0 79.6
90-95% 9.1 9.0 9.0 11.0
95-99% 13.8 13.6 11.3 23.4
Top 1% 7.2 7.1 5.8 26.3
Gini 0.45 0.46 0.39 0.76
Sample size 6,231 6,231 6,231 6,231
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics.
TABLE 2
Shares and means by net worth quintile in 2006
% Share of aggregate Mean (000s $ 2006)
Net Labor Total Cons, Net Labor
worth earnings income exp. worth earnings
Q1 -1.5 11.6 11.5 14.6 -15.5 29.4
Q2 1.2 14.2 14.0 15.3 13.3 37.8
Q3 6.0 20.3 19.5 19.6 71.1 57.4
Q4 14.7 20.8 20.6 20.9 213.2 73.1
Q5 79.6 33.1 34.4 29.7 1,344.4 134.6
Correlation 0.31 0.38 0.21
with net worth
Mean (000s $ 2006)
Total Cons, Expenditure
income exp. rate (%)
Q1 35.0 26.8 76.8
Q2 44.9 29.6 66.0
Q3 66.5 40.2 60.5
Q4 86.8 53.2 61.2
Q5 168.4 87.8 52.2
Correlation
with net worth
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics.
TABLE 3
Household characteristics by net worth quintile in 2006
Age Years of Worked Hours if Unemployed Own home
education last year worked last year
Q1 39.2 12.7 83.4 1,906.2 17.3 12.7
Q2 40.3 12.5 89.0 2,107.1 10.7 36.4
Q3 42.3 13.2 92.3 2,219.8 5.5 80.2
Q4 46.2 13.5 95.0 2,222.4 3.1 87.7
Q5 48.8 14.8 94.7 2,316.1 3.3 93.6
Own
financial
assets
Q1 9.9
Q2 14.3
Q3 33.6
Q4 54.9
Q5 82.7
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics.
TABLE 4
Annualized nominal changes in financial variables over 2004, 2006 net
worth quintiles
Net worth (%) Total income (%) Consumption
expenditures (%)
04-06 06-10 [DELTA] 04-06 06-10 [DELTA] 04-06 06-10
All 14.1 -3.4 -17.6 2.6 0.8 -1.8 5.5 -0.8
Q1 6.0 5.4 -0.6 6.4 0.8
Q2 69.1 16.1 -53.0 4.5 2.5 -2.0 5.9 1.8
Q3 26.9 3.9 -22.9 4.9 1.6 -3.3 9.0 0.4
Q4 15.4 1.1 -14.3 4.6 1.7 -2.9 6.0 -1.2
Q5 11.0 -5.6 -16.6 -0.4 -1.9 -1.4 3.2 -2.9
Consumption Expenditure rate
expenditures (%) (percentage points)
[DELTA] 04-06 06-10 [DELTA]
All -6.4 1.6 -0.9 -2.5
Q1 -5.5 0.2 -3.1 -3.3
Q2 -4.2 0.9 -0.4 -1.3
Q3 -8.6 2.3 -0.7 -3.0
Q4 -7.2 0.8 -1.7 -2.5
Q5 -6.1 1.7 -0.6 -2.3
Notes: Changes in expenditure rates are expressed as percentage point
changes. Changes in net worth, income, and consumption expenditures are
expressed as percentage changes.
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics.
TABLE 5
Difference in annualized growth rates between recession period and
normal times
Net worth (%) Disposable Consumption Expenditure
income (%) expenditures (%) rate
(percentage
points)
Data Model Data (a) Model Data Model Data Model
Q1 -20 -0.7 -2.3 -5.5 -2.2 -3.3 0.0
Q2 -53 -18 -2.6 -2.8 -4.2 -2.4 -1.3 0.3
Q3 -23 -12 -3.3 -4.0 -8.6 -2.7 -3.0 1.4
Q4 -14 -5 -3.3 -4.5 -7.2 -2.8 -2.5 2.0
Q5 -17 -4 -3.0 -5.4 -6.1 -2.9 -2.3 3.2
All -17.6 -4 -2.9 -4.4 -6.4 -2.6 -2.5 1.3
(a) Krueger, Mitman, and Perri calculate disposable, post-tax income
and use this in their model. Since our analysis uses only pre-tax
income, we report both their data and model results for this field. All
other data results report our own computations.
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics; and Krueger, Mitman, and Perri (2016) model
results.
TABLE 6
Transitions and annualized nominal consumption changes (%) across 2006
net worth quintiles, 2006-10
2010
Limits 2006Q Q1 Q2 Q3
[less than or equal to] $2.5k Q1 64.6 24.6 8.1
[-0.5] [2.5] [3.9]
$2.5-37.4k Q2 30.2 46.2 18.3
[1.1] [1.3] [2.0]
$37.4-133k Q3 12.5 22.9 43.8
[-2.8] [-3.3] [0.9]
$133-371k Q4 7.6 8.2 26.6
[-2.9] [-4.8] [-3.7]
>$371k Q5 3.3 1.4 7.2
[-26.8] [-12.2] [-5.9]
Total 23.7 20.6 20.8
[-3.3] [-0.6] [-0.8]
2010
Limits Q4 Q5 Total
[less than or equal to] $2.5k 2.1 0.5
[5.5] [4.6] [0.9]
$2.5-37.4k 4.6 0.7
[9.0] [5.4] [1.8]
$37.4-133k 16.9 4.0
[5.1] [3.1] [0.4]
$133-371k 42.9 14.7
[-0.1] [1.9] [-1.2]
>$371k 20.0 68.2
[-1.2] [-1.3] [-2.9]
17.3 17.6
[1.0] [-0.7]
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics.
TABLE 7
Annualized changes in employment variables over 2004, 2006 net worth
quintiles
Worked last year Hours if worked
04-06 06-10 [DELTA] 04-06 06-10 [DELTA]
All -0.8 -1.4 -0.7 0.0 -1.7 -1.7
Q1 -0.9 -1.9 -0.9 1.7 -0.4 -2.1
Q2 -1.4 -1.3 0.1 0.4 -2.0 -2.4
Q3 -0.7 -1.1 -0.4 -0.7 -1.5 -0.9
Q4 -0.4 -1.3 -0.8 -0.3 -1.9 -1.6
Q5 -0.5 -1.8 -1.3 -0.7 -2.5 -1.9
Unemployed last year Head earnings
if worked
04-06 06-10 [DELTA] 04-06 06-10 [DELTA]
All -0.7 1.1 1.8 4.5 1.1 -3.4
Q1 -3.3 0.5 3.8 7.2 5.8 -1.3
Q2 -0.2 1.2 1.4 4.4 2.7 -1.8
Q3 0.7 1.0 0.4 4.2 1.5 -2.6
Q4 0.5 2.0 1.5 5.3 1.5 -3.8
Q5 -1.2 0.9 2.1 3.8 -1.3 -5.0
Notes: Changes in working status are expressed as percentage point
changes. Hours conditional on working are expressed as percentage
changes.
Source: University of Michigan, Institute for Social Research, Panel
Study of Income Dynamics.
COPYRIGHT 2018 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
No portion of this article can be reproduced without the express written permission from the copyright holder.
Copyright 2018 Gale, Cengage Learning. All rights reserved.