首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月15日 星期日
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Geographic variation in health care: the role of private markets.
  • 作者:Philipson, Tomas J. ; Seabury, Seth A. ; Lockwood, Lee M.
  • 期刊名称:Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
  • 印刷版ISSN:0007-2303
  • 出版年度:2010
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Brookings Institution
  • 关键词:Health care costs;Health care industry;Insurance industry;Medical care;Medical care utilization;Medical care, Cost of;Medicare;Public sector

Geographic variation in health care: the role of private markets.


Philipson, Tomas J. ; Seabury, Seth A. ; Lockwood, Lee M. 等


ABSTRACT The Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care has documented substantial regional variation in health care utilization and spending, beyond what would be expected from such observable factors as demographics and disease severity. However, since these data are specific to Medicare, it is unclear to what extent this finding generalizes to the private sector. Economic theory suggests that private insurers have stronger incentives to restrain utilization and costs, while public insurers have greater monopsony power to restrain prices. We argue that these two differences alone should lead to greater regional variation in utilization for the public sector, but either more or less variation in spending. We provide evidence that variation in utilization in the public sector is about 2.8 times as great for outpatient visits (p < 0.01) and 3.9 times as great for hospital days (p = 0.09) as in the private sector. Variation in spending appears to be greater in the private sector, consistent with the importance of public sector price restraints.

**********

There is considerable variation in health care utilization and spending across geographic areas in the United States, but little evidence of corresponding differences in health outcomes or satisfaction with care. (l) This variability is often cited as evidence that current levels of health care spending reflect "flat-of-the-curve" medicine, that is, treatment for which the marginal benefit of an additional unit of care is approximately zero. Interpreted this way, these findings have dramatic implications for the potential to increase the productivity of health care spending, and for this reason they have figured prominently in the policy debate.

However, the evidence on regional variation is almost exclusively limited to the public sector, because it relies on Medicare data. Less is known about the corresponding patterns in the private sector. A venerable literature in economics has argued that private firms and their managers have stronger incentives to restrain costs and boost efficiency than their public counterparts. (2) In the health insurance context, Medicare does not face competition over premiums that might otherwise restrain its costs, and unlike private sector firms, Medicare does not have direct residual claimants whose standard of living improves with the efficiency of the enterprise.

To develop the implications of these incentive differences, this paper provides a theoretical and empirical analysis of how regional variation in health care differs across the public and the private sectors. We first examine conceptually how private efforts to control costs within a region, through selection of providers, might translate into differences in care across regions. In particular, our analysis implies that utilization controls within regions in the private sector should lead to lower regional variation in the private sector than in Medicare. However, the implications for variation in spending are less clear, because Medicare may also be able to better control prices through its greater monopsony power. If the private sector controls utilization while the public sector controls prices, the result is an ambiguous prediction for variation in spending.

We examine these implications empirically using individual-level data on patients with heart disease, comparing utilization and spending on patients who have private insurance with that on similar patients within Medicare. Data on the former come from a large database of private sector medical claims, and on the latter from the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey. Both datasets include patient-level demographics and co-morbidities, which allow us to identify regional variation distinct from individual characteristics such as health. The focus on heart disease helps mitigate the confounding impact of regional differences in health status on our analysis.

Our main object of interest is the regional variation in utilization and spending across sectors that cannot be explained by variation in patient characteristics. Our data suggest greater variation in utilization in the public sector: our main analysis suggests that variation in the public sector is about 2.8 times as great for outpatient visits (p < 0.01) and 3.9 times as great for hospital days (p = 0.09) as in the private sector. There is some evidence of greater variation for the number of hospitalizations in the public sector, but this evidence is less robust. Prescription drug utilization serves as our "placebo" case of insurance that was privately provided in both samples during the period investigated. Significantly, and unlike other types of medical care, drug utilization exhibits less variation among Medicare patients. On the other hand, there is greater spending variation in the private sector, suggesting the potential importance of monopsony power in the public sector.

The paper proceeds as follows. Section I provides the conceptual analysis of how differing cost-control measures within a region might lead to differences in regional variation in utilization and spending. Section II reports our empirical analysis comparing regional variation in the public and the private sectors. Section III discusses how our findings relate to the existing literature on health care variation and the resulting policy implications. Section IV discusses some limitations of our analysis and presents several robustness tests. Section V concludes.

I. A Simple Analysis of Regional Variation in Utilization and Spending

This section presents a simple analysis of how private and public incentives interact to create different degrees of regional variation in health care utilization and spending between the public and the private sector. (3) A key assumption is that private insurers have stronger incentives to restrain costs and utilization than a public insurer such as Medicare. This assumption is based on the literature demonstrating that, unlike public enterprises, private firms have to restrain costs in order to compete on price, and private firms' inefficiencies have direct impacts on the welfare of their owners and employees (Alchian and Demsetz 1972, De Alessi 1974a). For example, private payers may explicitly manage care and exert pressure on providers through utilization review and case management. They can also selectively contract with lower-cost providers, steer patients to preferred providers, and exclude inefficient doctors or hospitals. In addition, prior authorization of large expenditures is prevalent in the private health insurance sector, a practice that allocates major spending decisions to the payer rather than the provider. Finally, private payers can steer patients toward efficient care through benefits management--for example, by not covering certain services unless certain clinical criteria are met. In what follows, we use the shorthand of "utilization restrictions" (UR) to refer to all these practices.

We interpret UR as a limit on the provision of treatments whose costs exceed their benefits. This may still lead to regional variation in utilization, because there is substantial heterogeneity among apparently similar patients in the efficacy of different treatments. Excessive care for one patient may be cost-effective for another.

I.A. Causes of Sectoral Differences within Regions

We first consider the level of utilization in both the private and the public sectors. Define [y.sup.*] as the efficient utilization level, that at which marginal benefit equals marginal cost. Following the earlier literature, we assume that private insurers have stronger incentives to limit utilization that rises above this level. They do this through UR, which we assume places an upper bound on utilization, [y.sub.UR] [greater than or equal to] [y.sup.*], and perfectly eliminates inefficient utilization above that level. (4) The assumption of full efficiency is an analytical simplification; the positive predictions do not depend on it, and we do not emphasize the normative predictions.

Within any region there is a distribution of providers, who vary in the level of care they would provide to an identical patient. We characterize this distribution using the cumulative distribution function F(y) for the random utilization variable E Private payers' UR procedures limit utilization and thereby truncate the support of the providers participating in their plans. This results in the private mean utilization level, [mu] = E(Y/Y [less than or equal to] [y.sub.UR]). This constrained private sector mean is thus lower than the unconstrained public sector mean, [[mu].sup.p] = E(Y).

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Now consider a pure increase in utilization, holding health status fixed. This can be represented as a rightward shift in the function F(y). Assuming the efficient level of utilization remains fixed, the result is a greater difference in mean utilization across the two sectors, [[mu].sup.p] - [mu]. In other words, in regions with providers who have greater tendencies toward inefficiency, the difference in utilization between sectors will be larger.

The second key assumption is the presence of greater monopsony power in the public sector. The result is greater restraint of prices, as opposed to utilization, in the public sector. This affects the analysis of variation in spending, which combines the utilization effect and the price effect. If the government pays below-market prices through the exercise of either monopsony power or direct price regulation, the cost curves will differ across sectors. The result is depicted in figure 1. Average spending per patient in the private sector may exceed that in the public sector, if equilibrium marginal cost in the public sector, [MC.sup.p*], is less than equilibrium marginal cost in the private sector, [MC.sup.*].

I.B. Causes of Sectoral Differences across Regions

Next consider how mean utilization for each sector might vary across regions. Define the joint distribution G([[mu].sup.p], [mu]) of mean utilization levels across regions. Specifically, suppose that the underlying distribution F(y) differs across regions. Figure 2 illustrates how one might then characterize the relationship between changes in the public mean and the mean difference between sectors:

d[[mu].sup.p] - [[mu].sup.p]/d[[[mu].sup.p] = 1 - d[mu]/d[[mu].sup.p].

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

For example, consider the case of normally distributed public sector utilization, Y ~ N([[mu].sup.p], [[sigma].sup.2]). In this case, mean utilization in the private sector follows from the formula for the mean of a truncated normal random variable, [mu] = [[mu].sup.p] + [sigma][lambda]([alpha]), where [lambda]([alpha]) [equivalent to] [phi]([alpha])/[PHI]([alpha]) is the inverse Mills ratio and [alpha] = [y.sub.UR] - [[mu].sup.p]/sigma. This implies that the slope of the private mean as a function of the public mean is less than unity or, equivalently, that the between-sector difference rises with the public mean: (5)

0 [less than or equal to] d[[mu]/d[[mu].sup.p] [less than or equal to] 1

d([[mu].sup.p] - [mu])/d[[mu].sup.p] [greater than or equal to] 0.

When the public sector provides more care above the efficient level, this raises the between-sector difference. This in turn implies that the variance in the regional means in the public sector will exceed the variance in the regional means in the private sector: V([[mu].sup.p]) > V([mu]).

This simple framework leads to several testable empirical predictions: Private provision should lead to lower mean utilization and less variance in mean utilization across regions, but not necessarily lower mean spending. In addition, the difference in utilization between sectors is likely to rise with the mean level of public utilization. Note that all these predictions hold patient health status constant.

II. Empirical Analysis of Regional Variation across Sectors

In this section we describe our empirical analysis of regional variation in the public and private sectors aimed at testing the implications discussed above.

II.A. Data and Empirical Specification

We compare regional variation between a sample of privately insured patients and a sample of Medicare patients. The private data come from a large database of health insurance claims. The data capture all health care claims, including prescription drugs and inpatient, emergency, and ambulatory services, by employees and retirees while they are enrolled in the health plans of 35 Fortune 500 firms. The analytical database integrates component datasets of medical claims, pharmacy claims, and enrollment records. This allows us to calculate spending and utilization for all services provided to the patients over our study period. The enrollment records allow us to identify basic demographics of the patients, including age, sex, and some information on income. (6) Importantly for our purposes, the data also include information on area of residence, coded by metropolitan statistical area (MSA) and 3-digit zip code. This allows us to analyze health care spending and utilization patterns at different levels of geographic aggregation.

Our Medicare sample is taken from the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey (MCBS), which is administered to a nationally representative sample of aged, disabled, or institutionalized Medicare beneficiaries. Respondents, whether living in the community or residing in health care facilities, are interviewed up to 12 times over a 4-year period. Institutionalized respondents are interviewed by proxy. There is oversampling of the disabled under 65 years of age and of the oldest old (85 years of age or older). The MCBS uses a rotating panel design with limited periods of participation. Each fall a new panel is introduced with a target sample size of 12,000 respondents, and each summer a panel is retired. The MCBS data include detailed information on self-reported health status, health care use and expenditure, insurance coverage, and demographic characteristics. Additional Medicare claims data for beneficiaries enrolled in fee-for-service plans are also incorporated to provide more accurate information on health care use and expenditure. The MCBS data do not include actual claims data on prescription drugs; all information on prescription drug spending and utilization in the MCBS is self-reported. This leads to a known undercount of drug spending in the MCBS. (7)

Both datasets include information on medical claims that is used to compile utilization, spending, and baseline health information. That is, although the MCBS contains a survey component, all data on spending and utilization are compared with Medicare's administrative claims data (Eppig and Chulis 1997). However, since Medicare does not cover prescription drugs over our sample period, this validation procedure applies to medical care but not drugs. Finally, for both datasets we use information from 2000 to 2006. The one exception is prescription drug utilization and spending: to abstract from the complexities of Medicare Part D's introduction, we eliminate the 2006 data for these variables.

To mitigate differences in health status across sectors and regions, we condition inclusion in the sample on a diagnosis of ischemic heart disease (IHD). (8) We also use the diagnosis codes on medical claims to identify whether patients were treated for any of 30 different conditions in a calendar year. (9) The claims-based measures of the number of diseases are available in both the MCBS and the private health insurance data. (10) This is important because unmeasured differences in severity across regions could lead to spurious positive correlation between sectors.

The primary geographic unit of analysis for our study is the MSA. An alternative candidate would be the hospital referral region (HRR), used by the Dartmouth Atlas. However, HRRs are not reported in either of our datasets, and the private sector data do not contain 5-digit zip codes, which are required to construct an individual's HRR. We restrict our sample to the 99 MSAs where we have the largest samples. MSAs are somewhat larger than HRRs, and this may compress the variation for both sectors in our data.

Our final sample contains 240,028 private patients and 24,800 public patients. (11) Since there are many fewer public patients, it is important to correct for the effects of sample size on our estimates. We derive and report these corrections in detail below.

Table 1 reports some summary statistics comparing demographic characteristics in the public and the private samples. As one would expect, the average age in the private sample is lower than in the sample of Medicare patients, most of whom are older than 65. The private sample contains a greater fraction of males, in part because it is influenced by current or past employment status. (The private sample contains both active workers and retirees receiving benefits from their current or past employers.) Average income is also higher in the private sample. The greater variance in income for the public sample is likely due to the fact that income is reported individually in the MCBS, but imputed at the local level in the private sample.

The table also compares the health of individuals in the two samples. Since both samples are limited to individuals with a history of heart disease, we include a variable indicating the fraction of individuals who are diagnosed with heart disease in a particular year. In all cases, the presence of disease is taken from claims rather than from self-reported data. The incidence of heart disease is similar in the two samples: 0.32 in the private sample and 0.37 in the public sample.

In addition, the table reports the average number of adverse health conditions (out of the total of 30, including heart disease) per patient. As with heart disease, the health conditions are determined using the ICD-9 diagnosis codes from medical claims in both the public and the private samples. Unsurprisingly, the elderly individuals in the public sample are much sicker on average, with 2.9 adverse health conditions in the year compared with 1.4 in the private sample.

As a matter of course, the public and the private samples are drawn from different populations. We include a number of controls and analyses designed to mitigate and test for the impact of these differences, but heterogeneity across samples remains a possibility. Later we discuss the sources of heterogeneity, the methods we have employed to address them, and their possible implications for the analysis.

II.B. Descriptive Statistics

Table 2 presents some descriptive statistics for health care spending and utilization in the public and the private samples aggregated over all regions and patient characteristics. We present not only the mean and the standard deviation but also the 25th-percentile, median, and 75th-percentile values. Our utilization measures (all measured as yearly averages per patient) include the number of hospitalizations, total hospital days across all hospitalizations, the number of outpatient visits, and the number of 30-day-equivalent prescriptions in both samples. For spending, we record total (inpatient plus outpatient), inpatient, and outpatient spending, as well as spending on prescription drugs.

Utilization, in terms of hospitalizations, hospital days, and outpatient visits, is lower for the private patients. Spending for this group also tends to be lower. Total medical spending for individuals in the private plans is $8,401 per year, compared with $10,245 for the Medicare patients--about a 20 percent difference. The exception to the pattern is prescription drugs, for which both utilization and spending are greater among private patients.

Figures 3 and 4 provide a broad sense of the variation present in our samples. Figure 3 reports for both samples the estimated kernel densities of MSA-level deviations from the mean for both hospital days and outpatient visits. Each data point underlying the kernel estimate is the difference between an MSA-level mean and the overall sample mean. For both variables, the distributions appear to be tighter for the private than for the public sample. However, these distributions are based on raw, unadjusted numbers that do not account for disease or other covariates.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

Figure 4 repeats this exercise for inpatient and outpatient spending. Here the findings are decidedly more mixed. For outpatient spending the distribution appears to be slightly tighter for the public sample. The figure for inpatient spending is harder to interpret visually, as the differences in the densities are small and asymmetric. In any event, the differences observable visually between the spending and the utilization distributions suggest the possible importance of public sector price restraints, which would lower spending variation even with greater variation in utilization.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

Finally, figure 5 plots the relationship between deviations from the MSA-level means for public and private hospital days. This is the empirical analogue to the theoretical relationship in figure 2. The figure suggests that mean private hospital days increase slightly with mean public hospital days, but much less than one for one. This is consistent with there being less regional variation in the private sector; we test this hypothesis more formally in the following analyses.

II.C Framework for Estimating Regional Variation

We are particularly interested in the between-MSA variance in spending and utilization for the public and the private samples. We begin with the simplest possible approach that evaluates the variance between MSAs in the sample means. We then move to estimating the variance in regression-adjusted means, which we estimate from regressions that control for various factors that might also influence spending and utilization. In both cases we account for the relative bias that is created by the substantial differences in sample size across sectors: because the public samples are much smaller than the private samples, there is greater sampling variance in the public sector estimates and thus greater variation in the MSA-level means for Medicare patients. To estimate the true between-sector differences in regional variation, we estimate and remove the variability that is due to sample size differences alone.

Formally, the observed regional variation within a sector is due to the true variation and the sampling variance in estimating that variation. Denote by [[mu].sub.r], the true mean for region r and by [[??].sub.r], the corresponding sample estimate, whether unconditional or regression-adjusted. The sample mean is equal to the true mean plus sampling error, according to

[[??].sub.r] = [[mu].sub.r], + [z.sub.r].

The sampling error [z.sub.r] has zero mean, and the covariance of the sampling error across regions is E(z, [z.sub.s],) = [[sigma].sub.rs]. Define [bar.[mu]][equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][[mu].sub.r], the "grand mean" across regions. Similarly, define the corresponding sample analogue, [bar.[??]][equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][[??].sub.r]. Finally. define the average sampling error across regions, [bar.z][equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][z.sub.r]. The object of interest is the degree of regional variation in the true MSA means, RV [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][([[mu].sub.r] - [bar.[[mu]).sup.2] which has the sample analogue [??][equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][([??].sub.r] - [bar.[??]].sup.2].

The observed variation [??] is a biased estimator of RV, as a result of sampling error in the estimates. Moreover, this bias is likely to be larger for our public sector estimates because of the smaller public sector sample size, which yields noisier estimates of public sector utilization. However, we can recover a consistent estimate of the bias and correct for it, according to

E([??] = RV + 1/R [R.summation over (r=1)] [E([z.sub.r] - [??]).sup.2]

In the appendix we show how to estimate this bias from sample variances and covariances. Our formula works for both the case of unconditional sample means and the case of regression-adjusted means. In the simple case without covariance across regions or zero average error across regions, this expression simply states that the observed variation is the true variation plus the average squared standard error. More generally, the more precisely the sample means are estimated, the smaller is the bias correction.

In sum, the object of interest in our analysis is RV, which we estimate as [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] for both the public and the private sector. Using these estimates of regional variation, we report both the ratio of public to private variation and the difference between public and private variation. We construct standard errors around these by means of a bootstrap procedure, which samples individuals with replacement within each MSA, so that each bootstrap sample contains exactly the same number of individuals in each MSA as the original sample. (12) The bootstrap procedure reflects the nature of our sample design. We regard the set of MSAs as fixed but each sample within an MSA as a random sample of that MSA's population. Statistically, our set of MSAs approximates a population, but we have samples within each MSA.

Our regression-adjusted estimates employ a model with regional fixed effects that controls for disease severity and demographics. (13) For each sector s we estimate

[Y.sub.irts] = [[alpha].sub.0s] + [[CHI].sub.its][[beta].sub.s] + [[delta].sub.ts] + [[delta].sub.rs] + [[member of].sub.irts].

Here [Y.sub.irts] represents some measure of utilization or spending by patient i in region r at time t and in sector s. The vector [CHI] includes the following demographic characteristics for each patient: age, age squared, sex, income, income squared, age and age squared interacted with sex, as well as dummy variables for each of the adverse health conditions listed above. The terms [[delta].sub.ts] and [[delta].sub.rs] are sector-specific fixed effects for year and MSA, respectively. The sector-specific variance in the fixed effect [[delta].sub.rs] is the regression-adjusted analogue to the variance in the MSA-level sample means.

As a general matter, the covariates have relatively little predictive power within MSAs but a fair amount between MSAs. Across all specifications, for instance, the MSA means of the covariates explain about 50 to 70 percent of the between-MSA variation in utilization and spending, in the sense of [R.sup.2].

II.D. Regional Variance in Utilization and Spending

Table 3 reports the estimated regional variance in four utilization measures: number of hospitalizations, number of hospital days, number of outpatient visits, and number of prescription drugs (in terms of 30-day-equivalents). Again, prescription drug coverage is provided by the private sector in both populations throughout the sample period, and therefore we do not expect to see similar differences for prescription drugs as for the other measures.

The table shows overall between-MSA variation in the public and the private sectors. The observed variation (first two columns) is computed as the average MSA-level deviation from the overall mean. The top panel reports the variation based on unconditional means; in the bottom panel, both the overall mean and each MSA-level mean are regression-adjusted, as described above. The corrected variation (second two columns) is computed by subtracting the expected bias due to sampling error, as described above. The next column shows the absolute difference between the public and private variances, and the last column the ratio of the variances. Asterisks indicate statistically significant differences from zero for the differences, and from unity for the ratios.

Variation in hospital days is about three times, and variation in outpatient visits about two times, higher in the public sector. These differences are statistically significant at the l0 percent level or higher and appear regardless of whether we adjust for covariates (although the magnitudes differ somewhat). On the other hand, prescription drug utilization exhibits statistically less variation in the Medicare population; this is important because, again, even Medicare patients obtain their prescription drug insurance privately in our sample. Finally, there is no statistically significant difference in the variation for hospitalizations. It is likely that more statistical power is needed to pin down this variance, in one direction or the other. Overall, these results provide evidence suggesting higher variance in the public sector, but for a few of the outcomes our statistical tests lack the power to generate definitive results.

Table 4 reports the estimated regional variance in four spending measures: total spending, inpatient spending, outpatient spending, and prescription drug spending. The regression-adjusted estimates indicate that outpatient spending exhibits only about 35 percent as much variation in the public sector as in the private sector. Inpatient spending exhibits roughly equal variation in the two sectors. Finally, prescription drug spending varies less for Medicare patients. With that exception, these results are quite different from the utilization results and suggest that price restraints play a role in the public sector. In spite of greater variation in utilization, the public sector exhibits less variation in spending.

III. Comparisons with Existing Literature

Regional variation in spending and utilization in the public sector has been well documented in a literature that is almost 40 years old and well accepted by the academic community. In that sense, our contribution is to compare this with variation in the private sector, rather than to establish the existence of public sector variation.

Table 5 summarizes a few representative papers from this vast literature. (14) John Wennberg and Alan Gittelsohn (1973) provide an early example. Their study analyzed variation across "hospital service areas," a precursor to the HRRs typically analyzed in the modern Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care studies. The table also lists a couple of important studies that use states or MSAs. It is important to recognize this difference when comparing our MSA-level analysis with HRR-level analyses elsewhere, and it is important for future work to assess the potential implications of this difference.

The 2008 Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care reports that average spending on health care in the last 2 years of life (for deaths occurring from 2001 to 2005) ranged from a high of $59,379 in New Jersey to $32,523 in North Dakota (Wennberg and others 2008). This range, from 28 percent above to 30 percent below the national average, is similar to the range of quantity utilization reported across MSAs by MedPac: from 39 percent above the national average in Miami to 25 percent below in rural Hawaii (Medicare Payment Advisory Commission 2009).

These variations are not fully explained by factors such as age, insurance coverage, average income, and rates of illness or disease. David Cutler and Louise Sheiner (1999) investigate the extent to which variation in spending across HRRs can be explained by regional differences in illness, in the demand for health (for example, as measured by income and race), or in "exogenous differences in the structure of medical care markets" (for example, in the ratio of generalists to specialists). They find that regional demographics can explain about 70 percent of the variation in medical spending across regions, but the unexplained variation remains large. For example, when differences in demographics and the illness of the population are accounted for, bringing Medicare spending down to the level of the 10th-percentile region would reduce total spending by 15 percent.

Perhaps the existing study most closely related to ours is that of Michael Chernew and others (2010), who compare HRR-level variations in Medicare against those in a sample of large firms in the Thomson Reuters (Medstat) MarketScan Commercial Claims and Encounters Database. They estimate that the geographic variation in private sector spending is greater than that in Medicare spending (coefficient of variation of 0.21 versus 0.16). This is consistent with our findings for spending. They focus less on variation in utilization, although they do report a positive correlation between Medicare and non-Medicare inpatient days.

IV. Limitations of Our Analysis

There are several empirical questions that our data cannot address but that should be addressed in future work. The populations of privately insured and publicly insured patients differ, because the latter have often opted out of private health insurance options. The empirical implications of this are not clear a priori. Fee-for-service Medicare patients are likely to be sicker than their counterparts in private Medicare health maintenance organizations (HMOs), because HMOs attempt to select healthier patients (Morgan and others 1997). On the other hand, the privately insured nonelderly may also be healthier than the nonelderly overall, if private health insurers select against the sickest patients for similar reasons. The link between health insurance and employment in the nonelderly population adds further complexity, as those who are eligible for employment-based health insurance may be richer or healthier, or both, than their peers. Finally, the fact that our private sector data are based only on employees of large (Fortune 500) firms adds a further dimension of selection.

We ran several supplementary analyses to investigate some of these issues, but our data lack the power to reach definitive conclusions across the board. First, we narrowed the age range of our comparisons, to mitigate some of the differences in health status. We compared 60- to 64-year-olds in the commercially insured population with 66- to 70-year-olds in the fee-for-service Medicare population. As this restriction further reduces the sample, we limit our analysis to the 70 MSAs for which we have at least 25 observations in both samples.

Table 6 reports the result for the samples with the narrow age ranges. Generally, the point estimates based on these restricted age ranges are similar to those based on the full sample, but the precision of the estimates declines enough to eliminate statistical significance. The point estimates indicate that variation in the public sector is about 5.1, 3.4, and 1.2 times that in the private sector for hospital days, outpatient visits, and hospitalizations, respectively. As in the analysis based on the full sample, variation in prescription drug use is smaller in the public sector, about 53 percent as large as variation in the private sector.

Next we investigated the issue of selection based on employment by comparing our privately insured sample with Medicare patients who also have coverage from an employer. If an individual has such coverage, we know that he or she was employed and privately insured at one point.

Roughly 35 percent of Medicare enrollees in our sample also have employer-provided coverage. They are slightly younger (averaging 77 years, compared with 79 years for those without such coverage), richer (average income is 58 percent higher), and more likely to be male (52 percent versus 40 percent) than the average Medicare enrollee. Having employer coverage is associated with very small differences in the fraction of total expenses paid for by Medicare: Medicare pays 39 percent of the expenses of those without employer coverage and 38 percent of those with such coverage. The lack of a disparity is due to the fact that once an elderly Medicare beneficiary retires, the employer-provided coverage becomes secondary to Medicare. In our data just 9 percent of individuals in the Medicare sample with employer coverage are working, so for the vast majority Medicare is the primary payer. It thus seems reasonable to assume that Medicare is the primary driver of resource allocation for these individuals. A number of MSAs are left with very small samples after this restriction, so we limit our analysis to the 77 MSAs where we have at least 50 observations in both samples.

These results are presented in table 7. Again, the point estimates are similar to those based on the full sample, but the precision of the estimates declines enough to eliminate much of the statistical significance. The point estimates indicate that variation in the public sector is about 4.1, 3.8, and 1.6 times that in the private sector for hospital days, outpatient visits, and hospitalizations, respectively. The greater variation in outpatient visits in the public sample is statistically significant at the 1 percent level. The other differences are not significant at the 10 percent level. Variation in prescription drug use is slightly lower in the public sector, about 93 percent as large as in the private sector.

V. Concluding Remarks

It has long been recognized that public and private enterprises face different incentives to control costs. This paper has analyzed these differences in the health insurance context, along with their implications for variation in care. Public payers are likely able to restrain prices better than private payers but have weaker incentives to control costs through utilization controls. As a result, one might expect greater variation in utilization for the public sector, but the effects on total spending are ambiguous. Using samples of heart disease patients, we presented empirical evidence consistent with these implications.

Further research should focus more closely on the issue of whether and to what extent variations across sectors are the result of differences in the baseline health of the publicly and privately insured populations. Work is also needed to assess whether our basic findings can be generalized across other disease categories and geographical classifications. In addition, the analysis of health outcomes must be integrated into the analyses of utilization and of spending. As a related point, although we have focused on estimated variations, further research should be conducted into the sources of the mean differences in utilization and spending. Finally, and perhaps most important, research is needed to draw out the normative implications of variations in care both within and between sectors.

The normative implications of variation in care are not straightforward, in spite of the conventional wisdom that greater variation implies inefficiency. On the one hand, the literature has consistently found that areas exhibiting higher utilization of health care services do not exhibit demonstrably better outcomes for patients (Fisher and others 2003a). This has led many to conclude that these areas are practicing "flat-of-the-curve" medicine, where the marginal benefit approaches zero. However, Amitabh Chandra and Douglas Staiger (20071 demonstrate that productivity spillovers and specialization can explain regional variation in the utilization of intensive procedures, without resorting to inefficiency. Most notably, their model can reconcile the seemingly contradictory evidence that intensive treatments such as most surgery are often highly effective at the individual level, but that regions using these treatments more intensively do not have better average health outcomes. Chandra and Staiger observe that regions specializing in intensive treatment will find it optimal to provide that treatment to more patients; therefore, the marginal patient in such regions will be less suited to it than the marginal patient elsewhere. This mitigates the greater benefits of intensive treatment.

For this and other reasons, the efficiency implications of variation in care require a more careful analysis. Even in our simple framework, the normative impact of variation is unclear. For instance, if the private sector is pricing and producing efficiently, then the theory suggests that the public sector is engaging in inefficiently high utilization and inefficiently low pricing. On the other hand, if private sector prices are too high or if utilization is too low, then the effects of public insurance may actually represent second-best improvements to welfare. Evidently, it is important to investigate the baseline efficiency properties of the private health insurance market and to characterize how these are affected by the presence of publicly financed health insurance.

Regardless of the conclusions, normative analysis of this issue will likely generate a number of important policy implications. Many have noted that Medicare has lower administrative costs than the private sector. This is often interpreted as part of the value generated by centralized insurance. This is a typical finding when one is comparing a centralized with a decentralized model, but it could also be explained by the cost of administering utilization controls in the private sector. If so, any efficiency benefits of utilization controls would need to be weighed against these administrative costs. The benefits generated by administrative costs are often neglected in the policy debate, as are related issues such as the deadweight costs of the tax revenue required to fund public enterprise, the efficiency gains of marketing activities by private firms, and higher rates of fraud in the public Medicare system. The last of these is directly related to lax utilization controls. A fuller analysis of the costs and benefits of public versus private health insurance is needed.

The relative merits of public enterprise have a number of policy implications. The first concerns the appropriate size of Medicare Advantage, which operates through publicly provided premium subsidies to private HMOs. Medicare Advantage plans are not directly comparable to private payers, because they compete on quality rather than price, as long as there is no price competition through competitive bidding for plan members. Thus differences in incentives for utilization control operate through the need to enhance quality, subject to available premium resources, or result from residual claims on profits. Future research needs to investigate more carefully the differences and similarities in cost-control measures from this type of coverage and their effects on regional variations and efficiency.

The second implication regards the timely issue of comparative effectiveness research (CER), which has been offered as a means of raising health care quality and reducing costs. The rationale for CER is to generate better evidence, and to disseminate it to patients, payers, and providers, about what works and does not work in health care. Indeed, a common motivation for the use of CER is to reduce cost inefficiencies due to regional differences in care. Awareness of CER has been heightened recently by its significant public subsidization through the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009. (15) An overriding question raised by our analysis is whether regional variation in care occurs because of a lack of information or a lack of incentives for utilization control in the public sector.

Health economists have not yet paid sufficient attention to the differences in incentives across the public and the private sectors or to the corresponding implications for health care variation. The regional variations documented in the Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care have led several prominent researchers to conclude that high-use regions ought to model themselves after their low-use peers (Fisher, Bynum, and Skinner 2009). Our study suggests the importance of research focusing on another, different question: whether or not public sector health insurers ought to model themselves after their peers in the private sector.

APPENDIX

Sampling Error in Estimation of Regional Variation In the text we outlined our approach for obtaining a consistent estimate of regional variation, defined as

RV [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1] [([[mu].sub.r] - [??]).sup.2]

In this appendix we show how we solve for the bias in the sample analogue, [??] [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1] [([[mu].sub.r] - [??]).sup.2], and estimate it consistently using the variance covariance matrix of the estimates. Recall the definitions from the text: [[mu].sub.r] is the true population fixed-effect parameter for region r, [[??].sub.r]. is the corresponding sample estimate, and [z.sub.r] is a mean-zero sampling error with covariance across regions E([z.sub.r] [z.sub.s]) = [[sigma].sub.rs]. The sample estimate is the true value plus sampling error,

[??] = [[mu].sub.r] + [z.sub.r].

Define [??] [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1] [([[mu].sub.r], the mean regional fixed effect across regions; [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII], its sample analogue; and [bar.z] [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1] [z.sub.r], the average sampling error across regions.

Using the definitions above, we can write

[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],

where we rely on the fact that we are dealing with regional fixed effects, rather than random effects, to move the expectations operator inside the summation. Expanding the right-hand side of the expression results in

E([??]) = [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][E[([[mu].sub.r] - [??]).sup.2]].

Since [[mu].sub.r], and [??] are both scalars, this simplifies to

E([??]) = [equivalent to] 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1][([[mu].sub.r] - [??]).sup.2] - 2([[mu].sub.r] - [??])E ([z.sub.r] - [??]) + E[([z.sub.r] - [??]).sup.2]].

The distributional assumptions on z imply that E([z.sub.r]) = E([??]) = 0. Therefore, we can write

E([??]) = RV + 1/R [[summation].sup.R.sub.r=1]E[([z.sub.r] - [??]).sup.2].

To characterize the bias, note that

E[([z.sub.r] - [??]).sup.2] = E([z.sup.2.sub.r]) - 2E([z.sub.r] 1/R [R.summation over s=1] [z.sub.s]) + E[(1/R [R.summation over s=1] [z.sub.s]).sup.2],

which we can write in terms of the variance and covariance parameters as

E[([z.sub.r] - [??]).sup.2] = [[sigma].sub.rr] - 2/R [R.summation over s=1] [[sigma.sub.rs] + 1/[R.sup.2] [R.summation over s=1] [R.summation over t=1] [[sigma].sub.st].

The bias due to sampling variance is equal to the above expression, averaged across all regions. A consistent estimate of the bias can be calculated by summing up and taking the appropriate averages of estimated variances of and covariances between the estimated regional fixed effects. The more precisely the regional fixed effects are estimated, the smaller is the bias correction.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We thank the editors, David Cutler, Mark McClellan, and seminar participants at the University of Chicago, RAND, and the Brookings Institution for comments. Financial support from the George Stigler Center for the Economy and the State at the University of Chicago, the Leonard Schaeffer Center for Health Economics and Policy at the University of Southern California, and Pfizer Inc. is gratefully acknowledged.

References

Alchian, Armen A., and Harold Demsetz. 1972. "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization." American Economic Review 62, no. 5: 777-95.

Baicker, Katherine, Elliott S. Fisher, and Amitabh Chandra. 2007. "Malpractice Liability and the Practice of Medicine in the Medicare Program." Health Affairs 26, no. 3: 841-52.

Chandra, Amitabh, and Douglas O. Staiger. 2007. "Productivity Spillovers in Health Care: Evidence from the Treatment of Heart Attacks." Journal of Political Economy 115, no. 1: 103--40.

Chernew, Michael E., and others. 2010. "Geographic Correlation between LargeFirm Commercial Spending and Medicare Spending." American Journal of Managed Care 16, no. 2: 131-38.

Christensen, Sandra, and Judith Wagner. 2000. "'The Costs of a Medicare Prescription Drug Benefit." Health Affairs (Millwood) 19, no. 2: 212-18.

Cutler, David M., and Louise Sheiner. 1999. "The Geography of Medicare." American Economic Review 89, no. 2: 228-233.

De Alessi, Louis. 1974a. "An Economic Analysis of Government Ownership and Regulation: Theory and the Evidence from the Electric Power Industry." Public Choice 19: 1-42.

--. 1974b. "Managerial Tenure under Private and Government Ownership in the Electric Power Industry." Journal of Political Economy 82, no. 3: 645-53.

Drummond, Michael, and others. 1993. "Economic Evaluation of Pharmaceuticals: A European Perspective." Pharmacoeconomics 4, no. 3:173-86.

--. 1999. "Current Trends in the Use of Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes Research in Europe." Value in Health 2, no. 5: 323-32.

Eppig, Franklin J., and George S. Chulis. 1997. "Matching MCBS (Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey) and Medicare Data: The Best of Both Worlds." Health Care Financing Review 18, no. 3:211-29.

Fisher, Elliott S., Julie P. Bynum, and Jonthan S. Skinner. 2009. "Slowing the Growth of Health Care Costs--Lessons from Regional Variation." New England Journal of Medicine 360, no. 9: 849-52.

Fisher, E. S., and others. 2003a. "The Implications of Regional Variations in Medicare Spending. Part 1: The Content, Quality, and Accessibility of Care."

Annals of Internal Medicine 138, no. 4: 273-87. --. 2003b. "The Implications of Regional Variations in Medicare Spending. Part 2: Health Outcomes and Satisfaction with Care." Annals of Internal Medicine 138, no. 4: 288-99.

Fowler, Floyd J., and others. 2008. "Relationship between Regional per Capita Medicare Expenditures and Patient Perceptions of Quality of Care." JAMA 299, no. 20: 2406-12.

Gottlieb, Daniel J., and others. 2010. "Prices Don't Drive Regional Medicare Spending Variations." Health Affairs 29, no. 3: 537-43.

Kessler, Daniel, and Mark McClellan. 1996. "Do Doctors Practice Defensive Medicine?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, no. 2: 353-90.

--. 2002a. "Malpractice Law and Health Care Reform: Optimal Liability Policy in an Era of Managed Care." Journal of Public Economics 84, no. 2: 175-97.

--. 2002b. "How Liability Law Affects Medical Productivity." Journal of Health Economics 21, no. 6:931-55.

Medicare Payment Advisory Commission. 2009. "Measuring Regional Variation in Service Use." Washington.

Morgan, Robert O., and others. 1997. "The Medicare-HMO Revolving Door-The Healthy Go In and the Sick Go Out." New England Journal of Medicine 337, no. 3: 169-75.

Phelps, Charles E. 2000. "Information Diffusion and Best Practice Adoption." In Hundbook of Health Economics. vol. 1A, edited by Anthony J. Culyer and Joseph P. Newhouse. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science.

Rettenmaier, Andrew J., and Thomas R. Saving. 2009. "Perspectives on the Geographic Variation in Health Care Spending." Special Publication. Washington: National Center for Policy Analysis (June).

Sampford, M.R. 1953. "Some Inequalities on Mill's Ratio and Related Functions." Annals of Mathematical Statistics 24, no. 1: 130-32.

Sirovich, Brenda E., and others. 2006. "Regional Variations in Health Care Intensity and Physician Perceptions of Quality of Care." Annals of Internal Medicine 144, no. 9: 641--49.

Spann, Robert M. 1977. "The Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth and the Expanding Public Sector: Some Simple Tests of a Model of Government Growth." Journal of Public Economics 8, no. 3: 397-404.

Sutherland, Jason M., Elliott S. Fisher, and Jonathan S. Skinner. 2009. "Getting Past Denial--The High Cost of Health Care in the United States." New England Journal of Medicine 361, no. 13:1227-30.

Wennberg, John, and Alan Gittelsohn. 1973. "Small Area Variations in Health Care Delivery." Science 182, no. 4117:1102-08.

Wennberg, John E., and Megan McAndrew Cooper, eds. 1998. Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care, 1998. Chicago: Dartmouth Medical School and American Hospital Association.

Wennberg, John E., and others. 2008. Tracking the Care of Patients with Severe Chronic Illness: The Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care 2008. Lebanon, N.H.: Dartmouth Institute for Health Policy and Clinical Practice.

TOMAS J. PHILIPSON

University of Chicago

SETH A. SEABURY

RAND Corporation

LEE M. LOCKWOOD

University of Chicago

DANA P. GOLDMAN

University of Southern California

DARIUS N. LAKDAWALLA

university of Southern California

(1.) The main data source used to document regional variations is the Dartmouth Atlas of Health Care, which can be found at www.dartmouthatlas.org/(accessed January 15, 2010).

(2.) Alchian and Demsetz (1972) showed a greater incentive for shirking and inefficiency in public enterprise, where managers' and employees' own standards of living are unaffected by poor performance. De Alessi ( 1974a, 1974b) observed that inefficient private firms disappear, whereas inefficient public firms can last for long periods. Spann (1977) argued that private firms typically produce similar goods and services at much lower cost than their public counterparts.

(3.) This analysis is general enough to include several possible sources of regional differences, and in particular it allows for such differences to be efficient. However, differences in liability (Kessler and McClellan 1996, 2002a, 2002b, Baicker and Chandra 2007) or productivity (Chandra and Staiger 2007), for example, may imply differences in efficient levels of care.

(4.) Imperfect UR has qualitatively similar theoretical implications. The difference is one of degree rather than nature.

5. We use the fact that the derivative of the inverse Mills ratio with respect to [alpha] is strictly between zero and l, [lambda]'([alpha]) [member of] (0,1). (Sampford 1953).

(6.) Our proxy for income is median household income at the 3-digit zip code level; this is taken from the 2000 Census.

(7.) When estimating the cost of Medicare Part D (for example), the Congressional Budget Office scaled the reported MCBS prescription drug spending up by 33 percent for the noninstitutionalized population (Christensen and Wagner 2000).

(8.) Also called myocardial ischemia, IHD is characterized as reduced blood flow to the heart. In the private data we identify patients with IHD as those with at least one inpatient or outpatient claim with a primary diagnosis ICD-9 code of 410.xx, 411.xx, 412.xx, 413.xx, or 414.xx. In the public data we identify patients based on self-reports of ever diagnosed with heart disease. See the online data appendix (available on the Brookings Papers webpage at www.brookings.edu/economics/bpea.aspx, under "Conferences and Papers") for more information.

(9.) The specific conditions considered are essential hypertension, congestive heart failure, diabetes, asthma, hypercholesterolemia, ulcer, depression, chronic obstructive pulmonary disease, allergic rhinitis, migraine, arthritis, chronic sinusitis, anxiety disorder, cardiac disease, vascular disease, epilepsy, gastric acid disorder, glaucoma, gout, hyperlipidemia, irritable bowel syndrome, malignancy, psychotic illness, thyroid disorder, rheumatoid arthritis, tuberculosis, angina, human immunodeficiency virus infection, anemia, and stroke. Most co-morbidities are relatively uncommon, except for the ones involving heart disease (or risk lactors for heart disease).

(10.) The MCBS also contains self-reports of a number of distinct health conditions, as well as the individual's self-reported general health status (coded 1 to 5, with 1 indicating poor and 5 indicating excellent). Out regression analysis relies on the claims-based, rather than self-reported, disease measures for both the public and the private samples. More details appear in our online data appendix.

(11.) See the footnotes to tables 1 and 2 for a few sample size issues specific to certain variables.

(12.) The alternative block-bootstrap that samples MSAs with replacement generates nearly identical inferences for statistical significance in our analysis, and so does a "'flat" bootstrap.

(13.) A possible alternative is a random-effects model, but the Hausman test rejected this more efficient model in favor of the fixed-effects model in the majority of cases we analyzed.

(14.) For useful summaries from both the economic and the clinical literatures on geographic variation in health care, see Wennberg and Cooper (1998), Phelps (2000), Fisher and others (2003a, 2003b), Chandra and Staiger (2007) and Sutherland. Fisher, and Skinner (2009).

(15.) The explicit use of comparative effectiveness assessments is much more common outside the United States, particularly in the European Union. However, this is a relatively recent trend: no European countries formally required economic assessments for pricing and reimbursement decisions as of 1993. but a majority had such a policy either in place or in development by 1999 (Drummond and others 1993, 1999).

Comment and Discussion

COMMENT BY

DAVID M. CUTLER The issue of geographic variation in medical care spending played an important role in the recent health care reform debate. Supporters of reform cited the wide variation in spending across U.S. regions as evidence that care is inefficiently provided. According to a widely cited analysis by Elliott Fisher and others (2003), "If the United States as a whole could safely achieve spending levels comparable to those of the lowest-spending regions, annual savings of up to 30% of Medicare expenditures could be achieved." One-third of the nation's medical spending amounts to over $700 billion annually--a huge savings.

Few dispute that health care is characterized by significant inefficiency, but how best to limit that inefficiency is a subject of great debate. Broadly speaking, there are two approaches. The first is to use consumer demand to limit wasteful care. In this approach, informed, incentivized consumers would shop for efficient care just as they do for other products. Private insurers responding to this demand would then squeeze out excessive spending. The main barriers to this favorable competition, proponents argue, are the tax subsidy favoring the purchase of more generous insurance by employers in the private sector, and the lack of good stewardship of Medicare and Medicaid in the public sector. In the latter category, the biggest issue is the absence of a profit incentive to manage care for the bulk of Medicare and Medicaid enrollees.

The second approach focuses on the supply side. Here the key issue is how physicians and hospitals are paid for treating people. Doctors are reimbursed more for providing more care, but not for providing higher-quality care or limiting the need for care in the first place. Thus surgeons are paid for performing operations, but primary care physicians are not paid for the management involved in preventing surgery. Care will exceed the optimum because quantity is favored over quality.

These two theories have very different implications for health care reform. In the demand-side view, competition among insurers is the ideal, and private markets are preferred to public programs. Thus Medicare would do better to encourage entry by private plans than to focus on improving the fee-for-service system. In the supply-side view, the key is changing the financial incentives for providers. This is best accomplished by reforming the payment system in the traditional Medicare program, and working to spread that change throughout the health care system. Thus encouraging more private plans would not be a helpful step for Medicare, and might be harmful.

This paper by Tomas Philipson and his colleagues is directed at this debate. The idea behind the paper is to examine whether private insurers do a better job at limiting health care utilization than Medicare does. Evidence that private plans are better at rationing care would support the demand-side view of reform. The test that the authors propose is to look at the variability of care across a sample of metropolitan statistical areas. If private plans are better at eliminating excessive care, they should have lower spending in metropolitan areas where care is otherwise overprovided--defined in the paper as areas where Medicare fee-for-service costs are higher. Analytically, this would show up as lower variance of health care utilization across areas in the private sector.

Philipson and his coauthors test this hypothesis using data on patients with ischemic heart disease, a condition that bridges the over- and under-65 populations. They reach two conclusions. First, they show that the variation in two measures of utilization--the number of hospital days and outpatient visits--is indeed greater in Medicare than in private insurance. For both measures, the standard deviation across areas in Medicare is three times that across areas in private insurance. Interestingly, the average number of hospital stays per patient is not more variable in Medicare; rather, it is the average length of stay (hospital days) that is more variable. Private insurers seem better at getting people out of the hospital sooner.

In contrast, however, spending is much less variable across areas than is utilization. Areas with low private sector utilization have higher private sector prices than areas with higher utilization. This is not true in Medicare, where prices are set nationally.

Whether one concludes from these findings that the public or the private sector is more efficient depends on whether one puts more weight on utilization or on spending. Since greater utilization has a real resource cost, whereas higher prices paid for given resources are just a transfer (if one excludes the deadweight loss of raising tax revenue to support the public programs), one might imagine that lower utilization at higher prices is preferable to higher utilization at lower prices. This logic favors the private sector. On the other hand, the additional care that people receive in Medicare is not necessarily wasteful. If the added care in the public sector has high marginal value, more care received at lower prices would be preferred to less care at higher prices, and Medicare would be judged superior.

A priori, it is not clear whether the additional care provided in high-utilization areas is worth the cost. If health care obeyed standard market theory, the care that well-informed patients facing price incentives decide not to purchase (either when the care is offered, or earlier, when they choose a less generous insurance plan) would be the care that is least valued. But patients are not always sure about what care they need, and providers have imperfect incentives to fully inform them. Thus one natural extension of the paper would be to compare health outcomes in the public and private sector, to see whether patients get care of real value. The data that Philipson and his coauthors employ do not include ideal measures of outcomes, but some outcome assessment is possible: for example, one could examine the rate at which patients in the sample are later admitted to a hospital with cardiac complications.

There is also an obvious alternative explanation for the greater geographic variance of utilization in Medicare than in private insurance: health status may vary more in the Medicare population than in the privately insured population. To control for this variation, Philipson and coauthors perform a variety of risk adjustments. Having already limited the sample to people with ischemic heart disease, they further control for other conditions that those patients may have. But these adjustments are imperfect, as any risk adjustment is.

The reason to suspect that greater variation in health status in the Medicare population is important is that the reduction in variation in the private sector occurs at both the top and the bottom end of the utilization distribution. The theory that the authors put forward is that private insurers should ration care more when underlying utilization is higher. Thus private sector utilization should be disproportionately lower in high-use areas. That is the point of figure 2 in the paper. In contrast, however, their figure 3 shows a uniform reduction in the standard deviation of care in the private sector. That is, high-utilization areas are less far above the mean in private insurance, but low-utilization areas are less far below the mean. The reason why care in low-utilization areas would be greater in the private sector is not clear. One might imagine that providers are skimping on the Medicare population in low-utilization areas, and that private insurers encourage more care than providers would otherwise prescribe. But the analysis by Fisher and his coauthors does not suggest significant under-use of care in the low-spending Medicare areas, nor do patients report themselves less satisfied in those areas. Given the approximately proportional reduction in variation in the private sector compared with Medicare, it seems that a theory of variation in underlying health status garners at least as much support as a theory of efficient rationing.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

This conclusion is buttressed by a consideration of aggregate differences between Medicare and private insurance. An analysis of aggregate spending data does not suggest any superiority of private insurers in limiting cost increases over time. My figure 1 shows annual data on growth of real Medicare spending per beneficiary and private insurance premiums per enrollee. In each case the spending measure is limited to a common set of benefits, including hospital inpatient and outpatient care and physician services. The two series generally mirror each other. Cost growth was high in the 1980s, low in the 1990s, and resurgent in the 2000s. Overall, cost increases were greater in the private sector (averaging 4.9 percent per year) than in Medicare (3.7 percent).

A few anomalies in the pattern are of interest. Private insurance premiums rose more rapidly than Medicare spending in the 1980s, when prospective payment was introduced in the public sector. The managed care era of the 1990s saw moderately slower cost growth in the private sector than in Medicare. Managed care used the type of utilization restrictions that Philipson and his coauthors argue are effective.

But a good share of these utilization controls were reversed in the 2000s, when a backlash against managed care caused insurers to change their practices. Requirements for prior authorization were substantially weakened, and financial incentives for providers to perform less care were loosened. Further, providers responded to the presence of managed care by merging, and this led to higher prices in the private sector, where prices are flexible. The result was a decade of much higher private sector cost increases than Medicare cost increases.

The data that Philipson and coauthors analyze are from the 2000s. Figure 1 shows the peculiarity of the case that they make. They argue for the superiority of private utilization controls using data from a time when private sector controls on utilization were falling and costs were rising rapidly. It may be that people were wrong to reject the managed care strictures of the 1990s, and that a return to those practices would be beneficial. But few people argue that the version of managed care that prevailed in the 2000s is a sustainable model.

In the recent health care reform debate, the conclusion that public and private insurance were relatively similar in cost growth was more commonly accepted than the argument that private insurers were superior in reducing excess utilization. Added to this was the sense that private insurers engaged in significant and costly risk selection, wasting money and making insurance difficult to obtain. Thus, regulating private insurers to limit risk selection is a significant element of the recently enacted Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act (PPACA), whereas opening up new markets in Medicare for private insurers is not. Indeed, the act reduces Medicare payments to private insurers. In its place are a series of pilot programs and demonstration projects aimed at reforming the incentives in the existing fee-for-service program.

Whether the strategy underlying the PPACA is the right one or not will be determined in the next few years. If reform fails, it may be because private insurers were strangled too tightly. If so, this paper may point the way to a future reform. But for now we are likely to see tighter restrictions on private insurance before any significant new utilization controls.

REFERENCE FOR THE CUTLER COMMENT

Fisher, Elliott S., David E. Wennberg, Therese A. Stukel, Daniel J. Gottlieb, F. L. Lucas, and Etoile L. Pinder. 2003. "The Implications of Regional Variations in Medicare Spending. Part 2: Health Outcomes and Satisfaction with Care." Annals of Internal Medicine 138: 288-98.

GENERAL DISCUSSION Christopher Sims raised the question of how secondary private insurance fits into the classification of public versus private. Many Medicare beneficiaries have supplementary coverage, and whether an individual has it or not could affect his or her utilization choices. If there is regional variation in the share or beneficiaries using Medicare supplements, it could be affecting the paper's results.

Daniel Sacks asked whether the privately covered individuals in the sample were truly representative of people with private coverage generally. If the sample is drawn from Fortune 500 companies only, their health insurance plans may be better than the average private plan and have better, or at least different, cost management. He also wondered what incentives the executives of both public and private insurance plans actually face and whether they are as different as the paper assumes.

David Romer observed that the theory laid out in the paper makes a clear prediction of where the expected change in the distribution of fixed effects ought to appear: The incentives facing the private sector should lead to compression of the upper tail of the distribution in that sample but not the lower tail, yet no such pattern is visible in the data.
Table 1. Selected Patient Demographic and Health Characteristics (a)

                                         Private

                                            Standard
Patient characteristic               Mean   deviation

Age                                  55.4      7.1
Percent male                         65       48
Income (thousands of 2004 dollars)   42.8     10.8
Percent with heart disease in year   32       47
No. of adverse health conditions      1.4      1.4

                                         Public

                                            Standard
Patient characteristic               Mean   deviation

Age                                  78.2       7.9
Percent male                         46        50
Income (thousands of 2004 dollars)   28.5      46.8
Percent with heart disease in year   37        48
No. of adverse health conditions      2.9       2.4

Sources: Data on private patients come from a modified version
of the Ingenix Touchstone product. Data on public patients come
from the MCBS.

(a.) History of heart disease is self-reported in the public
sample and identified using medical claims in the private
sample. The private sample has 240,028 observations and the
public sample 24,800 observations.

Table 2. Distributions of Spending and Utilization Measures (a)

                                           Standard       25th
Measure                  Sample    Mean    deviation   percentile

Utilization (number per patient per year)

Hospitalizations         Private    0.36    1.15          0
                         Public     0.57    1.14          0
Hospital days            Private    1.23    7.13          0
                         Public     2.93    8.59          0
Outpatient visits        Private   -5.56    5.86          1
                         Public"    8.59   11.05          1
Drug prescriptions 'c)   Private   45.78   42.20         13
                         Public    35.45   29.93         14

Spending (thousands of 2004 dollars)

Total spending           Private    8.40   22.98          0.56
                         Public    10.25   18.8           1.25
Inpatient spending       Private    4.02   18.36          0
                         Public     4.94   13.21          0
Outpatient spending      Private    4.38    9.83          0.54
                         Public     5.30    9.14          1.13
Prescription drug        Private    2.80    5.78          0.53
  spending 'c)           Public     1.92    2.05          0.58

                                     75th
Measure                  Median   percentile

Utilization (number per patient per year)

Hospitalizations          0            0
                          0            1
Hospital days             0            0
                          0            1
Outpatient visits         4            8
                          5           12
Drug prescriptions 'c)   36           66
                         29           50

Spending (thousands of 2004 dollar

Total spending            2.10         6.88
                          3.91        11.4
Inpatient spending        0            0
                          0            4.65
Outpatient spending       1.85         4.86
                          2.94         6.44
Prescription drug         1.67         3.42
  spending 'c)            1.39         2.63

Source: Authors' calculations.

a. Figures are yearly averages during 2000-06 (2000-05 for drug
prescriptions) for patients with a history of heart disease,
which is self-reported in the public sample and identified using
medical claims in the private sample. Except where noted
otherwise, the private sample has 240.028 observations and the
public sample 24.800 observations.

b. Survey responses (used to cross-validate the claims data)
were incomplete in 3,769 cases, so that the public sample has
21,031 observations.

(c.) Because observations from 2006 are omitted, the private sample
has 231,802 observations and the public sample 21,140 observations.
Number of prescriptions is in terms of 30-day-equivalents.

Table 3. Regional Variation in Mean Utilization (a)

                                    Observed          Corrected
                                  variation (b)      variation (c)

Utilization measure             Private   Public   Private   Public

Unconditional means

Hospitalizations                0.013     0.015    0.012     0.009

Hospital days                   0.322     1.016    0.230     0.659

Outpatient visits               1.736     5.154    1.676     4.585

Drug prescriptions (d)          72.746    32.758   70.090    28.403

Regression-adjusted means (e)

Hospitalizations                0.006     0.011    0.005     0.006

Hospital days                   0.169     0.610    0.080     0.313

Outpatient visits               0.988     3.255    0.942     2.677

Drug prescriptions (d)          29.190    25.856   27.086    21.131

                                Difference,
                                public to     Ratio of
                                  minus       public to
Utilization measure               private      private

Unconditional means

Hospitalizations                 -0.003       0.728
                                 (0.003)      (0.204)

Hospital days                     0.429 **    2.870 *
                                 (0.199)      (1.017)

Outpatient visits                 2.909 ***   2.735 ***
                                 (0.502)      (0.323)

Drug prescriptions (d)          -41.687 ***   0.405 ***
                                 (3.896)      (0.043)
Regression-adjusted means (e)

Hospitalizations                  0.001       1.266
                                 (0.002)      (0.430)

Hospital days                     0.233 *     3.907 *
                                 (0.124)      (1.684)

Outpatient visits                 1.735 ***   2.841 ***
                                 (0.322)      (0.379)

Drug prescriptions (d)           -5.955 *     0.780 **
                                 (3.130)      (0.106)
Source: Authors' calculations.

(a.) Numbers in parentheses are standard errors on the difference
between public and private variation or the ratio of public to private
variation and are bootstrapped within MSAs, separately for public and
private patients, with 200 bootstrap draws. For both sectors, then,
the number of patients in each region in each bootstrapped sample is
the same as the number of patients in the original sample. Asterisks
indicate differences statistically significantly different from zero
or ratios statistically significantly different from 1 at the *** 1
percent. ** 5 percent, and * 10 percent level.

(b.) Variance in the regional means or fixed effects of the
utilization variables.

(c.) Unbiased measure of the true variance in the regional means or
fixed effects corrected for sampling error, as described in the text
and the appendix. All differences and ratios are based on these
numbers.

(d.) 30-day-equivalents.

(e.) Estimates of regional fixed effects on each utilization variable
from a regression that includes as other independent variables year
fixed effects, quadratic specifications of patient age and income,
patient sex, sex interacted with age, and dummy variables for 30
separate types of disease.

Table 4. Regional Variation in Mean Spending (a)

                                    Observed            Corrected
                                  variation (b)       variation (c)

Spending measure                Private    Public   Private    Public

Unconditional means

Total medical spending          4.443      3.907    3.571      2.352

Inpatient spending              1.634      1.587    1.109      0.842

Outpatient spending             1.263      1.048    1.082      0.634

Prescription drug spending      0.418      0.144    0.377      0.124

Regression-adjusted means (d)

Total medical spending
                                2.890      2.782    2.111      1.463

Inpatient spending
                                1.186      1.357    0.698      0.695

Outpatient spending
                                0.924      0.628    0.758      0.265

Prescription drug spending
                                0.251      0.086    0.214      0.064

                                Difference,
                                public        Ratio
                                minus         public to
Spending measure                private       private

Unconditional means

Total medical spending
                                -1.219         0.659 *
                                (0.981)       (0.207)
Inpatient spending
                                -0.266         0.760
                                (0.416)       (0.247)
Outpatient spending
                                -0.447         0.586
                                (0.355)       (0.266)
Prescription drug spending
                                -0.253 ***     0.329 ***
                                (0.049)       (0.060)
Regression-adjusted means (d)

Total medical spending

                                -0.647         0.693
Inpatient spending              (0.728)       (0.258)

                                -0.004         0.995
Outpatient spending             (0.324)       (0.298)

                                -0.494 *       0.349 **
Prescription drug spending      (0.261)       (0.272)

                                -0.150 ***     0.300 ***
                                (0.043)       (0.082)

Source: Authors' calculations.

(a.) Spending is measured in 2004 dollars. Numbers in parentheses arc
standard errors on the difference between public and private variation
or the ratio of public to private variation and are bootstrapped
within MSAs, separately for public and private patients, with 2W
bootstrap draws. For both sectors, then, the number of patients in each
region in each bootstrapped sample is the same as the number of
patients in the original sample. Asterisks indicate differences
statistically significantly different from zero or ratios
statistically significantly different from 1 at the *** 1 percent,
** 5 percent, and * 10 percent level.

(b.) Variance in the regional means or fixed effects of the spending
variables.

(c.) Unbiased measure of the true variance in the regional means or
fixed effects corrected for sampling error, as detailed in the text
and the appendix. All differences and ratios are based on these
numbers.

(d.) Estimates of regional fixed effects on each spending variable
from a regression that includes as other independent variables year
fixed effects, quadratic specifications of patient age and income,
patient sex, sex interacted with age, and dummy variables for 30
separate types of disease.

Table 5. Key Findings on Variation in Regional Health Care Spending
Using Medicare Data (a)

                                    Geographic
Study                               aggregation   Summary

Wennberg and Gittelsohn (1973)      Hospital      Studied geographic
                                    service       variation in
                                    area          utilization and
                                                  spending in Vermont.

Cutler and Sheiner (1999)           HRR           Calculated share of
                                                  regional variation
                                                  in Medicare spending
                                                  attributable to
                                                  regional differences
                                                  in health and
                                                  demographics.

Fisher and others (2003x)           HRR           Compared patients
                                                  across regions
                                                  holding other
                                                  characteristics
                                                  constant.

Sirovich and others (2006)          MSA           Compared variation
                                                  in intensity of
                                                  treatment with
                                                  physician
                                                  perceptions of
                                                  quality of care.

Chandra and Staiger (2007)          HRR           Specified a model of
                                                  patient treatment
                                                  choice with
                                                  productivity
                                                  spillovers and
                                                  tested the model
                                                  using treatment
                                                  choices and health
                                                  outcomes of heart
                                                  attack patients.

Fowler and others (2008)            HRR           Used as a patient
                                                  survey to compare
                                                  local variation in
                                                  spending and
                                                  utilization with
                                                  patient perceptions
                                                  of quality.

Wennberg and others (2008)          HRR           Summarized
                                                  Darthmouth Atlas
                                                  findings on
                                                  geographic
                                                  variations in
                                                  Medicare spending
                                                  and their
                                                  implications.

Rettenmaier and Saving (2009)       State         Studied how state
                                                  rankings in medical
                                                  spending per capita
                                                  change when
                                                  different
                                                  definitions of
                                                  spending are used,
                                                  such as Medicare
                                                  only or total
                                                  spending by all
                                                  payers.

Sutherland, Fisher, and Skinner     HRR           Updated Dartmouth
(2009)                                            Atlas findings on
                                                  geographic variation
                                                  in Medicare spending
                                                  and their
                                                  implications.

Chernew and others (2010)           HRR           Compared HRR-level
                                                  variation in medical
                                                  spending between
                                                  Medicare and large
                                                  firms.

Gottlieb and others (2010)          HRR           Examined role of
                                                  Medicare prices in
                                                  driving geographic
                                                  variations in health
                                                  care.

Study                               Key findings

Wennberg and Gittelsohn (1973)      Found wide
                                    variations
                                    apparently due to
                                    differences in
                                    practice style
                                    rather than in
                                    population health.
                                    Hospital days in
                                    highest-use area
                                    were 1.5 times that
                                    in lowest.

Cutler and Sheiner (1999)           Regional differences
                                    in demographics can
                                    explain about 70
                                    percent of regional
                                    differences in
                                    Medicare spending.
                                    but significant
                                    differences remain
                                    unexplained.

Fisher and others (2003x)           Patients in higher-
                                    spending regions
                                    received
                                    approximately 60
                                    percent more care.
                                    The increased
                                    utilization mostly
                                    arose from more
                                    frequent physician
                                    visits.

Sirovich and others (2006)          Medicare spending
                                    per capita in
                                    highest intensity
                                    quintile was 1.58
                                    times that in
                                    lowest.

Chandra and Staiger (2007)          Patterns of which
                                    patients benefit and
                                    which lose from
                                    intensive medical
                                    care are consistent
                                    with productivity
                                    spillover model.

Fowler and others (2008)            Regional differences
                                    in spending were not
                                    systematically
                                    related to
                                    differences in
                                    patient perceptions
                                    of care quality.

Wennberg and others (2008)          Three states spent
                                    more than 20 percent
                                    above the national
                                    average of $46,412.
                                    Conversely, three
                                    states spent 25
                                    percent below the
                                    national average or
                                    less. Inter quartile
                                    ratio (75th
                                    percentile over
                                    25th) is 1.26 for
                                    HRRs.

Rettenmaier and Saving (2009)       Found a state-level
                                    correlation between
                                    Medicare spending
                                    and total spending
                                    of 0.21, and that
                                    variation in
                                    Medicare spending
                                    exceeds variation in
                                    private spending.

Sutherland, Fisher, and Skinner     Inpatient days per
(2009)                              beneficiary in
                                    highest cost
                                    quintile were 1.50
                                    times that in
                                    lowest; physician
                                    visits in highest
                                    cost quintile were
                                    1.36 times that in
                                    lowest.

Chernew and others (2010)           Found substantial
                                    regional variation
                                    in spending, greater
                                    for large firms than
                                    for Medicare
                                    (coefficient of
                                    variation 0.21 v.
                                    0.16). Correlation
                                    between private and
                                    public inpatient
                                    utilization was
                                    0.59.

Gottlieb and others (2010)          Prices explain a
                                    small portion of
                                    variation in
                                    spending. The 80th
                                    percentile of price-
                                    adjusted Medicare
                                    Part B spending was
                                    1.37 times the 20th
                                    percentile.

Sources: Literature cited.

(a.) HRR = hospital referral region; MSA = metropolitan statistical

area.

Table 6. Regional Variation in Regression-Adjusted Mean
Utilization, Patients Aged 60 to 70 (a)

                    Observed           Corrected
                    variation (b)      variation (c)
Utilization
measure             Private   Public   Private   Public

Hospitalizations     0.015     0.035    0.011     0.014

Hospital days        0.258     2.038    0.130     0.656

Outpatient visits    1.460     7.207    1.335     4.524

Prescriptions       52.869    47.198   46.741    24.765

                    Difference,    Ratio of
Utilization         public minus   public to
measure                private      private

Hospitalizations      0.003          1.244
                     (0.010)        (0.921)

Hospital days         0.526          5.060
                     (0.886)        (4.134)

Outpatient visits     3.190          3.390
                     (2.316)        (1.695)

Prescriptions       -21.975 **       0.530
                    (11.090)        (0.209)

Source: Authors' calculations.

(a.) The private sample is restricted to patients aged 60 to 64 and
the public sample to patients aged 66 to 70. Both samples are
restricted to include only the 70 MSAs with at least 25 observations
in both samples. The private sample has 67,414 observations and the
public sample 3,568 observations. Numbers in parentheses are
standard errors on the difference between public and private
variation or the ratio of public to private variation and are
bootstrapped within MSAs. and separately for public and private
patients, with 200 bootstrap draws. For both sectors, then, the
number of patients in each region in each boot strapped sample is
the same as the number of patients in the original sample. Asterisks
indicate differences statistically significantly different from
zero or ratios statistically significantly different from 1 at the
*** I percent, **5 percent, and * 10 percent level.

(b.) Variance in the regional means or fixed effects of the
utilization variables.

(c.) Unbiased measure of the true variance in the fixed effects
corrected for sampling error, as detailed in the text and the
appendix. All differences and ratios are based on these numbers.

Table 7. Regional Variation in Regression-Adjusted Mean Utilization,
Patients with Some Private, Employer-Provided Coverage (a)

                      Observed            Corrected
                    variation (b)       variation (c)
Utilization
measure             Private    Public   Private    Public

Hospitalizations     0.006      0.017    0.005      0.008

Hospital days        0.144      0.709    0.049      0.198

Outpatient visits    3.774      4.462    0.911      3.438

Prescriptions       28.982     34.778   26.885     25.107

                    Difference,
                      public        Ratio
Utilization            minus      public to
measure               private      Private

Hospitalizations     0.003         1.572
                    (0.004)       (0.984)

Hospital days        0.149         4.058
                    (0.240)       (3.861)

Outpatient visits    2.527 ***     3.774 ***
                    (0.518)       (0.614)

Prescriptions       -1.778         0.934
                    (6.032)       (0.213)

Source: Authors' calculations.

(a.) The public sample is restricted to patients who report at least
some form of private, employer provided insurance coverage. Both
samples are restricted to include only the 77 MSAs that have at
least 50 observations in both samples. The private sample has
202,202 observations and the public sample 8,416 observations.
Numbers in parentheses are standard errors on the difference between
public and pri vate variation or the ratio of public to private
variation and are bootstrapped within MSAs, and separately for
public and private patients. For both sectors, then, the number of
patients in each region in each bootstrapped sample is the same as
the number of patients in the original sample. Asterisks indicate
differences statistically significantly different from zero or
ratios statistically significantly different from 1 at the ***I
percent, **5 percent, and * 10 percent level.

(b.) Variance in the regional means or fixed effects of the
utilization variables.

(c.) Unbiased measure of the true variance in the fixed effects
corrected for sampling error. as detailed in the text and the
appendix. All differences and ratios are based on these numbers.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有