Is there a bubble in the housing market?
Case, Karl E. ; Shiller, Robert J.
THE POPULAR PRESS is full of speculation that the United States, as
well as other countries, is in a "housing bubble" that is
about to burst. Barrons, Money magazine, and The Economist have all run
recent feature stories about the irrational run-up in home prices and
the potential for a crash. The Economist has published a series of
articles with titles like "Castles in Hot Air," "House of
Cards," "Bubble Trouble," and "Betting the
House." These accounts have necessarily raised concerns among the
general public. But how do we know if the housing market is in a bubble?
The term "bubble" is widely used but rarely clearly
defined. We believe that in its widespread use the term refers to a
situation in which excessive public expectations of future price
increases cause prices to be temporarily elevated. During a housing
price bubble, homebuyers think that a home that they would normally
consider too expensive for them is now an acceptable purchase because
they will be compensated by significant further price increases. They
will not need to save as much as they otherwise might, because they
expect the increased value of their home to do the saving for them.
First-time homebuyers may also worry during a housing bubble that if
they do not buy now, they will not be able to afford a home later.
Furthermore, the expectation of large price increases may have a strong
impact on demand if people think that home prices are very unlikely to
fall, and certainly not likely to fall for long, so that there is little
perceived risk associated with an investment in a home.
If expectations of rapid and steady future price increases are
important motivating factors for buyers, then home prices are inherently
unstable. Prices cannot go up rapidly forever, and when people perceive
that prices have stopped going up, this support for their acceptance of
high home prices could break down. Prices could then fall as a result of
diminished demand: the bubble bursts.
At least one aspect of a housing bubble--the rapid price
increases--has clearly been seen recently. A rapid surge in home prices
after 2000, as tabulated, for example, by the Economist Intelligence
Service, has been seen in almost all the advanced economies of the
world, with the exception of Germany and Japan. In some of these
countries, price-to-rental ratios and price-to-average income ratios are
at levels not seen since their data begin in 1975. (1)
But the mere fact of rapid price increases is not in itself
conclusive evidence of a bubble. The basic questions that still must be
answered are whether expectations of large future price increases are
sustaining the market, whether these expectations are salient enough to
generate anxieties among potential homebuyers, and whether there is
sufficient confidence in such expectations to motivate action.
In addition, changes in fundamentals may explain much of the
increase. As we will show, income growth alone explains the pattern of
recent home price increases in most states. Falling interest rates
clearly explain much of the recent run-up nationally; they can also
explain some of the cross-state variation in appreciation because of
differences in the elasticities of supply of homes, including land.
To shed light on whether the current boom is a bubble and whether
it is likely to burst or deflate, we present two pieces of new evidence.
First, we analyze U.S. state-level data on home prices and the
"fundamentals," including income, over a period of seventy-one
quarters from 1985 to 2002.
Second, we present the results of a new questionnaire survey
conducted in 2003 of people who bought homes in 2002 in four
metropolitan areas: Los Angeles, San Francisco, Boston, and Milwaukee.
The survey replicates one we did in these same metropolitan areas in
1988, during another purported housing bubble, after which prices did
indeed fall sharply in many cities. The results of the new survey thus
allow comparison of the present situation with that one. Our survey also
allows us to compare metropolitan areas that have reputedly gone through
a bubble recently (Los Angeles, San Francisco, and Boston) with one that
has not (Milwaukee).
The notion of a bubble is really defined in terms of people's
thinking: their expectations about future price increases, their
theories about the risk of falling prices, and their worries about being
priced out of the housing market in the future if they do not buy.
Economists rarely ask people what they are thinking when they make
economic decisions, and some economists have argued that one should
never do so. (2) We disagree. If questions are carefully worded and
people are surveyed at a time close to their making an actual economic
decision, then by making comparisons across time and economic
circumstances, we can learn about how the decisions are made. (3)
On the Origin of the Term "Housing Bubble"
There is very little agreement about housing bubbles. In fact, the
widespread use of the term "housing bubble" is itself quite
new. Figure 1 shows a monthly count since 1980 of stories incorporating
the words "housing bubble" in major newspapers in the English
language around the world, as tabulated using Lexis-Nexis. (The data in
years before 2003 are rescaled to account for the smaller coverage of
Lexis-Nexis in earlier years.) The term "housing bubble" had
virtually no currency until 2002, when its use suddenly increased
dramatically, even though the run-up in real estate prices in the 1980s
was as big as that since 1995. The peak in usage of "housing
bubble" occurred in October 2002. The only real evidence of its
currency before 2002 is a few uses of the term just after the stock
market crash of 1987, but that usage quickly died out.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The term "housing boom" has appeared much more frequently
since 1980. As figure 1 also shows, the use of this term was fairly
steady from 1980 through 2001, although it, too, took off in 2002, also
peaking in October. The term "boom" is much more neutral than
"bubble" and suggests that the rise in prices may be an
opportunity for investors. In contrast, the term "bubble"
connotes a negative judgment on the phenomenon, an opinion that price
levels cannot be sustained.
Perhaps journalists are shy about using the word "bubble"
except after some salient public event that legitimizes the possibility,
such as the stock market crash of 1987 or that after 2000. The question
is whether such journalistic use of the term also infects the thinking
of homebuyers: do homebuyers think that they are in a bubble?
The Previous "Housing Bubble"
The period of the 1980s and the declines in housing prices in many
cities in the early 1990s are now widely looked back upon as an example,
even a model, of a boom cycle that led to a bust. A pattern of sharp
price increases, with a peak around 1990 followed by a decline in many
important cities around the world, including Boston, Los Angeles,
London, Sydney, and Tokyo, looks consistent with a bubble.
Housing prices began rising rapidly in Boston in 1984. In 1985
alone, home prices in the Boston metropolitan area went up 39 percent.
In a 1986 paper, Case constructed repeat-sales indexes to measure the
extent of the boom in constant-quality home prices. (4) The same paper
reported that a structural supply-and-demand model, which explained home
price movements over ten years and across ten cities, failed to explain
what was going on in Boston. The model predicted that income growth,
employment growth, interest rates, construction costs, and other
fundamentals should have pushed Boston housing prices up by about 15
percent. Instead, they went up over 140 percent before topping out in
1988. The paper ended with the conjecture that the boom was at least in
part a bubble.
The following year we described price changes by constructing a set
of repeat-sales indexes from large databases of transactions in Atlanta,
Chicago, Dallas, and San Francisco. (5) We used these indexes in a
subsequent paper to provide evidence of positive serial correlation in
the changes in real home prices. (6) In fact, that paper showed that a
change in price observed over one year tends to be followed by a change
in the same direction the following year between 25 and 50 percent as
large. The paper found evidence of inertia in excess returns as well.
This strong serial correlation of price changes is certainly consistent
with our expectation of a bubble. (7)
During the 1980s, spectacular home price booms in California and
the Northeast helped stimulate the underlying economy on the way up, but
they ultimately encountered a substantial drop in demand in the late
1980s and contributed significantly to severe regional recessions in the
early 1990s. The end of the 1980s boom led to sharp price declines in
some, but not all, cities.
Since 1995, U.S. housing prices have been rising faster than
incomes and faster than other prices in virtually every metropolitan
area. Despite the fact that the economy was in recession from March to
November of 2001, and despite the loss of nearly 3 million jobs since
2000, prices of single-family homes, the volume of existing home sales,
and the number of housing starts in the United States have remained at
near-record levels. There can be no doubt that the housing market and
spending related to housing sales have kept the U.S. economy growing and
have prevented a double-dip recession since 2001.
The big question is whether there is reason to think that such a
run-up in prices will be followed by a similar or even worse decline
than the last time. To answer this question, we need to try to
understand better the causes of these large movements in the housing
market.
Home Prices and the Fundamentals, 1985-2002
A fundamental issue to consider when judging the plausibility of
bubble theories is the stability of the relationship between income and
other fundamentals and home prices over time and space. Here we look at
the relationship between home price and personal income per capita and a
number of other variables by state, using quarterly data from 1985:1 to
2002:3. The data contain 3,621 observations covering all fifty states
and the District of Columbia. (8)
Measures of Home Prices
The series of home values was constructed from repeat-sales price
indexes applied to the 2000 census median values by state. Case-Shiller
(CS) weighted repeat-sales indexes constructed by Fiserv CSW Inc. are
available for sixteen states. (9) In addition, the Office of Federal
Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO) makes state-level repeat-value
indexes produced by Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac available for all states.
The Case-Shiller indexes are the best available for our purposes,
and wherever possible we use them. Although OFHEO uses a similar index
construction methodology (the weighted repeat-sales method of Case and
Shiller), (10) their indexes are in part based on appraisals rather than
exclusively on arm's-length transactions. CS indexes use controls,
to the extent possible, for changes in property characteristics, and it
can be shown that they pick up turns in price direction earlier and more
accurately than do the OFHEO indexes. Nonetheless, for capturing broad
movements over long periods, the indexes tend to track each other quite
well, and OFHEO indexes are used in most states to achieve broader
coverage.
The panel on home prices was constructed as follows for each state:
(1) [V.sup.t.sub.i] = [V.sup.1999:1.sub.i] [I.sup.t.sub.i],
where
[V.sup.t.sub.i] = adjusted median home value in state i at time t
[V.sup.1999:1.sub.i] = median value of owner-occupied homes in
state i in 1999:1
[I.sup.t.sub.i] = weighted repeat-sales price index for state i at
time t, 1999:1 = 1.0.
The baseline figures for state-level median home prices are based
on owner estimates in the 2000 census. A number of studies have
attempted to measure the bias in such estimates. The estimates range
from -2 percent to +6 percent. (11)
Measures of the Fundamentals
Data on personal income per capita by state are available from the
Bureau of Economic Analysis website. The series is a consistent time
series produced on a timely (monthly) schedule.
Population figures by state are not easy to obtain on a quarterly
basis. The most carefully constructed series that we could find was put
together by Economy.com (formerly Regional Financial Associates).
The most stable and reliable measure of employment at the state
level is the nonfarm payroll employment series from the Bureau of Labor
Statistics (BLS) Establishment Survey, which is available monthly, and
which we have converted to quarterly data.
The unemployment rate by state is available monthly from the BLS as
part of its Household Survey.
Data on housing starts are not generally available by state before
1995. The series used here was produced by Economy.com based on the
historical relationship between permits and starts and a proprietary
data base on permits.
Data on average mortgage interest rates on thirty-year fixed rate
mortgages, assuming payment of 2 points (2 percent of the loan value)
and an 80 percent loan-to-value ratio, are available from Fannie Mae.
For each quarter the ratio of income to mortgage payment per $1,000
borrowed was calculated by dividing annual income per capita by twelve
(to convert it to monthly) and then dividing by the monthly mortgage
payment per $1,000 of loan value for a thirty-year fixed rate with 2
points.
Home Prices and Income: A First Look
Table 1 presents ratios of home price to annual income per capita
for the eight states where prices have been most volatile and the seven
states where they have been least volatile. The least volatile states
exhibit remarkable stability and very low ratios. The ratio for
Wisconsin, for example, a state that we will explore at some length
later, remains between 2.1 and 2.4 for the entire eighteen years of our
sample. A simple regression of home prices on income per capita in
Wisconsin generates an [R.sup.2] of 0.99.
On the other hand, the eight most volatile states exhibit equally
remarkable instability. Connecticut's ratio, for example, varies
between 4.5 and 7.8, and we find that income explains only 45 percent of
the variation in home prices. Table 2 shows the variation for all fifty
states and the District of Columbia. Glancing down the table reveals
that forty-three of the fifty-one observations have a standard deviation
below 0.41, whereas only those eight states listed in table 1 as most
volatile have standard deviations above 0.41. These calculations reveal
that states seem to fall into one of two categories. In the vast
majority of states, prices move very much in line with income. But in
New England, New York, New Jersey, California, and Hawaii, prices are
significantly more volatile.
Plots of the ratio of price to income per capita for the states of
California, Massachusetts, and Wisconsin (figure 2) show clearly that
the pattern of variation is anything but a random walk. In California
and Massachusetts the pattern is one of a long inertial upswing followed
by a long inertial downturn followed by another rise that has now lasted
several years. In Wisconsin the ratio is much smaller and remarkably
stable.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
We conclude that whereas income alone almost completely explains
home price increases in the vast majority of states, about eight states
are characterized by large swings in home prices that exhibit strong
inertia and cannot be well explained by income patterns.
Home Prices and Other Fundamentals
To explore the relationship between housing prices and other
fundamental variables, we performed linear and log-linear reduced-form
regressions with three dependent variables: the level of home prices,
the quarter-to-quarter change in home prices, and the price-to-income
ratio described above. The results for the linear versions of these
regressions are given in tables 1 and 3; the results for the log-linear
regressions are similar. In those states where income and home prices
are very highly correlated, the addition of mortgage rates, housing
starts, employment, and unemployment to the regression added little
explanatory power. However, for the eight states where income is a less
powerful predictor of home prices, the addition of changes in
population, changes in employment, the mortgage rate, unemployment,
housing starts, and the ratio of income to mortgage payment per $1,000
borrowed added significantly to the [R.sup.2] (table 1).
Table 3 reports the pattern of significant coefficients for three
sets of regressions on data from the eight states where price-to-income
ratios are most volatile. Since the equations are in reduced form, the
individual coefficients are plagued by simultaneity. For example,
housing starts may proxy for supply restrictions. That is, where supply
is restricted, starts may be low, pushing up prices. On the other hand,
builders clearly respond to higher prices by building more. Similarly,
the change in employment could have a positive impact on home prices as
a proxy for demand. On the other hand, rising home prices have been
shown to have a negative effect on employment growth in a state by
making it difficult to attract employees to a region with high housing
costs. (12) In the equations in which the change in price is the
dependent variable (top panel of the table), the number of housing
starts has a positive and significant coefficient in seven of the eight
states. However, in equations in which the price level is the dependent
variable (middle panel), which are estimated over a shorter time horizon
(1985:2 through 1999:4), housing starts has a significant but negative
coefficient in five of the eight states. Income has a significant and
positive coefficient in twenty of the twenty-four equations presented.
The change in employment had a significant and negative effect in
fourteen of the twenty-four equations. Unemployment has a significant
and negative coefficient in the price level equations in five of the
eight states.
Of interest is the fact that the mortgage rate has an insignificant
coefficient in all but one of the regressions presented. This again
could be the result of simultaneity: low rates stimulate the housing
market, but low rates may be caused by Federal Reserve easing in
response to a weak economy and housing market.
Including the ratio of income to mortgage payment in the regression
allows us to take account of the wide swings in interest rates over this
period. During 2000-02, the combination of low interest rates and high
incomes made housing more affordable. Although this variable had a
positive and significant sign in the equations run on all quarters in
twenty-one states, it was significant and positive only in New York
among the eight states with a high variance of income to home price.
To look more closely at the strength of the housing sector since
the stock market crash of 2000-01 and the recession of 2001, we used the
results from the price level equation estimated with 1985:2-1999:4 data,
described above, to forecast the level of home prices for the period
from 2000:1 through 2002:3. We did the same exercise with two sets of
regressions described in the bottom two panels of table 3.
The results from the middle panel of table 3 are presented in
figure 3. In all of the eight states except Hawaii, the fundamentals
significantly underforecast the actual behavior of home prices since
1999. Diagrams constructed from the results of the bottom panel of table
3 look exactly the same.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
To conclude this section, we find that income alone explains
patterns of home price changes since 1985 in all but eight states. In
these states the addition of other fundamental variables adds
explanatory power, but the pattern of smoothly rising and falling
price-to-income ratios and the consistent pattern of underforecasting of
home prices during 2000-02 mean that we cannot reject the hypothesis
that a bubble exists in these states. For further evidence we turn to
our survey.
The 1988 Survey
In our 1988 paper we presented the results of a survey of a sample
of 2,000 households who bought homes in May 1988 in four markets: Orange
County, California (suburban Los Angeles); Alameda County, California (suburban San Francisco); Middlesex County, Massachusetts (suburban
Boston); and Milwaukee County, Wisconsin. (13) The four locations were
chosen to represent hot (California), cooling (Boston), and steady
(Milwaukee) markets. The survey was inspired in part by an article on
page 1 of the June 1, 1988, Wall Street Journal, which described the
current "frenzy in California's big single family home
market" and included colorful stories of angst and activity in the
housing market there. (14) We wanted to find out what was going on in
California and compare it with other places in a systematic way.
The results of that survey provide strong evidence for some
parameters of a theory that a housing bubble did exist in 1988: that
buyers were influenced by an investment motive, that they had strong
expectations about future price changes in their housing markets, and
that they perceived little risk. Responses to a number of questions
revealed that emotion and casual word of mouth played a significant role
in home purchase decisions. In addition, there was no agreement among
buyers about the causes of recent home price movements and no cogent analysis of the fundamentals.
One additional finding in our 1988 paper lends support to an
important stylized fact about the U.S. housing market that has not been
well documented in the literature, namely, that home prices are sticky downward. That is, when excess supply occurs, prices do not immediately
fall to clear the market. Rather, sellers have reservation prices below
which they tend not to sell. This tendency not to accept price declines
is connected with a belief that prices never do decline, and with some
of the parameters of thinking that underlie a housing bubble.
Homebuyer Behavior in Four Metropolitan Areas, 1988 and 2003
Before we present the results of a virtually identical survey done
in 2003, we describe home price behavior in the four survey areas.
Although the timing was not identical, Los Angeles, San Francisco, and
Boston have experienced two boom cycles and a bust in housing prices
over the last twenty years. Table 4 describes the timing and the extent
of these cycles, which are also shown in nominal terms in figure 4.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
The first boom in California was similar in Los Angeles and San
Francisco. Prices in both metropolitan areas peaked in the second
quarter of 1990 after a 125 percent nominal (55 percent real) run-up,
which began slowly, gradually accelerated into 1988, and then slowed as
it approached the peak. The first boom in Boston was also similar, but
it accelerated earlier and actually peaked in the third quarter of 1988
after a 143 percent nominal (more than 100 percent real) increase.
The bust that followed was most severe and longest lived in Los
Angeles, where prices dropped 29 percent in nominal terms (40 percent in
real terms) from the peak to a trough in the first quarter of 1996.
Prices in San Francisco dropped only 14 percent (20 percent real) from
the 1990 peak and began rising again in the first quarter of 1993, three
years earlier than in Los Angeles. Boston was on the mend two years
earlier than that.
All three metropolitan areas have seen a prolonged boom ever since,
although San Francisco has shown some volatility since mid-2002. Home
prices during this boom rose 129 percent in nominal terms in San
Francisco, 94 percent in Los Angeles, and 126 percent in Boston, despite
very low overall inflation. At the time participants in the second
survey sample were buying their homes, prices were still rising in all
four metropolitan areas.
The price index for Milwaukee could not be more different. It shows
a very steady climb at a rate of 5.6 percent annually, essentially the
same rate of growth as income per capita. Interestingly, over the entire
cycle, Milwaukee did about as well as Los Angeles, but not as well as
Boston or San Francisco. Home prices in Boston increased more than
fivefold in nominal terms over the cycle, while prices in San Francisco
quadrupled and prices in both Milwaukee and Los Angeles tripled.
Three of the four metropolitan areas--Los Angeles, San Francisco,
and Boston--show pronounced cycles. These three might be called glamour
cities, in that they are the home of either international celebrities,
or the entertainment industry, or world-class universities, or
high-technology industries, and the prices of homes in these
metropolitan areas are high as well as volatile. (15)
Table 5 looks at the latest boom cycle in a bit more detail. Using
the state data described in the earlier section, the table makes two
points. First, in all three states, home price increases outpaced income
growth. (Note that the price increases are not as great as in the
metropolitan area data because the indexes are for the entire state.)
All three states had increases in their ratios of home price to annual
income, but the changes were dramatically larger in the boom-and-bust
states.
After peaking at nearly 10 percent in early 1995, the thirty-year
fixed rate dropped below 7 percent by mid-1999. During 2000 rates spiked
back to 8.5 percent but then fell steadily from mid-2000 until 2003,
when they briefly went below 5 percent.
Table 5 also shows the effect of declining mortgage rates on the
cash costs of buying a home. In 1995, at the beginning of the current
run-up, the thirty-year fixed rate was 8.8 percent. It had fallen to 6
percent at the time the sample was drawn, keeping the monthly payment
required to buy the median home from rising faster than income. The
ratio of annual payment to income per capita actually fell in California
and Wisconsin and stayed constant in Massachusetts. This fact adds
weight to the argument that fundamental factors have an important effect
on current home prices.
Survey Method
A random sample of 500 home sales was drawn from each of the same
four counties as in our 1988 survey, and so we can make comparisons with
these earlier results. We also used the very same questionnaire as in
our 1988 survey, adding only several new questions at the end so that
there was no change in the context of any questions. The accompanying
letters were essentially similar to those of 1988.
Survey methods followed guidelines outlined elsewhere. (16)
Ordinary mail was used because we judged that the use of e-mail was
still not widespread enough to produce a representative sample. The
questionnaire was ten pages long and included questions on a number of
topics. The focus was on the homebuyers' expectations,
understandings of the market situation, and behavior. The questionnaire
encouraged respondents to "write comments anywhere on the
questionnaire," and their comments were indeed helpful to us in
interpreting the significance of the answers.
During the first survey, in 1988, two of the four markets were
booming (the California counties), one market was at its peak and
showing excess supply (Boston), and one was drifting (Milwaukee). This
time three of the four markets were in remarkable booms, and Milwaukee
again served as a control city, where no real boom was taking place.
The survey was sent to 2,000 persons who had bought homes between
March and August 2002. These dates fall just before the peak in media
usage of the term "housing bubble" in October 2002.
Questionnaires with personalized letters to the respondents were mailed
in January 2003, a reminder postcard was sent in February, and
replacement questionnaires with personalized letters were again sent to
those who had not responded in March. These dates were just after the
peak in media use of the term "housing bubble." Thus we
managed to get our questionnaire survey out at a time when attention to
the possibility of a housing bubble must have been close to its maximum.
Our respondents had the opportunity to participate in the real estate
market at a time of intense public attention to the possibility of a
bubble and had the opportunity to read and think about this experience
for some months afterward. This is what we wanted to do, since our
purpose is to gauge human behavior during a purported bubble.
Just under 700 questionnaires were returned completed and usable in
the 2003 survey, for a somewhat lower response rate than in the 1988
survey. Response rates for each county are given in table 6.
At the time of the 2003 survey, the economy was recovering from the
recession that had ended in November 2001, but the recovery was slow,
and the National Bureau of Economic Research had not yet announced that
the recession was over. In contrast, at the time of our 1988 survey,
there had been no recession for several years. In addition, the Federal
Reserve had reduced interest rates to historic lows at the time the
buyers in our 2003 survey were signing purchase and sale agreements. In
1988, in contrast, interest rates were on the rise.
Table 7 describes the sample. A substantial majority of buyers were
buying as a primary residence, and only a small minority were buying to
rent. First-time buyers were a majority of the sample in Milwaukee. The
lowest percentage of first-time buyers was in Los Angeles. We were
surprised to see that, in the 2003 survey, more than 90 percent of the
homes purchased in all four markets were single-family homes, a much
larger share than in the 1988 survey. We have no explanation as yet for
this.
Survey Results
The results of the 2003 survey, presented in tables 8 through 14,
shed light on a number of aspects of homebuying behavior--including
investment motivations and the expectation of further price rises, the
amount of local excitement and discussion about real estate, the sense
of urgency in buying a home, adherence to simplistic theories about
housing markets, the occurrence of sales above asking prices, and
perceptions of risk--that suggest the presence or absence of a bubble in
home prices.
Housing as an Investment
A tendency to view housing as an investment is a defining
characteristic of a housing bubble. Expectations of future appreciation
of the home are a motive for buying that deflects consideration from how
much one is paying for housing services. That is what a bubble is all
about: buying for the future price increases rather than simply for the
pleasure of occupying the home. And it is this motive that is thought to
lend instability to bubbles, a tendency to crash when the investment
motive weakens.
Table 8 presents the responses to questions about housing as an
investment. For the vast majority of buyers, either investment was
"a major consideration" or they at least "in part"
thought of their purchase as an investment. In Milwaukee and San
Francisco investment was a major consideration for a majority of buyers.
This tendency to view housing as an investment is similar to what it was
in the boom period that we observed in our 1988 survey, although
somewhat weaker. Far fewer of the homebuyers in 2003 said that they were
buying "strictly for investment purposes." Thus conditions
reported in 2003 would appear to be consistent with a bubble story,
although less so than they were in 1988.
The apparent attractiveness of housing as an investment is further
enhanced if the buyer perceives that the investment entails only very
little risk. As table 8 also shows, in all cities in both 1988 and 2003,
only a small percentage of buyers thought that housing involved a great
deal of risk, although the fraction seeing a great deal of risk rose
(perhaps not surprisingly) to a fairly high level (14.8 percent) in San
Francisco in 2003. In three of the four cities (Milwaukee being the
exception), there was more perception of risk in 2003 than there had
been in 1988, which is what one would expect given all the media
attention to bubbles in 2003. Even so, the perception of risk of price
decline is small: one may say that homebuyers did not perceive
themselves to be in a bubble.
Exaggerated Expectations, Excitement, and Word of Mouth
Table 9 gets to the meat of the housing bubble issue: the role of
price expectations, the emotional charge, and the extent of talk about
real estate. Expectations about the future price performance of homes
were high in both 1988 and 2003. In both of these housing booms, roughly
90 percent or more of respondents expected an increase in home prices
over the next several years, and the average expected increase over the
next twelve months was very high, even surpassing 9.8 percent in San
Francisco in 2003. (17)
But it is the long-term (ten-year) expectations that are most
striking. When asked what they thought would be the average rate of
increase per year over the next ten years, respondents in Los Angeles
gave an average reply of 13.1 percent (versus 14.3 percent in 1988); in
San Francisco they were even more optimistic, at 15.7 percent (14.8
percent in 1988); in Boston the answer was 14.6 percent (8.7 percent in
1988); and in Milwaukee it was 11.7 percent (7.3 percent in 1988). Note
that even a rate of increase of only 11.7 percent a year means a
tripling of value in ten years. Thus, although the one-year expectations
in the glamour cities were lower in 2003 than they had been in 1988, the
ten-year expectations were even higher. (18)
Fewer respondents in 2003 said that it was a good time to buy a
home because prices may be rising in the future, but at least two-thirds
agreed with the statement in all four cities. Many thought not only that
now was a good time to buy, but also that there was a risk that delay
might mean not being able to afford a home later.
The number who admitted to being influenced by
"excitement" about home prices was still high, close to 50
percent in Los Angeles, but lower than in 1988. The amount of talk was
nearly as high as in 1988, and talk is an important indicator of a
bubble, since word-of-mouth transmission of the excitement is a
hallmark.
We conclude that these general indicators of the defining
characteristics of bubbles were fairly strong in 2003. However, they
were generally less strong than in 1988 in the glamour cities and
stronger than in 1988 in Milwaukee.
Simple (or Simplistic) Theories
Table 10 shows results on respondents' agreement with a number
of simple, popular theories or stories about speculative price movements
that might influence how their interpretation of recent events
translated into bubble expectations. Our survey results indicate that
these simplistic theories are quite a powerful force and, moreover, a
bit different in the glamour or bubble cities of Los Angeles, San
Francisco, and Boston than in cities generally thought less exciting,
like Milwaukee.
The most simplistic theory is one that we have often heard
expressed in casual conversation: that desirable real estate just
naturally appreciates rapidly. The theory expressed seems to confuse the
level of prices with the rate of change. The most elementary economic
theory would say that properties that people find most attractive will
be highly priced, but not necessarily increasing more rapidly in price
than other properties. We tried to gauge agreement with this theory by
asking whether people agreed with the statement "Housing prices
have boomed in [city] because lots of people want to live here."
There was overwhelming agreement with this statement in all the glamour
cities, but not in Milwaukee.
An even more outrageous fallacy that we detect in popular
conversation about home prices is that "When there is simply not
enough housing available, price becomes unimportant." To our
respondents' credit, most did not agree with this statement. But
from 20 to 40 percent did agree, particularly in the glamour cities.
Another fallacy we think we have detected is in the interpretation
of prices closing above asking prices. Homeowners sometimes seem to
think that this phenomenon is a sign of a crazy boom that suspends the
economic laws of supply and demand. Indeed, most homebuyers in the
glamour cities thought that at such a time "there is panic buying
and price becomes irrelevant."
These results do not firmly prove that people are guilty of
economic fallacies, because the questions admit of alternative
interpretations, and people were probably not focusing clearly on their
exact wording. However, we do believe that the strong agreement with
some of these statements is at least suggestive of such fallacies. We
believe that there is a sort of knee-jerk reaction to stories about boom
markets in real estate that does not accord with economic theory, but
that does affect the prices people are willing to pay for their homes.
We leave clearer proof that people adhere to such fallacies to further
work. A closer study of such popular fallacies is difficult to carry
out, for if we draw out the fallacy clearly enough to reveal their
belief in it to our satisfaction, respondents may be educated out of the
fallacy by the very questioning intended to reveal it.
All these theories about panic buying and the irrelevance of price
do not, however, indicate that people generally believe that markets are
driven by psychology. The results of the last question in table 10 show
that people generally do not believe that markets are driven primarily
by psychology, even in a booming real estate market. We interpret this
as further confirming our general conclusion that most homeowners do not
perceive themselves to be in a bubble even at the height of a bubble.
Popular Themes in Interpreting Recent Price Movements
We have documented that people talked a lot about the housing
market both in 1988 and in 2003. What is it that they are likely to have
talked about? We need to know the news stories that are on their mind if
we are to understand the origins of the purported housing bubble.
Table 11 shows some results from two open-ended questions that were
put on the questionnaire, along with a space for the respondent to write
in answers in his or her own words. Responses to these questions are
especially interesting because they elicit themes that are already on
the minds of respondents, rather than putting words in their mouths.
One would perhaps not expect any one theme to dominate in answers
to such questions, since people are so different and such broad
questions allow so many different interpretations. But we do see what
appears to be a dominating theme both in 1988 and in 2003, namely,
interest rates. Clearly, interest rates have fallen substantially and
have contributed to the run-up in prices since 1995, at least in the
cities where, in our regressions, the interest rate variable was
significant. Although, according to basic economic theory, interest
rates should be more important in regions where the elasticity of supply of housing is relatively low or the likely growth of future demand
relatively high, there is little evidence of this effect in
state-by-state regressions.
Many of the answers to these questions are disappointing. Typically
the answers read like random draws from the business section of the
newspaper, or else the respondents refer to casual observations that one
might make just driving around town. Respondents presented no
quantitative evidence and made no reference to professional forecasts.
One should not be surprised at this, however. After all, the
single-family home market is a market of amateurs, generally with no
economic training.
Once more we see evidence that in neither period did many
homebuyers perceive themselves to be in a housing bubble. References to
market psychology were quite rare.
Relation of Investment Demand in 2003 to the Stock Market Boom and
Bust
The appearance of the real estate bubble right after the stock
market drop has lent support to the notion that the two are somehow
connected. One popular theory is that the stock market drop was followed
by investor disgust with the stock market and a "flight to
quality," as people sought safer investments in real assets like
homes. There has been a lot of discussion about people shifting their
assets toward housing because the stock market has performed so poorly
since 2000. On the other hand, a falling stock market could have a
negative wealth effect on home buying decisions. (19)
Table 12 presents the responses to three questions that we did not
ask in 1988 but were added at the end of the questionnaire in 2003.
Recall that the survey was virtually finished before the stock market
rally (25 percent on the S&P500) of March 11-July 8, 2003, and that
the respondents had purchased their homes several months before.
The answers to the last question in table 12, about whether the
experience with the stock market encouraged purchase of a home, show
that for the vast majority of people in all four counties the
performance of the stock market "had no effect on my decision to
buy my house." However, one should not discard the notion that the
stock market's behavior was at least partly responsible for the
boom in the real estate market. Judging from their additional comments,
it appears that some of the majority who said the stock market had no
effect on the decision to buy a home said so only because they would
have bought some home in any event, even if perhaps a smaller home. More
significantly, many other respondents (roughly between a quarter and a
third) said that the stock market's performance
"encouraged" them to buy a home, whereas only a small
percentage found it discouraging.
Immediately after this question we included an open-ended question,
"Please explain your thinking here," followed by an open
space. Although most left this space blank, the answers we did get were
all over the map, as respondents apparently viewed the question as an
opportunity to vent on any subject.
Some of the answers from those who said they were encouraged by the
stock market did refer to the drop in the stock market after 2000 as a
reason to buy a home now. Quoting a few of their answers verbatim will
illustrate: "Housing costs continue to increase. Value of home
investment to increase. Stock market not so promising." "Could
be better investment than stock market." "I lost $400,000 in
my pension and personal stock portfolio--at least buying this big
beautiful home I know it's a hard asset that would hold its value
& appreciate while it gives me great enjoyment." "Money
that we had saved for a house was starting to become a loss in the
market." "I have only made money in real estate and lost a lot
in the stock market." "The stock market at my age is not
helping me. Short-term real estate is the strongest investment you can
make short or long term." "Stock market went down. House
market is still going up." "Renting is not cheap, stock is
declining, this implies our total assets is [sic] not going
anywhere." "The value of my condo had increased significantly
compared to the gains to my portfolio. With interest rates low a new
home seemed more likely to increase than a comparable investment in the
stock market and brings tax & quality of life benefits."
Some respondents referred to the increased volatility or other
uncertainty in the stock market since 2000, rather than its changed
level, as a reason to shift their portfolio: "It seemed that
shifting some of our net worth to cash and homeownership was a wise move
in the face of the market volatility in 2000-2002." "I'm
buying the house for the long term. The house will probably depreciate in the next couple years, but it will certainly appreciate over 10+
years. This is because it is a good house in a good community. This is
information that I am confident of. In contrast, there is no confidence
that I have full (or even good) information about the stock market (or
that even my mutual fund managers have good information about the
companies they invest in). So, I buy the house." "A house
seems like a more solid investment than stocks. Less volatile."
Although this evidence is far from proof of a connection between
the stock market and the housing market, we interpret it as confirming
the notion that people got fed up with the stock market after the
decline and high volatility following the 2000 peak and became more
positive about real estate.
Excess Demand and Upward Rigidity in Asking Prices
In the boom cities, newspaper articles feature stories of homes
that sold well above the asking price. We have already noted that it was
an article in the Wall Street Journal referring to "frenzy in
California's big single family home market" that inspired our
original survey. In fact, such frenzy seems to be a fairly common
occurrence in boom cities. As table 13 shows, quite a large number of
people reported selling above the asking price in both the 1988 and 2003
surveys. An amazing 45 percent of respondents in San Francisco in the
2003 survey reported selling at above the asking price in 2002, well
after the sharp decline in employment following the NASDAQ collapse,
which began in 2000. Sellers in Los Angeles reported that about 20
percent of properties sold for more than the asking price, as did a
slightly smaller share in Milwaukee, which had no boom.
Many of those who sold felt that if they had charged 5 or 10
percent more, the property would have sold just as quickly. This was the
sense of over 20 percent of sellers in all markets in 2003, a
substantially larger fraction than in 1998 except in Los Angeles, where
it stayed the same. An amazing number of the 2003 respondents--in fact,
a majority in San Francisco and Boston, a near majority in Milwaukee,
and 26 percent in Los Angeles--thought that charging more than they did
would be unfair. On the other hand, the number who reported that their
home was not intrinsically worth more than they were asking dropped in
the latest survey compared with that in 1988.
Downward Rigidity and Excess Supply
An important question on which the survey sheds some light is, What
happens in a bust? How do sellers respond to rising inventories and
increasing time on the market? It is important first to point out that
the housing market is not an auction market. Prices do not fall to clear
the market quickly, as one observes in most asset markets. Selling a
home requires agreement between buyer and seller. It is a stylized fact
about the housing market that bid-ask spreads widen when demand drops,
and the number of transactions falls sharply. This must mean that
sellers resist cutting prices.
Table 14 supports the notion that sellers lower their asking prices
only as a last resort. A majority of respondents in all cities and in
both years of the survey argue that the best strategy in a slow market
is to "hold up until you get what you want." Only a small
minority reported that they would have "lowered the price until I
found a buyer." In addition, large majorities ranging from 79
percent in San Francisco in 1988 to 93 percent in post-boom Boston
reported having reservation prices.
There is clear evidence that such resistance prevents home prices
from falling at the onset of a down period and that, if the underlying
fundamentals come back quickly enough, they can prevent a bubble from
bursting. Instead, the danger when demand drops in housing markets is
that the volume of sales may drop precipitously. This could do more
damage to the U.S. economy today than a modest decline in prices.
A Model of Speculative Bubbles in Housing
Buyers and sellers in the housing market are overwhelmingly
amateurs, who have little experience with trading. High transactions
costs, moral hazard problems, and government subsidization of
owner-occupied homes have kept professional speculators out of the
market. These amateurs are highly involved with the market at the time
of home purchase and may overreact at times to price changes and to
simple stories, resulting in substantial momentum in housing prices.
Shiller argues that speculative bubbles are caused by
"precipitating factors" that change public opinion about
markets or that have an immediate impact on demand, and by
"amplification mechanisms" that take the form of
price-to-price feedback. (20) A number of fundamental factors can
influence price movements in housing markets. On the demand side,
demographics, income growth, employment growth, changes in financing
mechanisms or interest rates, as well as changes in locational
characteristics such as accessibility, schools, or crime, to name a few,
have been shown to have effects. On the supply side, attention has been
paid to construction costs, the age of the housing stock, and the
industrial organization of the housing market. The elasticity of supply
has been shown to be a key factor in the cyclical behavior of home
prices.
The cyclical process that we observed in the 1980s in those cities
experiencing boom-and-bust cycles was that general economic expansion,
best proxied by employment gains, drove demand up. In the short run
those increases in demand encountered an inelastic supply of housing and
developable land, inventories of for-sale properties shrank, and vacancy declined. As a consequence, prices accelerated. This provided the
amplification mechanism as it led buyers to anticipate further gains,
and the bubble was born. Once prices overshoot or supply catches up,
inventories begin to rise, time on the market increases, vacancy rises,
and price increases slow, eventually encountering downward stickiness.
With housing, a significant precipitating factor may be employment
gains, if only because they are highly visible. Employment releases
occur on the first Friday of each month, with state data released
somewhat later. Both national and state releases by the BLS receive
dramatic fanfare in the press. In all three of the cities with volatile
prices, substantial employment gains and falling unemployment preceded
the upward acceleration of home prices during both booms.
The predominant story about home prices is always the prices
themselves; the feedback from initial price increases to further price
increases is a mechanism that amplifies the effects of the precipitating
factors. If prices are going up rapidly, there is much word-of-mouth
communication, a hallmark of a bubble. The word of mouth can spread
optimistic stories and thus help cause an overreaction to other stories,
such as stories about employment. The amplification can also work on the
downside as well. Price decreases will generate publicity for negative
stories about the city, but downward stickiness is encountered
initially.
The amplification mechanism appears to be stronger in the glamour
cities that were undergoing rapid price change at the time of our
surveys than in our control city of Milwaukee. We saw in our survey
results that talk about real estate is more frequent in those cities and
that excitement is stronger there. Presumably this greater talk and
excitement have something to do with the greater price volatility seen
historically in the glamour cities, leading to greater public interest
and concern with movements in real estate prices. Thus real estate price
volatility can be self-perpetuating: once started, it generates more
public attention and interest, and thus more volatility in the future.
Longer-run forces that come into play tend eventually to reverse
the impact of any initial price increases and the public overreaction to
them. New construction can bring some new housing online in the space of
about a year. The United States now has a highly sophisticated national
construction industry, dominated by national firms such as Pulte Homes,
Lennar Corporation, and Centex Corporation. These firms are capable of
moving their operations into a city quickly if they perceive the ability
to build homes for less than the going price. However, there are
important barriers to their moving into certain cities, as executives
from these firms will animatedly tell you. In many mature cities there
is no place to build, and obtaining permits can be long and costly. Case
has argued that differences in supply elasticity across cities explained
a larger percentage of price changes than do demographics. (21) Clearly,
prices of homes can go up more rapidly than building costs only if
supply is inelastic at least in the short run.
Zoning restrictions are an important barrier to the construction of
new homes. These restrictions prevent more intensive use of available
land, for example by building more closely spaced houses or taller
high-rise apartment buildings. Edward Glaeser and Joseph Gyourko have
shown a close correlation across U.S. cities between a measure of zoning
strictness derived from the Wharton Land Use Control Survey and the
ratio of existing housing prices to the cost of new construction. (22)
They found that there is relatively little correlation between
population density and home prices, even though economic theory might
seem to suggest such a correlation. Thus zoning has been fundamental in
limiting the supply of housing.
Even if shortages of places to build are long lasting, in the
longer run positive impulses to employment can, if there are barriers to
the supply response, lead to outflow of industries that have little
reason to stay in the city, thereby eventually reversing the high demand
for homes. At the height of a boom, both labor supply and labor demand
can be negative factors, with high home prices deterring workers from
coming to an area and a labor shortage deterring industry from locating
there. Moreover, retirees and families with children (who have higher
housing demand) will tend eventually to leave high-price cities. Thus
cities that have attracted certain industries and have seen a surge in
employment eventually become more specialized: Silicon Valley, for
example, has become almost exclusively a mecca for people who need to
benefit from the synergies of the electronics industry.
This process can eventually reverse the price increases. This
process of reversal, however, is hardly on the minds of most homebuyers,
who, as we have seen, are preoccupied with relatively simplistic stories
about housing when they consider their investments. The relatively poor
performance of their city after the boom comes as a surprise to them.
Over long intervals in most states, the growth rate of home prices
has tended to track growth in nominal income per capita. It is not
surprising that this should be so, for two reasons. First, land zoned
for new construction in scarce or important locations is fixed, and if
people target a fraction of their income for the costs of a home, given
fixed supply the price of that fixed land should increase with income.
Second, construction costs, which are mostly labor costs, tend to track
income per capita as well. Thus, over the period from 1980 to 2000,
price growth in Los Angeles and price growth in Milwaukee have been
about the same. But there is a big difference in the shorter-run
behavior of prices in those two cities.
The upward trend in home prices that is implied by the growth rate
of income per capita, along with the tendency for home price decreases
to be slow and sluggish, has meant that relatively few citywide home
price declines have been observed in history. More often one sees
periods of flat real estate prices, where the ratio of price to income,
or the ratio of price to the consumer price index, is falling but
nominal prices themselves have not fallen. Outright price declines are
much more salient in investor psychology than failures of prices to keep
up with income. Thus popular culture has not identified bubbles as a
problem in real estate, or did not until last year.
The popular impression has been that real estate is an investment
that cannot lose money. The declines in prices in the early 1990s in
many cities, documented for the first time in history by accurate real
estate price indexes developed by us and others, have forever reduced
the salience of this public impression, but, as our latest survey
documents, the idea still lingers. There is also a popular impression
that real estate is a candidate for the "best investment" that
can be made (see top panel of table 12). Whether real estate is in fact
the best possible investment is not something amenable to economic
analysis, since one cannot measure the "dividend" in the form
of housing services that homes offer. Presumably there is diminishing marginal utility to owning a bigger and bigger house, and so the psychic dividend declines with the amount of house purchased. The basic question
that individuals must resolve is how big a house to buy, and the theory
that "housing is always the best investment" is a poor clue to
how to answer this question. Yet that theory has a salience that is
quite strong in the current market.
Is a Housing Bubble about to Burst?
Clearly, one can construct an argument that home price increases
nationally since 1995 have been driven by fundamentals. For more than
forty states, income growth alone explains virtually the entire increase
in housing prices, and falling interest rates have reduced financing
costs sufficiently to keep the ratio of annual mortgage payments to
income from rising even in the boom states of Massachusetts and
California. In the vast majority of states, housing is actually more
affordable than it was in 1995.
Nonetheless, our analysis indicates that elements of a speculative
bubble in single-family home prices--the strong investment motive, the
high expectations of future price increases, and the strong influence of
word-of-mouth discussion--exist in some cities. For the three glamour
cities we studied, the indicators of bubble sentiment that we documented
in tables 8 and 9 remain, in general, nearly as strong in 2003 as they
were in 1988. Some of these are surprisingly high in 2003, notably the
ten-year expectations for future price change, where the average
expected annual price increase is in the 13 to 15 percent range for all
these cities. Even our fourth city, Milwaukee, is perhaps showing some
bubble sentiment, for the expected annual price increase for the next
ten years there is 11.7 percent.
All of the fundamental measures of bubble activity--the
expectations, the sense of opportunity and urgency, the excitement and
amount of talk--are generally down from their levels in 1988 in the
glamour cities, but up from their levels of 1988 in Milwaukee. (Long-run
expectations, however, are generally up substantially from 1988. If
long-run expectations matter most, one might say that the 2003
exuberance is just as strong as the 1988 one.) Most people do not
perceive themselves in 2003 as in the midst of a bubble, despite all the
media attention to the possibility. However, neither did people perceive
themselves to be in a bubble in 1988, after which real prices fell
sharply in many cities.
Although these indicators do not suggest such strong evidence of a
bubble as was observed in 1988, it is reasonable to suppose that, in the
near future, price increases will stall and that prices will even
decline in some cities. We have seen that people are not as confident of
real estate prices as they were even before the 1980s real estate bubble
burst, and this lack of confidence may translate into an amplification
of any price declines. Real home prices are already flat in Denver and
Detroit, following periods of rapid growth. More declines in real home
prices will probably come in cities that have been frothy, notably
including some cities on both coasts of the United States, and
especially those that have weakening economies. But declines in real
estate prices might appear even in cities whose employment holds steady.
The consequences of such a fall in home prices would be severe for
some homeowners. Given the high average level of personal debt relative
to personal income, an increase in bankruptcies is likely. Such an
increase could potentially worsen consumer confidence, creating a
renewed interest in replenishing savings.
Personal consumption expenditure, which has driven the economy so
far in the current recovery, may drop, stalling the recovery. However,
judging from the historical record, a nationwide drop in real housing
prices is unlikely, and the drops in different cities are not likely to
be synchronous: some will probably not occur for a number of years. Such
a lack of synchrony would blunt the impact on the aggregate economy of
the bursting of housing bubbles.
Table 1. Ratio of Average Home Price to Personal Income
per Capita and Results of Regressions Explaining Home
Prices, Selected States, 1985-2002
Ratio
Standard In
State Trough Peak deviation 2002:3
States with most volatile home prices
Hawaii 7.8 12.5 1.34 10.1
Connecticut 4.5 7.8 1.06 5.4
New Hampshire 4.0 6.6 0.84 5.3
California 6.0 8.6 0.80 8.3
Rhode Island 4.6 7.1 0.75 6.1
Massachusetts 4.3 6.6 0.72 5.9
New Jersey 4.5 6.8 0.68 5.6
New York 3.8 5.6 0.52 4.9
States with least volatile home prices
Nebraska 1.8 2.1 0.09 1.9
Wisconsin 2.1 2.4 0.08 2.4
Illinois 2.6 2.9 0.08 2.9
Kentucky 2.1 2.4 0.08 2.2
Indiana 2.0 2.3 0.06 2.1
Iowa 1.7 1.9 0.06 1.8
Ohio 2.3 2.5 0.04 2.5
[R.sup.2] of
regression
of home price
on (a)
Income Other
Quarter per fundamental
State of peak capita variables (b)
States with most volatile home prices
Hawaii 1992:3 0.83 0.89
Connecticut 1988:1 0.45 0.69
New Hampshire 1987:2 0.49 0.78
California 1989:4 0.78 0.89
Rhode Island 1988:1 0.65 0.79
Massachusetts 1987:3 0.70 0.88
New Jersey 1987:3 0.73 0.90
New York 1987:3 0.77 0.86
States with least volatile home prices
Nebraska 1985:2 0.96 0.99
Wisconsin 2002:3 0.99 0.99
Illinois 2002:3 0.98 0.99
Kentucky 1985:1 0.99 0.99
Indiana 1986:4 0.99 0.99
Iowa 2002:3 0.98 0.99
Ohio 2002:3 0.99 0.99
Sources: Fiserv CSW Inc., OFHEO, and Bureau
of Economic Analysis data.
(a.) Observations are for the seventy-one
quarters from 1985:1 through 2002:3.
(b.) Regressions use as additional explanatory
variables the following fundamental variables:
population, nonfarm payroll employment, the
unemployment rate, housing starts, and mortgage
interest rates.
Table 2. Ratio of Home Price to Personal Income
per Capita, All States, 1985-2002 (a)
Standard
State Median Trough Peak deviation Mean
Hawaii 9.79 7.83 12.50 1.34 10.03
Connecticut 5.41 4.47 7.84 1.06 5.67
New Hampshire 4.68 3.98 6.63 0.84 4.94
California 6.76 5.96 8.57 0.80 7.07
Rhode Island 5.49 4.58 7.12 0.75 5.62
Massachusetts 4.97 4.34 6.60 0.72 5.20
New Jersey 5.25 4.48 6.77 0.68 5.34
New York 4.54 3.83 5.60 0.52 4.55
Texas 2.48 2.20 3.59 0.41 2.61
Maine 3.98 3.44 4.77 0.40 3.98
District of Columbia 3.61 3.10 4.52 0.37 3.66
Vermont 4.11 3.64 4.85 0.37 4.19
Louisiana 2.56 2.42 3.53 0.33 2.70
Alaska 3.26 2.48 4.07 0.33 3.29
Oregon 2.25 1.49 2.69 0.32 2.23
Utah 2.87 2.29 3.21 0.31 2.81
Mississippi 2.28 2.21 3.15 0.29 2.43
Maryland 4.01 3.62 4.69 0.29 4.05
Oklahoma 2.13 2.05 3.04 0.28 2.25
Washington 3.12 2.28 3.36 0.26 3.00
Delaware 3.62 3.33 4.14 0.26 3.69
Colorado 2.60 2.19 3.18 0.25 2.57
Virginia 3.47 3.04 3.87 0.24 3.44
Georgia 2.76 2.58 3.25 0.23 2.83
Arizona 3.53 3.38 4.17 0.22 3.63
North Dakota 2.24 2.05 2.98 0.22 2.32
Arkansas 2.22 2.13 2.84 0.22 2.33
Montana 2.55 2.02 2.71 0.22 2.44
Florida 3.04 2.80 3.51 0.21 3.08
Missouri 2.32 1.18 2.71 0.21 2.38
Pennsylvania 2.70 2.43 3.14 0.21 2.73
Wyoming 2.12 1.82 2.65 0.21 2.15
New Mexico 3.38 3.12 3.85 0.20 3.40
Tennessee 2.35 2.23 2.80 0.19 2.43
Nevada 3.56 3.32 3.97 0.18 3.59
Alabama 2.38 2.31 2.84 0.17 2.47
Michigan 1.93 1.69 2.37 0.17 1.98
Minnesota 2.40 2.27 2.92 0.16 2.47
North Carolina 2.60 2.50 2.98 0.16 2.67
Idaho 2.58 2.27 2.91 0.15 2.58
West Virginia 2.32 2.22 2.79 0.15 2.38
South Carolina 2.69 2.57 3.06 0.15 2.74
Kansas 1.97 1.84 2.30 0.14 2.02
South Dakota 1.87 1.73 2.20 0.11 1.89
Nebraska 1.88 1.76 2.12 0.09 1.89
Illinois 2.74 2.57 2.87 0.08 2.73
Wisconsin 2.26 2.12 2.44 0.08 2.25
Kentucky 2.21 2.11 2.41 0.08 2.23
Iowa 1.78 1.68 1.92 0.06 1.79
Indiana 2.12 2.03 2.25 0.06 2.13
Ohio 2.34 2.27 2.46 0.04 2.34
Source: Fiserv CSW Inc. OFHEO, and Bureau
of Economic Analysis data.
(a.) States are listed in descending order according
to their standard deviation of home prices.
Table 3. Regressions of Home Prices on Fundamentals in the Most
Price-Volatile States (a)
Independent New
variable (b) Hawaii Connecticut Hampshire
Dependent variable: quarterly change in home prices, 1985:1-2002:3
Change in population (percent)
Change in employment (percent) -
Mortgage rate (percent a year)
Unemployment rate (percent) - +
Housing starts + +
Income per capita + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.54 0.69 0.71
Dependent variable: quarterly level of home prices 1985:1-1999:4
Change in population (percent) + - +
Change in employment (percent) - - -
Mortgage rate (percent a year)
Unemployment rate (percent) + -
Housing starts + - -
Income per capita +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.97 0.49 0.48
Dependent variable: quarterly level of home prices 1985:1-1999:4
One-year change in population + +
(percent)
One-year change in employment - - -
(percent)
Ratio of income per capita to
annual mortgage payment
Unemployment rate (percent) - -
Income per capita + + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.97 0.48 0.73
Independent Rhode Massa-
variable (b) California Island chusetts
Dependent variable: quarterly change in home prices, 1985:1-2002:3
Change in population (percent) + + -
Change in employment (percent)
Mortgage rate (percent a year)
Unemployment rate (percent)
Housing starts + + +
Income per capita + + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.75 0.63 0.57
Dependent variable: quarterly level of home prices 1985:1-1999:4
Change in population (percent) - -
Change in employment (percent) - -
Mortgage rate (percent a year)
Unemployment rate (percent) - -
Housing starts - +
Income per capita + + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.82 0.66 0.66
Dependent variable: quarterly level of home prices 1985:1-1999:4
One-year change in population
(percent)
One-year change in employment - - -
(percent)
Ratio of income per capita to
annual mortgage payment -
Unemployment rate (percent) -
Income per capita + + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.86 0.48 0.76
Independent New New
variable (b) Jersey York
Dependent variable: quarterly change in
home prices, 1985:1-2002:3
Change in population (percent)
Change in employment (percent) -
Mortgage rate (percent a year)
Unemployment rate (percent) + +
Housing starts + +
Income per capita + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.72 0.56
Dependent variable: quarterly level of
home prices 1985:1-1999:4
Change in population (percent) - +
Change in employment (percent)
Mortgage rate (percent a year) -
Unemployment rate (percent) - -
Housing starts - -
Income per capita +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.82 0.78
Dependent variable: quarterly level of
home prices 1985:1-1999:4
One-year change in population - +
(percent)
One-year change in employment -
(percent)
Ratio of income per capita to
annual mortgage payment
Unemployment rate (percent) -
Income per capita + +
Adjusted [R.sup.2] 0.73 0.83
Source: Authors' regressions.
(a.) A plus sign indicates that the coefficient on the variable
is positive and statistically significant at the 5 percent level,
and a minus sign indicates that it is negative and significant
at the 5 percent level.
(b.) Independent variables use quarterly data except where
stated otherwise.
Table 4. Change in Average Home Price in Survey Cities during
Boom and Bust, 1982-2003 (a)
Percent
Period Los Angeles San Francisco Boston Milwaukee
1982-peak +128 +126 +143 ... (b)
Peak quarter 1990:2 1990:2 1988:3
Peak to trough -29 -14 -16 ...
Trough quarter 1996:1 1993:1 1991:1
Trough to peak +94 +129 +126 ...
Peak quarter 2003:1 2002:3 2003:1
Whole period +214 +325 +419 +213
At annual rate 5.6 7.1 8.2 5.6
Source: Fiserv CSW Inc. repeat-sales indexes.
(a.) Data cover the period 1982:1-2003:1.
(b.) Home prices displayed no clear peak or trough during the
period.
Table 5. Home Prices, Personal Income, and Mortgage Payments, Selected
States, 1995 and 2002
Current dollars except where stated otherwise
Measure California Massachusetts Wisconsin
Home prices
1995:1 158,954 121,091 50,557
2002:3 276,695 231,994 73,071
Total change (percent) +74 +92 +45
At annual rate (percent) 7.7 9.1 5.1
Personal income per capita
1995:1 24,044 27,224 22,203
2002:3 33,362 39,605 30,138
Total change (percent) +39 +45 +35
At annual rate (percent) 4.5 5.1 4.1
Ratio of home price to income
per capita
1995:1 6.61 4.45 2.28
2002:3 8.29 5.86 2.42
Annual mortgage payment (a)
1995:1 12,145 9,253 3,862
2002:3 15,908 13,338 4,201
Ratio of mortgage payment to
income per capita
1995:1 0.51 0.34 0.17
2002:3 0.47 0.34 0.14
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Economy.com, Fannie Mae,
U.S. Bureau of the Census data adjusted using CSW or blended
repeat-sales indexes.
(a.) Assumes thirty-year fixed rate mortgage at 80 percent loan to
value at annual interest rate of 8.8 percent (February 1995) or 6.0
percent (August 2002).
Table 6. Survey Sample Sizes and Response Rates in 1988 and 2003
Returns Response rate
Sample size tabulated (percent)
Metropolitan area 1988 2003 1988 2003 1988 2003
Los Angeles 500 500 241 143 48.2 28.6
San Francisco 530 500 199 164 37.5 32.8
Boston 500 500 200 203 40.0 40.6
Milwaukee 500 500 246 187 49.2 37.4
Total 2,030 2,000 886 697 43.9 34.9
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
Table 7. Characteristics of Respondents' Home Purchases
Percent of responses except where stated otherwise
San
Los Angeles Francisco
Description 1988 2003 1988 2003
Single-family home 70.0 95.2 55.9 96.4
First-time purchase 35.8 31.7 36.2 46.0
Bought as primary 88.4 95.6 72.7 93.3
residence
Bought to rent to others 3.7 2.8 12.1 3.0
Boston Milwaukee
Description 1988 2003 1988 2003
Single-family home 39.7 97.5 71.1 91.6
First-time purchase 51.5 41.6 56.9 53.1
Bought as primary 92.0 97.1 88.2 90.0
residence
Bought to rent to others 3.0 0.9 4.1 5.3
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
Table 8. Survey Responses on Housing as an Investment,
1988 and 2003
Percent of responses except where stated otherwise
Los San
Angeles Francisco
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
In deciding to buy your property, did you think
of the purchase as an investment?
It was a major 56.3 46.8 63.8 51.8
consideration
In part 40.3 46.2 31.7 34.4
Not at all 4.2 7.0 4.5 9.8
No. of responses 238 143 199 164
Why did you buy the
home that you did?
Strictly for investment 19.8 7.5 37.2 10.6
purposes
No. of responses 238 142 199 164
Buying a home in [city]
today involves
A great deal of risk 3.4 7.9 4.2 14.8
Some risk 33.3 47.5 40.1 51.9
Little or no risk 63.3 44.6 55.7 33.3
No. of responses 237 143 192 164
Boston Milwaukee
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
In deciding to buy your property, did you think
of the purchase as an investment?
It was a major 48.0 33.9 44.0 50.3
consideration
In part 45.0 56.2 45.7 42.2
Not at all 7.0 9.9 10.3 7.5
No. of responses 200 203 243 187
Why did you buy the
home that you did?
Strictly for investment 15.6 8.2 18.7 13.8
purposes
No. of responses 199 203 246 187
Buying a home in [city]
today involves
A great deal of risk 5.1 7.8 5.9 4.3
Some risk 57.9 62.5 64.6 57.3
Little or no risk 37.1 29.6 29.5 38.4
No. of responses 197 203 237 187
Source: Author's survey described in the text.
Table 9. Survey Responses on Price Expectations, Sense
of Excitement, and Talk, 1988 and 2003
Percent of responses except where stated otherwise
San
Los Angeles Francisco
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Do you think that housing prices in the [city]
area will increase or decrease over the next
several years?
Increase 98.3 89.7 99.0 90.5
Decrease 1.7 10.3 1.0 9.5
No. of responses 240 145 199 158
How much of a change do you expect there
to be in the value of your home over the
next 12 months?
Mean response 15.3 10.5 13.5 9.8
(percent)
Standard error 0.8 0.6 0.6 0.6
No. of responses 217 139 185 147
On average over the next 10 years, how much
do you expect the value of your property to
change each year?
Mean response 14.3 13.1 14.8 15.7
(percent)
Standard error 1.2 1.2 1.4 1.8
No. of responses 208 137 181 152
Which of the following best describes the
trend in home prices in the [city] area since
January 1988?
Rising rapidly 90.8 76.2 83.7 28.6
Rising slowly 8.8 22.4 12.8 51.0
Not changing 0.4 1.4 3.1 14.3
Falling slowly 0.0 0.0 0.5 6.2
Falling rapidly 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
No. of responses 239 143 196 161
It's a good time to buy because housing prices
are likely to rise in the future.
Agree 93.2 77.0 95.0 82.1
Disagree 6.8 23.0 5.0 17.9
No. of responses 206 126 180 145
Housing prices are booming. Unless I buy
now, I won't be able to afford a home later.
Agree 79.5 48.8 68.9 59.7
Disagree 20.5 51.2 31.1 40.3
No. of responses 200 124 167 134
There has been a good deal of excitement
surrounding recent housing price changes. I
sometimes think that I may have been
influenced by it.
Yes 54.3 46.1 56.5 38.5
No 45.7 53.9 43.5 61.5
No. of responses 230 141 191 156
In conversations with friends and associates
over the last few months, conditions in the
housing market were discussed ...
Frequently 52.9 32.9 49.7 37.4
Sometimes 38.2 50.3 39.0 43.6
Seldom 8.0 14.7 9.7 17.2
Never 0.8 2.1 1.5 1.8
No. of responses 238 143 195 163
Boston Milwaukee
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Do you think that housing prices in the [city]
area will increase or decrease over the next
several years?
Increase 90.2 83.1 87.1 95.2
Decrease 9.8 16.9 12.9 4.8
No. of responses 194 201 233 187
How much of a change do you expect there
to be in the value of your home over the
next 12 months?
Mean response 7.4 7.2 6.1 8.9
(percent)
Standard error 0.6 0.4 0.5 1.0
No. of responses 176 179 217 160
On average over the next 10 years, how much
do you expect the value of your property to
change each year?
Mean response 8.7 14.6 7.3 11.7
(percent)
Standard error 0.6 1.8 0.5 1.3
No. of responses 177 186 211 169
Which of the following best describes the
trend in home prices in the [city] area since
January 1988?
Rising rapidly 3.0 29.6 8.7 33.0
Rising slowly 34.3 49.2 53.0 57.3
Not changing 37.4 12.6 23.9 8.6
Falling slowly 22.2 8.5 11.7 1.1
Falling rapidly 3.0 0.0 2.6 0.0
No. of responses 198 199 230 185
It's a good time to buy because housing prices
are likely to rise in the future.
Agree 77.8 66.1 84.8 87.0
Disagree 22.2 33.9 15.2 13.0
No. of responses 171 174 210 161
Housing prices are booming. Unless I buy
now, I won't be able to afford a home later.
Agree 40.8 37.1 27.8 36.4
Disagree 59.2 62.9 72.2 63.6
No. of responses 169 175 194 154
There has been a good deal of excitement
surrounding recent housing price changes. I
sometimes think that I may have been
influenced by it.
Yes 45.3 29.6 21.5 34.8
No 54.7 70.4 78.5 65.2
No. of responses 181 199 233 184
In conversations with friends and associates
over the last few months, conditions in the
housing market were discussed ...
Frequently 30.3 31.0 20.0 27.6
Sometimes 55.1 53.7 50.2 40.5
Seldom 12.1 14.3 25.1 28.1
Never 2.5 1.0 4.7 3.8
No. of responses 198 203 235 185
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
Table 10. Survey Responses on Homebuyers' Agreement with Simple
Theories of Housing Prices, 1988 and 2003
Percent of responses except where stated otherwise
Los Angeles San Francisco
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Housing prices have boomed in [city] because lots of people
want to live here.
Agree 98.6 93.8 93.3 89.1
Disagree 1.4 6.2 6.7 10.9
No. of responses 210 128 178 147
The real problem in [city] is that there is just not enough
land available.
Agree 52.8 60.3 83.9 59.6
Disagree 47.2 39.7 16.1 40.4
No. of responses 197 121 174 141
When there is simply not enough housing available, price
becomes unimportant.
Agree 34.0 31.9 40.6 32.6
Disagree 66.0 68.1 59.4 67.4
No. of responses 197 116 165 141
In a hot real estate market, sellers often get more than one
offer on the day they list the property. Some are even over
the asking price. There are also stories about people waiting
in line to make offers. Which is the best explanation?
There is panic buying and price becomes
irrelevant. 73.3 63.7 71.2 73.9
Asking prices have adjusted slowly or
sluggishly to increasing demand. 26.7 36.2 28.8 26.1
No. of responses 210 135 177 153
Which of the following better describes your theory about
recent trends in home prices in [city]?
It is a theory about the psychology of
homebuyers and sellers. 11.9 10.8 16.7 15.0
It is a theory about economic or demo-
graphic conditions such as population
changes, changes in interest rates,
or employment. 88.1 89.2 83.3 85.0
No. of responses 226 130 180 153
Boston Milwaukee
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Housing prices have boomed in [city] because lots of people
want to live here.
Agree 69.6 77.8 16.1 23.0
Disagree 30.4 22.2 83.9 77.0
No. of responses 181 176 193 148
The real problem in [city] is that there is just not enough
land available.
Agree 54.2 72.9 17.2 35.4
Disagree 45.8 27.1 82.8 64.6
No. of responses 168 177 192 158
When there is simply not enough housing available, price
becomes unimportant.
Agree 26.9 32 20.7 25.2
Disagree 73.1 68 79.3 74.8
No. of responses 171 172 193 151
In a hot real estate market, sellers often get more than one
offer on the day they list the property. Some are even over
the asking price. There are also stories about people waiting
in line to make offers. Which is the best explanation?
There is panic buying and price becomes
irrelevant. 61.4 73.1 34.6 46.8
Asking prices have adjusted slowly or
sluggishly to increasing demand. 38.6 39.9 65.4 53.2
No. of responses 176 197 211 173
Which of the following better describes your theory about
recent trends in home prices in [city]?
It is a theory about the psychology of
homebuyers and sellers. 21.3 11.8 10.7 13.7
It is a theory about economic or demo
graphic conditions such as population
changes, changes in interest rates,
or employment. 78.7 88.2 89.3 86.3
No. of responses 188 195 215 168
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
Table 11. Survey Responses: Popular Themes Mentioned in Interpreting
Recent Housing Price Changes, 1988 and 2003
Percent of responses (a)
San
Los Angeles Francisco
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
National factors
Interest rate changes 32 33 40 10
Stock market crash 2 4 2 11
September 11, 2001 6 9
Iraq war 2003 2 4
Dot-com bust 2 21
Corporate scandals, 0 1
loss of confidence
Poor or slow economy 5 24
Regional factors
Region is a good place 17 13 18 8
to live
Immigration or 20 8 8 7
population change
Asian investors 3 0 27 0
Asian immigrants 2 0 14 0
Income growth 3 1 2 4
Anti-growth legislation 11 0 3 0
Not enough land 8 5 19 2
Local taxes 3 0 0 0
Increasing black 0 0 0 0
population
Rental rates and vacancies 0 1 3 0
Traffic congestion 4 0 7 1
Local economy--general 25 3 5 6
Other
Psychology of the 5 2 7 2
housing markets (b)
Quantitative evidence (c) 0 0 0 0
Boston Milwaukee
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
National factors
Interest rate changes 25 20 27 39
Stock market crash 25 13 2 8
September 11, 2001 16 7
Iraq war 2003 2 3
Dot-com bust 4 0
Corporate scandals, 0 0
loss of confidence
Poor or slow economy 34 15
Regional factors
Region is a good place 6 5 2 3
to live
Immigration or 11 5 2 8
population change
Asian investors 0 0 0 0
Asian immigrants 1 0 0 0
Income growth 2 2 1 2
Anti-growth legislation 0 1 0 0
Not enough land 2 3 0 0
Local taxes 4 0 10 4
Increasing black 0 0 7 0
population
Rental rates and vacancies 7 3 2 0
Traffic congestion 0 0 0 0
Local economy--general 30 6 18 5
Other
Psychology of the 18 1 1 1
housing markets (b)
Quantitative evidence (c) 0 0 0 0
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
(a.) Percent of questionnaires that mentioned, in answer to either
of two open-ended questions, the general subject indicated as
determined by the author's reading of their text answers. The questions
were the following: "What do you think explains recent changes in
home prices in the [city]? What ultimately is behind what's going
on?" and "Was there any event (or events) in the last two years that
you think changed the trend in home prices?"
(b.) Any reference to panic, frenzy, greed, apathy, foolishness,
excessive optimism, excessive pessimism, or other such factors was
coded in this category.
(c.) The coder was asked to look for any reference at all to any
numbers relevant to future supply or demand for housing or to any
professional forecast of supply or demand. The numbers need not have
been presented, so long as the respondent seemed to be referring
to such numbers.
Table 12. Survey Responses on Real Estate versus Stock Market
Investment, 2003
Percent of responses except where stated otherwise
Los San
Question Angeles Francisco Boston Milwaukee
Do you agree with the following statement:
"Real estate is the best investment for long-term holders,
who can just buy and hold through the ups and downs
of the market"?
Strongly agree 53.7 50.6 36.7 31.3
Somewhat agree 33.1 39.5 48.5 45.9
Neutral 10.3 6.7 9.3 11.3
Somewhat disagree 2.7 2.4 4.9 9.1
Strongly disagree 0.0 0.6 0.4 2.1
No. of responses 145 162 204 185
Do you agree with the following statement: "The stock
market is the best investment for long-term holders,
who can just buy and hold through the ups and
downs of the market"?
Strongly agree 8.2 8.0 14.7 14.9
Somewhat agree 32.4 38.2 44.3 33.6
Neutral 32.4 27.7 17.7 25.6
Somewhat disagree 20.0 16.0 15.2 20.3
Strongly disagree 6.8 9.8 7.8 5.3
No. of responses 145 162 203 187
The experience with the stock market
in the past few years ...
Much encouraged me to 13.9 15.5 14.3 9.1
buy my house
Somewhat encouraged me 11.1 16.7 13.8 13.9
to buy my house
Had no effect on my 74.1 64.5 70.7 74.7
decision to buy my
house
Somewhat discouraged me 0.0 2.4 0.9 2.1
from buying my house
Much discouraged me from 0.6 0.6 0.0 0.0
buying my house
No. of responses 143 161 202 186
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
Table 13. Survey Responses on Excess Demand and Upward Rigidity in
Asking Prices, 1988 and 2003 (a) Percent of responses except where
stated otherwise
San
Los Angeles Francisco
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Did you finally settle on the
price that was ...
Above the asking price? 6.3 19.9 9.8 45.8
Equal to the asking price? 38.0 50.4 26.8 27.5
Below the asking price? 55.7 29.7 63.4 26.7
No. of responses 237 141 194 153
If you had asked 5 to 10 percent
more for your property, what
would the likely outcome have
been? (a)
It wouldn't have been sold. 21.3 23.5 23.4 27.1
It would have sold but it
would have taken much more
time. 44.9 47.1 46.9 40.7
If buyers had to pay that much
they might not be able to
obtain financing (a buyer
cannot obtain financing
unless an appraiser confirms
the worth of the property). 7.9 4.1 9.4 6.8
It probably would have sold
almost as quickly. 24.7 23.5 17.2 20.3
Other 1.1 1.5 3.1 5.1
No. of responses 89 68 64 59
If you answered that it would
have sold almost as quickly,
which of the following (you can
check more than one) explains
why you didn't set the price
higher? (a)
The property simply wasn't
worth that much. 32.4 25.8 27.3 23.1
It wouldn't have been fair to
set it that high; given what
I paid for it, I was already
getting enough for it. 16.2 25.8 22.7 61.5
I simply made a mistake or got
bad advice; I should have
asked for more. 21.6 19.4 18.2 7.7
Other 29.7 29.0 31.8 7.7
No. of responses 37 31 22 26
In the six months prior to the
time you first listed the
property, did you receive any
unsolicited calls from a real
estate agent or anyone else
about the possibility of selling
your house? (a)
Yes 71.9 69.1 59.0 55.6
No 28.1 30.9 41.0 44.4
Approximate number of calls
Mean 8.7 5.0
Standard error 1.2 0.3
No. of responses 89 68 61 63
Boston Milwaukee
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Did you finally settle on the
price that was ...
Above the asking price? 0.5 21.3 3.3 17.5
Equal to the asking price? 23.5 59.1 22.7 52.4
Below the asking price? 76.0 28.6 74.0 31.1
No. of responses 200 203 242 183
If you had asked 5 to 10 percent
more for your property, what
would the likely outcome have
been? (a)
It wouldn't have been sold. 31.1 27.7 32.5 26.1
It would have sold but it
would have taken much more
time. 54.1 38.6 37.2 39.3
If buyers had to pay that much
they might not be able to
obtain financing (a buyer
cannot obtain financing
unless an appraiser confirms
the worth of the property). 0.0 4.8 9.3 8.7
It probably would have sold
almost as quickly. 11.5 26.5 16.3 21.7
Other 3.3 2.4 4.7 4.4
No. of responses 61 83 43 46
If you answered that it would
have sold almost as quickly,
which of the following (you can
check more than one) explains
why you didn't set the price
higher? (a)
The property simply wasn't
worth that much. 38.5 13.5 25.0 13.3
It wouldn't have been fair to
set it that high; given what
I paid for it, I was already
getting enough for it. 15.4 54.1 31.3 46.7
I simply made a mistake or got
bad advice; I should have
asked for more. 19.2 8.1 25.0 13.3
Other 26.9 24.3 18.8 26.7
No. of responses 26 37 16 15
In the six months prior to the
time you first listed the
property, did you receive any
unsolicited calls from a real
estate agent or anyone else
about the possibility of selling
your house? (a)
Yes 38.7 53.0 43.2 ... (b)
No 61.3 46.0 56.8 ...
Approximate number of calls
Mean 3.9 2.7
Standard error 0.4 0.2
No. of responses 62 83 48 44
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
(a.) Responses from buyers surveyed who had also sold a home. The
sale is assumed to have occurred in the same metropolitan area as
the purchase.
(b.) The question was not asked.
Table 14. Survey Responses on Excess Supply and Downward Rigidity
in Asking Prices, 1988 and 2003 (a)
Percent of responses except where stated otherwise
Los Angeles San Francisco
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Since housing prices are unlikely to drop
very much, the best strategy in a
slow market is to hold up until you
get what you want for a property.
Agree 69.0 64.0 69.6 69.0
Disagree 31.0 36.0 30.4 31.0
No. of responses 174 111 148 129
If you had not been able to sell your
property for the price that you
received, what would you have done? (a)
Left the price the same and waited for 42.0 32.3 38.7 29.5
a buyer, knowing full well that it
might have taken a long time
Lowered the price step by step hoping 20.5 32.3 38.7 26.7
to find a buyer
Lowered the price till I found a buyer 4.5 7.7 3.2 11.5
Taken the house off the market 18.2 21.5 17.7 27.9
Other 14.8 6.2 1.6 4.9
No. of responses 88 65 62 61
If you answered that you would have
lowered your price, is there a limit
to how far you would have gone if the
property still hadn't sold? (a)
Yes 81.8 85.7 78.9 81.3
No. of responses 33 35 38 32
Boston Milwaukee
Question 1988 2003 1988 2003
Since housing prices are unlikely to drop
very much, the best strategy in a
slow market is to hold up until you
get what you want for a property.
Agree 57.5 51.2 50.6 61.9
Disagree 42.5 48.8 49.4 38.1
No. of responses 160 166 180 147
If you had not been able to sell your
property for the price that you
received, what would you have done? (a)
Left the price the same and waited for 32.8 21.7 32.6 39.5
a buyer, knowing full well that it
might have taken a long time
Lowered the price step by step hoping 42.6 47.0 20.9 30.2
to find a buyer
Lowered the price till I found a buyer 4.9 12.0 7.0 9.3
Taken the house off the market 11.5 15.7 27.9 16.3
Other 8.2 3.6 11.6 4.6
No. of responses 61 83 43 43
If you answered that you would have
lowered your price, is there a limit
to how far you would have gone if the
property still hadn't sold? (a)
Yes 93.1 87.7 87.5 90.3
No. of responses 29 57 16 32
Source: Authors' survey described in the text.
(a.) Responses from buyers surveyed who had also sold a home. The
sale is assumed to have occurred in the same metropolitan area as
the purchase.
We are grateful for generous research support from Wellesley
College and are indebted to Sonyay Lai, Semida Munteanu, and Xin Yu for
excellent research assistance. Fiserv CSW, Inc. has supplied us with
important data and assistance.
(1.) "Castles in Hot Air," The Economist, May 28, 2003.
(2.) See Friedman (1953).
(3.) See Bewley (2002).
(4.) Case (1986).
(5.) Case and Shiller 0987).
(6.) Case and Shiller (1989).
(7.) Case and Shiller (1990) used time-series and cross-sectional
regressions to test for the forecastability of prices and excess
returns, using a number of independent variables. We found that the
ratio of construction costs to price, changes in the adult population,
and increases in real income per capita are all positively related to
home prices and excess returns. The results add weight to the argument
that the market for single-family homes is inefficient.
(8.) The analysis and conclusions are consistent with
Malpezzi's (1999) model of home prices estimated with data for 1979
through 1996.
(9.) See Case and Shiller (1987, 1989) on the construction of these
indexes.
(10.) Case and Shiller (1987).
(11.) The -2 percent estimates are from Kain and Quigley (1972) and
Follain and Malpezzi (1981) and the +6 percent estimate is from Goodman and Ittner (1992).
(12.) Case (1986).
(13.) Case and Shiller (1988).
(14.) A. Nomani, Sr., "Nesting Fever: Buyers" Panic
Sweeps California's Big Market in One-Family Homes," Wall
Street Journal, June 1, 1988, p. 1.
(15.) Differences in glamour across cities is a sensitive topic,
but one that is nonetheless very real and ought to be taken note of
here. Some of our respondents were very opinionated about these
differences. One Milwaukee respondent wrote on the questionnaire:
"I was laid off and forced to expand my job search nationwide. I
did not want to leave Chicago and certainly did not want to relocate to
Milwaukee, a second rate city with high unemployment.... However, the
upside is that the housing prices in Chicago are so much higher than
Milwaukee County and I was able to sell my tiny Cape Cod for a beautiful
4 bedroom historic house on a prime residential street."
(16.) Dillman (1978).
(17.) In 2003 the median expected twelve-month price increases were
10 percent for Los Angeles, 7 percent for San Francisco, 5 percent for
Boston, and 5 percent for Milwaukee. The lower values for the medians
than for the corresponding means reflect the fact that the high
expectations for future price increase were especially concentrated
among a relatively few respondents."
(18.) The median ten-year expectations were 8 percent in Los
Angeles, 7 percent in San Francisco, 5 percent in Boston, and 5 percent
in Milwaukee; once again the medians show less strikingly high
expectations.
(19.) See Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2001).
(20.) Shiller (2000).
(21.) Case (1994).
(22.) The zoning strictness measure is the length of time it takes
for an application for rezoning to result in a building permit for a
modest-sized single-family subdivision of fewer than fifty units
(Glaeser and Gyourko, 2002).
Comments and Discussion
Christopher Mayer: It is an honor to discuss this paper. I had not
yet started graduate school when Karl Case and Robert Shiller wrote
their first paper together. After finishing graduate school, I took my
first job at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, where Case was then a
visiting scholar. He and I had many discussions about the housing
market, and we coauthored several papers. The output of those
conversations remains with me today.
I will begin with a brief summary of the paper's findings,
focusing on my interpretations of the authors' principal results
and on the strengths (and limitations) of their data. I will also
examine why there is currently a popular perception of a housing market
bubble. On this point I will consider a couple of issues that get less
attention in this paper and that might give a slightly different
perspective on its findings, namely, the role of nominal interest rates
and expected inflation. I will conclude with some comments about whether
we should be worried about a housing bust today.
SUMMARY OF FINDINGS. The first striking fact to note in this paper
is how stable the home price-to-income ratio is in many parts of the
country (the authors' tables 1 and 2). In most states the
difference between the minimum and the maximum price-to-income ratio is
between 10 and 20 percent of its median value over the sample period.
These numbers suggest a strong relationship, with little variation,
between home prices and a simple (univariate) proxy for demand. These
statistics argue against the popular perception (including that of many
economists) that housing markets are excessively volatile.
But the data also show that, in a few states, the home
price-to-income ratio is quite volatile. Case and Shiller examine eight
such states and show that the fundamentals appear to explain much less
of the variability in home prices (or the home price-to-income ratio)
over time. Although one might say that eight out of fifty states is not
a large number, these eight states include the most valuable real estate
in the country. I would not be surprised if these eight states (which
include California, Massachusetts, New Jersey, and New York) account for
a majority of total home value in the United States.
Another difference between these eight states and the rest of the
country is where the economies of those states stand today. In none of
the eight states is the home price-to-income ratio as high as it was in
the late 1980s. However, that fact in and of itself is not necessarily
cause for optimism, because home prices fell in those eight states in
the aftermath of the runup that led to those high ratios. At the same
time, many of the other states, although their prices have been less
volatile, have a home price-to-income ratio that appears at or near its
historic peak in the Case and Shiller data.
Most of the paper describes results from two surveys of recent
homebuyers that the authors conducted in 1988 and 2003 in four
metropolitan areas. As one who has been citing their 1988 survey results
for a long time, I was excited to discover that they had updated the
survey. This is a great time to conduct a follow-up study, although it
would have been even more interesting to see a comparison from a bust
year in the early 1990s as well. In the previous survey I was always
struck by the cross-sectional comparison between homeowners' high
expectations of price appreciation in the booming metropolitan areas of
Boston, Orange County, and San Francisco and the more moderate
expectations of homeowners in Milwaukee.
When compared with the earlier survey results, the 2003 findings,
with one real exception, are relatively unchanged. Although some of the
numbers went up or down a little bit, most of the changes are likely to
be within the standard error bounds from the previous findings. The
exception is that a preponderance of the homebuyers in Milwaukee
expressed higher expectations of home price appreciation than did
Milwaukee homebuyers in the previous survey, despite the fact that
Milwaukee home prices have not boomed to the same extent as those in the
other locations surveyed. However, in discussions with the authors I
learned that the differences in means that are cited in the paper are
considerably more striking than the differences in medians. The median
expected appreciation in the Milwaukee sample for the next ten years is
about 5 percent a year, and that for some of the other cities is 7 or 8
percent--still fairly high, but not quite as outlandish as the mean
expectations, which exceed 10 percent in all four metropolitan areas in
the 2003 survey.
Other results in the paper seem reasonable to me, even if they seem
less so to the authors. Homeowners perceive housing to be a stable
investment relative to the stock market. One reason is that they
recognize that no matter what happens to the price of housing, they
still get to live in their home. This observation makes a lot of sense
when comparing housing with stocks, because stocks pay very low and
variable (and sometimes no) dividends. So, when stock prices fall, as
they have recently, owners of stocks are hurt. In contrast, the dividend
in the housing market is tangible. Most of the financial return from a
house comes from getting to live in the house, not from the expected
capital gain. (After all, average real home prices increased just 1.2
percent a year between 1975 and 2000, according to data from OFHEO.)
Whether or not the price of that house goes up or down, the owner still
realizes consumption value. Academic economists debate how to measure
that value, and how it co-varies with the value of housing. But, from
the perspective of most homeowners, who cannot easily hedge their
housing investments, that consumption flow is unchanged over cycles in
the housing market. Todd Sinai and Nick Souleles have written a
compelling paper showing how home ownership can serve as an effective
hedge against real estate cycles and the volatility of rent, which
suggests that homeowners may also get other benefits relative to renters
in the housing market. (1) Case and Shiller's survey suggests that
some homeowners perceive the value of a home as coming from consumption,
and that the housing market is less risky than the stock market. These
findings seem perfectly reasonable for most U.S. homeowners.
Another major result from the survey (to which I will return at the
end) is that home prices are sticky. This certainly appears to be true.
I have done some work with David Genesove showing that loss aversion and
liquidity constraints can help explain sticky home prices, at least
during busts. (2) A third factor appears to be that people are just very
slow to adjust their reservation prices. This slow adjustment may have
to do with institutional factors, such as the use of lagged appraisals
to set current asking prices.
The paper suggests that one should not expect large declines in
home prices, even in the most volatile states, if demand for housing
falls. However, there is some inconsistency between this claim and the
observation that these states have volatile home price-to-income ratios.
In addition, these are places where nominal housing prices have in fact
fallen in the past. Finally, my previous work in this area suggests that
even if prices are sticky, the number of transactions can fall
considerably, which, as the paper notes, could lead to considerable
macroeconomic distress.
TECHNICAL ISSUES. A few technical issues are worth considering,
although they are not critical to interpreting the results in this
paper. For example, the use of state-level home price indexes is likely
to underestimate the volatility of home prices in metropolitan areas.
However, reliable income data do not exist at the metropolitan level,
which necessitates the state-level analysis. Also, the OFHEO home price
indexes that are used for most of the states miss the high end of the
market, because they are based on sales of homes with "conforming
loans," which exclude the highest-priced homes in the country.
Indexes from OFHEO may well understate the price increases for
high-priced homes, which have clearly been larger relative to those for
low-priced homes, and this bias might be greater in the highest-priced
areas. So the OFHEO data almost certainly understate the extent of price
increases and underestimate volatility, because the values of
high-priced homes are typically more volatile than those of low-priced
homes. (3)
Also, as John Quigley notes in his comment, supply clearly matters.
However, I will start with the same premise that the authors implicitly
do: that the supply of housing is inelastic, at least in the eight
volatile states. If this assumption were not true, and the supply of
housing were perfectly elastic, we would have nothing to talk about.
Home prices would be driven by the sum of construction cost and the
opportunity cost of land (that is, its value in agricultural use). The
fact that any demand-side variables are correlated with home prices
provides evidence that supply is not perfectly elastic.
Another issue relates to Case and Shiller's observation that
consumers do not typically describe empirical evidence or use
sophisticated ideas when talking about the housing market. In fact,
consumers have no choice, because there are no appreciable data
available to them (or to researchers) that can be used to study local
home prices. The authors started a wonderful company that generates
high-quality local price indexes, but their data are not widely
disseminated. When I go to the Internet to find home price indexes for
individual metropolitan areas, the OFHEO data are the only data
available. I cannot easily get data from Case, Shiller, and Weiss to
describe local markets. And the typical real estate broker does not
really understand what a price index is, let alone have any reliable
data. So it is not very surprising that, in the stock market, people
talk about price-earnings ratios, but in the housing market they do not.
The data are not available. One could say that that is endogenous, but
nonetheless, even sophisticated buyers and sellers are limited in this
market by poor data.
WHY DO CONSUMERS "THINK" THERE IS A HOUSING BUBBLE? An
issue that Case and Shiller raise early in the paper is the perception
in the media that the United States is in a housing bubble. This
perception is puzzling in that a lot of economists, at least, do not
seem to see a lot of evidence of a bubble. Here I consider two related
issues that might affect this perception: the role of interest rates and
the role of expected inflation.
Many observers have commented that the housing market really is a
regional or even a local market. That has certainly been true in the
past. Yet in the last several years there has been much more of a common
factor in the movement of home prices in many different parts of the
country. Most observers point to historically low interest rates as that
common factor.
When I have run regressions of home prices on the user cost of
housing, I have typically found a remarkably low coefficient on user
costs. That is, it seems as if, historically, housing purchase behavior
and housing values have not been very responsive to changes in interest
rates. (An alternative hypothesis is that user costs are poorly
measured, which is probably true as well.) But the recent data on home
prices reveal historically unprecedented patterns. I do not know of a
previous recession in which home prices increased as the economy turned
down. I see almost nothing else that one can point to besides interest
rates to explain rising home prices at a time of failing employment and
incomes. One implication is that, if interest rates rise from their
current low levels, the housing market could suffer more broadly than it
has in the past when interest rates rose.
That home prices were rising in a recession must be related to the
perception of a housing bubble. In the forty-two states with relatively
stable home price-to-income ratios, that ratio is at or near its peak of
the last thirty years in almost all. For the eight remaining,
high-volatility states, the home price-to-income ratio is high, but not
as high as it was in the late 1980s or early 1990s, just before home
prices began a dramatic fall in these states. However, this fact might
provide only limited comfort for homeowners in these states, because the
past housing bust was severe in states such as California and
Massachusetts.
Another, related fact is that the commercial real estate market
exhibits a pattern similar to that in the housing market. Commercial
real estate prices have been setting new highs even as rents have been
falling. This is unusual in that the commercial real estate market
rarely mirrors the housing market. Some observers have suggested that
this represents another bubble, and many well-known commercial real
estate owners have publicly announced that they are selling assets in
the United States.
Figure 1 below shows real home prices nationally over roughly the
last quarter century. (These data come from OFHEO, as do most of the
data used in this comment, and so they are subject to the biases I
discussed earlier.) What is striking in this figure is that, unlike in
previous business cycles, home prices did not turn down in 2000 when the
expansion ended. It is difficult to come up with convincing explanations
for this fact. Strikingly, when I examine some of the explanations that
other people have raised, it turns out that theory would predict the
opposite effect.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
INTEREST RATES AND REAL HOME PRICES. Consider today's
historically low interest rates. The standard metric used to consider
the impact of interest rates on real estate values is the user cost of
housing, (4) which is defined as the rental cost of a unit of housing
divided by the price of housing, as follows:
[R.sub.H]/[P.sub.H] = (1 - MTR)(r + [[pi].sup.e] + [[tau].sub.p]) +
[delta] + [alpha] - [[pi].sup.e.sub.H].
In words, the user cost equals 1 minus the marginal tax rate,
multiplied by the nominal interest rate (which here is decomposed into
the real interest rate r plus expected inflation [[pi].sup.e] plus
property taxes [[tau].sub.p]. To this are added depreciation and a risk
premium, and the expected rate of appreciation of housing is subtracted
off.
In theory, one should expect that, before taxes, home price
inflation ([[pi].sup.e.sub.H]) will increase one for one with expected
inflation in the economy as a whole ([[pi].sup.e]). Using that
relationship and examining the user cost model further yields two
interesting predictions. The first is that decreases in expected
inflation lead to a higher user cost of housing and thus lower (real)
home prices. The reason is that homeowners get to deduct nominal
interest payments from taxable income. A decline in expected inflation
by [DELTA][[pi].sup.e] decreases the rate of growth of home prices by
[DELTA][[pi].sup.e] but lowers interest costs by only (1 -
MTR)[DELTA][[pi].sup.e]. Thus the net effect of a decline in expected
inflation is to increase the after-tax user cost of housing.
Empirical evidence supports the opposite prediction: that higher
expected inflation is associated with higher real home prices. James
Poterba presented a Brookings Paper in 1991 showing that home price
increases were relatively larger for higher-priced homes than for
lower-priced homes in the early 1980s, when expected inflation had
increased. (5) This evidence is consistent with the (after-tax) user
cost model in that owners of higher-priced homes face a higher marginal
tax rate and thus get a larger tax benefit from expected inflation than
do owners of lower-priced homes, many of whom do not even itemize their
deductions and thus get no benefit from the tax deductibility of
mortgage interest expense.
So, from a theoretical perspective, decreases in expected inflation
should be bad for real home prices. My figure 2 presents data from the
Livingston survey on expected inflation. These data show a slow and
steady decline in expected inflation over the last fifteen years.
Contrary to the popular perception, low expected inflation should be bad
for the housing market, not good.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
The survey results from the Case and Shiller paper provide no
evidence that consumers have lowered their expectations of home price
increases in line with lower expected inflation in 2003 relative to
1988. Expected annual inflation has declined from 5 percent to just
under 2 percent today, according to projections of what the Livingston
survey is likely to show for 2003. Yet consumers in the Case and Shiller
survey seem to have had similar expectations of (nominal) home price
increases in both 1988 and 2003. If anything, their expectations in 2003
are even higher.
Low expected inflation, then, cannot easily explain the rise in
real home prices or consumers' predictions of a relatively high
growth rate for home prices. Alternatively, one can also look at changes
in real mortgage rates. After all, low real mortgage rates will lead to
higher real home prices. My figure 3 traces nominal and real mortgage
rates over the last thirty-one years. Although nominal rates are at or
near historic lows, and real mortgage rates are low as well, real rates
are not quite as low as they were for much of the 1970s. Of course, real
mortgage rates have fallen in the last four years, mirroring the rise in
real home prices.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The question is, Which should matter more, nominal rates or real
rates? Or, alternatively, why might low nominal rates spur the housing
market? As I mentioned earlier, regressions on historical data do not
show an enormous impact of real interest rates on home prices, and real
home prices have always fallen in previous recessions.
Low nominal interest rates are the only factor that I can point to
that might explain the recent surge in home prices during a recession.
One could argue that consumers are confusing nominal and real interest
rates. One way that this might happen is if consumers (or lenders)
target a fixed payment-to-income ratio. If consumers are liquidity
constrained, lower nominal rates allow people to afford more housing.
A skeptic might point out that consumers have always been liquidity
constrained, or at least that has been the conclusion of many academic
studies. So what is different today? One possibility is that lenders
have become much more aggressive and are willing to make loans to
consumers who make very low down payments. Thus the down payment
constraint no longer binds today; instead the income constraint is
binding. But if this model is correct, the immediate conclusion is that
as soon as nominal interest rates rise again, people will be able to
afford less housing for a fixed payment-to-income ratio, and home prices
will fall. Of course, this model assumes that home prices are not
forward-looking.
There are many reasons to be skeptical of a model in which demand
for housing is generated by a fixed payment-to-income ratio. For
example, this model clearly does not hold when one examines
cross-sectional data for U.S. metropolitan areas, which show that
consumers do not have a fixed ratio of housing costs to income. Evidence
suggests that homeowners and renters spend a higher percentage of income
in high-priced areas like San Francisco than in low-priced ones like
Milwaukee. So, at least cross-sectionally, this theory does not hold.
Whether it is true within metropolitan areas, one could make some
arguments. Although it is hard to believe in a target payment-to-income
ratio completely, it is the only model that I can come up with that
predicts that lower nominal interest rates will lead to higher home
prices.
LONG-RUN HOME PRICE GROWTH RATES ACROSS CITIES. Case and Shiller
point out that people in places where home prices have risen
substantially, such as San Francisco and Boston, have higher
expectations for home prices in the future than do people in places
where home prices have risen slowly. These expectations are not as crazy
as one might think. I am working on a research project with Joseph
Gyourko and Todd Sinai examining the factors that lead to long-run
differences in home price appreciation across U.S. metropolitan areas.
Using census data from 1940 to 1970, we show that, nationwide, real home
prices increased by 2 percent a year on average, whereas real home
prices in San Francisco and Boston grew by 3.9 percent and 3.1 percent a
year, respectively. Far from being a temporary trend, these patterns
accelerated between 1975 and 2000, according to data from OFHEO, when
real home prices rose annually by 4.6 percent in San Francisco, 3.4
percent in Boston, and only 1.2 percent for the United States as a
whole. (6) Yet rising home prices are not a fact of life in all places.
Real home prices fell in cities such as Houston, Fort Worth, Fort
Lauderdale, and West Palm Beach.
Since 1975 the real price of housing in San Francisco relative to
the rest of the country has gone up 250 percent, which a skeptic might
say is unprecedented, except that the same thing happened in the
previous thirty years as well. San Francisco has been a place where home
prices have continued to go up at above-average rates. Given this
sixty-year trend, it is not unreasonable for consumers to expect this
pattern to continue. (7)
IS A BUBBLE ABOUT TO BURST? What about the question that matters
most at the end of the day: Will real home prices fall? I think there
are warning signs out there. The survey evidence looks pretty
consistent. The level of home prices as well as the home price-to-income
ratio is high in many places.
If fixed payment-to-income ratios are at all important in the
mortgage market, to lenders or borrowers, then any appreciable increase
in mortgage rates (or any decrease in lending or tightening of mortgage
standards) could have a negative impact on home prices. Although
historical data would not predict a decline in home prices, there may be
reasons why the situation is different now than in the past.
The first sign of a decline in demand for housing would be a fall
in sales of single-family houses. Case and Shiller argue that nominal
home price declines are rare and that declines in sales volume are more
common. Yet although nominal home prices have never fallen at the
national level, nominal prices have fallen in many metropolitan areas.
Case and Shiller suggest that policymakers should look at changes
in sales volume if demand for housing falls. Even if sales volume falls
before prices do, eventually prices will catch up. This observation is
based on extensive research that Genesove and I have done in the Boston
condominium market, where prices fell 40 percent in three years. (8)
Although asking prices were sticky at first, and homeowners preferred to
leave their home on the market rather than cut their asking price,
eventually asking prices did catch up to the market.
In the Dallas condominium market, nominal prices fell almost 60
percent during the bust. In the Boston area, nominal prices in the
overall housing market fell about 17 percent over three years. Thus
nominal home prices can fall. The question is what is going on with the
underlying economics. I wish I were a little more confident in the
underlying economics of the housing market right now.
John M. Quigley: This paper by Karl Case and Robert Shiller makes
provocative and sober reading in an economy mired in a postrecession .
nonrecovery and in which the implications of recent changes in tax and
expenditure policies are just beginning to be sorted out. The authors
raise the question of whether the recent run-up in the U.S. housing
market is a manifestation of an irrational bubble, which will put the
economy at some risk when it is eventually popped. In contrast to most
of the recent literature in the bubble genre (and there has been a lot),
this paper presents some original empirical analysis that is relevant,
at least arguably, to the existence of a bubble in asset prices.
The paper makes three contributions. First, it clears the air by
defining what an asset bubble really is. In much popular discussion and
in the analyses presented in the financial press, abnormal price
increases alone are sufficient to signify a bubble in the asset market.
Case and Shiller suggest instead that an asset bubble appears when
current prices depend upon expectations of future price increases. In
this circumstance, when expectations change--perhaps on the basis of
rumor or a mere shred of hard information--current prices may decline
precipitously. Thus, measuring expectations is relevant. Second, the
authors document recent trends in home prices at the state level and the
course of home prices, home price changes, and income-to-home price
ratios. For forty-two of the fifty states, the course of income is
sufficient to explain price movements. For the eight remaining states,
other economic variables add explanatory power, but these variables
(what the authors call the "fundamentals") yield forecasts of
home prices for 2000-02 that are lower than those actually observed.
Third, and most important, Case and Shiller report the results of a
survey mailed to 500 home purchasers in four different metropolitan
areas. The authors document the buyers' expectations and market
perceptions and provide a wealth of survey information about what people
say they think when considering buying a home.
Case and Shiller show that investment motives are clearly important
among home buyers, although they remark somewhat bizarrely that this is
a "defining characteristic of a housing bubble." They document
that perceptions of risk are real and that risk is perceived to be more
important in 2003 than it appeared to be in similar research they
conducted in 1988.
Case and Shiller also document that recent homebuyers expected
substantial price increases during their first year of occupancy, even
in Milwaukee, and that they expected really amazing ten-year gains.
Average one-year price increases are expected to be 7 to 11 percent.
Average ten-year price expectations are a good bit higher, about 12 to
16 percent a year in these markets. People also generally view housing
investment as an escalator--if you don't buy now, you won't be
able to buy later.
The findings and the accompanying discussion make fascinating
reading, and the authors are to be congratulated for their hard work in
data collection and presentation. I do think the authors greatly
overinterpret the consistency of their findings with the presence of an
asset bubble, however.
Consider the dominant motive for house purchase--investment--and
the escalator nature of the investment. Case and Shiller interpret these
survey responses as evidence of a bubble in the current market. But ever
since the Federal Housing Administration and the institution of the
fixed-rate, level-payment, self-amortizing mortgage came into being,
home buying has been like a Christmas club: it represents a long-term
payment contract with serious penalties for not following through with
regularly scheduled investments. The payments are for
"shelter," and the "investment" is painless. Of
course, the housing market is an escalator. It is impossible to force
yourself to save enough money so that you can buy the home tomorrow.
These psychological aspects of the housing contract and saving behavior
do not depend upon any price appreciation at all. Price increases are
just a bonus. This is what your father told you.
Consider the perception that housing is a risky investment. Case
and Shiller seem to interpret this as evidence of a bubble. But housing
is the largest item in most household portfolios, and no methods are
widely available to hedge the concentrated risk. It would be ironic if
these two scholars should claim that this risk is a manifestation of an
asset bubble, since both have been at the forefront in devising
derivatives so that consumers may diversify the risks of homeownership.
The evidence on price expectations is quite disturbing, especially
the fact that people think annual ten-year price increases will exceed
one-year price increases. I do wonder if this is a manifestation of a
bubble, or just the popular misunderstanding of compound interest. Might
the response have been different if the equivalent question had been
asked: Do you think your home will quadruple in value in nine years?
My interpretation of their conclusion is "Despite popular
discussion of housing bubbles, most buyers in these four markets do not
perceive one currently."
The big reason for concern about price increases for housing assets
is the perceived analogy between the run-up and crash in the stock
market and the current price increases experienced in the housing
market. How compelling is that analogy?
The long-run relationship between housing costs and construction
costs casts doubt on the analogy. The average price of new housing moved
in tandem with engineering measures of housing construction costs
(excluding land) until about 1987. Thereafter the price of newly built
housing began to increase. By the end of the 1990s, new houses cost
about 25 percent more than construction costs. (1) Have we had a housing
bubble for the past fifteen years?
I think that there are at least eight reasons to question the
existence, or at least the importance, of a bubble in the housing market
in 2003. First, housing demand is sensitive to income. Case and Shiller
discuss the role of income in detail. Based on their state-by-state
analysis, in only a couple of states--but big ones--is there any
divergence seen between incomes and housing prices.
Second, housing demand is sensitive to price. The user cost of
capital is the annual price at which these assets are enjoyed by
homeowners. These costs include depreciation and maintenance, property
taxes, real interest rates, federal income tax rates, the rate of
capital gains, and inflation. Steven Raphael and I have estimated the
course of user costs during the past quarter century. (2) Even if one
ignores capital gains, the trends are clear. Well before the recent and
substantial reductions in mortgage interest rates, user costs had been
declining. In fact, user costs have declined secularly since about 1980.
When costs decline, the demand for an asset goes up.
Third, there is reason to believe that household formation,
population aging, and immigration will increase the demand for shelter,
for dwellings, and for owner-occupied housing. Forecasts are for 1.2
million new households a year to be created over the next decade. (3)
These trends can be expected to stimulate demand for housing, as older
households continue to resist downsizing, as the rapidly growing demand
for homeownership increases, and as the "echo boomers" (the
children of the baby-boom generation) enter the market. One celebrated
error of the late 1980s, the forecast of a 47 percent fall in housing
prices, (4) arose because these kinds of demographic changes were
ignored.
Fourth, the operation of land markets and the spatial concentration
of growing metropolitan areas make built-up areas in desirable housing
markets even more valuable. Most of the growth in metropolitan areas,
indeed most of the economic activity in America, is coastal. Coastal
metropolitan areas are not like the concentric circles of housing
markets shown in textbooks. For a given amount of economic activity, the
extensive margin is farther out from the city center. Savings in
transport costs and increases in amenities are greater for close-in
properties. Prices get bid up to reflect these transport savings and
amenity differences.
Furthermore, most of these concentrations of growth are in the
South and the West. For a variety of reasons to which Case and Shiller
allude, it is almost illegal to build new dwellings in the West,
especially in California. California has smart growth and growth
controls. There are moratoriums on new construction--it is hard for a
developer to build until you get as far inland as the Central Valley.
Fifth, in the housing market more than in other asset markets, the
timing of transactions is affected by a reluctance to realize losses.
The trade-off between the selling price of a dwelling and time on the
market is well recognized, and the other discussant for this paper has
documented loss aversion. (5) Housing prices are sticky downward. Prices
are slow to decline.
Sixth, transactions costs are higher in this market than in other
asset markets, such as the market for equity shares or for tulip bulbs.
The turnover rate for publicly traded stocks is fifteen times the rate
for houses. Selling costs are high (5 or 6 percent in brokerage), moving
costs are high, and the psychological costs of moving among
neighborhoods, schools, and so on are not trivial. It should come as no
surprise that there are few day traders in housing.
Seventh, none of these intertemporal price comparisons take into
account quality improvements in housing. Quality improvements are
reckoned at about 1.3 percent a year. This affects the comparison and
interpretation of price changes, at least in the longer run.
Eighth, markets are local. The fortunes of real property are
intimately connected to the goods and services produced in different
metropolitan areas, and the specialization of cities varies. (There are
hints of this in the blunt state-by-state regressions presented by Case
and Shiller.) Recall that the closest thing to a real and precipitous
decline in housing prices in recent decades was the Texas bust of the
late 1980s. Oil had gone from an average of $18 a barrel in 1979 to an
average of $35 a barrel in 1981, and single-family housing construction
tripled shortly thereafter. Then oil prices crashed, and so did housing
prices. This was an oil price bubble, perhaps, but hardly a housing
bubble. Asset prices are only imperfectly correlated across markets,
making large aggregate declines unlikely. During the past two decades,
58 of the 100 largest metropolitan areas had at least one one-year price
decline of 10 percent or more. But in only one year did aggregate U.S.
housing prices decline--by 0.9 percent in 1991.
A 10 percent decline in housing values nationally would thus
require some very large declines in some markets. But suppose a 10
percent decline did occur. How would this affect household consumption?
As of last December, the aggregate value of residential housing was
estimated at $13.7 trillion, and aggregate mortgage debt was a bit over
$6 trillion, leaving $7.6 trillion in equity. A 10 percent national
decline in home values would reduce equity by $1.4 trillion, to $6.2
trillion. This would reduce aggregate homeowner equity to its level at
the end of 1999.
To estimate the effects of such a decline on consumption, one can
apply one's preferred wealth effect coefficients to this equity
change. My favorite is the 0.5 to 1.0 percent estimate of Case, Quigley,
and Shiller. (6) This works out to at most a reduction of $14 billion in
spending, or something like a reduction of one-sixth of 1 percent of
annual consumer spending. This is not trivial, but it is not a large
effect either.
General discussion: The authors' interpretation of the survey
responses received considerable attention. Martin Baily disagreed with
the authors' view that respondents' answers to certain
questions reflected confusion, because the distinction in the questions
between levels and rates of change was not as clean as the authors
suggested. Home prices in regions with inelastic supply should be
expected to rise more rapidly in response to growing demand than prices
in regions with elastic supply. And it seems quite reasonable for
respondents to assume that supply is relatively inelastic in cities
where "there is just not enough land available." Growth in
income per capita, for example, should be expected to have a greater
effect on home prices in San Francisco than in Houston. Similarly, it
seems quite reasonable for respondents to view the phrase "because
lots of people want to live here" as indicating expected future
growth in housing demand. Hence Baily did not regard the responses as
necessarily revealing confusion between levels and rates of change. He
added that, with sticky prices, even a demand shock that shifts the
long-run equilibrium level of prices would be expected to lead to a
higher rate of growth of prices over the short run. Alan Blinder supported the use of household surveys to try to understand whether a
bubble psychology underlay the housing boom in the glamour states. But
he agreed that the wording of some of the questions about simple
theories made it difficult for respondents to know whether a statement
was about the level or the rate of change. Indeed, he thought that many
of his students would not have been sensitive to the difference without
tutoring.
Various panelists criticized the empirical analysis of the
importance of fundamentals in determining home prices. William Brainard
believed the authors had not treated interest rates adequately. He was
puzzled that the equations explaining changes in prices did not use
first differences of variables in the level equations. In particular,
they used the level of the mortgage rate in both the level and the
change equations. Brainard wondered whether the change in the mortgage
rate would do a better job of explaining the change in price. Agreeing
with Baily, Jeffrey Frankel noted that variables such as population and
growth in income per capita should have larger effects in regions with
relatively inelastic housing supply. He suggested using a panel
regression that allowed the coefficients on variables such as growth in
income per capita and population to differ across regions, but only by a
common factor. Blinder would have liked to know more about trends in the
purchase price-to-rental ratio. In cities like San Francisco stocks of
rental and owner-occupied housing are quite similar in character. In
these circumstances, rental income and its rate of growth may be good
measures of the value of housing services of owner-occupied houses. Alan
Auerbach agreed that looking at the price-to-rental ratio would be
informative. Rising prices alone do not prove the existence of a bubble;
a bubble exists only if prices increase more than what the economic
fundamentals justify. A simple way to check this would be to see if the
price-to-rental ratio is consistent, given interest rates, with the rate
of growth of rentals.
Benjamin Friedman noted that the sample of respondents apparently
included both first-time buyers and households that are trading up or
down. He would have liked to see questions that clearly distinguished
between these two groups, for whom the implications of expectations of
rapidly rising prices are obviously quite different. Christopher Sims
observed that the [R.sup.2] between two slowly moving series is expected
to be very high. Because income is a very stable time series, the fact
that [R.sup.2]s are high in markets where volatility is low, and lower
in more volatile markets, adds little to the discussion.
(1.) Sinai and Souleles (2001).
(2.) Genesove and Mayer (1997 and 2001).
(3.) Mayer (1993).
(4.) Poterba (1984).
(5.) Poterba (1991).
(6.) Preliminary census data from 1970 to 2000 confirm the patterns
from the OFHEO data.
(7.) Our working paper will consider the economic reasons behind
these facts, differentiating between production factors, such as
agglomeration, and the consumption benefits of living in certain
"superstar cities" like San Francisco and Boston.
(8.) Genesove and Mayer (1997).
(1.) See Quigley and Raphael (forthcoming).
(2.) Quigley and Raphael (forthcoming).
(3.) Joint Center for Housing Studies (2003).
(4.) Mankiw and Weil (1989).
(5.) Genesove and Mayer (2001).
(6.) Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2001).
References
Bewley, Truman F. 2002. "Interviews as a Valid Empirical Tool
in Economics." Journal of Socioeconomics 31(4): 343-53.
Case, Karl E. 1986. "The Market for Single-Family Homes in the
Boston Area." New England Economic Review (May/June): 38-48.
--. 1994. "Land Prices and House Prices in the United
States." In Housing Markets in the United States and Japan, edited
by Yukio Noguchi and James M. Poterba. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research.
Case, Karl E., and Robert J. Shiller. 1987. "Prices of
Single-Family Homes Since 1970: New Indexes for Four Cities." New
England Economic Review (September/October): 45-56.
--. 1988. "The Behavior of Home Buyers in Boom and Post-Boom
Markets." New England Economic Review (November/December): 29-46.
--. 1989. "The Efficiency of the Market for Single-Family
Homes." American Economic Review 79(1): 125-37.
--. 1990. "Forecasting Prices and Excess Returns in the
Housing Market." American Real Estate and Urban Economics
Association Journal 18(3): 253-73.
--. 1994. "A Decade of Boom and Bust in the Prices of
Single-Family Homes: Boston and Los Angeles: 1983 to 1993." New
England Economic Review (March): 40-51.
Case, Karl E., John M. Quigley, and Robert J. Shiller. 2001.
"Comparing Wealth Effects: The Stock Market vs. the Housing
Market." Working Paper 8606. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of
Economic Research (November).
Dillman, Don A. 1978. Mail and Telephone Surveys: The Total Design
Method. John Wiley & Sons.
Follain, James R., and Stephen Malpezzi. 1981. "Are Occupants
Accurate Appraisers?" Review of Public Data Use 9(1): 47-55.
Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. University of
Chicago Press.
Genesove, David, and Christopher Mayer. 1997. "Equity and Time
to Sale in the Real Estate Market." American Economic Review 87(3):
255-69.
--. 2001. "Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior: Evidence from
the Housing Market." Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(4):
1233-60.
Glaeser, Edward L., and Joseph Gyourko. 2002. "The Impact of
Zoning on Housing Affordability." Working Paper 8835. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (March).
Goodman, John L., Jr., and John B. Ittner. 1992. "The Accuracy
of Home Owners' Estimates of House Value." Journal of Housing
Economics 2(4): 339-57.
Joint Center for Housing Studies. 2003. The State of the
Nation's Housing Market. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University.
Kain, John F., and John M. Quigley. 1972. "Note on Owners
Estimate of Housing Value." Journal of the American Statistical
Association 67(340): 803-06.
Malpezzi, Stephen. 1999. "A Simple Error Correction Model of
House Prices." Journal of Housing Economics 8(1): 27-82.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, and David Weil. 1989. "The Baby Boom, the
Baby Bust, and the Housing Market." Regional Science and Urban
Economics 21(4): 547-52.
Mayer, Christopher J. 1993. "Taxes, Income Distribution and
the Real Estate Cycle: Why All Houses Do Not Appreciate at the Same
Rate." New England Economic Review (May/June): 39-50.
Poterba, James. 1984. "Tax Subsidies to Owner-Occupied
Housing: An Asset-Market Approach." Quarterly Journal of Economics
99(4): 729-52.
--. 1991. "House Price Dynamics: The Role of Tax Policy and
Demographics." BPEA, 1991:2, 143-203.
Quigley, John M., and Steven Raphael. Forthcoming. "Is Housing
Unaffordable? Why Isn't It More Affordable?" Journal of
Economic Perspectives.
Shiller, Robert J. 2000. Irrational Exuberance. Princeton
University Press.
Sinai, Todd M., and Nicholas S. Souleles. 2001. "Owner
Occupied Housing as a Hedge against Rent Risk." Working Paper.
University of Pennsylvania (January).
KARL E. CASE
Wellesley College
ROBERT J. SHILLER
Yale University