Current unemployment, historically contemplated.
Juhn, Chinhui ; Murphy, Kevin M. ; Topel, Robert H. 等
ELEVEN YEARS AGO, our Brookings Paper "Why Has the Natural
Rate of Unemployment Increased over Time?" analyzed long-term
changes in joblessness among American men. (1) We documented the
dramatic rise between 1967 and 1989 in both unemployment and
nonparticipation in the labor force among prime-aged males. Our main
conclusion was that a steep and sustained decline in the demand for
low-skilled workers had reduced the returns to work for this group,
leading to high rates of unemployment, labor force withdrawal, and long
spells of joblessness for less-skilled men. We found that time spent out
of the labor force and time spent unemployed accounted in roughly equal
measure for the long-term growth in joblessness. We concluded that
structural factors, primarily the decline in the demand for low-skilled
labor, had dramatically changed the prospects for a return to low rates
of joblessness any time soon.
After that paper was published, things appeared to change. The
1990s opened with a brief recession that was followed by the longest
sustained decline in unemployment in modern U.S. history. By the end of
that expansion, the unemployment rate had reached its lowest level since
the late 1960s, falling below 4 percent for the first time since 1969.
Some macroeconomists argued that the so-called natural rate of
unemployment had permanently shifted to 5 percent or below. (2) Because
we had emphasized changes in the structure of labor demand that had made
a return to low rates of joblessness unlikely, these facts presented a
challenge to our 1991 framework. Maybe we were just wrong--maybe the
demand and supply framework of our previous work is inconsistent with
rates of joblessness in the post-1990 period. If so, we would join a
distinguished group of social scientists who have drawn attention to a
significant empirical phenomenon only to watch that phenomenon disappear
immediately thereafter. (3) As it turns out, however, the framework that
we developed for thinking about pre-1990 patterns of joblessness also
does fairly well in helping to understand jobless time in the post-1990
period.
In this paper we look in some detail at employment data from the
1990s, revisiting issues raised in our earlier work. Specifically, we
ask:
--Have the trends we identified in our earlier paper--the
concentration of nonemployment among the less skilled, the growth of
nonparticipation in the labor force, and the increased duration of
joblessness--been reversed with the fall in aggregate unemployment?
--Did the expansion of the 1990s really return the U.S. labor
market to conditions of the late 1960s, as unemployment statistics seem
to indicate?
--Does the economic framework of supply and demand we utilized a
decade ago still help in understanding long-term developments in
unemployment, nonemployment, and labor force participation?
Our answers are surprising. First, the basic trends toward longer
spells of joblessness and rising nonemployment have continued in spite
of the prolonged expansion of national output and the concomitant fall
in unemployment rates. Long jobless spells and labor force withdrawal
were more important in the 1990s than ever before. Second, the fall in
unemployment to levels close to historical lows is very misleading.
Broader measures of joblessness show that the labor market of the late
1990s was more like the relatively slack labor market of the late 1980s
than like the booming labor market of the late 1960s. Finally, the basic
forces of supply and demand identified in our previous paper continue to
have explanatory power. The theory does a reasonably good job of
explaining those trends that have continued, as well as those that have
changed.
Recent data also provide considerable insight into what has
happened in the labor market over the past decade. Over the 1990s, even
as unemployment was falling, time spent out of the labor force was
rising. In fact, the increase in time spent out of the labor force was
so large that total joblessness--which combines the unemployed with
those who have withdrawn from the labor force--was as high at the
business-cycle peak in 2000 as it had been at the previous cyclical peak
of 1989, even though the unemployment rate was roughly 2 percentage
points lower. In terms of total joblessness, the often-praised boom of
the 1990s really represented little in the way of employment progress
for American males.
Although the growth in the amount of time American males spend out
of the labor force continues a trend found in our earlier research,
other features of the data changed in the 1990s. The real wages of
less-skilled men, which had been falling steadily since the early 1970s,
stabilized in the 1990s and even rebounded slightly in the second half
of the decade. It appears that the thirty-year trend toward greater wage
inequality has run its course, at least at the bottom of the wage
distribution. The data on joblessness reflect the impact of the changing
wage trends. The long-term divergence in employment rates between
low-wage workers and those with higher wages, so pronounced in our
earlier work, has stopped, and unemployment and wage gaps across skill
groups have narrowed. The congruence between patterns of change in wages
and in employment comports with our previous work, which stressed
demand-driven wage changes as the dominant factor driving secular
changes in employment rates.
We are not the first to study the decline in unemployment in the
1990s. Others have emphasized changes in the composition of the labor
force as a source of this decline. Robert Shimer found that aging of the
labor force is important in explaining the decline in unemployment,
particularly compared with the late 1970s. (4) Lawrence Katz and Alan Krueger investigated to what extent the withdrawal of the incarcerated population from the labor force, among other factors, has led to a drop
in the aggregate unemployment rate. (5) Other papers have explored the
role of improvements in job search technology. For example, David Autor
argues that temporary help agencies may have helped improve the
efficiency with which job seekers are matched with employers, thus
bringing about a decline in frictional unemployment. (6) The arrival of
the Internet may have also reduced search costs, although its impact is
less certain. (7)
We show in this paper that a sharp decline in the incidence of
jobless spells accounts for the lower unemployment rates of the 1990s,
but that at the same time durations of spells have remained high. This
fact is inconsistent with a theory built on declining search costs,
which would imply shorter unemployment spells.
A related line of research compares the divergence in employment
outcomes between the United States and Europe. Although both the U.S.
and the EU economies may have experienced similar patterns of labor
demand during the 1970s and the 1980s, it is widely believed that
more-flexible labor markets and wages kept American unemployment rates
relatively low, while European rates rose. Along these lines, several
papers emphasize the importance of interactions between macroeconomic shocks and labor market institutions. (8) These papers find that
although neither macroeconomic variables (oil prices, real interest
rates, total factor productivity, the labor share of income) nor labor
market institution variables (unemployment benefits and duration, union
coverage, collective bargaining, employment protection policies) alone
can explain the differences between the United States and Europe, a
model that allows for interaction effects fits the data well. But this
shocks-plus-institutions framework is less successful in understanding
recent changes in U.S. unemployment. For example, Giuseppe Bertola,
Francine Blau, and Lawrence Kahn reported that the model significantly
underpredicts the decline in U.S. unemployment in the late 1990s. (9)
We revisit the evolution of joblessness in the United States, using
thirty-four years (1967-2000) of microdata from the Current Population
Surveys (CPS) conducted by the Bureau of the Census and the Bureau of
Labor Statistics. Our main conclusions are the following:
--Falling unemployment rates over the 1990s greatly exaggerate the
improvement in labor market conditions for prime-aged males. Rates of
overall joblessness--which include time out of the labor force--remained
roughly the same in the late 1990s as they had been in the late 1980s,
even as unemployment rates fell. Rising labor force nonparticipation
among prime-aged men largely offset declining unemployment, so that the
employment-to-population ratio held constant.
--Trends toward longer durations of both unemployment and
nonemployment continued in the 1990s, in spite of declining unemployment
rates. The probability of entering unemployment (or nonemployment) fell
dramatically during the 1990s. The decline in the incidence of jobless
spells was so large that the likelihood of experiencing one reached its
lowest level in the thirty-four years covered by our data. But there was
no decline in the duration of unemployment spells--these were about 2.8
weeks longer in 1999-2000 than they had been a decade earlier--and the
duration of nonemployment spells increased by over four months during
the 1990s. Broadly speaking, all of the long-term growth in joblessness
is the product of longer durations of jobless spells.
--Although nonemployment continues to be concentrated among
less-skilled men, the trend toward rising joblessness among the least
skilled reversed course somewhat in the 1990s. The largest declines in
unemployment occurred among men in the lowest skill categories.
Unemployment among men in the bottom 10 percent of the wage distribution
fell by 4.6 percentage points between the cyclical peaks of 1989-90 and
1999-2000, while the decline in unemployment at the median of the wage
distribution was about 1 percentage point. In contrast, over the longer
term the growth in nonemployment is heavily weighted toward less-skilled
men. Among men at the bottom of the wage distribution, the nonemployment
rate increased by 13.5 percentage points between the late 1960s and
2000, but by less than 1 percentage point for men with wages above the
median of the distribution.
--The long-term decline in the real wages of less-skilled men
stopped in the early 1990s and actually reversed itself slightly in the
latter part of the decade. Although the wages of highly skilled men grew
most rapidly of all during the 1990s--continuing past patterns of
relative growth-inequality between men at the bottom of the wage
distribution and men at the median contracted slightly over the decade.
Overall, the trend toward greater wage inequality appears to have
stopped for males in the bottom half of the wage distribution.
--Joblessness among less-skilled men has shown up increasingly as
time spent out of the labor force rather than as time spent unemployed.
Consistent with our earlier work, we believe that this continued trend
toward labor force withdrawal reflects two factors: relatively low
returns to work (real wages for the least skilled remain substantially
lower than in the past) and increasingly attractive nonwork
opportunities, such as collecting disability payments, which have
shifted labor supply among the least skilled. We find that more than 40
percent of the growth in nonparticipation is associated with an increase
in men claiming to be ill or disabled.
--Despite rising wages and rates of labor force participation for
women, the high rate of joblessness among less-skilled men is not the
outcome of improved labor market opportunities for their working wives.
Nonemployment rates and rates of labor force withdrawal increased most
among men who did not have a working wife. Looking across the male wage
distribution, the proportion of men with a working wife actually fell
among low-skilled men, whose wages and employment rates were falling,
and rose among men in the top 40 percent of the wage distribution, where
wages rose and employment rates were stable. We conclude that long-term
changes in joblessness have been the result of adverse shifts in labor
demand, perhaps coupled with policy-driven shifts in labor supply, among
low-skilled men.
Data
Our data are drawn from the 1968-2001 Annual Demographic Files that
supplement the March CPS. The CPS collects information monthly from a
rotating, random sample of approximately 50,000 U.S. households. It
forms the basis for published government statistics on earnings,
employment, unemployment, and labor force participation, among other
measures. Whereas published labor market statistics rely on questions
about each survey respondent's employment status in the reference
week of the survey (usually the third week of the month), we study
retrospective information, collected each March, on labor market
outcomes in the previous calendar year. Hence our data cover the
thirty-four calendar years from 1967 through 2000.
In addition to personal and household characteristics for each
respondent, the retrospective data in the March survey record the number
of weeks during the previous year that the respondent worked, was
unemployed, and was out of the labor force, as well as the
respondent's number of unemployment spells. We measure time spent
unemployed (U) as the percentage of the year spent in that state (for
example, for the ith individual, [U.sub.i] is the number of weeks
unemployed divided by 52); time spent out of the labor force (O) and
time spent nonemployed (N = U + O) are measured in analogous fashion.
This differs from the usual method of measuring time in unemployment,
which divides weeks unemployed by weeks in the labor force. Our method
better summarizes the allocation of time across the three states, and it
naturally aggregates across individuals. (10) Using methods described
below, we use information on weeks worked, unemployed, and out of the
labor force to calculate both the incidence and the duration of jobless
spells.
The survey also records a respondent's annual earnings and
usual weekly hours worked from all jobs as well as occupation, industry,
and other characteristics for the longest job held during the previous
year. We use the information on earnings, weeks worked, and hours worked
to calculate average hourly wages and to assign individuals a percentile
position in the overall wage distribution, as described below. This
allows us to track changes in employment outcomes (U, O, and N) for
persons in different parts of the wage distribution.
We focus our analysis on males because they were the focus of our
earlier work and because labor force participation issues for women are
significantly more complex. To avoid issues associated with early
retirement, Social Security, and pensions, we focus on men who have one
to thirty years of potential labor market experience. For high school
graduates this cutoff yields men who are roughly nineteen to forty-nine
years of age, with correspondingly higher age intervals for those with
more schooling. We define years of labor market experience as the
smaller of two numbers: age minus years of education minus seven, and
age minus seventeen. (11) In addition, in order to avoid measurement
problems for men who spent part of the year in school or in the
military, we exclude those who report that they did not work part of the
year because of school or military service.
The employment measures we study are based on CPS respondents'
weeks worked, weeks unemployed, weeks out of the labor force, and number
of unemployment spells during the previous year, as reported in the
survey week. Using these data, we are able to identify the fraction of
respondents who experienced some unemployment or time out of the labor
force during the year, as well as the number who worked no weeks during
the year. We refer to the latter event as full-year nonemployment.
Imputing Wages for Nonparticipants and Other Adjustments
We construct two samples for analysis. The "wage sample"
contains non-self-employed men for whom valid observations are available
on annual earnings, weeks worked, and usual weekly hours. (12) For men
in the wage sample, we calculate an hourly wage as the ratio of annual
earnings to the product of weeks worked and usual weekly hours. The
"employment sample" includes the entire wage sample plus those
men who lack valid wage data because they did not work. For men not
included in the wage sample, we impute a statistical distribution of
wages based on education, experience, and weeks worked. For each
individual with recorded earnings, weeks, and hours we project the log
hourly wage on a quartic function in potential experience, and we assign
each individual a percentile rank based on his position in the
distribution of the residuals. For persons with zero weeks worked in the
previous calendar year, we impute a wage distribution based on the
observed distribution of wages for those who worked from one to thirteen
weeks in that year. (13) The imputation assigns ten probability
weights--each corresponding to the probability that the
individual's wage would come from a given decile of the wage
distribution--along with a mean wage for each decile.
Our 1991 paper sought to explain changes in jobless time by changes
in wages across skill categories. As we showed then, the relationship
between calculated wages and time worked during a year is contaminated by measurement error in the latter, and the relative importance of this
type of measurement error declines with the number of weeks worked in
the previous calendar year. (14) This builds in a negative relationship
between labor supply (weeks worked) and calculated wages, particularly
among men with high calculated wages. As in our 1991 paper, we use data
on hourly wages for March respondents who were also in the outgoing
rotation groups to calculate the wage adjustments that would equate the
distributions of calculated retrospective wages from the previous
calendar year and reported hourly wages from the survey week. We then
apply these adjustments to each percentile of the wage distribution. The
procedure effectively compresses the wage distribution in each year by
an amount that we attribute to measurement error in calculated wages.
Armed with calculated wages for those in the wage sample and an
imputed wage distribution for those without valid wage data, we group
individuals into five "skill" categories based on their
positions in the wage distribution. The percentile intervals are 1-10,
11-20, 21-40, 41-60, and 61-100. As described above, each
individual's wage percentile is calculated based on his wages
relative to those of men with the same level of experience in a given
year. Individuals in the wage sample are assigned to one of the five
categories based on their actual wage, whereas those with imputed wages
are assigned probabilities of being in each of the categories.
Changes in Wages, 1967-2000
In light of the prominence we assigned to wage changes in our 1991
paper, it is worthwhile to review what has happened to both wage levels
and the distribution of wages since then. Figure 1 and table 1 summarize the main features of the data. Figure 1 shows trends in real hourly
wages by wage percentile group (skill category) since 1967; the data are
indexed to equal 100 in 1970. For our purposes the most interesting
aspect of these data is that wage inequality stopped increasing in the
1990s, especially at the lower end of the wage distribution, and that
the real wages of all skill categories increased after 1993. For
less-skilled workers, real wage growth in the 1990s represented a slight
reversal of a twenty-year decline in the returns to work, which had
fallen by nearly 30 log points after 1972. Even so, average wages of the
least-skilled men were roughly 20 percent lower in 2000 than in the late
1960s (table 1), whereas those of men in the top 40 percent of the
distribution increased by a roughly equivalent amount. As we showed in
our 1991 Brookings Paper, wage declines were most prominent among those
whose employment outcomes are most sensitive to wage changes--the least
skilled--whereas rising wages are concentrated among those with less
elastic labor supply.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
With this evidence as background, we turn to evidence on changes in
joblessness, both in the aggregate and across the wage percentile groups
defined above. We return to the implications of wage changes in the
concluding section.
Unemployment, Nonparticipation, and Nonemployent
We begin by describing trends in unemployment and comparing our
March CPS-based data with unemployment statistics from the monthly CPS
published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Figure 2 shows that by 2000
the unemployment rate had reached its lowest level in thirty years, and
unemployment rates in 1999-2000 were close to the extremely low rates
seen during the late 1960s. (15) This is the culmination of a long
downward trend in unemployment: in both the 1991-92 and the 2001-02
recessions (not shown), the peak unemployment rate was lower than the
peak in the preceding recession, reversing a trend of rising peaks
across the 1970-71, 1974-75, and 1982-83 recessions. (16) It appears
from the figure that the U.S. economy has come full circle: unemployment
rose for fifteen years (from 1968 to 1983) and then fell over the next
seventeen years (from 1983 to 2000), with intervening cyclical swings.
One might conclude from these data that the labor market conditions of
the late 1960s and late 1990s were comparable.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Figure 2 also shows annual unemployment rates for our sample of
prime-aged males (calculated from the March CPS data as weeks unemployed
divided by weeks in the labor force). Although the two series should not
be identical because of differences in the underlying populations (our
sample consists only of prime-aged males, whereas the overall
unemployment data are from the full population of labor force
participants aged sixteen and over), the two series are remarkably
similar in terms of underlying trends and rankings of cyclical
variations in unemployment. One would reach the same basic conclusions
about unemployment trends from the published monthly series as from our
calculations based on the March CPS data. From here forward we analyze
the March CPS data exclusively.
A major finding of our 1991 paper was that the long-term growth in
unemployment greatly understated the growth in joblessness. Recent data
suggest that changes in unemployment shown in the aggregate and in the
CPS statistics are even more misleading for the 1990s. This is
illustrated in figure 3, which plots two series: the fraction of annual
weeks spent unemployed and the fraction of annual weeks spent out of the
labor force. The nonemployment rate is the sum of these fractions, so
that the combined height of the two shaded regions represents the
proportion of the year spent out of work. Figure 3 confirms that
measured unemployment fell during the 1990s to levels comparable to
those in the 1960s, but the conclusion in terms of overall jobless time
is much different: the late 1990s were much like the 1980s, in that the
decline in unemployment over the 1990s is not reflected in a lower
overall rate of joblessness. This means that, on net, men who left
unemployment did not find jobs but rather left the labor force, so that
the employment-to-population ratio was unchanged from its level in the
1980s.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
Table 2 summarizes the data in figure 3 by aggregating the data
into nine time intervals corresponding roughly to peaks and troughs in
the business cycle, as measured by aggregate unemployment rates.
Unemployment shows a strong cyclical pattern as well as a long-run
upward trend (whether measured peak to peak or trough to trough) until
the recession of 1982-83. After 1982-83 unemployment rates fall or stay
constant (again whether measured peak to peak or trough to trough). In
contrast, the fraction of the year spent out of the labor force rises
between every pair of intervals. In fact, whereas the unemployment rate
in 1999-2000 is very close to its level in 1967-69, the nonemployment
rate is 4.7 percentage points higher, and the fraction of the year spent
out of the labor force is roughly double what it was in 1967-69. It is
difficult to conclude from these data that employment conditions of the
late 1960s and the late 1990s were "similar" in any meaningful
sense.
Consider next the eleven-year interval between the business-cycle
peaks of 1988-89 and 1999-2000. Over this peak-to-peak time span the
unemployment rate fell by 1.3 percentage points--from 4.3 percent to 3.0
percent--but the percentage of men who were out of the labor force rose
by exactly the same amount, from 6.7 percent to 8 percent. This left the
nonemployment rate at the same level (11.0 percent) in 1999-2000 as in
1988-89, even though this period spans the longest sustained economic
expansion, and the largest decline in unemployment, on record.
We next divide the growth in nonemployment along a second
dimension. The percentage of weeks spent out of work is equal to the sum
of two components: the fraction of men who did not work at all over the
year (for whom the fraction of weeks spent out of work is 100 percent)
and the fraction of weeks spent out of work for those who worked some
positive amount (multiplied by the fraction of men who worked at least
one week). In what follows we refer to these two components as
"full-year nonemployment" and "part-year
nonemployment," respectively. This decomposition allows us to
examine how much of the growth in nonemployment is accounted for by men
with very long stretches of joblessness--that is, spells that are so
long that men do not work at all during a calendar year--and how much is
due to men with "transitory" jobless spells.
The results, shown in table 3 and figure 4, are striking. The
amount of joblessness accounted for by those working at least part of
the year was only slightly higher in 1999-2000 than in 1967-69 (4.9
versus 4.5 percent). But the amount of joblessness accounted for by
those who did not work at all over the year more than tripled, from 1.8
percent in the 1960s to 6.1 percent in 1999-2000. Moreover, whereas
part-year nonemployment declined by 4.5 percentage points from its
recessionary peak in 1982-83 to 1999-2000, full-year nonemployment
increased slightly. This is particularly striking given that the
intervening period is characterized by two of the longest economic
expansions on record.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
What explains this trend toward long-term joblessness? One
possibility is that those men with the least favorable labor market
prospects have simply dropped out of the labor market: the so-called
discouraged worker effect. Figure 5 addresses this possibility by
disaggregating nonemployment and nonparticipation, respectively, by
reported reason. We distinguish among three main groups: those who
reported that they could not find work, those who reported that they
were ill or disabled, and a residual category we label
"other." Over the period covered by our data, the figure shows
only a small increase in the proportion of men who reported that they
could not find work. Rising shares of the "ill or disabled"
and "other" categories account for the largest changes of both
nonemployment and nonparticipation. The larger impact of the "ill
or disabled" category is on the nonparticipation rate (middle panel
of figure 5): men in this category account for about 42 percent (0.8 out
of 1.9 percentage points) of the increase in nonparticipation between
1982-83 and 1999-2000. The rest is "other." The bottom panel
of figure 5 narrows the focus to men who were full-year nonworkers, for
whom the effect of rising disability is more prominent still. Virtually
none of the long-term increase in full-year joblessness is accounted for
by discouraged workers: the "other" category and persons
reporting joblessness for health reasons account for the secular
increase.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
A large literature examines the impact of changes in the disability
benefits program on the labor market participation of male workers. (17)
These papers document a substantial growth in the disability rolls in
the early 1970s, linked to the sharp decline in participation among
older males. Because real wages were rising for the most part over this
period, the earlier episode is consistent with a reduction in labor
supply in response to the improving nonmarket alternative represented by
disability payments. During the early 1980s, however, legislative and
administrative changes tightened eligibility standards; these tighter
standards led to reductions in new awards and terminated benefits for a
substantial fraction of beneficiaries.
After 1984, eligibility criteria were substantially liberalized,
and this led to increased receipt of disability payments. (18) Examining
aggregate time series as well as cross-state variation, John Bound and
Timothy Waidmann concluded that virtually all of the increase in
nonemployment among those reporting that they were ill or disabled in
the CPS could be explained by increased receipt of disability benefits.
(19) Autor and Mark Duggan concluded that liberalization of eligibility
for disability insurance interacts with adverse shifts in labor demand,
as otherwise employable men opt for subsidized nonparticipation over
unemployment or low-wage work. Figure 6 offers indirect supportive
evidence on this point, comparing the changes in unemployment and
nonparticipation between peaks and troughs of different business cycles.
The figure shows that increased nonparticipation accounted for a much
larger fraction of rising nonemployment in 1989-92 than in earlier
recessions. The smallest contribution of nonparticipation was in the
recession of 1992, when eligibility rules were tightened. The increase
in nonemployment among the ill or disabled accounted for nearly 16
percent of the total change in nonemployment between 1989 and 1992 (not
shown), a much higher proportion than in previous recessions.
Nonemployment of the ill or disabled actually fell during the 1982
recession, an observation that also likely reflects the tightening of
eligibility rules during this period.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
Table 4 decomposes secular changes in nonemployment between 1967-69
and 1999-2000, as well as over the 1990s. In the 1990s the data indicate
that roughly half (0.8 percentage point) of the 1.5-percentage-point
increase in nonparticipation reflects a shift in labor supply caused by
improving nonmarket alternatives to working. There is no reason to
believe that the health of American men deteriorated over the decade
(and much reason to believe that it improved). (20) Yet nonparticipation
caused by self-reported health reasons increased by 0.8 percentage point
over the decade. Unlike in the early 1970s, when real wages were rising
rapidly as nonparticipation increased, real wages remained low and were
falling over the first half of the 1990s. This fact makes it more
difficult to parcel out the component due to shifting labor supply. Yet
with the increase in real wages in the latter half of the decade,
continuing growth of non-participation indicates a shift in labor
supply. In a manner analogous to interpretations of the European
unemployment experience, the data indicate that the interaction of
disability benefits and labor market shocks may be of key importance in
understanding rising rates of labor force withdrawal. (21)
Figure 7 summarizes our previous results, showing long-term changes
in three alternative measures of joblessness since the late 1960s. The
unemployment rate shows the most dramatic improvement of the three
measures in the 1990s, nearly returning to 1960s levels. By this common
measure of labor market performance, events have come full circle, and
one might argue that the natural rate of joblessness has returned to
previous low levels. Adding nonparticipants who are discouraged workers
changes the conclusion slightly, although the figure also demonstrates
that there has been no reduction in discouraged workers since the 1980s.
Adding in other nonparticipants to give total nonemployment changes the
interpretation substantially. By this measure there was no improvement
in overall joblessness from the late 1980s to 2000, despite falling
unemployment rates. In this sense, changes in unemployment provide a
misleading picture of changes in employment opportunities and the
likelihood of finding work.
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
The Incidence and Duration of Jobless Spells
The data on full-year nonemployment suggest that the concentration
of unemployment and nonemployment increased dramatically over the period
covered by our data. Table 5 provides further evidence, showing, for
various periods, the distributions of spells of joblessness during a
calendar year. The trend toward long-term joblessness is unmistakable.
For example, in the 1960s, when the nonparticipation rate was 6.3
percent, men who were jobless for the entire year accounted for 28.8
percent of nonemployment. But by the end of the 1990s--when
nonemployment reached 11 percent--full-year nonemployment accounted for
over half of all joblessness. A similar pattern holds for unemployment
(table 6). Although unemployment rates in 1999-2000 were roughly
comparable to those in the 1960s, the share of unemployment due to short
spells (one to thirteen weeks) fell by one-third, from 30 percent to 20
percent. Individuals with more than six months of unemployment accounted
for about a quarter of all unemployment in the 1960s, but 46 percent by
the end of the 1990s. These shifts toward long-term joblessness mean
that particular rates of unemployment and nonparticipation have much
different meanings today than in past decades.
To examine the increased importance of long spells more closely, we
use information in the CPS to estimate both the incidence and the
duration of jobless spells. Focusing first on unemployment, we note that
the rate of unemployment can be decomposed into the product of two
components: the probability of an individual entering unemployment (the
entry rate), and the average duration of an unemployment spell. Denote the instantaneous transition rates from employment (e) and out of the
labor force (o) to unemployment (u) at date t by [[lambda].sub.eu](t)
and [[lambda].sub.ou](t), respectively, and the corresponding rates at
which individuals leave unemployment by [[lambda].sub.ue] (t) and
[[lambda].sub.uo](t). Then the rate of change in the unemployment rate
is
(1) du(t) / dt =
e(t)[[lambda].sub.eu]+o(t)[[lambda].sub.ou](t)-u(t)
[[[lambda].sub.ue](t)+[[lambda].sub.uo](t)].
The steady-state fraction of weeks spent unemployed, [du(t)/dt =
0], corresponding to the entry and exit rates at any given point in time
satisfies
(2) [u.sup.*](t) = [1 - [u.sup.*](t)][[lambda].sub.u](t) /
[[lambda]'.sub.u](t),
where
(3) [[lambda].sub.u](t) = [e.sup.*](t) / 1 - [u.sup.*](t)
[[lambda].sub.eu](t) + [o.sup.*](t) / 1 - [u.sup.*](t)
[[lambda].sub.ou](t), and [[lambda]'.sub.u](t) =
[[lambda].sub.ue](t) + [[lambda].sub.uo](t).
Here [[lambda].sub.u] is the rate at which individuals enter
unemployment, being a share-weighted average of entry rates for persons
who are employed and those who are out of the labor force. Similarly,
[[lambda]'.sub.u](t) is the rate at which individuals leave
unemployment by becoming employed or by leaving the labor force. Since
1/[[lambda]'.sub.u](t) is the average duration corresponding to the
contemporaneous rate of exit from unemployment, and [1 -
[u.sup.*](t)][[lambda].sub.u](t) is the expected number of spells of
unemployment per year at the current entry rate, equation 2 has a
natural interpretation in terms of entry and duration. Growth in the
steady-state fraction of the year spent unemployed can be decomposed
into growth in the probability of becoming unemployed (entry) and the
average duration of unemployment spells.
To implement this framework empirically, we use two identities that
correspond to equation 1 integrated over the year. The change in the
unemployment rate from the beginning to the end of year [tau] is
(4) [U.sub.1]([tau]) - [U.sub.0]([tau]) + [1 - [bar]U(tau)][[bar]
[lambda]'.sub.u]([tau]),
where [U.sub.1]([tau]) is the unemployment rate (measured as a
fraction of the population) at the end of year [tau], [U.sub.0]([tau])
is the corresponding rate at the start of the year, and [bar]U([tau]) is
the average unemployment rate over the year. With these definitions,
[[bar][lambda].sub.u]] ([tau]) and [[bar][lambda]'.sub.u]] ([tau])
are weighted averages of the instantaneous transition probabilities to
and from unemployment. (22) The expected number of spells of
unemployment over the year is then
(5) S([tau]) = [U.sub.0]([tau]) + [1 - [bar]U(tau)][[bar]
[lambda].sub.u]([tau]),
since spells are generated either by starting the year unemployed,
[U.sub.0]([tau]), or by becoming unemployed during the year, [1 -
[bar]U(tau)][[bar][lambda].sub.u]([tau]). To estimate the entry and exit
parameters, we use the data from the CPS together with monthly data on
aggregate rates to interpolate the starting and ending numbers for each
year. Solving equations 4 and 5 gives our estimating equations for
unemployment transitions as
(6) [[bar][lambda].sub.u]([tau]) = S([tau]) - [U.sub.0] ([tau]) / 1
- [bar]U([tau])
and
(7) [[bar][lambda]'.sub.u]([tau]) = S([tau]) - [U.sub.1]
([tau]) / [bar]U([tau]).
The resulting estimates are shown in the top panel of figure 8 and
in the first two data columns of table 7. For unemployment, the key
finding is that an increase in durations accounts for the entire growth
in unemployment over the 1967-2000 period. The entry rate into
unemployment was actually lower in 1999-2000 (0.7 percent a month) than
it was in 1967-69 (1.1 percent a month), whereas durations of
unemployment spells doubled from 2.1 to 4.2 months. Notice from equation
3 that a declining incidence of unemployment spells can be caused either
by a decline in the rate at which individuals lose their jobs,
[[lambda].sub.eu](t), or by a decline in the rate at which
nonparticipants start to look for work, [[lambda].sub.ou](t). These
contributions are not separately identified, although it is likely that
the o [right arrow] u transition has declined substantially as
nonparticipation has become a permanent labor force state for larger
numbers of men. In any case, we cannot conclude from table 6 and figure
8 that the e [right arrow] u transition has declined, that is, that jobs
have become more stable.
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
According to figure 8, until the recession of 1991-92, cyclical
fluctuations in unemployment were driven by changes in both the
incidence and the duration of spells, with roughly equal weights on each
component. But rising incidence played a minor role in the recession of
1991-92, while durations soared. Indeed, unemployment durations in 1993
were virtually the same as in the recession year 1983, which were the
highest in all the years of our data, while the entry rate was about 25
percent lower. The ensuing decline in unemployment over the remainder of
the decade is driven almost entirely by reduced probabilities of
becoming unemployed; durations of unemployment remained high. From these
data it appears that the main characteristic of the 1990s is that the
historic correspondence between the incidence and the duration of
unemployment spells came to an abrupt end. With fewer but longer spells,
the population distribution of unemployment is much more concentrated
than in earlier years.
The last two columns of table 7 and the bottom panel of figure 8
show corresponding calculations for the incidence and duration of
nonemployment spells. In the case of nonemployment, the CPS does not
provide information on the number of spells in a calendar year--separate
spells of nonparticipation are not recorded--and so we use data on the
incidence of nonemployment over the year (that is, the fraction of men
with positive weeks of nonemployment) to infer the entry rate. (23)
These calculations show that the contrast between entry and duration is
even more extreme than in the case of unemployment. As with
unemployment, the rate of entry to nonemployment is actually lower in
1999-2000 than it was in the 1960s, but durations show a steady upward
trend over the thirty-four years covered by our data, with no sign of
slower growth in the 1990s. By the end of the decade the average
duration of nonemployment spells was over fifteen months, which is more
than double the length of spells in the late 1960s. The average duration
of spells rose by over four months from the late 1980s to 1999-2000,
reflecting the increasing proportion of men who have simply quit the
labor force.
Table 7 and figure 8 paint a clear picture. Although the rates of
entry into unemployment and nonemployment have returned to or even
fallen below levels experienced during the late 1960s, the durations of
jobless spells are more than twice as long at the end of the period.
Indeed, jobless spells were longer in 1999-2000 than at any previous
cyclical low of unemployment, and they exceeded the average duration of
spells over the whole period of the data. It should be clear from these
data that the employment patterns of the late 1990s resemble other
periods of low unemployment--the late 1960s in particular--only in terms
of the overall rate of unemployment and the rates at which individuals
enter joblessness. The durations of spells are very different and very
much longer. For the typical worker, the occurrence of a jobless spell
is a far different event than it was in the past.
Unemployment, Nonemployment, and Wages
Our previous analysis of wage and employment data through 1989
found that the patterns of change in unemployment and nonemployment
varied significantly across skill groups, as defined by percentile
intervals of the overall wage distribution. Figure 9 and table 8
summarize our results based on wage percentile groupings for the period
1967-2000. Table 8 records changes in unemployment, nonparticipation,
and total joblessness between 1967-69 and 1988-89 (the end of the data
in our 1991 paper), between 1988-89 and 1999-2000, and over the full
period of our data.
[FIGURE 9 OMITTED]
All components of nonemployment increased the most for low-wage
workers, especially before 1989. Over the 1990s, nonparticipation
continued to rise while unemployment rates declined sharply. Reversing
previous trends, in the 1990s both unemployment and overall
nonemployment fell the most for workers in the bottom 10 percent of the
wage distribution. Other low-wage groups also experienced lower
unemployment over the decade, although nonemployment was largely
unchanged for workers above the bottom 10 percent, reflecting rising
rates of labor force withdrawal. Even with the sharp decline in
unemployment for low-wage workers in recent years, however, for the full
period both unemployment and nonemployment increased most among the
least skilled. Nonemployment rose by roughly 12 percentage points for
the two lowest wage groups, but by less than 1 percentage point for men
above the 60th percentile of the wage distribution. For workers near the
median (percentiles 41-60), unemployment was essentially unchanged over
the period as a whole, yet nonemployment increased by 3 percentage
points.
Cyclical increases in joblessness are known to fall most heavily on
the least skilled. Figure 10 compares the skill distributions of
cyclical and secular changes in nonemployment. For each of the wage
intervals shown in table 8, the figure shows the average cyclical change
in jobless time going into and out of four recessions (1970-71, 1975-76,
1982-83, and 1991-92), (24) the secular change between the cyclical
peaks of 1967-69 and 1988-89 (the period covered in our 1991 paper), and
the shorter secular change over the more recent 1988-89 to 1999-2000
period. Compared with business-cycle increases in nonemployment, the
secular change in nonemployment from the late 1960s to the late 1980s
was much more skewed toward low-skilled men, with virtually no impact on
persons above the median of the wage distribution. The secular movement
over the recent period is more nearly skill neutral, with the exception
that nonemployment fell significantly for men in the first decile of the
wage distribution. In this sense the 1990s represent a small reversal of
declining employment opportunities among the least skilled. We relate
these changes to concomitant changes in the distribution of wages below,
but first we take a brief detour to explore an alternative explanation
for changing jobless rates among prime-aged men, namely, the labor
market opportunities of their wives.
[FIGURE 10 OMITTED]
Did Working Wives Shift Male Labor Supply?
It remains our view that long-term changes in male joblessness were
driven by changes in labor demand that disproportionately affected
less-skilled workers. These adverse demand conditions continued into the
1990s, although somewhat mitigated, so that nonemployment continued to
rise even as measured unemployment was falling. An alternative
explanation--with far different welfare implications--is that increased
wages and greater labor force participation of women have shifted
men's labor supply: as the labor market opportunities of wives
improved, husbands chose to work less and household utility rose. On
this view, at least part of the long-term increase in nonemployment
among men represents a welfare-improving change in household labor
supply decisions.
Table 9 and figure 11 explore this issue. Table 9 records male
earnings, the percentage of households with a working wife, average
earnings of wives, and average household income for households in
different percentiles of the male wage distribution. Among less-skilled
men, where the largest increases in nonemployment occurred, the
percentage of households with a working wife actually fell over time.
For these men, declining marriage rates offset increased labor force
participation of women, so that fewer low-wage men today reside with a
working wife. For less-skilled men, average household income (which
includes earnings of all household members) increased only slightly from
1972-73 (when the trend toward rising inequality began) to 1999-2000:
average household income rose by 11 percent in each of the percentile
intervals 1-10 and 21-40; in these groups, increases in the average
earnings of working wives by 40 percent helped to offset declining male
earnings. In contrast, the presence of a working wife is both higher and
rising in households above the 60th percentile of the male wage
distribution, where men's wages were rising and employment rates
were stable. The share of these households in which a working wife was
present increased by 9 percentage points after 1972-73 and by 12
percentage points from the 1960s, and the average earnings of these
wives increased by 153 percent between 1972-73 and the end of the
century.
[FIGURE 11 OMITTED]
It is difficult to square these facts with the view that long-term
increases in labor force withdrawal among men have been driven by
improved labor market opportunities for their wives. To settle the
issue, figure 11 shows changes in unemployment, nonparticipation, and
full-year nonemployment for men with and without working wives. The
clear pattern is that rising unemployment and labor force withdrawal
have been concentrated among men who do not have a working wife. The
contrast in trends is particularly striking for nonparticipation and
full-year nonemployment, where men without a working wife have
steadily withdrawn from regular employment. From these data we conclude
that a theory built on shifts in household labor supply will not go far
in explaining changes in male joblessness.
Wage Changes, Labor Supply, and Nonemployrnent
So far our discussion has focused on changes in unemployment and
nonemployment over time. Figure 1 and table 1 showed that many of the
same patterns observed with regard to employment and unemployment hold
for real wages. Inequality in real wages grew significantly from 1970 to
1990 across the full range of the wage distribution. Since 1990,
inequality has continued to increase at the top of the wage
distribution, but inequality has held steady or even narrowed slightly
at the bottom: both low-wage and middle-wage workers experienced real
wage increases starting around 1995. These increases in real hourly
wages represent the first significant growth in real wages for low- to
middle-wage males since the early 1970s. According to our earlier
analysis, rising wages for these groups should lead to increased
employment rates, especially among the least skilled, for whom we
concluded that labor supply elasticities were largest.
At a general level, trends in nonemployment by wage percentile
group (bottom panel of figure 9) and trends in real wages for these same
groups (figure 1) reveal a similar pattern. In both cases low-wage
workers fared far worse than their middle- and high-wage counterparts
for much of the sample period, and in both cases the divergence stops in
the 1980s (after roughly 1983 in the case of employment, and after
roughly 1989 in the case of wages). Our earlier paper formalized this
connection, arguing that declining rewards to work provoked labor supply
responses from less-skilled workers, who chose to work less. To what
extent does the demand-driven explanation we stressed in our earlier
paper--that individuals respond to changing real wage
opportunities--help us to understand the changes since 1989 in
employment for men in different skill categories?
Table 10 presents estimated partial labor supply elasticities
obtained from cross-sectional data for the years 1972-73 and 1988-89.
(25) Our estimates correspond closely to those reported in our earlier
paper. They show substantially higher elasticities at low wages: the
employment rates of less-skilled workers are more responsive to wage
changes. The top panel of the table illustrates the fact that the large
wage declines (shown in the second data column), together with the
estimated elasticities, can account for most of the rise in
nonemployment from 1972-73 to 1988-89. The bottom panel of the table
uses the same labor supply elasticities estimated from pre-1990 data,
together with post-1989 wage changes, to predict changes in
nonemployment during the 1990s. There is a reasonable correspondence
between the predicted and the actual changes: we predict an improvement
in employment for the lowest wage group and somewhat worsening conditions for the other groups below the median. Yet we also
underpredict the improvement in employment for the least-skilled group.
Although wages and employment are obviously linked in the long run, our
interpretation of the results is that the labor supply model is less
successful in predicting the dynamics of employment and wage changes
over a relatively short period. Notice also that employment gains
preceded the recovery in wages among the least skilled, which is
inconsistent with a pure labor supply explanation of changing employment
rates.
Conclusion
We have examined unemployment and nonemployment among prime-aged
males in the United States using thirty-four years of data on labor
market outcomes. Although recent unemployment rates have fallen to
levels reminiscent of the 1960s, we find that rising nonparticipation
rates have offset reductions in unemployment, leaving nonemployment
rates unchanged. The rise in nonparticipation appears to be due to both
an expansion of the disability benefits program--as previous research
has argued--and continued low levels of real wages of less-skilled men
during the 1990s.
Compared with earlier decades, the increase in nonparticipation in
the 1990s is more evenly distributed across skill groups. Employment
rates of the least skilled rose the most, even as their wages lagged
behind other groups for much of the decade. This suggests that rising
inequality, which characterized labor markets in the 1970s and 1980s,
may have run its course.
Is the American labor market today fundamentally different from
that of the 1960s? Despite the comparability of unemployment rates
between the late 1960s and the late 1990s, the changing composition of
nonemployment--from unemployment to nonparticipation, and from part-year
to full-year nonemployment--suggests that the combination of low wages
and the availability of nonwork alternatives has made out-of-work males
increasingly less likely to enter new jobs. From this perspective, our
assessment of the labor market for less-skilled men is rather grim.
Our earlier work concluded that the natural rate of unemployment,
or of nonemployment, is not a constant toward which the economy
gravitates over time. Rather, it varies with labor market conditions in
a manner consistent with the original formulation of Edmund Phelps. (26)
Over the long term, the natural rate of nonemployment has increased
because changing patterns of labor demand have reduced the returns to
work for less-skilled men. In this setting, the low unemployment rates
of the latter half of the 1990s have a far different interpretation than
comparable rates of the past. By the end of the 1990s, an important
proportion of less-skilled men had withdrawn from the labor force for
demand-related reasons. That they are not counted among those seeking
work is not a sign of strength in current labor market conditions.
Table 1. Changes in Real Wages, by Wage Percentile Group, 1967-2000 (a)
Percent
Wage percentile group
Period 1 to 10 11 to 20 21 to 40
1967-69 to 1988-89 -24.8 -19.9 -12.7
1988-89 to 1994-95 -3.9 -7.1 -8.3
1994-95 to 1999-2000 6.1 6.7 6.8
1988-89 to 1999-2000 2.2 -0.4 -1.5
1967-69 to 1999-2000 -18.7 -13.2 -5.9
Wage percentile group
Period 41 to 60 61 to 100
1967-69 to 1988-89 -4.0 5.5
1988-89 to 1994-95 -7.6 -3.6
1994-95 to 1999-2000 6.4 10.7
1988-89 to 1999-2000 -1.2 7.1
1967-69 to 1999-2000 2.4 16.2
Source: Authors' calculations using annual March Current Population
Survey (CPS) data.
(a.) Reported hourly wage (in natural logarithms) is projected on a
quartic function in potential experience. Men are assigned a percentile
category based on their position in the residual distribution. Wages
for nonworkers and self-employed workers are imputed.
Table 2. Unemployment, Nonparticipation, and Nonemployment during
Business-Cycle Peaks and Troughs, 1967-2000
Units as indicated
Labor force status
(percent of calendar year (a))
Phase of
Period business cycle Unemployed Nonparticipating
1967-69 Peak 2.2 4.1
1971-72 Trough 4.5 4.9
1972-73 Peak 3.8 5.0
1975-76 Trough 6.9 5.6
1978-79 Peak 4.3 5.9
1982-83 Trough 9.0 6.3
1988-89 Peak 4.3 6.7
1991-92 Trough 6.3 7.5
1999-2000 Peak 3.0 8.0
Labor force status
(percent of calendar year (a)
Phase of
Period business cycle Nonemploved (b)
1967-69 Peak 6.3
1971-72 Trough 9.4
1972-73 Peak 8.8
1975-76 Trough 12.4
1978-79 Peak 10.2
1982-83 Trough 15.2
1988-89 Peak 11.0
1991-92 Trough 13.8
1999-2000 Peak 11.0
Change in Change in
Phase of unemployment nonparticipation
Period business cycle (percentage points) (percentage points)
1967-69 Peak
1971-72 Trough 2.3 0.8
1972-73 Peak -0.7 0.1
1975-76 Trough 3.0 0.6
1978-79 Peak -2.5 0.3
1982-83 Trough 4.6 0.4
1988-89 Peak -4.7 0.5
1991-92 Trough 2.0 0.8
1999-2000 Peak -3.3 0.5
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Number of weeks in indicated status divided by 52.
(b.) Unemployed plus nonparticipating; details may not sum to totals
because of rounding.
Table 3. Part-Year and Full-Year Nonemployment, 1967-2000 (a)
Percent of calendar year
Phase of
Period business cycle Part-year (b) Full-year (c) Total
1967-69 Peak 4.5 1.8 6.3
1971-72 Trough 6.5 2.9 9.4
1972-73 Peak 6.0 2.8 8.8
1975-76 Trough 8.4 4.1 12.4
1978-79 Peak 6.8 3.8 10.2
1982-83 Trough 9.4 5.8 15.2
1988-89 Peak 6.5 4.6 11.0
1991-92 Trough 7.7 6.0 13.8
1999-2000 Peak 4.9 6.1 11.0
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Details may not sum to totals because of rounding.
(b.) Fraction of males nonemployed for part of the year multiplied by
the average percent of the calendar year spent nonemployed for this
group.
(c.) Fraction of males nonemployed for the entire year multiplied by
the percent of the calendar year spent nonemployed (100 percent).
Table 4. Changes in Nonemployment, by Reported Reason for
Nonemployment, 1967-2000 (a)
Percentage points
Reason for nonemployment
No work Illness or
Measure available disability Other Total
Change 1967-69 to 1999-2000
Nonemployment 1.2 1.7 1.8 4.7
Out of labor force 0.6 1.7 1.7 4.0
Unemployment 0.6 0.0 0.0 0.6
Change 1988-89 to 1999-2000
Nonemployment -1.9 0.8 1.1 0.0
Out of labor force -0.4 0.8 1.0 1.5
Unemployment -1.5 0.0 0.0 -1.5
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Details may not sum to totals because of rounding.
Table 5. Distribution of Nonemployment, 1967-2000 (a)
Percent of nonemployed
Number of weeks a year
Period 2 or fewer 3 to 12 13 to 25 26 to 38
1967-69 2.4 17.2 18.9 18.0
1971-72 1.5 12.9 18.8 21.2
1972-73 1.6 12.4 17.2 21.7
1975-76 1.1 9.9 16.6 22.5
1978-79 1.5 13.1 17.7 20.2
1982-83 0.8 8.1 13.9 20.6
1988-89 1.0 10.3 13.2 19.0
1991-92 0.8 8.8 12.7 19.1
1999-2000 0.7 8.0 9.7 13.9
Number of weeks
a year
Period 39 to 51 52
1967-69 14.8 28.8
1971-72 15.9 29.7
1972-73 15.3 31.9
1975-76 17.2 32.7
1978-79 14.4 33.2
1982-83 18.3 38.3
1988-89 15.2 41.3
1991-92 14.9 43.8
1999-2000 12.2 55.5
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Details may not sum to 100 because of rounding.
Table 6. Distribution of Unemployment, 1967-2000 (a)
Percent of unemployed
Number of weeks a year
Period 13 or fewer 14 to 26 27 to 39 40 to 49 50 to 52
1967-69 30.3 42.3 14.9 8.9 3.6
1971-72 20.4 40.6 21.5 10.9 6.6
1972-73 20.6 39.9 21.0 10.4 8.2
1975-76 17.8 31.2 22.8 14.5 13.7
1978-79 27.0 34.2 19.0 11.8 8.0
1982-83 13.7 28.9 21.7 17.9 17.7
1988-89 22.6 33.5 18.5 14.8 10.5
1991-92 16.9 31.7 20.6 16.4 14.3
1999-2000 20.4 33.4 18.2 14.6 13.4
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Details may not sum to 100 because of rounding.
Table 7. Estimated Entry Rates and Durations of Unemployment and
Nonemployment, 1967-2000
Units as indicated
Unemployment (a)
Entry rate
Phase of (percent a Duration
Period business cycle month) (months)
1967-69 Peak 1.1 2.1
1971-72 Trough 1.5 3.2
1972-73 Peak 1.4 2.9
1975-76 Trough 1.8 4.1
1978-79 Peak 1.5 3.1
1982-83 Trough 1.9 5.1
1988-89 Peak 1.3 3.5
1991-92 Trough 1.5 4.5
1999-2000 Peak 0.7 4.2
Nonemployment (b)
Entry rate
(percent a Duration
Period month) (months)
1967-69 1.0 6.7
1971-72 1.2 8.6
1972-73 1.1 8.5
1975-76 1.5 9.6
1978-79 1.4 8.4
1982-83 1.5 12.0
1988-89 1.1 11.0
1991-92 1.3 12.4
1999-2000 0.8 15.1
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Estimated from the number of spells using equations 5, 6, and 7.
(b.) Based on incidence of nonemployment; see text for details.
Table 8. Changes in Unemployment, Nonparticipation, and Nonemployment,
by Wage Percentile Group, 1967-2000
Percentage points
Wage percentile group
Period 1 to 10 11 to 20 21 to 40 41 to 60
Unemployment
1967-69 to 1988-89 6.4 4.9 2.6 1.5
1988-89 to 1999-2000 -4.6 -3.1 -1.6 -1.0
1967-69 to 1999-2000 1.8 1.8 1.1 0.5
Nonparticipation
1967-69 to 1988-89 10.9 7.2 2.9 1.3
1988-89 to 1999-2000 0.8 2.4 2.6 1.3
1967-69 to 1999-2000 11.7 9.5 5.5 2.6
Nonemployment
1967-69 to 1988-89 17.3 12.1 5.6 2.8
1988-89 to 1999-2000 -3.8 -0.8 1.0 0.3
1967-69 to 1999-2000 13.5 11.3 6.6 3.0
Full-year nonemployment
1967-69 to 1988-89 10.2 6.3 2.9 1.6
1988-89 to 1999-2000 1.7 2.7 2.4 1.3
1967-69 to 1999-2000 12.0 8.9 5.4 2.9
Wage percentile group
Period 61 to 100
Unemployment
1967-69 to 1988-89 0.3
1988-89 to 1999-2000 -0.5
1967-69 to 1999-2000 -0.1
Nonparticipation
1967-69 to 1988-89 0.0
1988-89 to 1999-2000 0.9
1967-69 to 1999-2000 0.9
Nonemployment
1967-69 to 1988-89 0.3
1988-89 to 1999-2000 0.4
1967-69 to 1999-2000 0.8
Full-year nonemployment
1967-69 to 1988-89 0.5
1988-89 to 1999-2000 0.9
1967-69 to 1999-2000 1.4
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
Table 9. Household Earnings Characteristics, by Wage Percentile Group,
1967-2000 (a)
1996 dollars a year, except where noted otherwise
Item 1967-69 1972-73 1978-79
1st to 10th percentile
Male earnings 11,134 11,354 11,479
Percent of households
with working wife 38 36 36
Wife's earnings (b) 3,050 3,392 3,766
Household income 22,965 26,366 28,140
21st to 40th percentile
Male earnings 23,746 25,213 23,579
Percent of households
with working wife 49 48 48
Wife's earnings 5,132 5,773 6,133
Household income 35,394 39,137 40,770
61st to 100th percentile
Male earnings 44,213 49,375 47,147
Percent of households
with working wife 41 45 50
Wife's earnings 4,786 5,918 7,219
Household income 54,456 61,722 61,861
All households
Male earnings 31,230 34,121 32,686
Percent of households
with working wife 44 45 48
Wife's earnings 4,713 5,548 6,388
Household income 42,263 47,538 48,560
Item 1988-89 1999-2000
1st to 10th percentile
Male earnings 8,625 9,584
Percent of households
with working wife 31 29
Wife's earnings (b) 3,975 4,770
Household income 25,952 29,194
21st to 40th percentile
Male earnings 21,522 21,507
Percent of households
with working wife 46 40
Wife's earnings 7,410 8,091
Household income 40,773 43,431
61st to 100th percentile
Male earnings 51,449 59,843
Percent of households
with working wife 55 54
Wife's earnings 11,537 14,993
Household income 71,937 88,507
All households
Male earnings 33,193 36,789
Percent of households
with working wife 49 45
Wife's earnings 8,895 10,854
Household income 52,821 61,541
Sources: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data and Economic
Report of the President, 2001.
(a.) Earnings and household income are deflated by the price index for
personal consumption expenditure. Male's and wife's earnings include
income from wages, salary, and self-employment; household income
includes all sources of earned and non-earned income of all household
members.
(b.) Average of wife's earnings for all males in the sample; the
observation is zero when there is no working wife.
Table 10. Estimated Labor Supply Elasticities and Changes in
Nonemployment and Wages, 1972-2000 (a)
Units as indicated
Partial Change in
labor real log
supply hourly wage
Wage percentile group elasticity (b) (percent)
1972-73 to 1988-89
1 to 10 0.287 -24.8
11 to 20 0.217 -22.3
21 to 40 0.170 -16.5
41 to 60 0.126 -9.2
61 to 100 0.048 -0.2
Entire sample n.a. -9.9
1988-89 to 1999-2000
1 to 10 0.287 2.3
11 to 20 0.217 -0.4
21 to 40 0.170 -1.5
41 to 60 0.126 -1.2
61 to 100 0.048 7.0
Entire sample n.a. 2.4
Change in
nonemployment
(percentage points)
Wage percentile group Predicted Actual
1972-73 to 1988-89
1 to 10 7.0 10.2
11 to 20 4.7 5.7
21 to 40 2.7 2.6
41 to 60 1.1 0.8
61 to 100 0.1 -0.1
Entire sample 2.0 2.2
1988-89 to 1999-2000
1 to 10 -0.7 -3.8
11 to 20 0.1 -0.8
21 to 40 0.3 1.0
41 to 60 0.2 0.3
61 to 100 0.1 0.4
Entire sample 0.1 0.0
Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data.
(a.) Labor supply elasticities and observed changes in real wages are
used to predict the change in nonemployment.
(b.) Elasticities in both panels are estimated using cross-sectional
data on average wage and employment, by percentile, for 1972-73 and
1988-89.
Comments and Discussion
Lawrence F. Katz' Chinhui Juhn, Kevin Murphy, and Robert Topel
have produced an insightful and informative extension into the 1990s of
their earlier important work on the evolution of joblessness among U.S.
prime-aged males. Their earlier study documented a large increase in the
nonemployment rate of prime-aged males from 1967 to 1989, concentrated
among low-skilled (low-wage) workers and in long-term spells of
joblessness. (1) Increases in the shares of men classified as unemployed
and as out of the labor force contributed to this rise in the
nonemployment rate. The authors concluded that a secular decline in the
demand and labor market opportunities for low-skilled males was the
driving force behind rising U.S. male nonemployment in the 1970s and
1980s.
In their new work, the authors find that some of the earlier trends
continued into the 1990s and some did not. The share of prime-aged men
not participating in the labor force continued to rise in the 1990s. The
large reduction in unemployment in the 1990s for prime-aged men was
completely offset by this increase in nonparticipation, so that the
overall nonemployment rate for these men did not decline from the
late-1980s business-cycle peak to the 1999-2000 peak. The rise in
prime-aged male nonparticipation is concentrated in full-year
nonemployment, and those listing illness or disability as the main
reason for nonemployment account for a large share of the growth in male
labor force nonparticipation (0.8 percentage point of a
1.5-percentage-point increase from 1988-89 to 1999-2000).
On the other hand, the authors document that the rise in
nonemployment among low-skilled men (those in the bottom 40 percent of
the wage distribution) of the 1970s and 1980s stopped and may even have
reversed itself in the 1990s. But nonemployment and nonparticipation
continued to rise for men in the top half of the wage distribution. And
the trend of large reductions in the real wages of low-skilled men
stopped: these men saw real wage increases in the second half of the
1990s. Thus the 1990s expansion generated less inequality in labor
market outcomes for prime-aged males than the experiences of the 1970s
and 1980s.
The authors call their paper "Current Unemployment,
Historically Contemplated." A wordier but more appropriate title
would be "Almost-Current U.S. Prime-Aged Civilian Noninstitutional
Male Unemployment, Contemplated through the Lens of the March Current
Population Surveys." One reason is that the authors limit their
analysis to prime-aged U.S. males (which they define as those with one
to thirty years of potential experience) and focus on the information
available in the March Current Population Survey (CPS) through calendar
year 2000. Prime-aged males are indeed a key labor force group, but
women and older workers (those with more than thirty years of potential
experience) have become increasingly important labor force participants
in recent years. In addition, their analysis is not fully
"current," because it does not include the most recent
recession. Furthermore, the use of the March CPS limits the analysis to
the civilian noninstitutional population and thus fails to capture a
major component of the rise in male nonemployment: the massive increase
in U.S. incarceration rates over recent decades. The CPS does not
include institutionalized groups (such as those held in state and
federal prisons and in jails). Finally, the paper addresses only
employment in the United States; some useful perspective on U.S.
employment patterns could be gained through comparisons with other major
developed economies.
The inclusion of other important labor force groups (women and
older males) in the analysis, and comparison of the U.S. experience with
that of other economies of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD), would generate a somewhat more positive overall
assessment of U.S. employment performance over the full period studied
by the authors, and especially the 1990s. U.S. female unemployment has
declined and converged with male unemployment: there has been no rise in
the unemployment rate for prime-aged females despite a more than 50
percent rise in the employment rate for women since 1969. And the
long-term trend of a declining employment rate for near-elderly men
(those fifty-five to sixty-four years old) ceased in .the United States
in the 1990s. Sustained real wage growth in the 1990s boom translated
into greater reductions in measured poverty than in the 1980s and 1970s.
Economic prosperity was more widely shared in the 1990s expansion than
in the 1980s expansion.
Also, in comparative perspective, the U.S. labor market provided
improving opportunities in the 1990s for prime-aged males relative to
OECD Europe and to Japan. Over the 1990s the nonemployment rate for
prime-aged males (those twenty-five to fifty-four years old) was stable
in the United States (10.9 percent in 1990 and 11.0 percent in 2000),
but it increased sharply in both OECD Europe (from 11.0 percent in 1990
to 13.6 percent in 2000) and in Japan (from 3.8 percent in 1990 to 6.5
percent in 2000). Over the same period, the nonemployment rate actually
declined by 0.4 percentage point for U.S. men aged fifty-five to
sixty-four, while it increased substantially (by 5.7 percentage points)
in OECD Europe. And the employment rate remained much higher and the
unemployment rate much lower for adult females in the United States than
in OECD Europe. (2)
On the other hand, the expansion of the sample to include the
incarcerated would undo the apparent improvement in employment that the
authors find for low-skilled U.S. males in the 1990s. Such a more
complete sample leads to an even more pessimistic set of conclusions
concerning the labor market for low-skilled males at the end of the
1990s relative to that of the late 1960s, despite similar aggregate
unemployment rates.
I will focus the remainder of my comments on three issues: the role
of changing disability policies in rising male nonemployment rates; the
impact of rising incarceration rates; and some puzzles related to the
authors' supply-side analysis of the role of real wage movements in
changes in prime-aged male employment rates by skill group.
The authors find that increases in the share of individuals
reporting illness or disability as the main reason for nonemployment
contribute substantially to the rise in male nonemployment over the last
several decades. Their analysis of the March CPS data indicates that
about one-third of the rise in prime-aged male nonemployment over the
last three decades (1.7 percentage points of a 4.7-percentage-point
increase from 1967-69 to 1999-2000) results from those indicating
illness or disability as their main reason for nonemployment. And as
already noted, this group accounts for more than half the rise in the
rate of nonparticipation in the 1990s. The authors suggest that the
growing attractiveness of disability benefits relative to work and job
search could help explain this pattern.
I strongly agree with this conclusion. In fact, the share of the
U.S. nonelderly adult population receiving disability benefits, either
Social Security Disability Insurance (SSDI) or the means-tested
Supplemental Security Income (SSI), has expanded substantially over much
of the last forty years. The disability rolls grew rapidly in the 1960s
and 1970s, especially SSDI for males from forty-five to sixty-four years
of age; this was followed by a strong clampdown on disability recipiency
in the early 1980s. Congressional legislation in 1984 ended the
clampdown and relaxed the eligibility rules and screening criteria for
SSDI, with a broader definition of disability (especially providing more
flexibility on allowing claims of mental illness and pain), ending
Continuing Disability Reviews for existing recipients, and providing
applicants and their own medical providers greater opportunity to
influence the decision process. The relaxation of eligibility
requirements also applied to SSI. In the late 1980s and early 1990s,
Congress mandated outreach efforts to inform potentially eligible
low-income individuals of SSI benefits and to put greater weight on
information from an SSI or SSDI applicant's own medical provider in
award decisions. (3)
The result has been a resurgence in the growth of SSDI and SSI
rolls since the mid-1980s. The share of nonelderly adults on SSDI
increased from 1.8 percent in 1985 to 3.0 percent in 2000, with a
similar increase for SSI, from 1.3 percent to 2.3 percent, over the same
period. (4) Since about one-fourth of SSDI recipients also receive SSI,
(5) the share of the nonelderly adult population receiving disability
benefits (either SSDI or SSI) may be around 4.5 percent today, compared
with 2.7 percent in 1985. In fact, the rise in the disability rolls more
than offset the more familiar decline in the welfare rolls (Aid to
Families with Dependent Children and, after 1995, Temporary Assistance
to Needy Families) of the 1990s in terms of the number of nonelderly
adults supported by cash transfers. SSDI is now the largest income
transfer program directed toward nonelderly adults, with cash transfers
of approximately $50 billion in 2000.
The rise in the SSDI rolls is likely to be far more important for
understanding rising labor force nonparticipation among prime-aged males
than the rise in the SSI rolls. About 85 percent of SSDI applicants were
employed for several years before applying, whereas only a small
fraction (under 30 percent) of SSI applicants have been employed in the
years before applying. (6)
The recent increase in the share of prime-aged men leaving the
labor force to go on disability reflects the relaxation of screening
criteria since the mid-1980s and the increasing generosity of SSDI
benefits relative to work for low-skilled males. The progressive nature
of SSDI benefits means that there has been a substantial increase in the
replacement rates for low-wage males in the face of declining real wages
for these workers since the 1970s. David Autor and Mark Duggan estimate
that the cash income replacement rate for a male at the 10th (from the
bottom) percentile of the wage distribution increased from 46 percent in
1979 to 54 percent in 1999 (and from 59 percent to 84 percent over the
same period if one includes the value of Medicare benefits and in-kind
employee benefits in the calculation). (7) They also present strong
evidence that adverse labor demand shocks led to larger increases in
disability applications and high rates of labor force withdrawal for
less-educated males in the period since the liberalization of disability
insurance benefits in the mid- 1980s.
The growth in prime-aged adults receiving disability benefits seems
to be a response to changes in screening and in economic incentives to
enter disability programs and not due to a decline in true health
status. The available evidence suggests improving rather than declining
health over this period. (8) And Autor and Duggan find that the new flow
of SSDI recipients increasingly comes from those whose disabilities are
characterized by lower mortality rates and longer typical durations on
the disability rolls (for example, musculoskeletal and mental
disorders). (9)
How much of the rise in male nonemployment and nonparticipation
documented by Juhn, Murphy, and Topel can be explained by a shift of
workers onto the SSDI rolls? Table 1 of this comment shows that the SSDI
recipiency rate for prime-aged males (here defined as those eighteen to
fifty-four years old) increased from 1.0 percent in 1970 to 2.2 percent
in 1999. Thus, possibly 1.2 percentage points of the 4-percentage-point
rise in the share of (noninstitutional) prime-aged males out of the
labor force since the late 1960s can be explained by the growth of SSDI.
The growth in SSI might explain a little bit more. And SSDI growth is
much larger for the low-skilled (less-educated) males who experienced
the largest increases in nonemployment over the past three decades.
As I have mentioned, the authors' estimate of prime-aged male
nonemployment from the March CPS covers only the noninstitutional
population. The rapidly growing number of incarcerated males disappears
from the population covered by the CPS and thus is missing from both the
numerator and the denominator of the authors' estimates of
nonemployment and nonparticipation rates. This incarcerated group is
heavily concentrated among the less educated and the less skilled. An
expanded measure of nonemployment (and nonparticipation) that
consistently includes the incarcerated as nonemployed (and out of the
labor force) indicates a substantially larger rise in male nonemployment
and nonparticipation rates in recent decades. And such an expanded
measure implies that the increase in male nonemployment since 1970 is
even more concentrated among the less skilled than indicated by the
authors' tabulations from the March CPS.
Table 1 also shows that the share of U.S. prime-aged males who are
incarcerated increased even more rapidly than the SSDI rolls from 1970
to 1999. It increased by 1.7 percentage points, from 0.7 percent in 1970
to 2.4 percent over that period, including a 0.9-percentage-point
increase in the 1990s alone. Thus, when the incarcerated are included,
the prime-aged male nonemployment rate, rather than being stable in the
1990s, actually increased by 0.8 percentage point. And the overall
increase in the primeaged male nonemployment rate from 1967-69 to
1999-2000 rises by 30 percent, from 4.7 to 6.1 percentage points. (The
corresponding increase in the nonparticipation rate is an even greater
35 percent, from 4.0 to 5.4 percentage points.)
It is less clear what the causal impact of changes in incarceration
policies has been, but this mechanical measurement effect should be
taken into account for an accurate reading of recent changes in the
labor force status of prime-aged U.S. males. A disproportionate share of
the incarcerated are likely to be nonemployed when out of custody. (10)
Surveys of prisoners clearly indicate that the growth in the
incarcerated population is concentrated among less-educated, low-wage,
and minority males. This suggests that the March CPS may particularly
understate the growth of nonemployment for low-skilled males. If, under
a possibly conservative assumption, 80 percent of incarcerated males
would be in the low-skilled group (the bottom 40 percent of the wage
distribution), then the nonemployment rate for low-skilled males
increased by an additional 3.4 percentage points from 1970 to 1999. The
inclusion of the incarcerated also implies a slight rise in the
nonemployment rate for low-skilled males in the 1990s, in contrast to
the authors' finding of a modest decrease.
These patterns suggest that a major issue for social policy in the
coming decade is how the labor market will treat the rising number of
low-skilled males with criminal records and under the continuing
supervision of the criminal justice system. Nevertheless, the economic
recovery of the 1990s was associated with sharp reductions in crime
rates. Tight labor markets, with better earnings opportunities for
low-skilled males in the legitimate economy relative to criminal
opportunities, may play an important role in reducing crime and
decreasing permanent reductions in human capital from increases in the
share of potential workers stigmatized by criminal records. Much
evidence shows a strong positive response of property crime rates to
local unemployment rates and wages in low-wage sectors, and this
response is observed across U.S. metropolitan and regional labor
markets. (11)
Finally, wage inequality increased dramatically for U.S. males, and
the real wages of low-skilled males declined substantially, from the
early 1970s to the early 1990s. The authors emphasize the role of
declining rewards to work in the 1970s and 1980s in generating labor
supply responses from less-skilled males, who chose to work less and, in
many cases, to drop out of the labor force. The authors point to a
decline in the relative demand for less-skilled workers as the key
factor behind these real wage declines. This pattern contrasts with
stable real wages and a rather stable employment rate for high-wage
males (those above the 60th wage percentile) over the same period. The
authors also argue that an increase in real wages in the 1990s played a
key role in the shift toward rising employment rates for less-skilled
males. But I would like to point out some puzzles for the authors'
simple framework in which stable labor supply curves combined with labor
demand shifts drive the observed employment changes by skill group. In
particular, as the authors point out, their framework does a reasonable
job for long periods, but it has problems matching the actual dynamic
patterns of employment and wage changes in the data.
First, a large part of the secular rise in nonemployment for
low-skilled males occurred before the period of declining real wages.
The nonemployment rate of low-skilled males increased substantially from
its 1967-69 peak to its 1972-73 peak, despite substantial real wage
growth in this period, and it does not seem to have accelerated with
declining real wages over next two decades. In fact, the nonemployment
of less-skilled men did not really rise from the early 1980s to the
early 1990s, despite continuing noticeable declines in real wages. These
figures suggest that cyclical factors affected employment changes beyond
the response to real wage changes along a stable labor supply curve. And
a permanent adverse labor supply shift (possibly from the expansion of
disability programs, and possibly from changes in illegal labor market
opportunities) appears to have occurred from 1967-69 to 1972-73.
Second, a key remaining question for the authors' approach is
what caused an apparent slowdown in adverse demand shifts against
less-skilled males in the 1990s relative to the previous two decades.
Indicators of skill-biased technological change (such as computer
investment) continued rising in the 1990s, and trade with less developed
countries grew more rapidly in the 1990s than in the 1980s. It may be
that tight labor markets and rapid productivity growth themselves
improve the demand for less-skilled males, because optimistic firms are
willing to take chances on workers whom they would not hire in a weaker
labor market. The authors' framework needs a clearer and testable
story about what drives the relative demand shifts that are doing the
work in their story of changes in U.S. male nonemployment rates.
Robert Shimer: This is a provocative paper. The conventional wisdom
is that, in the late 1990s, the U.S. unemployment rate fell to levels
not seen in three decades because demand for labor was so strong. This
paper points out that the nonemployment rate, the fraction of
individuals who are either unemployed or out of the labor force in an
average week, has behaved very differently in recent years, at least for
prime-aged men. For example, between the business-cycle peak at the end
of the 1980s and that at the end of the 1990s, the unemployment rate for
prime-aged men fell from 4.3 percent to 3.0 percent. In contrast, as the
authors' figure 3 shows, the nonemployment rate for this group
remained constant at 11.0 percent across those cyclical peaks. Moreover,
as their figure 8 reveals, these numbers mask an important increase in
nonemployment durations, from eleven months on average at the end of the
1980s to about fifteen months a decade later.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
That nonemployment among prime-aged men is high should be
uncontroversial, even if its causes and consequences are not. Indeed,
there is no need to use microdata to uncover this fact. According to the
standard Bureau of Labor Statistics time series, available from the
agency's homepage and displayed in my figure 1, unemployment among
twenty-five to fifty-four-year-old men reached a cyclical low in 1989 at
3.8 percent, but in the subsequent cycle it fell further, to 2.7 percent
in 2000. (1) Over the same eleven-year period, however, the fraction who
were nonemployed rose from 10.1 percent to 11.0 percent. By comparison,
during the deepest post-World War II recession, in 1983, the
nonemployment rate for this group peaked at an only modestly higher 13.9
percent. By this measure, then, the labor market for prime-aged men at
the end of the century remained slack.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The increase in nonemployment duration, on the other hand, is hard
to measure, and its occurrence should be more controversial. This does
not mean that nonemployment duration is unimportant. Assuming labor
insurance markets are incomplete, even a pure utilitarian cares about
both the incidence and the duration of nonemployment spells. Workers can
self-insure against nonemployment by building up a buffer stock of
savings; however, that buffer stock will generally be too small to allow
the individual to maintain his or her accustomed level of consumption
during a very long spell of nonemployment. Put differently, the average
worker's utility will be lower if 8.3 percent of the population is
out of work for the entire year than if everyone is nonemployed for one
month. Of course, many other social welfare functions would also imply
that long nonemployment durations are intrinsically undesirable, for
example because they yield a more unequal distribution of income. In
addition, it is plausible that a very long spell of nonemployment makes
it increasingly difficult for a worker to reenter employment, because
that worker's basic labor market skills begin to atrophy. Such
forces lead to hysteresis in nonemployment.
What, then, is the evidence that nonemployment duration increased
from eleven to fifteen months during the 1990s? Unfortunately, the
Current Population Survey does not ask individuals how long it has been
since they were last employed. Instead, the authors infer the duration
of nonemployment indirectly from another question, which asks the number
of weeks worked, including paid vacation and sick leave, during the
previous year. Let E denote the fraction of the relevant population who
report being employed during a typical week of the year and N the
fraction who report being nonemployed. If we assume for simplicity that
these fractions are constant during the year, then the fraction of the
population who find a job, N[[lambda].sub.ne], must equal the fraction
of the population who lose a job, E[[lambda].sub.en], where
[[lambda].sub.ne], and [[lambda].sub.en] are the fraction of nonemployed
workers who become employed and the fraction of employed workers who
become nonemployed, respectively. Since E + N = 1, this gives us one
important equation, N[[lambda].sub.ne] = (1 - N))[[lambda].sub.en]. A
second equation comes from the definition of the fraction of the
population who experience a spell of nonemployment, S. This is assumed
to be equal to the fraction of people who begin the year nonemployed, N,
plus the fraction who become nonemployed during the year,
E[[lambda].sub.en]. Thus S = N + (1 - N)[[lambda].sub.en]. Combining
these equations gives
(1) 1 / [[lambda].sub.ne] = N / S - N.
The left-hand side of equation 1 is the inverse of the likelihood
of a nonemployed worker finding employment, or, equivalently, the
average duration of a nonemployment spell in years. This is a function
of the fraction of nonemployed workers N and the fraction of workers who
experience a spell of nonemployment S. Both of these quantities are then
measured using the retrospective question in the March CPS. N is the
fraction of the year that the average worker reports that he did not
work, and S is the fraction of workers who report working less than
fifty-two weeks during the year. Similarly, the same two equations imply
that the entry rate into nonemployment, that is, the incidence of
nonemployment, satisfies
(2) [[lambda].sub.en] = S - N / 1 - N.
Both the measured increase in nonemployment duration and the
decrease in nonemployment incidence reflect a decline in S - N, the
difference between the fraction of workers who experience a spell of
nonemployment and the fraction of weeks spent nonemployed. This, in
turn, is primarily due to the enormous increase in the incidence of
full-year nonemployment (documented in the authors' figure 4).
The authors' finding, using this methodology, that
nonemployment duration nearly doubled during the 1980s and 1990s is so
striking that it seems worth attempting to verify it using an
alternative methodology. This can be done by looking at data on gross
worker flows between employment and nonemployment, constructed from
matched monthly CPS files. The CPS sample is a rotating panel, although
the public-use microdata do not contain unique individual identifiers.
Still, there are well-established procedures for matching individual
records across months--and these procedures have well-known
shortcomings, which I will discuss shortly. Following the authors'
approach, I focus my analysis on men with one to thirty years of
potential labor market experience, which I define as age minus years of
education minus six. (2) In each month from 1976 to 2001, I calculate
the fraction of employed men who leave employment (the incidence of
nonemployment) and the fraction of nonemployed men who become employed
(the inverse of the duration of nonemployment). I then aggregate these
to get annual average data, which should be comparable to the numbers in
the paper.
Figure 2 shows the results from this exercise. I find that
nonemployment durations increased from 4.5 months in 1978 to 4.8 months
in 1988 and then to 5.4 months in 1999, a cumulative increase of about
20 percent. This is much smaller than the increase in nonemployment
duration that tile authors report. The flip side of this is the
incidence of nonemployment, which they find decreases from 1.4 percent a
month to 0.8 percent during the 1980s and 1990s, whereas I find that the
incidence actually increased slightly, from 2.4 percent to 2.8 percent.
Thus there is a difference in both the level and the trend of
nonemployment duration and incidence between the gross flows data and
the retrospective data from the March CPS.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Measurement and classification error explains part of the reason
why I find such a short duration and a high incidence of nonemployment.
An individual who is mistakenly recorded as employed in one month will
generate two spurious transitions, first from nonemployment to
employment and then from employment back to nonemployment, and similarly
for an individual who is mistakenly recorded as nonemployed. This
shortcoming of the gross flows data has been analyzed at great length,
notably by John Abowd and Arnold Zellner and by James Poterba and
Lawrence Summers. (3) Abowd and Zellner used data from households that
were interviewed twice to conclude that as many as 40 percent of
reported transitions are spurious. This would, roughly speaking, reduce
the incidence of nonemployment by 40 percent and raise the duration of
nonemployment by a similar amount. Unfortunately, there is no way to
tell whether these reporting errors have increased or decreased over
time, because, to my knowledge, no one has updated Abowd and
Zellner's study. Although it is conceivable that the redesign of
the CPS instrument in 1994 reduced reporting errors--which would mask an
increase in nonemployment duration--work that I have done with Katharine
Abraham indicates that this is not the case. (4) One can see this in my
figure 2, where nothing special occurs in 1994.
The importance of measurement error can be addressed directly by
matching CPS files across three consecutive months. An individual who is
measured as employed in January and February is likely to have been in
fact employed in both those months. This means that, by looking only at
workers who are employed in both months, we avoid contaminating the
employed population with misclassified nonemployed workers. The fraction
of these workers who become nonemployed in March therefore reflects both
genuine incidents of nonemployment and misclassification of workers who
remain employed, but it does not reflect misclassification of
nonemployed workers. Likewise, by looking at the probability of entering
employment of workers who are nonemployed for two consecutive months,
the sample does not include employed workers who were misclassified. I
find that doing this nearly doubles the measured duration of
nonemployment and halves the incidence. However, the trends--or, more
precisely, the lack of trends--remain the same. There is no evidence in
gross worker flow data that the nonemployment duration of prime-aged men
has sharply increased during the last decade.
So the question is, Which numbers are correct? Has nonemployment
duration sharply increased and nonemployment incidence fallen during the
last decade, as the authors argue? Perhaps not surprisingly, I will make
the case that the gross flows data are more reliable than the March CPS
data.
One shortcoming of the March CPS data is that the measured number
of spells of nonemployment is capped at one per person. If we lived in a
world in which people were either employed or nonemployed but were
otherwise identical, this would not be a big problem. In such a world,
all employed individuals are equally likely to become nonemployed in a
given month, and all nonemployed individuals are equally likely to
become employed. In other words, there is a two-state Markov process for
individual employment status. If this were the case, it would imply that
very few people find a job and then lose it within the same year,
because the relevant transition rates are extremely small. But, of
course, we do not live in such a world. Newly employed workers are much
more likely to become nonemployed than are workers with long tenure.
This means that many workers are likely to experience multiple spells of
nonemployment during a year, and this biases downward the authors'
measure of the number of nonemployment spells S. Nevertheless, there is
no evidence that this bias has changed much over time. For example,
there is no secular shift in the likelihood of a newly employed worker
losing his job, compared with that of a worker who has at least two
months' tenure. Thus I think the explanation for the different
results must lie elsewhere.
Another possibility is that there are time-varying biases in the
way that people answer retrospective questions in the March CPS. Recall
that the driving force behind the authors' finding was the increase
in the fraction of nonemployment accounted for by full-year
nonemployment. Perhaps in recent years people have been more likely to
give extreme responses, that is, to say that they worked either zero or
fifty-two weeks in the previous year, rather than recollect a short
intervening spell of employment or nonemployment. This might be the case
if respondents have become increasingly careless in the way they answer
questions over time.
To see whether such an explanation is plausible, it is useful to
look at the mean weeks of nonemployment among individuals who report
between one and fifty-one weeks worked. If there has indeed been an
increase in nonemployment duration, mean nonemployment duration should
have increased for the part-year nonemployed, not only the fraction of
workers experiencing full-year nonemployment. Figure 3 below compares
the mean weeks of nonemployment for all prime-aged men who report less
than fifty-two weeks worked with the mean weeks of nonemployment for
prime-aged men who report one to fifty-one weeks worked. The two time
series track each other from 1975 to 1993 before diverging. As a result,
from 1989 to 2000 nonemployment in the full sample of prime-aged men
increased by 4.9 weeks a year, while nonemployment in the sample
excluding the extreme response increased by only 0.4 week a year. In
other words, all of the increase in nonemployment duration is accounted
for by an increase in full-year nonemployment. Although there are other
possible explanations for this finding, it seems plausible that this
reflects at least in part a change in how individuals report their
employment status retrospectively.
To reiterate, this is a provocative paper. Despite the strong labor
market in the United States in the 1990s, the nonemployment rate for
prime-aged men did not fall. Moreover, the paper argues that the
constant rate of nonemployment masks a sharp increase in the duration of
nonemployment and a sharp decrease in its incidence. If this is really
the case, it is likely to have significant and adverse welfare
implications. However, other data sources do not indicate that there was
much of an increase in nonemployment duration or a decrease in
nonemployment incidence for this group of men. Instead, the measured
increase in nonemployment duration may be due to a change in the way
people answer retrospective questions in the CPS. Nevertheless, the
finding that the labor market for prime-aged men was no stronger in 2000
than it was a decade earlier is surprising indeed.
General discussion: Several participants discussed what to make of
the rising trend toward nonemployment among men. Katharine Abraham
reasoned that the low unemployment rates of the last half of the 1990s
made it unlikely that any man who wanted a job could not find one. The
low real wages of less-skilled workers and the easier access to
disability insurance during the past decade both could be factors behind
men's decision not to work. She warned, however, against the easy
interpretation that the rising nonemployment of men is necessarily a bad
thing, noting that few would jump to that interpretation if women were
the group under consideration, and she commented that it would be of
interest to know more about how nonemployed men were spending their
time.
The impact on nonemployment of more comprehensive disability
insurance generated further discussion. Robert Gordon argued that the
growth in disability insurance may have contributed to the decline in
the NAIRU during the 1990s just as increased incarceration of the
unemployed had done according to Lawrence Katz and Alan Krueger's
1999 study in the Brookings Papers. (1) Robert Hall added that the
open-ended nature of the current disability insurance program has
undesirable side effects: an individual's duration on disability is
correlated with a decreased likelihood of eventually reentering the work
force and with a deterioration of work skills. William Nordhaus compared
the coverage in the disability insurance program to the poverty line,
suggesting that both seemed to be ratcheting up over time. For example,
carpal tunnel syndrome would probably not have been considered a
disability thirty years ago, but today it is. Erik Brynjolfsson interpreted the rise in disability rolls as partly the result of a
policy decision, in which individuals who were previously considered fit
for work are now categorized as disabled. He took this as a social value
judgment that these people should no longer have to work, and he
suggested that this was not necessarily a bad thing.
William Dickens observed an important difference between the
findings in the present paper and those in the authors' paper of a
decade ago: at the time of the earlier paper, unemployment and
nonparticipation in the labor force were moving in the same direction,
whereas now they seem to be moving in opposite directions. This suggests
that the supply-demand model that is useful for explaining nonemployment
is not good for explaining unemployment. Olivier Blanchard noted that a
striking feature of the data was the decrease in the flow out of
employment. He argued that this phenomenon deserved more interpretation
than the paper had given it. Nordhaus suggested that a change in survey
design in the early 1990s may have biased some of the entry and duration
results.
Table 1. Disability Insurance Recipiency Rates and Incarceration Rates
for Males Aged 18 to 54, 1970-99
Percent
Social Security disability
Year insurance recipiency rate (a) Incarceration rate (b)
1970 1.02 0.67
1980 1.45 0.83
1983 1.19 0.97
1989 1.51 1.47
1990 1.59 1.55
1999 2.24 2.35
Source: Author's calculations based on data from Bureau of the Census,
Statistical Abstract of the United States, various years; Social
Security Bulletin, Statistical Supplement, 2000; Bureau of Justice
Statistics, Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics, 2000.
(a.) Ratio of SSDI recipients to resident population.
(b.) Ratio of jail inmates plus state and federal prisoners to resident
population. Number of incarcerated males aged 18 to 54 is estimated
from data on the total number of adult males incarcerated. Based on the
characteristics of prisoners in state and federal correctional
institutions in 1991 and 1997, it is assumed that 3.5 percent of
incarcerated adults are aged fifty-five or older. For 1970 and 1980,
where separate eslimates by sex are not available, it is assumed that
90 percent of inmates are male; this is similar to the share observed
in the early 1980s.
(1.) Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991).
(2.) Data on nonemployment and unemployment rates by age and sex
for the United States, OECD Europe, and Japan are from OECD (2001, table
C, pp. 216-20).
(3.) Autor and Duggan (forthcoming).
(4.) Data on the number of nonelderly adult SSDI and SSI recipients
(those aged eighteen to sixty-four) are from the 2001 Annual Statistical
Supplement to the Social Security Bulletin, tables 5.D3 and 7.A9. Data
on the nonelderly adult population are from tabulations of the CPS
provided by David Autor and Mark Duggan.
(5.) Bond, Burkhauser, and Nichols (2001).
(6.) Bond, Burkhauser, and Nichols (2001).
(7.) Autor and Duggan (forthcoming).
(8.) As documented, for example, by Cutler and Richardson (1997).
(9.) Autor and Duggan (forthcoming).
(10.) Kling (2002) estimates that only 35 percent worked in the
year before incarceration.
(11.) See, for example, Gould, Mustard, and Weinberg (2002).
(1.) These numbers are based on Bureau of Labor Statistics time
series LFU21003301 (the unemployment rate) and LFU1603301 (the
employment-to-population ratio, or 100 percent minus the nonemployment
rate) and refer to a slightly older group of men than do the authors.
This probably explains why I find a slightly lower unemployment rate. To
calculate the unemployment rate for men with one to thirty years of
potential labor market experience, as the authors do, one must look at
the microdata.
(2.) The authors define potential experience as age minus years of
education minus seven because the questions in the March CPS refer to
employment during the previous year. The basic monthly CPS questions
refer to contemporaneous employment and nonemployment experiences, and
so potential experience is one year greater.
(3.) Abowd and Zellner (1985); Poterba and Summers (1986).
(4.) Abraham and Shimer (2001).
(1.) Katz and Krueger (1999).
We thank the Brookings Panel participants for helpful comments.
Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the National Bureau of
Economic Research Labor Studies meeting and at the University of
Missouri. We acknowledge financial support from the Center for the Study
of the Economy and the State and the Milken Foundation.
(1.) Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991).
(2.) See, for example, Stiglitz (1997), Gordon (1998), and Staiger,
Stock, and Watson (2001).
(3.) Malthus founded the club. His theory that the forces of
endogenous population growth doomed the common people to perpetual poverty "explained" why incomes had failed to increase over
the period his data covered. Publication of Malthus' s theory was
followed by two centuries of almost continuous progress. More recently,
when the returns to a college education were at a record low in 1979,
Richard Freeman (1976) offered a supply-based theory in The Overeducated
American, only to see returns to a college education increase steadily
over the next fifteen years, reaching a record high. To Freeman's
credit, his model did predict a rebound, although not so large and
sustained as the one that actually occurred.
(4.) Shimer (1998).
(5.) Katz and Krueger (1999). They conclude that up to 0.4
percentage point of the rise in the male employment-to-population ratio
from 1985 to 1998 could be due to the bias from ignoring the
institutionalized population. For the sample of prime-aged males we
study here, the bias could be larger, further underscoring our finding
that labor market conditions did not improve much for prime-aged males
in the 1990s.
(6.) Autor (2000a).
(7.) Autor (2000b); Kuhn and Skuterud (2000).
(8.) Bertola and Inchino (1995); Blanchard and Wolfers (2000);
Ljungqvist and Sargent (1998); Bertola, Blau, and Kahn (2001).
(9.) Bertola, Blau, and Kahn (2001).
(10.) Since the denominator for [U.sub.i], [N.sub.i], and [O.sub.i]
is always 52, the corresponding jobless rate is simply the sample
average of weeks in the state divided by 52.
(11.) We use age minus education minus seven rather the standard
measure, age minus education minus six, because age is measured at the
survey week and we wish to measure potential experience at the time of
our wage and employment measures (which is the year before the survey).
(12.) For the early years (before the 1976 survey) we impute usual
weekly hours from hours worked in the last week and individual
characteristics, and we impute weeks worked and unemployed from the
categorical data based on averages calculated for the 1976-80 period.
(13.) Men with zero weeks worked resemble those with one to
thirteen weeks worked in terms of years of schooling completed and in
terms of living arrangements (living alone, with a spouse, or with other
family). We also matched the outgoing rotation groups to the March
survey, yielding data on current (March) hourly wages for those who
worked during the survey week. Among individuals with zero weeks worked
in the previous year but who worked in the survey week, average log
wages are nearly identical to those of men who worked one to thirteen
weeks in the previous year. See Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991) for
further details.
(14.) See Juhn (1992) for a more complete description.
(15.) The published rate has been adjusted downward by 0.86
percentage point to equate the means of the monthly and the March series
over the sample.
(16.) The recession of 1980 did not fit this pattern, but as the
figure shows, it did not represent much of a peak in terms of
unemployment rates.
(17.) Parsons (1980); Bound (1989); Bound and Waidmann (1992);
Autor and Duggan (forthcoming).
(18.) Autor and Duggan (forthcoming); Bound and Waidmann (2000).
(19.) Bound and Waidmann (2000).
(20.) See Murphy and Topel (2001), for example.
(21.) Autor and Duggan (forthcoming).
(22.) The weights in these weighted averages are (1 - u)([theta])
and u([theta]), respectively, where [theta] indexes weeks over the year.
(23.) The fraction of individuals who experience zero nonemployment
(that is, who are employed for the full year) is given by F([tau]) =
[E.sub.0]([tau])exp[-12[[lambda].sup.*]([tau])], where
[[lambda].sup.*]([tau]) is the average monthly nonemployment hazard over
the year for individuals who have not yet entered nonemployment, and
[E.sub.0]([tau]) is the employment rate at the start of the year. In
general, [[lambda].sup.*.sub.n]([tau]) < [bar][lambda]([tau]), where
[bar][lambda]([tau]) is the average rate of transition to nonemployment
for the population of employed people. This will cause our estimates of
entry and exit rates to be biased downward. We attempted to assess the
magnitude and variability in this bias with similar calculations for
unemployment, where the number of spells is recorded. In that case the
bias varied little over time, lending some confidence that this method
should not be too far off.
(24.) We measure this by the average of the change going into and
out of each recessionary period. The periods are defined using the same
year groupings used in the tables: 1967-69, 1970-71, 1972-73, 1975-76,
1978-79, 1982-83, 1988-89, 1991-92, and 1999-2000.
(25.) To obtain these elasticities, we fit a quadratic function using average wage and employment data by percentile category. We report
the slope at each percentile.
(26.) Phelps (1974).
References
Abowd, John M., and Arnold Zellner. 1985. "Estimating Gross
Labor-Force Flows." Journal of Business and Economic Statistics
3(3): 254-83.
Abraham, Katharine G., and Robert Shimer. 2001. "Changes in
Unemployment Duration and Labor-Force Attachment." In The Roaring Nineties: Can Full Employment Be Sustained? edited by Alan B. Krueger and Robert M. Solow. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.
Autor, David H. 2000a. "Outsourcing at Will: Unjust Dismissal
Doctrine and the Growth of Temporary Help Employment." Working
Paper 7557. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research
(February).
--. 2000b. "Wiring the Labor Market." Working Paper 7959.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (October).
Autor, David H., and Mark G. Duggan. 2001. "The Rise in
Disability Recipiency and the Decline in Unemployment." Working
Paper 8336. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research
(June).
--. Forthcoming. "The Rise in Disability Rolls and the Decline
in Unemployment." Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Bertola, Giuseppe, and Andrea Inchino. 1995. "Wage Inequality
and Unemployment: United States vs. Europe." In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg. MIT Press.
Bertola, Giuseppe, Francine D. Blau, and Lawrence M. Kahn. 2001.
"Comparative Analysis of Labor Market Outcomes: Lessons for the US
from International Long-Run Evidence." Working Paper 8526.
Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (October).
Blanchard, Olivier, and Justin Wolfers. 2000. "The Role of
Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment: The
Aggregate Evidence." Economic Journal 110(462): C1-C33.
Bound, John. 1989. "The Health and Earnings of Rejected
Disability Insurance Applicants." American Economic Review 79(3):
482-503.
Bound, John, and Timothy Waidmann. 1992. "Disability
Transfers, Self-Reported Health, and the Labor Force Attachment of Older
Men: Evidence from the Historical Record." Quarterly Journal of
Economics 107(4): 1393-1419.
--. 2000. "Accounting for Recent Declines in Employment Rates
among the Working-Aged Disabled." Working Paper 7975. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (October).
Bound, John, Richard Burkhauser, and Austin Nichols. 2001.
"Tracking the Household Income of SSDI and SSI Applicants."
Michigan Retirement Research Center Working Paper 99-03. University of
Michigan (May).
Cutler, David M., and Elizabeth Richardson. 1997. "Measuring
the Health of the U.S. Population." BPEA, Microeconomics, 217-72.
Gordon, Robert J. 1998. "Foundations of the Goldilocks
Economy: Supply Shocks and the Time-Varying NAIRU." BPEA, 2:1998,
297-333.
Gould, Eric D., David B. Mustard, and Bruce A. Weinberg. 2002.
"Crime Rates and Local Labor Market Opportunities in the United
States: 1979-1997." Review of Economics and Statistics 84(1):
45-61.
Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M. Murphy, and Robert H. Topel. 1991.
"Why Has the Natural Rate of Unemployment Increased over
Time?" BPEA, 1:1991, 75-126.
Katz, Lawrence F., and Alan B. Krueger. 1999. "The
High-Pressure U.S. Labor Market of the 1990s." BPEA, 1:1999, 1-65.
Kling, Jeffrey R. 2002. "The Effect of Prison Sentence Length
on the Subsequent Employment and Earnings of Criminal Defendants."
Woodrow Wilson School Economics Discussion Paper 208. Princeton
University (April).
Kuhn, Peter, and Mikal Skuterud. 2000. "Job Search Methods:
Internet versus Traditional." Monthly Labor Review 123(10): 3-11.
Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas J. Sargent. 1998. "The European
Unemployment Dilemma." Journal of Political Economy 106(3): 514-50.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 2001. OECD
Employment Outlook. Paris.
Parsons, Donald O. 1980. "The Decline in Male Labor Force
Participation." Journal of Political Economy 88(1): 117-34.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1974. "Economic Policy and Unemployment in
the 1960's." Public Interest 34(Winter): 30-46.
Poterba, James M., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1986. "Reporting
Errors and Labor Market Dynamics." Econometrica 54(6): 1319-38.
Shimer, Robert. 1998. "Why Is the U.S. Unemployment Rate So
Much Lower?" In NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by Ben S.
Bernanke and Julio J. Rotemberg. MIT Press.
Staiger, Douglas, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 2001.
"Prices, Wages and the U.S. NAIRU in the 1990s." Working Paper
8320. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (June).
Stiglitz, Joseph. 1997. "Reflections on the Natural Rate
Hypothesis." Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(1): 3-10.
CHINHUI JUHN
University of Houston
KEVIN M. MURPHY
University of Chicago
ROBERT H. TOPEL
University of Chicago