The minimum balance at risk: a proposal to mitigate the systemic risks posed by money market funds.
McCabe, Patrick E. ; Cipriani, Marco ; Holscher, Michael 等
V.B. Some Practical Issues for MBR Implementation
Although the focus of this paper is on the conceptual rationale for
an MBR, we discuss here some practical policy issues to help illustrate
how an MBR might be introduced. We also address some concerns that have
been raised about the effectiveness of an MBR.
SHOULD ALL MONEY FUNDS HAVE AN MBR? A number of commenters on the
FSOC's proposed recommendations for MMFs have suggested that
reforms for money funds should focus exclusively on prime MMFs, which,
as noted above, largely hold private debt securities (see, for example,
Investment Company Institute 2013, Rosengren 2013). (42) Prime funds do
appear to pose the most direct threats to financial stability. These
funds mostly provide financing to large global financial institutions
(Scharfstein 2012, Hanson and others 2012), and the run in 2008 was
focused on these funds.
Other types of MMFs also may be vulnerable to runs, however. The
portfolios of government and tax-exempt MMFs have credit and interest
rate risks, and each type has experienced strains in recent years. (43)
Nonetheless, the top priority for MMF reform probably should be shoring
up prime funds. Indeed, the FSOC's Alternative Two, which includes
an MBR, would exempt from the MBR requirement any MMFs that invest
primarily in Treasury securities (FSOC 2012b). (44)
WHAT OTHER ADJUSTMENTS TO SUBORDINATION RULES MIGHT BE POSSIBLE? As
noted in section II.C, the flexibility of the MBR concept allows a
variety of adjustments, such as an exemption of the first $50,000 of
redemptions from triggering subordination. Another adjustment would cap
the amount of an investor's balance that could be subordinated at a
fraction of her MBR. This adjustment could limit potentially extreme
outcomes if only a few investors redeem shares from a troubled MMF, and
although it would reduce the effectiveness of an MBR of a given size,
the MBR itself could be increased to offset the subordination limit.
(45)
WOULD AN MBR REALLY STOP RUNS BY PANICKED INVESTORS? Some critics
of an MBR rule have suggested that investors will redeem shares from
MMFs in a crisis, regardless of the incentives created by subordination
(see, for example, BlackRock 2012, Investment Company Institute 2013).
To be sure, accurate predictions of investors' behaviors in a
crisis are difficult. Nonetheless, an MBR rule could reverse pressures
on rational investors to exit MMFs during crises. In the event that some
investors run regardless of incentives, the rules that we propose would
help ensure that they bear the costs of their actions and would provide
extra protections for other investors, so that staying invested in the
fund could be a rational decision.
COULD INVESTORS "BROKER" THEIR ACCOUNTS TO TAKE ADVANTAGE
OF A $50,000 EXEMPTION FOR SUBORDINATION? In principle, investors could
divide their large cash holdings into separate $50,000 accounts at
different MMFs for this purpose, but the effectiveness of such a
strategy likely would be quite limited for large institutional
investors. One indicator of the magnitude of the account balances in
institutional MMFs is their requirements for minimum initial
investments, which averaged $18 million as of March 2013 for
institutional prime funds with assets over $1 billion. (46) At the end
of 2012, there were 241 prime MMFs, based on their filings of form N-MFP
with the SEC. Thus, even if large institutional MMFs dropped their
minimum investment requirements and a shareholder with an $18 million
balance spread it evenly across all funds in the industry, she still
would have more than $50,000 in each fund.
OMNIBUS ACCOUNTS AND IMPEDIMENTS TO IDENTIFYING INDIVIDUAL
SHAREHOLDERS A more challenging obstacle to the functioning of an MBR is
the use of omnibus accounts by intermediaries (such as broker-dealers)
that sell MMF shares. An omnibus account is an aggregated account for
multiple customers, and MMFs may have access to information about these
accounts only at the aggregated level. An MBR rule applied only at the
account level could be counterproductive. For example, even with a 5
percent MBR, a broker-dealer that has two customers with $100 accounts
and hence a $200 omnibus account with an MMF could allow one customer to
redeem all of his shares. The second customer would effectively face a
10 percent MBR.
To address this issue in its proposed recommendations on MMFs, the
FSOC noted that
MMFs would be required to apply the MBR requirement to each of
their recordholders. This would include recordholders that are financial
intermediaries, such as banks or broker-dealers that hold shares on
behalf of their customers, unless the intermediaries provide the MMF
sufficient information to apply the MBR requirement to the
intermediaries' individual customers directly. Absent such
information, an MMF and its financial intermediary recordholders would
allocate between themselves the responsibility (and associated costs) of
applying the MBR requirement equitably. (FSOC 2012b, p. 44)
However, the lack of transparency associated with omnibus accounts
has undesirable effects that go well beyond the difficulties it creates
for administering an MBR. Omnibus accounts, for example, played a role
in facilitating a widespread abusive-trading scandal that roiled the
mutual fund industry in 2003. (47) Hence, there are good reasons to
consider rule changes requiring that MMFs have better information about
their actual shareholders, which also would allow more effective
application of MBR rules.
VI. Conclusion
This paper has described a new proposal, the minimum balance at
risk, to mitigate the vulnerability of money market funds to runs. The
MBR would be a small fraction of each MMF shareholder's recent
balances that is subject to a 30-day redemption delay. An MBR would
diminish or eliminate the advantages enjoyed by shareholders who redeem
quickly, before others do, when an MMF is in distress, by ensuring that
redeeming investors are not able to shift risks and losses to those who
remain invested. By discouraging redemptions during crises, an MBR also
would help prevent the destabilizing and costly dynamics of a run and
the strains that MMF runs can propagate throughout the financial system.
Thus, an MBR not only would benefit MMFs and their investors, but also
would mitigate externalities associated with these funds.
A key element of our proposal is that a portion of redeeming
investors' MBRs would be subordinated, to provide a deterrent to
running from an MMF to avoid imminent losses. The disincentive to redeem
would be negligible in normal times but would become salient on the rare
occasions when investors grow concerned about the risk of losses. When
that risk is high, the MBR would create a trade-off for investors, who
could either redeem shares to maintain their own liquidity or stay
invested in the fund to safeguard their principal. In contrast, under
current rules, investors who redeem from a troubled MMF preserve both
liquidity and principal, while those who remain behind are put at
greater risk of losing both.
An MBR offers some important advantages over other proposals for
reducing the vulnerability of MMFs to runs. Importantly, it could allow
MMFs to maintain features that are central to their attractiveness to
investors, in particular their stable $1 NAVs, their market-based
yields, and the immediate liquidity of the vast majority of each
investor's balance. An MBR would not require MMFs to raise the
large sums of capital needed to create a meaningful capital buffer, and
thus likely would be more feasible than a stand-alone capital option
(although a capital buffer could complement an MBR rule well). Moreover,
an MBR rule would create a deterrent to redeeming in times of
stress--one that neither a floating NAV nor a capital buffer can
provide. And unlike some proposals for conditional ("standby")
restrictions or fees on redemptions, an MBR would not set up incentives
for preemptive runs. Indeed, an MBR likely would improve market
discipline for MMFs by strengthening investors' incentives to
monitor and respond to MMF risks when they first arise, rather than wait
to redeem until serious problems are imminent.
On the basis of historical data on MMF losses, including a novel
data set from the Treasury and the SEC on losses suffered by MMFs in
2008, we have gauged the size of an MBR that would be needed to protect
MMFs from runs. Our analysis also incorporates evidence about the value
of preserving liquidity in a crisis, which strengthens investors'
incentives to redeem. We find that, for an MMF with a 0.5 percent
capital buffer, an MBR of at least 3 to 4 percent probably would be
adequate to create disincentives for redemptions. (48)
The run on MMFs in September 2008 underscored that these
funds' structural vulnerabilities can have potentially deleterious
consequences for the entire financial system. In addition, the 2008 run
may have made funds' institutional investors more skittish and thus
more prone to run. Heavy redemptions by institutional investors during
the summer of 2011, partly in response to increasing concerns about the
funds' European holdings, indicate that institutional investors are
more responsive to the risks in MMFs than they were before 2008. (49)
But policymakers have fewer tools to address MMF runs now than during
the financial crisis, particularly because the Treasury's temporary
guarantee program, which was instrumental in stopping the 2008 run, is
no longer possible under current law.
In this environment the need for MMF reform is particularly
salient. Fortunately, there may be near-term opportunities for
implementing meaningful reforms. The Financial Stability Oversight
Council's proposed recommendations to the SEC, which were published
in November 2012, include an alternative featuring an MBR requirement
for MMFs. The SEC in June 2013 proposed two options for MMF reform for
public comment: a floating NAV for institutional prime MMFs and a
requirement that funds impose or consider fees and restrictions for
redemptions if their liquid assets fall below a threshold (U.S. SEC
2013). Thus, careful consideration of MMF reform options is timely and
potentially very useful to policymakers. We believe that the MBR is a
particularly promising option, offering a means of preserving the key
features that make MMFs attractive to investors while providing MMFs
with the stability needed to ensure that they continue to play an
important role in the U.S. financial system, even in the event of
another systemic crisis.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We thank the editors for many helpful comments. We
are also grateful to Ken Anadu, Steffanie Brady, Wendy Lai-Ching Chan,
Darrell Duffle, Matt Eichner, Josh Gallin, Jamie McAndrews, Susan
McLaughlin, Eric Rosengren, Nathan Yeung, and seminar participants at
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, and the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System for
comments on earlier versions of this paper, and we thank Greg Nini,
Henry Shilling, and Sarah ten Siethoff for help in providing and
interpreting data. The views expressed herein are those of the authors
and do not necessarily reflect the view of the Board of Governors, the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, or the Federal Reserve System.
References
Anderson, Neil. 2010. "Less Than One Percent of Primary's
Assets Are Still in Reserve." TheMutualFundWire.com (16 July).
www.mfwire.com/article.asp?
storyID=32827&template=article&bhcp=1.
BlackRock. 2010. "ViewPoint: Money Market Funds. A Proposal
for a Capitalized Special Purpose Entity." New York (February 7).
https://www2.blackrock.com/
webcore/litService/search/getDocument.seam?venue=PUB_IND&source=GL
OBAL&contentId=1111124986.
--. 2011. "Money Market Funds: Potential Capital
Solutions." New York (August).
https://www2.blackrock.com/webcore/litService/search/getDocument. seam?
venue=PUB_IND&source=GLOBAL&contentId=1111146889.
--. 2012. "Money Market Funds: A Path Forward." New York
(September 27). https://www2.blackrock.com/webcore/litService/search/getDocument.seam? venue=PUB_IND&source=GLOBAL&contentId=1111173537.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2009.
"Monetary Policy Report to the Congress." Washington (24
February). www.federalreserve.gov/
monetarypolicy/mpr_20090224_part2.htm.
Brady, Steffanie A., Ken E. Anadu, and Nathaniel R. Cooper. 2012.
"The Stability of Prime Money Market Mutual Funds: Sponsor Support
from 2007 to 2011." Risk and Policy Analysis Unit Working Paper no.
12-3. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston (August 13).
www.bos.frb.org/bankinfo/qau/wp/2012/qau1203.pdf.
Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Martin Oehmke. 2013. "The
Maturity Rat Race." Journal of Finance 68, no. 2: 483-521.
Chernenko, Sergey, and Adi Sunderam. 2013. "Frictions in
Shadow Banking: Evidence from the Lending Behavior of Money Market
Funds." Ohio State University and Harvard Business School (February
2). www.people.hbs.edu/ asunderam/mmf_2013-02-02.pdf.
Coeure, Benoit. 2012. "Central Banks and the Challenges of the
Zero Lower Bound." Remarks at the Meeting on the Financial Crisis,
hosted by the Initiative on Global Markets at the University of Chicago
Booth School of Business (February 19).
www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2012/html/sp 120219.en.html.
Federal Open Market Committee. 2008. "Minutes of the Federal
Open Market Committee." Washington (October 28-29).
www.federalreserve.gov/monetary policy/files/fomcminutes20081029.pdf.
Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC). 2011. Annual Report.
Washington. www.treasury.gov/initiatives/fsoc/documents/FSOCAR2011.pdf.
--. 2012a. Annual Report. Washington.
www.treasury.gov/initiatives/fsoc/ Documents/2012%20Annual%20Report.pdf.
--. 2012b. "Proposed Recommendations Regarding Money Market
Mutual Fund Reform." Federal Register 77, no. 223:69455 (November
19). www. gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/FR-2012-11-19/pdf/2012-28041.pdf.
Goebel, Scott C., Carrie E. Dwyer, and C. David Messman. 2011.
Fidelity, Charles Schwab, and Wells Fargo comment letter to the
Securities and Exchange Commission regarding File No. 4-619, Release No.
IC-29497, President's Working Group Report on Money Market Fund
Reform (May 3). www.sec.gov/ comments/4-619/4619-97.pdf.
Gordon, Jeffrey N., and Christopher M. Gandia. 2013. "Money
Market Fund Risk: Will Floating Net Asset Value Fix the Problem?"
Columbia University School of Law Center for Law and Economic Studies
Working Paper no. 426 (March).
Group of Thirty. 2009. Financial Reform: A Framework for Financial
Stability. Washington (January 15).
www.group30.org/images/PDF/Financial_Reform-A_Framework for
Financial_Stability.pdf.
Hanson, Samuel G., David S. Scharfstein, and Adi Sunderam. 2012.
"An Evaluation of Money Market Fund Reform Proposals." Comment
letter regarding Financial Stability Oversight Council, "Proposed
Recommendations Regarding Money Market Mutual Fund Reform"
(December 20). www.regulations.gov/#!
documentDetail;D=FSOC-2012-0003-0032.
HSBC Global Asset Management. 2011. "Liquidity Fees: A
Proposal to Reform Money Market Funds." (November 3).
Investment Company Institute. 2009. "Report of the Money
Market Working Group." Washington (March 17).
www.ici.org/pdf/ppr_09_mmwg.pdf.
--. 2012. Investment Company Fact Book. Washington.
www.ici.org/pdf/2012_factbook.pdf.
--. 2013. Comment letter of the Investment Company Institute
regarding Financial Stability Oversight Council, "Proposed
Recommendations Regarding Money Market Mutual Fund Reform" (January
24). www.regulations.gov/#! documentDetail;D=FSOC-2012-0003-0071.
Keister, Todd. 2011. "Why Is There a 'Zero Lower
Bound' on Interest Rates?" Liberty Street Economics blog
(November 16). libertystreeteconomics.new
yorkfed.org/2011/11/why-is-there-a-zero-lower-bound-on-interest-rates.html.
Lacker, Jeffrey M. 2011. Comment letter to the Securities and
Exchange Commission regarding File No. 4-619, Release No. IC-29497,
President's Working Group Report on Money Market Fund Reform
(January 10). www.sec.gov/ comments/4-619/4619-54.pdf.
McCabe, Patrick E. 2010. "The Cross Section of Money Market
Fund Risks and Financial Crises." Federal Reserve Board Finance and
Economics Discussion Series Working Paper no. 2010-51 (September 12).
www.federalreserve.gov/ pubs/feds/2010/201051/201051pap.pdf.
Mendelson, Simon, and Richard Hoerner. 2011. BlackRock comment
letter to the Securities and Exchange Commission regarding Release No.
IC-29497, File No. 4-619 (January 10).
www.sec.gov/comments/4-619/4619-22.pdf.
Moody's Investors Service. 2010. "Sponsor Support Key to
Money Market Funds." New York (August 8).
--. 2012a. "Frequently Asked Questions: Impact of Negative
Yields on Money Market Funds." New York (October 15).
--. 2012b. "JPMorgan Liquidity Funds: Launch of Share Class
Aims to Manage Low/Negative Yields." New York (November 16).
--. 2012c. "Lehman Support in Prime Money Market Funds."
New York (April 30).
President's Working Group on Financial Markets (PWG). 2010.
"Report of the President's Working Group on Financial Markets:
Money Market Fund Reform Options." Washington (October).
www.treasury.gov/press-center/press-releases/
Documents/10.21%20PWG%20Report%20Final.pdf.
Rosengren, Eric S. 2012. "Money Market Mutual Funds and
Financial Stability." Remarks at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Atlanta's 2012 Financial Markets Conference (April 11).
www.bos.frb.org/news/speeches/rosengren/2012/041112/ 041112.pdf.
--. 2013. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston comment letter regarding
Financial Stability Oversight Council, "Proposed Recommendations
Regarding Money Market Mutual Fund Reform" (February 12).
www.regulations.gov/#!document Detail;D=FSOC-2012-0003-0100.
Schapiro, Mary. 2010. "Statement on Money Market Funds before
the Open Commission Meeting." Washington: Securities and Exchange
Commission (January 27).
www.sec.gov/news/speech/2010/spch012710mls-mmf.htm.
--. 2011. "Remarks at SIFMA's 2011 Annual Meeting."
Washington: Securities and Exchange Commission (November 7).
www.sec.gov/news/speech/2011/ spch110711 mls.htm.
--. 2012. "Testimony on 'Perspectives on Money Market
Mutual Fund Reforms' before U.S. Senate Committee on Banking,
Housing, and Urban Affairs." Washington (June 21).
www.banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Files.
View&FileStore_id=66f4ddb5-4823-4341-bad9-Sf99cdf5fe9a.
Scharfstein, David S. 2012. "Testimony on 'Perspectives
on Money Market Mutual Fund Reforms' before U.S. Senate Committee
on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs." Washington (June 21).
www.banking.senate.gov/public/
index.cfm?FuseAction=Files.View&FileStore_id=ca1f8420-b2de-46dd-aee1-9a22d47b198c.
Sellon, Gordon H., Jr. 2003. "Monetary Policy and the Zero
Bound: Policy Options When Short-Term Rates Reach Zero." Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Economic Review, 4th Quarter: 5-43.
Squam Lake Group. 2011. "Reforming Money Market Funds,"
Comment letter to the Securities and Exchange Commission regarding File
No. 4-619, Release No. IC-29497, President's Working Group Report
on Money Market Fund Reform (January 14).
www.sec.gov/comments/4-619/4619-57.pdf.
Stevens, Paul Schott. 2011. Investment Company Institute comment
letter to the Securities and Exchange Commission regarding
President's Working Group Report on Money Market Fund Reform
Options, File No. 4-619 (January 10).
www.sec.gov/comments/4-619/4619-49.pdf.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2008. "Guarantee Agreement
(Stable Value Single Fund)." Washington (September).
www.treasury.gov/about/organizationalstructure/offices/Domestic-
Finance/Documents/Guarantee_Agreement_Stable-Value_Single-Fund.pdf.
U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). 1999. "In the
Matter of Craig S. Vanucci and Brian K. Andrew, Respondents: Order
Instituting Public Administrative and Cease-and-Desist
Proceedings." Administrative Proceeding File no. 3-9804. Washington
(January 11). www.sec.gov/litigation/admin/33-7625.txt.
--. 2005. "Final Rule: Mutual Fund Redemption Fees." File
no. S7-11-04. Washington (March 11).
www.sec.gov/rules/final/ic-26782.pdf.
--. 2009. "Money Market Fund Reform: Proposed Rule."
Release no. IC-2880730. Washington (June 30).
www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/2009/ic-28807. pdf.
--. 2010. "Money Market Fund Reform: Final Rule." Release
no. IC-29132. Washington (February 23).
www.sec.gov/rules/final/2010/ic-29132.pdf.
--. 2012. "Response to Questions Posed by Commissioners
Aguilar, Paredes, and Gallagher," Washington (November 30).
www.sec.gov/news/studies/2012/ money-market-funds-memo-2012.pdf.
--. 2013. "Money Market Fund Reform; Amendments to Form
PF." Release no. 33-9408. Washington (June 5).
www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/2013/33-9408.pdf.
Volcker, Paul A. 2011. Comment letter to the Securities and
Exchange Commission regarding File no. 4-619, Release no. IC-29497,
President's Working Group Report on Money Market Fund Reform.
Washington (February 11). www.sec. gov/comments/4-619/4619-79.pdf.
Witmer, Jonathan. 2012. "Does the Buck Stop Here? A Comparison
of Withdrawals from Money Market Mutual Funds with Floating and Constant
Share Prices." Bank of Canada Working Paper no. 2012-25. Ottawa
(August). www.bank ofcanada.ca/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/wp2012-25.pdf.
Comments and Discussion
COMMENT BY MARTIN NEIL BAILY
Money market funds (MMFs) currently play an important role in
providing liquidity to financial intermediaries. At the end of 2012,
these funds accounted for over one-fifth of all U.S. mutual fund assets,
with $2.7 trillion in assets under management. MMFs typically provide a
higher yield than bank deposits, and before the recent financial crisis
they were widely thought to be as safe as insured deposits, at least by
retail investors, although their value was not in fact guaranteed by the
government. As the crisis unfolded, wholesale investors began to doubt
the stability of the funds and started to withdraw their shares. As
Patrick McCabe and his coauthors point out in this paper, under the
current rules governing MMFs, investors who are quick to redeem from a
troubled MMF are able to protect both their liquidity and their
principal, shifting the risks onto less savvy investors. This problem,
inherent in the incentive structure of these funds, provides the context
for the authors' proposed reform of MMFs.
The first MMF established was the Reserve Fund, which opened in
1971. From there the number of MMFs grew quickly, as they offered a way
to avoid interest rate regulation on bank deposits (Regulation Q) and so
reap higher returns. This is an important point, indicating that MMFs
are a reflection of regulatory arbitrage, and since Regulation Q has now
disappeared, the rationale for the continued existence of MMFs has come
into question.
MMFs are regulated under the Investment Company Act of 1940 and
under rule 2a-7 of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), adopted
in 1983, which allows MMFs to use a variety of procedures to maintain a
stable net asset value (NAV) of $1 per share. In only a few cases has an
MMF's NAV dropped below this $1 level ("broken the
buck"): the authors report only two instances since 1983. Yet there
have been other cases where runs on MMFs resulted in portfolio losses,
and in some of these the MMF would have broken the buck but for the
support of its sponsoring financial institution. The authors note that
since the birth of the MMF industry in the 1970s, sponsors have
intervened to support an MMF in over 300 instances.
The vulnerability of MMFs to runs results in part from the fact
that they generally hold similar portfolios. The restrictions they
face--MMFs can hold only assets with the highest short-term
ratings--coupled with their need to maintain a stable NAV, severely
limit the diversification available to MMF portfolios. The authors point
out that as of September 2012, 50 private issuers accounted for 91
percent of all MMF investments in private entities, and that of these
50, all but 4 were financial firms. Because the portfolios of different
MMFs have a significant degree of overlap, trouble at one MMF very often
has direct implications for others. The authors identify this as a
"contagion risk among MMFs," whereby a surge in redemptions
from one or more troubled MMFs can depress asset prices and put other
MMFs with overlapping portfolios at risk. This gives investors an
incentive to redeem preemptively from those MMFs as well.
These concerns became acute during the financial crisis, especially
in 2008. In the weeks following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in
September 2008, prime MMFs experienced an outflow of $400 billion.
During 2008 the Reserve Primary Fund lost 1.6 percent of its value.
Almost all of this run behavior was on the part of institutional
investors, whose holdings account for over 65 percent of all MMF shares.
Retail investors, in contrast, displayed a great deal of inertia, in
that they were significantly less likely to run from their MMFs.
In September and October 2008, more than two dozen MMFs received
contributions from their sponsors in order to avoid breaking the buck.
On September 19, 2008, the U.S. Treasury extended a guarantee to MMF
investors that they could withdraw their funds without breaking the
buck; that guarantee stayed in place until September 18, 2009. However,
the Economic Stabilization Act of 2008 outlawed similar guarantees in
the future. Thus, without a change in the law, the Treasury will not be
able to guarantee MMFs in any future crisis.
I noted earlier that retail shareholders tended not to run from
MMFs in the crisis, but that statement has to be qualified because of
the Treasury guarantee. Retail shareholders did not run immediately in
the crisis, but they might have run eventually without the guarantee. In
2010, in response to what had happened in the crisis, the SEC tightened
its risk requirements for MMFs, mandating that they hold at least 10
percent of their assets in highly liquid assets, such as privately
issued securities maturing within a day and Treasury securities, and at
least 30 percent in assets maturing within a week.
At prevailing prices, investor demand for risk-free, liquid assets
is strong. The government provides backing for a large share of these
assets through the insurance of bank deposits by the Federal Deposit
Insurance Corporation (up to a limit) and adds directly to the supply by
issuing large volumes of short-term Treasury securities. Private markets
look for additional ways to supplement the supply. For example,
investors can circumvent the regulatory limit on insured bank deposits
by spreading their assets across a number of banks. MMFs created demand
deposits that technically carried some risk but were assumed by many
investors to be risk free. In the crisis the Treasury felt obliged to
validate that misperception, and so regulating MMFs must be part of a
broader decision about the extent to which government, and hence
taxpayers, should be on the hook to support risky assets. The Dodd-Frank
legislation was clear in wanting to limit taxpayer liability and to
avoid having the federal government dragged into providing such support
in another crisis.
One of the things I liked about this paper is that it identifies a
market failure in MMFs and devises a policy that is geared directly to
addressing that failure. The authors argue that the current set-up of
MMFs results in an externality, by allowing savvy investors to withdraw
at the first signs of trouble and retain the full value of their
principal, in the process passing the losses on to the investors who
stay in the MMF. This encourages investors to run at the first hint of
trouble, and the potential for such behavior compounds the riskiness of
an MMF even if its underlying assets are in fact sound. Any institution
that issues demand deposits of fixed value is prone to a run, because it
is costless for investors to withdraw their money and hold it in cash or
deposit it in an alternative liquid asset. Market failures in finance
are often tied to incomplete or asymmetric information, and the authors
make such a connection. The more savvy (and presumably richer) investors
know more about the quality of a fund's portfolio and are able to
pass the losses on to the smaller investors who are less informed.
Yet one can take a different perspective on MMFs and question the
severity or even the existence of the market failure. It is important
that investors monitor the health of the MMFs in which they place their
assets, and take action if the fund managers fail to act in a manner
consistent with the risk goals of the fund. In a climate of very low
interest rates, fund managers have a tendency to "reach for
yield," making risky investments in order to generate an adequate
return or to attract investors by offering higher yields than competing
funds. Savvy investors who withdraw assets from a fund are giving a
signal to the market. Their exit serves as a counterbalance to the
inertia of retail investors who pay no attention to the safety of the
fund. In this view information is something investors can choose to
acquire and use. This argument only goes so far, however, because large
corporate investors will have much easier access to information and are
better able to understand risks than small retail investors.
POLICY RESPONSES A variety of policy responses have been proposed
to diminish the systemic risk introduced by MMFs. The first of these
would abolish the fixed NAV. A floating NAV would communicate
information to current and potential investors about the risks in an
MMF's portfolio; all investors, wholesale and retail, would then be
regularly informed about the value of the fund and the nature of its
investments. Additionally, it is argued that a floating NAV would
discourage risky investments on the part of MMF managers, as these risks
would quickly be communicated to potential and current investors, to a
much greater degree than is the case currently with the $1 per share
peg. Another benefit of this approach is that it would, at the margin,
discourage preemptive redemptions by risk-averse investors, as any
signal of trouble within the MMF would entail a decrease in the NAV,
reducing the amount of their principal they recouped. Under current
practice, in contrast, redeeming investors always get the same return of
$1. Finally, proponents of this view contend that the floating NAV is
simpler than a peg, as the latter involves instruments used in rounding
the NAV, which introduce complexities and costs.
One argument against this solution is that if very large investors
were to suddenly withdraw their funds, it would be difficult for the
fund to come up with the cash, even with a lower NAV. Robert Pozen, a
long-time industry practitioner, has pointed out to me, however, that
very large withdrawals can be dealt with by giving the redeeming
investors a pro rata share of the fund's assets in kind, to dispose
of as they wish.
Another argument against the floating NAV, offered by Samuel
Hanson, David Scharfstein, and Adi Sunderam (2013), is that it may not
prevent runs from becoming a systemic problem. With a floating NAV, they
claim, investors will pull out even more quickly to avoid a price
decline. One variant of the floating-NAV approach is to separate
wholesale and retail funds. Since retail investors are
"stickier" and less prone to runs, retail funds may not need
the same rules as for wholesale funds.
The authors of this paper propose a second policy solution to MMF
regulation, which they call the minimum balance at risk (MBR). The basic
idea is that a small proportion of an investor's total holdings in
an MMF would be subject to a delay (they propose 30 days) if the
investor attempts to redeem during a potential run. A second component
of the proposal is that of subordination, whereby in the event of a run,
the MBRs of those investors who have chosen to redeem early would be the
first assets used to absorb whatever losses the MMF incurs. Rather than
spreading the losses evenly across MBRs, the proposal would have the MMF
manager preferentially protect the MBRs of those investors who decide to
stay put. The virtue of this proposal is that it speaks directly to the
externality whereby the first investors to withdraw pass the costs on to
the less savvy investors left behind. Instead, under the MBR proposal,
the investors who try to get out first would be forced to bear more of
the costs. Thus, the proposed solution acts directly to restrain runs on
MMFs by penalizing those investors who run.
The authors do a nice job of laying out the specifics of their
proposal, and they show that if an MMF also maintains a small capital
buffer in place (0.5 percent), the MBR could be set at a level of about
3 to 5 percent of shares. They examine the impact of different shocks
and the nature of the protection provided by MBRs of different sizes and
structures.
A concern about the MBR proposal is that it works against one of
the major appeals of MMFs, namely, that they provide an investment
vehicle for highly liquid assets that can respond rapidly to changing
market opportunities. Instituting a 30-day delay on a portion of
redemptions may adversely impact investors' business decisions. It
may also dampen the appeal of the MMFs themselves. Even if the MBR were
applied only where there is a risk of a run, its imposition may
discourage the use of MMFs out of concerns about the possible
implementation of the MBR plan. At the retail level, investors concerned
about paying taxes on time or being surprised by medical expenses will
be reluctant to wait 30 days to redeem their funds. Aware of this
problem, the authors discuss possible exemptions for smaller retail
investments.
The third possible approach to MMF regulation is the capital buffer
proposal made by Hanson and coauthors, which has also been endorsed by
the Squam Lake Group, of which I am a member. The idea is
straightforward. MMFs would be required to hold loss-absorbing capital
equal to some percentage of their assets, so that if the value of the
assets declines, the capital can be used to preserve the fixed NAV and
allow investors to withdraw their funds at par. The presence of a
capital buffer, it is argued, would discourage investors from running
and thus avoid or at least mitigate the systemic risk problem.
One problem with a capital buffer is determining how large the
buffer should be in practice. A buffer that is too small may be quickly
overwhelmed, putting the fund back in a floating-NAV situation. But if
the buffer is too large, it will reduce the returns that the MMF is able
to achieve, possibly destroying its economic viability. A second problem
with a capital buffer is that it may bolster the all-too-common but
mistaken belief that MMF investments are without risk.
WEIGHING THE ALTERNATIVES The problem of MMF regulation has no easy
answer--witness the slowness of the SEC to implement new rules. In
fairness, the SEC did act promptly to require MMFs to keep a set
proportion of their assets liquid, a step that made the funds more
robust to sudden withdrawals.
Some of the participants in the Brookings Panel discussion of this
paper argued that MMFs are really an anomaly that grew out of Regulation
Q and have now outlived their usefulness. I am quite sympathetic to that
view, provided that any transition away from MMFs is made smoothly. At
present, MMFs provide short-term funding to other financial
institutions, but if they were to lose their competitive advantage, the
wholesale and retail shares they now hold would flow back into bank
accounts or into other financial institutions, where they would be
available to be recycled.
If instead MMFs are given a chance to survive and compete, my
preferred regulatory proposal is that they eliminate the fixed NAV.
Wholesale investors understand fluctuations in asset values and can
decide whether or not they wish to continue keeping funds in an
instrument with a variable price. Many retail investors in MMFs also
hold stock and bond mutual funds and are quite aware of the ups and
downs of the market. Investors in floating-NAV funds should be warned
that their principal is at risk, and if they do not like small price
variations, they should hold their money in insured bank accounts
instead. It is important to have clarity about the extent of government
insurance of demand deposits.
There is not a generally accepted theory of what causes financial
market panics, but it seems that most runs occur when some party tries
to maintain a fixed price for some asset in the presence of fluctuating
demand and supply. As soon as the fixed price comes into jeopardy,
everyone rushes for the exit. For example, in currency crises a country
tries to maintain a fixed exchange rate but eventually is forced to
devalue. Having a capital buffer for MMFs seems rather similar to having
foreign exchange reserves, with the same danger that in very adverse
circumstances, investors will try to run before the reserves are used
up. The MBR proposal is actually rather like the capital buffer, except
that the buffer is provided by setting aside a percentage of each
shareholder account. Since I am not sure what drives unstable financial
dynamics, some humility is in order, but I do not buy the argument that
a variable NAV will make investors more likely to run in a new crisis.
And as noted earlier, a variable NAV communicates the message beforehand
that there is principal risk.
Since the Panel meeting, the SEC has issued proposed new rules,
described in a 700-page document with a request for comments. The SEC
proposal suggests that MMFs could choose to have a floating NAV, but it
offers an alternative option whereby they could keep a fixed NAV as long
as their liquidity ratio (the fraction of the fund's assets with
maturity of one week or less) remains above 15 percent. Once the ratio
falls below that point, the fund's board could decide either to
impose a 2 percent fee on withdrawals ($98 back for every $100 invested)
or to "gate" (put a hold on) redemptions for a period of time.
Although not the same as the MBR proposal, the SEC has thus opted for a
restriction on withdrawals as the leading alternative to a floating NAV.
REFERENCE FOR THE BAILY COMMENT
Hanson, Samuel, David Scharfstein, and Adi Sunderam. 2013. "An
Evaluation of Money Market Fund Reform Proposals." Working paper.
Harvard Business School.
COMMENT BY SAMUEL G. HANSON
Many academics, policymakers, and market participants have recently
been pushing for a significant overhaul of money market fund (MMF)
regulations. Others oppose any significant changes in these regulations.
Why has this historically sleepy corner of the mutual fund sector become
a frontline battle in the postcrisis debate about financial regulation?
And what can this debate tell us about the theory and practice of
financial regulation and its future prospects for success?
In this superb and timely paper, Patrick McCabe, Marco Cipriani,
Michael Holscher, and Antoine Martin put forth a novel proposal for MMF
reform, which they call the minimum balance at risk (MBR). I begin this
discussion by providing some further background on MMFs and explain why
a growing number of observers believe that MMFs pose a significant
threat to financial stability. I contrast various approaches to
financial regulation and argue that the current debate over MMF
regulation is best understood through the lens of systemic financial
regulation: the goal of these proposals is to better safeguard the
stability of the financial system. Drawing heavily on my own recent
paper with David Scharfstein and Adi Sunderam, I then lay out what I see
as the main goals of MMF reform. Finally, I evaluate three prominent
reform proposals--floating net asset values (NAVs), the MBR proposal,
and subordinated capital buffers--in light of these goals. I note that
the MBR is a form of subordinated capital, so the second and third
proposals are close cousins. I argue that these two proposals are far
more likely to achieve the goals of MMF reform than floating the NAV.
BACKGROUND ON MMFS A money market fund is a type of mutual fund
that is required by law to invest in short-term, low-risk securities.
MMFs pay dividends that reflect the level of short-term interest rates.
MMFs come in institutional and retail varieties. Institutional MMFs are
high-minimum-investment, low-expense funds marketed to large firms and
institutional investors. Retail MMFs are low-minimum-investment,
higher-expense funds marketed to households.
Like other mutual funds, MMFs are not insured by the Federal
Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) and are regulated by the Securities
and Exchange Commission under the Investment Company Act of 1940.
However, because MMFs have very low risk compared with other mutual
funds, they are exempt under rule 2a-7 of the act from certain
regulations that apply to mutual funds more broadly. Specifically, an
MMF is not required to mark its assets to market as long as its NAV per
share is greater than $0.995. Instead MMFs, like banks, are allowed to
use amortized-cost accounting. However, MMFs are subject to a variety of
bank-like regulations that explicitly restrict their asset risk, again
setting them apart from other mutual funds.
In November 2012 the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC)
solicited public comment on a range of structural reform proposals for
MMFs. (1) The principal concern cited by the FSOC is that a wide-scale
run on MMFs could result in a systemwide run on large financial firms.
Such a run would, in turn, disrupt credit markets and the payments
system, with severe adverse consequences for the real economy. This is
the "systemic risk posed by MMFs" that motivates the proposal
of McCabe and coauthors.
The FSOC asked for comments on three reform proposals for MMFs: the
first would require MMFs to "float" their NAVs; the second
would require MMFs to maintain a 1 percent subordinated capital buffer
and adopt a 3 percent MBR; the third would require MMFs to maintain a 3
percent subordinated capital buffer but no MBR. The second alternative
is a variant of the proposal described by McCabe and coauthors and draws
heavily on their work.
WHAT DO MMFS DO? Like the authors in this paper, I focus here on
prime MMFs, which are thought to pose the greatest systemic risk. Prime
MMFs invest in short-term debt instruments issued by private borrowers,
mainly large, global banks; only 3 percent of prime MMF assets are in
paper issued by nonfinancial firms. (2) Thus, the core function of prime
MMFs is to collect savings from households and firms to provide
short-term financing to financial institutions (Hanson, Scharfstein, and
Sunderam 2013). In other words, prime MMFs function like
"correspondent banks" that take deposits and invest those
funds in the deposits of other banks.
Prime MMFs create a number of bank-like benefits. On the liability
side, they provide savers with money-like, demandable claims--that is,
claims with a highly stable nominal value that are redeemable on
demand--and offer a variety of transactional services. In addition, MMF
shares pay an interest rate that closely tracks movements in short-term
market rates such as the federal funds rate, making them attractive
relative to the savings products offered by commercial banks (such as
savings and money market deposit accounts), which typically pay
below-market rates. On the asset side, prime MMFs function as delegated
monitors and asset managers, providing savers with access to a
diversified portfolio of the short-term liabilities of many large banks.
Access to a more diversified portfolio is useful to savers, and
delegation may reduce duplicative monitoring in the spirit of Douglas
Diamond (1984).
However, MMFs also pose a set of bank-like risks to the stability
of the financial system. Since MMF shares are subject to redemption on
demand each day, the existence of MMFs arguably raises the risk of a
systemwide run due to the greater systemwide maturity transformation
they provide. For instance, imagine a world in which large banks
financed themselves by issuing 10-day certificates of deposit (CDs). In
such a world, the banking system would need to roll over 10 percent of
its funding every night. Now imagine that an MMF sector is inserted
between savers and banks. Specifically, suppose that savers invest all
of their funds in MMFs, which then buy the banks' 10-day CDs.
Because the MMF shares are redeemable on a daily basis, the financial
system would now need to roll over 100 percent of its funding each
night, so it is reasonable to conclude that the risk of a systemwide run
has increased.
Delegated monitoring also opens the door to agency problems and
raises the classic question of "who monitors the monitor?"
Indeed, a number of recent studies suggest that MMFs have strong private
incentives to take on excessive portfolio risk ex ante (Kacperzyck and
Schnabl forthcoming, Chernenko and Sunderam 2013). An increase in an
individual fund's risk will increase that fund's yield. This
increase in yield is likely to result in significant additional inflows
from institutional investors, who seek out riskier MMFs with higher
yields because they believe they can redeem their shares before bearing
any losses. But when investors protect themselves in this way, they
exacerbate stresses on MMFs ex post, potentially triggering more
widespread financial instability. This yield-seeking behavior also means
that MMFs take risk at the worst times from a systemic perspective: the
imposition of market discipline occurs in a disorderly fashion late in a
crisis, rather than in an orderly fashion in the early stages of a
crisis.
FINANCIAL REGULATORY APPROACHES Before I discuss the specific goals
of MMF reform, it is worth contrasting several different regulatory
approaches: traditional securities regulation, traditional bank
regulation, and systemic financial regulation. This contrast is relevant
since proponents of overhauling MMF regulations typically adopt the
systemic perspective, whereas opponents of significant MMF reform
typically advocate more traditional regulatory approaches.
The primary goals of traditional securities regulation--for
example, as embodied in the Securities Act of 1933, the Securities
Exchange Act of 1934, and the Investment Company Act of 1940--are to
ensure that all investors are properly informed about investment
products and can transact at fair market prices. More specifically, the
goal of traditional securities regulation is to increase transparency,
reduce asymmetric information, and protect unsophisticated retail
investors.
The goal of traditional bank regulation is to ensure that each
individual bank is sufficiently "safe and sound"--for example,
that it has enough equity capital--to ensure that FDIC losses and
taxpayer bailouts are highly unlikely. For this reason traditional bank
regulation is sometimes described as "microprudential" in
nature. The market imperfection motivating microprudential bank
regulation stems from moral hazard. Given the existence of mispriced
deposit insurance, banks have incentives to take excessive risks to
maximize the expected value of taxpayer support. Thus, traditional bank
regulation is seen as a necessary counterweight to this moral hazard.
Since this view is tied to the existence of deposit insurance,
traditional bank regulation is institutional rather than systemic in
nature--for example, from this perspective there is no need to regulate
a bank that has no recourse to the taxpayer safety net.
Following Hanson, Anil Kashyap, and Jeremy Stein (2011), I take the
goal of systemic financial regulation to be that of mitigating the
excessive contractions in credit or disruptions of payments that may
arise when the financial system is hit with an aggregate shock. Since
the goal is to ensure that the financial system as a whole is safe and
sound, this is often described as "macroprudential"
regulation. In contrast to traditional securities and bank regulation,
systemic regulation is decidedly general equilibrium in conception. The
idea is that because the financial system is subject to fire-sale and
credit-crunch externalities, the amount of leverage and maturity
mismatch that is privately optimal for individual financial firms may
not be socially optimal, since it makes the system as a whole overly
vulnerable to costly financial crises. Since these externalities can
arise even in the absence of FDIC-induced moral hazard, systemic
regulation is functional as opposed to institutional. Indeed, the
systemic regulator worries about credit disruptions from regulated
depository institutions, nonbank financial institutions, and markets
alike.
GOALS OF MMF REFORM For proponents of systemic financial
regulation, prime MMFs appear to be a prime example of regulatory
arbitrage. MMFs perform the core economic activities that define
banking--they finance illiquid assets with demandable liabilities and
undertake liquidity transformation--and pose risks to financial
stability similar to those posed by banks. However, unlike banks, MMFs
are not subject to subordinated capital requirements and only recently
have become subject to bank-like liquidity requirements, two regulatory
tools often advocated by proponents of systemic regulation.
Thus, in Hanson and others (2013), we look at MMF regulation
through the lens of the systemic approach to financial regulation. We
argue that the primary objectives for MMF reform should be threefold.
First, regulation should reduce MMFs' incentives to chase yield and
take excessive risk ex ante. Second, regulation should reduce the
likelihood of a widespread and systemically disruptive run on MMFs. And
third, regulation should attempt to preserve the monetary services that
MMFs provide to savers. Otherwise one worries that savings will flow
toward unregulated, MMF-like products that would continue to pose the
same risks to financial stability.
EVALUATION OF REFORM PROPOSALS I now discuss the three main
alternatives for structural MMF reform that have been put forward by the
FSOC: floating the NAV, subordinated capital buffers, and the MBR
provision.
Floating the NAV The first proposal is to require MMFs to float
their NAV, that is, to report their true NAV and allow investors to
transact at it every day, just as all other mutual funds do. This
proposal has natural appeal for adherents of traditional securities
regulation, since it increases the transparency of MMFs. It may also
address the worry that a fixed $1.00 NAV per share places retail
investors at a disadvantage because institutions are able to pull their
money out more quickly when trouble arises.
However, proponents of floating the NAV also cite two potential
systemic benefits. First, moving to a floating NAV may lower the
probability of "strategic" runs on MMFs. Currently, if the
true NAV falls, investors who redeem early receive $1.00 per share,
while those who redeem late receive less. This cliff effect creates a
strategic motive to run. Second, moving to a floating NAV might lower
the probability of "panicked" runs, because it would remove
the regulatory imprimatur of safety that MMFs enjoy and force skittish,
risk-averse investors to recognize that MMFs are not completely safe.
In Hanson and others (2013) we argue that these systemic benefits
are likely overstated. First, since most prime MMF assets tend to be
quite illiquid--secondary markets for short-term private paper are
extremely thin--the strategic incentive for MMF investors to run at the
first sign of danger is likely to remain. Specifically, the incentive to
run stems from the combination of demandable liabilities and illiquid
assets, as in Diamond and Philip Dybvig (1983), not simply from the
cliff effect due to a fixed $1.00 NAV. Investors who redeem early get
paid in full but consume the fund's more liquid assets. By
contrast, investors who redeem late will receive the depressed,
fire-sale value of the fund's more illiquid paper. Indeed, the
recent crisis also saw widespread runs on MMF-like products with
variable NAVs, including ultra-short bond funds in the United States and
variable-NAV MMFs in Europe.
Second, floating-NAV MMFs would continue to attract a highly
skittish, risk-averse investor base. They would still be subject to
strong risk-limiting provisions under rule 2a-7 and thus would continue
to benefit from a strong regulatory imprimatur of safety. Furthermore,
since the NAV would fluctuate little, if at all, in normal times, highly
risk averse investors would still be drawn to the product, setting the
stage for runs at the first sign of danger.
Subordinated capital buffers The idea of a junior capital buffer is
quite simple. A capital buffer divides the risks and rewards of MMF
assets between subordinated capital, which bears the first losses, and
ordinary, senior MMF shares. In return for the protection provided by a
subordinated capital buffer, the latter would earn a slightly lower
yield in normal times.
In Hanson and others (2013) we argue that subordinated capital
buffers are the preferred regulatory solution from the standpoint of
reducing systemic risk, for several reasons. First, junior capital
reduces the probability of systemwide runs. Senior MMF shares will be
protected by the capital buffer, so MMFs would have to suffer larger
losses than under current rules before ordinary MMF investors are
endangered. Second, because subordinated capital providers bear the
first losses, they will have an explicit incentive to discipline ex ante
risk taking. Indeed, Marcin Kacperzyck and Philipp Schnabl (forthcoming)
show that fund sponsors, who implicitly have capital at stake, rein in
the risk taking of their MMFs. Finally, subordinated capital
preserves--and potentially enhances--the monetary benefits enjoyed by
ordinary MMF shareholders and would be unlikely to trigger a migration
to less regulated savings products.
Hanson and others (2013) perform a calibration based on Oldrich
Vasicek's (2002) model of credit portfolio losses. For a
well-diversified portfolio of MMF assets, our estimates suggest that a 4
percent subordinated capital buffer would reduce the probability that
senior shares suffer losses to 0.1 percent, the tolerance level used in
the Basel II bank capital regulations. In return for this protection, we
estimate that senior shares would earn just 0.05 percent less in normal
times.
Minimum balance at risk Under the minimum balance at risk proposal
of McCabe and coauthors, some fraction (say, 3 or 5 percent) of each
investor's recent balances would be available for redemption only
with a delay of 30 days. This would ensure that sophisticated investors
cannot chase yield and then run at the first sign of danger, sticking
less sophisticated investors with all the losses. Furthermore, the
"strong MBR" proposal advocated by these authors adds a
conditional subordination feature whereby the MBRs of redeeming
investors become subordinated relative to those of nonredeemers and bear
the first losses if the MMF breaks the buck. As the authors argue, this
strong MBR provision provides an explicit disincentive for MMF investors
to withdraw when concerns about moderate fund losses arise.
Thus, the proposed MBR is a form of subordinated capital. The main
differences between an actual capital buffer and the MBR have to do with
who provides the capital and when they provide it. With an MBR,
risk-averse MMF investors are forced to provide junior capital ex post.
With a capital buffer, other, more risk tolerant investors or the fund
sponsor provide this junior capital ex ante.
There are costs and benefits of each approach. The MBR may be more
effective at discouraging excessive risk taking, because the MMF
investors themselves are forced to bear the costs of chasing yield ex
ante. With respect to reducing the tendency for investors to run ex
post, note that the MBR assigns losses to skittish, risk-averse
investors in a complex fashion, whereas a capital buffer assigns losses
to more risk tolerant investors in a simple fashion. If one adopts a
rational, strategic view of runs, the MBR may be more effective at
discouraging them. However, if one adopts a more behavioral, panic-based
view of runs, one might worry that the MBR would be less effective.
Finally, the MBR may partially diminish the value of the monetary
services provided by MMFs. As a result, one may worry that a large MBR
requirement might lead savers to substitute away from MMFs and toward
other unregulated products, which may also pose threats to financial
stability.
Overall, a subordinated capital buffer and an MBR are quite
similar, and either could largely achieve the goals of MMF reform.
Furthermore, as the authors note, these approaches may be complementary,
so that a hybrid of buffer and MBR solutions may be most effective.
CONCLUSION In the aftermath of the crisis, the broad question is
where to draw the line between investment products that can be left
largely unregulated, such as hedge funds, and core financial and
payments services that require stronger regulation. The debate on MMF
reform reflects this broader question. Floating-NAV proposals hope to
move MMFs firmly into the investment category, a realm where
policymakers are typically happy to stop at the objectives of
traditional securities regulation. Proposals for capital buffers and
MBRs would bring MMFs further under the regulatory umbrella in the name
of systemic risk regulation. I have argued that the combination of
demandable liabilities and illiquid assets that defines MMFs means that
a systemic or macroprudential approach is essential and, thus, that the
latter approach is likely to be most effective.
REFERENCES FOR THE HANSON COMMENT
Chernenko, Sergey, and Adi Sunderam. 2013. "Frictions in
Shadow Banking: Evidence from the Lending Behavior of Money Market
Funds." Working paper. Harvard Business School.
Diamond, Douglas. 1984. "Financial Intermediation and
Delegated Monitoring." Review of Economic Studies 51, no. 3:
393-414.
Diamond, Douglas, and Philip Dybvig. 1983. "Bank Runs, Deposit
Insurance, and Liquidity." Journal of Political Economy 91, no. 3:
401-19.
Hanson, Samuel, Anil Kashyap, and Jeremy Stein. 2011. "A
Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation." Journal of
Economic Perspectives 25, no. 1: 3-28.
Hanson, Samuel, David Scharfstein, and Adi Sunderam. 2013. "An
Evaluation of Money Market Fund Reform Proposals." Working paper.
Harvard Business School.
Kacperczyk, Marcin, and Philipp Schnabl. Forthcoming. "How
Safe are Money Market Funds?" Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Vasicek, Oldrich. 2002. "Loan Portfolio Value." Risk 15:
160-62.
(1.) The FSOC was created by the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and
Consumer Protection Act of 2010, which grants the FSOC broad authority
to monitor and respond to emerging threats to financial stability.
(2.) MMFs are classified as prime, government, or tax-exempt.
According to the Investment Company Institute, MMFs managed a total of
$2.60 trillion in assets as of November 2012. Most of these assets
($1.45 trillion) were in prime MMFs. The remainder were in government
MMFs ($0.87 trillion), which hold Treasury bills and other short-term
U.S. government and agency paper, and in tax-exempt MMFs ($0.27
trillion), which hold short-term paper issued by states and
municipalities.
GENERAL DISCUSSION
Robert Pozen argued that those money market funds that invest only
in government-issued securities should be exempt from any minimum
balance at risk, because these funds carry very little risk and hence
are unlikely to experience a run. Indeed, during the 2008 crisis, many
of these funds received inflows from the prime money market funds, which
invest primarily in nongovernment securities.
Pozen, who noted by way of disclosure that he had formerly been
president of FMR Company, the investment adviser to the Fidelity funds,
also pointed out that prime money funds have average maturities of only
about 60 days and are required to hold at least 97 percent of their
assets in the highest-rated short-term paper, and the remainder in the
next-highest category. Thus, any notion that these funds might invest in
highly risky securities was unfounded. Moreover, these funds are now
required to hold 30 percent of assets in so-called liquidity buckets,
which are redeemable in either one or seven days, making them highly
liquid. Finally, among those money market funds that cater to large
institutional investors, some have offered redemptions in kind at times
when liquidity was strained: institutions seeking to make large
withdrawals were instead given a pro rata share of the securities in the
fund's portfolio. That option, Pozen suggested, could be used more
widely. All these arguments weakened the case, in his view, for further
regulation of money market funds.
Pozen nevertheless recognized that a credible case could be made
for further regulation of institutional money market funds. The
institutions that park money in these funds often hold very large
positions, and they monitor the markets closely and trade actively, so
that a run becomes a real danger. It was no coincidence, Pozen observed,
that the only two money funds to date that have broken the buck were
both institutional funds.
By contrast, an MBR--and indeed any of the regulatory proposals
currently on the table--would essentially put the retail money market
funds out of business, in Pozen's estimation. The small investors
that currently use such funds would simply shift their money to banks,
which do not face such restrictions. Further regulation of these funds
seemed to Pozen unnecessary in any case, because most retail money fund
investors did not run even during the 2008 crisis, and since then the 30
percent liquidity bucket requirement has made those funds even safer.
On the asset side, Pozen noted that money market funds, with some
$3 trillion in assets, are today the most important short-term lenders
to many large companies, banks, and municipalities. If further
regulation led investors to abandon these funds, he asked, who would
step up to do that lending in their stead? Banks probably would not,
because they are more interested in longer-term lending where their
specialization in maturity transformation produces greater profits. If
banks did take up the slack, they would need to increase their equity
capital, at a time when they are already struggling to raise capital. A
likely scenario, Pozen thought, was that new types of hedge funds or
private equity funds would emerge to meet the short-term needs of banks.
These new lending vehicles would be largely unregulated and would likely
trade more actively than the institutions that today finance the
short-term market for money market instruments. The result, ironically,
could be to increase the likelihood of a run in the short-term market.
Raquel Fernandez was unclear about how the authors were able to
calculate that runs would occur with lower probability with an MBR than
without one. As she saw it, the situation was essentially characterized
by multiple equilibria: if a sufficiently large fraction of investors
decide to run, a run will occur. She did not see how an MBR would change
that dynamic so that a probability of a run could be calculated.
Benjamin Friedman thought that more regulation of money market
funds was called for, and his own preference would be to do away with
the fixed share price and mandate a floating net asset value. More
fundamentally, however, Friedman asked what difference it would make if
the institutional money fund industry simply went out of business. As
Samuel Hanson had pointed out in his discussion, prime institutional
money funds today are mainly lending to banks, and in particular the
broker-dealer operations of foreign banks: a recent paper by David
Scharfstein showed that of the 50 largest borrowers from these funds,
almost all were banks, and indeed most were non-U.S, banks; hardly any
were nonfinancial businesses. Although there was nothing wrong with
borrowing and lending taking place between consenting parties, domestic
or foreign, Friedman saw no reason such lending should be a public
policy priority. However, intermediation of such activity by money
market funds in particular gave rise to a systemic risk that needed to
be regulated, Friedman argued. It was thus worth asking whether the
institutional money fund industry needed preserving in the first place.
Retail money market funds, on the other hand, do provide a
worthwhile service to small investors, Friedman argued. But that, in his
view, did not necessarily imply a need for further regulation of that
part of the industry. Mutual fund families like Fidelity operate money
market funds so that when investors decide to sell their shares in, say,
the Fidelity Magellan Fund, and are not yet ready to buy shares of
another Fidelity fund, the money stays with Fidelity. The fund families
thus have an incentive to subsidize their money funds, as indeed they
have proved willing to do, to assure investors of their safety.
Kristin Forbes wondered what evidence was available about the
likely response of money market fund investors to the MBR proposal.
Would they in fact shift their money to banks? or perhaps to foreign
money market funds? If the latter, what impact would that have on total
liquidity in the United States? She was also interested in knowing more
about how the mutual fund industry itself rank-ordered the various
reform proposals. Given their evident opposition to all of
them--floating NAVs, increased capital requirements, MBRs--which did
they see as the least of the various evils, and why?
George Perry, who like Pozen had been active in the mutual fund
industry, also saw money market funds as providing a valuable service
within the financial system and to retail investors in particular. When
interest rates rose in the 1970s, bank deposit rates were prevented by
Regulation Q from rising in tandem, effectively excluding small
investors from reaping the higher returns. Money funds, he felt, should
not be regulated out of existence just because they compete with banks.
And with interest rates currently at almost zero, any additional cost
due to increased regulation would erase the remaining margin and
effectively wipe out the money fund industry.
Perry also questioned whether any of the proposed reforms would
have their intended effect in a real crisis like that of 2008-09. Larger
capital buffers could in principle help smooth out fluctuations of the
magnitude that occur in normal times, thus allowing the one-dollar NAV
to be maintained, but would not protect against an event like the Lehman
Brothers bankruptcy. In Perry's view, a reform that worked only
some of the time, but not when needed most, was unlikely to justify its
additional cost.
Richard Cooper seconded Friedman in questioning the paper's
basic assumption that the money market fund industry was something worth
preserving. He agreed with Perry that these funds had served an
important purpose in the 1970s, but that purpose was one of regulatory
arbitrage and presumably disappeared when the regulation did. Cooper
also challenged Pozen's contention that banks are interested only
in lending long. Historically, Cooper noted, an important function of
banks was to provide trade credit, an inherently short-term activity; he
saw no reason why banks today could not again profitably operate at the
short end of the yield curve. Cooper acknowledged that the sheer volume
of assets involved made it prudent to establish a period of transition,
and he suggested a period of five or six years for the funds to either
adapt, become banks themselves, or exit.
Justin Wolfers argued that the difficulty in judging among
regulatory proposals for money market funds stemmed from the underlying
presumption that demand exists for an asset of perfectly stable value,
which implies a discontinuity in the utility function. It was unclear to
Wolfers how that discontinuity arises, and thus unclear how to evaluate
the welfare consequences of any given proposal. Approaching the issue in
terms of Kahneman-Tversky-style risk aversion seemed unhelpful, because
the players involved in the institutional segment of the market are more
sophisticated than typical Kahneman-Tversky-type actors.
Laurence Ball added his voice to those questioning the need to
preserve money market funds as an institution. In their absence, savers
seeking maximum safety could use ordinary insured bank accounts, and
short-term borrowers could take out lines of credit from the same bank.
He pointed out that even if short-term lending is an unattractively low
margin business today, it might become less so as savers and borrowers
shift their activity from money funds to banks. Ultimately, he asked, if
people are attracted to money funds because they are bank-like, what
prevents banks from providing the same service?
Ricardo Reis agreed with Samuel Hanson that the key underlying
problem raised by money market funds was the fire-sale problem: a fund
experiencing large redemptions must sell off large amounts of assets,
pushing their market price downward and thus lowering the firm's
NAV. Anticipating this, investors redeem even more, even sooner, and the
result is a rush toward the exits at the first hint of trouble. From
that perspective, Reis thought, the MBR proposal made sense as far as it
went, because in effect it turned what were one-day-callable deposits
into 30-day-callable deposits. But the MBR would still perform liquidity
transformation only over a longer time frame. Thus, Reis saw the
proposal as vulnerable to the Lucas critique: with an MBR in place,
funds will be led to invest in somewhat longer term assets: 60-day
options, say, instead of 30-day options. A term mismatch will remain,
and investors will still have an incentive to run when trouble looms.
With the transition to the 60-day options, bank runs will simply take
place over the longer period. Moreover, Reis observed, banks, too, are
subject to the fire-sale problem, and this led him to wonder: If MBRs
are a good idea for money market funds, why are they not also a good
idea for banks?
Frederic Mishkin focused on the authors' point that an MBR
actually creates a disincentive to redeem when the fund is facing
difficulties. As he saw it, that implied that the MBR made funds even
more illiquid than the authors claimed: not only was the amount subject
to subordination--5 percent in the authors' example--less liquid
than before; rather, the entire amount invested was less liquid. If that
was the case, it defeated the whole purpose of such funds.
Mishkin was agnostic as to whether money market funds had any
distinct rationale in the post-Regulation Q era. Some innovations, he
suggested, arise by historical accident, under stressful conditions that
ultimately prove temporary, but once discovered are found to have
lasting value. Money market funds could be such an innovation. That
said, if present arrangements in the money fund market are seen as
subsidizing risk taking in some way, his recommendation was to either
remove the subsidy or tax it away, and then let the market determine
whether the funds survive or become extinct. Unfortunately, Mishkin
noted, the money market funds industry has devoted enormous resources to
avoiding any kind of regulation, and so far it has largely succeeded.
Hence, aside from the pure economics of the issue, there was also an
issue of political economy to be addressed, which Forbes had touched on:
are any of the current regulatory proposals both effective and
sufficiently salable to the interests involved to have a chance of being
enacted?
David Romer pointed out that nothing in the authors' proposal
would prevent money fund investors from, in effect, buying insurance
against becoming subject to an MBR, for example by creating derivatives
that imposed on a third party the obligation to pay the MBR when it
bound. Such an instrument would effectively convert the MBR into a
capital requirement, with the third party providing the capital. Or,
more precisely, it gave market participants the option of submitting to
the MBR or paying in capital. That flexibility seemed to Romer a point
in the proposal' s favor.
Romer also noted that the existence of money market funds was seen
by some as an important constraint on monetary policy: in this view, one
reason the Federal Reserve has refrained from lowering the federal funds
rate all the way to zero is that doing so would wipe out any margin the
money funds still earn, causing every one of them to break the buck.
This kind of monetary forbearance, Romer argued, imposes a real social
cost: a further 50 basis points of interest rate reduction in the
current environment would do a lot of economic good. Was preserving the
money fund industry worth it, or might some form of regulation be found
that removed that barrier to further monetary ease?
Gerald Cohen lamented the widespread misconception among retail
money fund investors that they were reaping a higher return than they
could get at a bank, with no countervailing increase in risk. Although
the danger of a run comes mainly from the institutional money fund
investors, the misplaced confidence of retail investors that their money
fund will never break the buck is potentially costly as well, because it
may give rise to a disequilibrium.
Donald Kohn sought to reassure the money funds' defenders that
the various reform proposals were not intended to drive the funds out of
business, but only to internalize the externality they created. Kohn
himself saw the need for such measures as all the greater, given that
the Dodd-Frank legislation has set limits on potential government
support for these funds in a future crisis. For example, the Federal
Reserve now has to jump through many more regulatory hoops when it
wishes to extend section 13(3) loans to nonbank institutions, and there
is a much greater emphasis on security and collateral than before the
act was passed. Now that Congress has decided that money funds will not
be bailed out in the next crisis, Kohn saw it as imperative that the
systemic risks they pose be minimized. He agreed that neither increased
capital nor MBRs nor floating NAVs would suffice to prevent another
major crisis, but such measures might at least alert the public to the
fact that money funds have risks.
Liliana Rojas-Suarez cautioned the Panel against expecting too much
from a single reform of one part of one side of the financial
system's ledger. As she saw it, the core of any systemic banking
crisis is on the asset side--not the liability side, which the MBR
addressed. She doubted that a reform that focused only on one type of
bank funding would do much to reduce systemic risk, and she worried that
reform of the money fund industry undertaken in isolation would lead to
regulatory arbitrage, causing assets to be channeled to other,
unregulated or less regulated instruments and institutions, possibly in
foreign financial havens.
Steven Davis expanded on Reis's point that if MBRs would be
good for the money market funds, they should be good for banks as well.
He observed that many of the costs associated with a run are internal to
the institution--broadly defined to include both shareholders and
depositors-experiencing the run. That implies that financial
institutions themselves have strong incentives to prevent runs,
especially when no public provider of deposit insurance or lender of
last resort is present. This observation led Davis to wonder whether
there was anything to learn from the pre-deposit insurance era in the
United States. Did banks back then experiment with MBRs or MBR-like
mechanisms? If not, why not?
Bradford DeLong, addressing Davis's question, said that the
New York banks, at least, of that era dealt with crises by explicitly
suspending payment on deposit accounts. They gave depositors the choice
of taking their money out on the spot at 98 cents on the dollar, or
forbearing while J. P. Morgan and the other captains of finance tried to
resolve the crisis, and receiving 100 cents on the dollar if they
succeeded. This kind of private ad hoc central banking worked reasonably
well, as evidenced by the fact that the public did not abandon their use
of banks in the crisis's aftermath. Jeffrey Miron added that the
banks in these episodes often took these extreme steps in the face of
explicit prohibition by state and other regulators, which under the
circumstances either looked the other way or actively encouraged or even
directed the banks to suspend payment. DeLong cited similar instructions
from the British chancellor of the Exchequer to the governor of the Bank
of England during the 19th century.
The discussion of past policy responses prompted Christopher
Carroll to cast the net further. Many countries today, he observed, have
well-developed financial systems today that did not have them in J. P.
Morgan's day. Have any of these experimented with solutions to runs
from which lessons could be drawn?
Responding to the discussion, Patrick McCabe suggested a general
framework for thinking about money market funds. He observed that these
funds at present claim to offer three benefits: principal stability,
immediate and complete liquidity, and market-based yields that reflect
holdings with some credit risk. That, he posited, was not a tenable
combination, and because of the externalities it generated, something
had to be given up. If one believes that by sacrificing one of these
three features, the money fund industry becomes nonviable, that says
something about whether it should have existed in the first place. He
and his coauthors were persuaded, however, that a portfolio system of
regulation could be devised where investors themselves could choose
which of the three mutually incompatible features to give up, and the
money fund industry could in principle survive. In the end the authors
were agnostic as to whether the industry should survive, but they
believed that it could survive without creating a permanent and costly
distortion.
McCabe remarked further that the paper's intention was not to
offer a global solution but only to describe the specific MBR proposal.
That said, the authors believed that an MBR could usefully complement
increased capital requirements. Large capital buffers might prove
effective for a number of years only to be overrun in a major crisis, as
Perry had noted; the MBR provided a disincentive to such a run. The two
measures could thus work in tandem.
McCabe also addressed the question of the money fund
industry's rank ordering of preferences. Essentially the industry
wanted none of the above--neither floating NAVs nor increased capital
requirements nor MBRs--but instead was leaning toward a fourth proposal:
when a fund's liquidity drops below a certain level, all
redemptions would be suspended or fees would be imposed. This approach
would avoid taking any of the three benefits listed above off the table,
at least in normal times, but in the authors' view it would
heighten rather than dampen the probability of preemptive runs,
contagion, and the like when markets become jittery. It was akin, McCabe
remarked, to spreading kindling in a dry forest.
On the question of differentiating between institutional and retail
investors, McCabe said that he and his coauthors were mindful of the
fact that the latter did not run from money funds during the recent
crisis. Accordingly, the paper called for an exemption from
subordination for redemptions under $50,000, but the authors were not
wedded to that figure. One of the proposals offered by the Financial
Stability Oversight Council suggested a $100,000 exemption.
Replying to Reis, McCabe argued that the MBR proposal was expressly
designed to give institutional managers an incentive to carefully
monitor the money funds in which they were investing well in advance of
any problems. He noted that the Reserve Primary Fund had maintained an
extremely conservative portfolio until the summer of 2007, when it
dramatically increased its yield, and it tripled its assets between
August 2007 and mid-2008. But the smart money in this institutional fund
believed, correctly as it turned out, that in a crisis they could get
their money out before everyone else. An MBR, McCabe suggested, would
have dissuaded investors from piling into this increasingly risky fund
in such unstable conditions.
PATRICK E. McCABE
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
MARCO CIPRIANI
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
MICHAEL HOLSCHER
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
ANTOINE MARTIN
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
(1.) For example, at the end of 2012, MMFs owned over 40 percent of
outstanding dollar-denominated financial commercial paper (short-term
debt issued by financial corporations, usually with maturities of under
90 days). The funds also owned 29 percent of banks' large time
deposits (deposits with fixed maturities in amounts of $100,000 or more)
issued in the United States. These figures come from MMF filings of U.S.
Securities and Exchange Commission form N-MFP, the Depository Trust
& Clearing Corporation, and Federal Reserve Flow of Funds data.
(2.) Like other "open end" mutual funds, MMFs transact
directly with shareholders (investors), who can purchase shares from the
MMF or redeem shares (sell them back to the fund) at a price equal to
the fund's NAV. In a run on an MMF, investors redeem shares
immediately, possibly only because they believe they otherwise would be
harmed by the effects of other investors' redemptions.
(3.) We originally proposed the MBR in a July 2012 working version
of this paper, available at
www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr564.pdf. The Financial
Stability Oversight Council subsequently incorporated the MBR, much as
we described it there, in its "Proposed Recommendations Regarding
Money Market Mutual Fund Reform" (Financial Stability Oversight
Council 2012b). Alternative Two in the Financial Stability Oversight
Council's proposed recommendations would require MMFs to have MBRs.
See section I below.
(4.) The SEC adopted rule 2a-7 under the Investment Company Act of
1940 to allow MMFs to use procedures that help maintain a stable NAV.
Most notably, rule 2a-7 allows a fund to round the underlying market
value of its shares to the nearest cent when calculating its NAV. In
return for allowing these procedures, rule 2a-7 places restrictions on
MMF portfolios with regard to credit quality, liquidity, maturity, and
diversification. Rule 2a-7 has been amended several times since 1983,
most recently in 2010, when portfolio restrictions were tightened and
new reporting requirements added.
(5.) These figures are based on our own calculations using SEC form
N-MFP data for prime MMFs. See also Scharfstein (2012) and Hanson and
others (2012).
(6.) The PWG, which was essentially the predecessor of the
Financial Stability Oversight Council, comprised the secretary of the
Treasury, the chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, the chairman of the SEC, and the chairman of the Commodity
Futures Trading Commission.
(7.) "Taxpayers and Money Market Funds [Editorial]," Wall
Street Journal, May 9, 2011.
(8.) Section IV.E discusses the appropriate length for the delay
period in more detail. In addition, the period over which R is computed
should be as long as the redemption delay period, since a shorter period
for calculating R would allow investors to circumvent the delay period
for all but a tiny portion of their shares by redeeming all available
balances and waiting a few days for the reference amount to decline.
(9.) If the investor's reference amount is his high-water
mark, his balance cannot exceed his reference amount.
(10.) Alternative Two of the FSOC's proposed recommendations
would provide a $100,000 exemption both from the MBR and from any
subordination (FSOC 2012b).
(11.) We are grateful to Eric Rosengren for suggesting, during
discussions with staff at the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, the
possibility of a threshold below which subordination would not apply.
(12.) Retail MMFs were much less likely than their institutional
counterparts to suffer very large outflows during the run in 2008 (PWG
2010, McCabe 2010), and retail funds experienced relatively small net
outflows in the summer of 2011, when concerns about MMFs' European
exposures and the possible consequences of a breakdown in debt ceiling
negotiations triggered large redemptions from institutional MMFs (see,
for example, Chernenko and Sunderam 2013). Indeed, differences in the
riskiness of retail and institutional funds led the SEC to consider
different liquidity requirements for the two types in its proposed
amendments to rule 2a-7 (U.S. SEC 2009). However, many MMFs have both
retail and institutional investors--this was one factor that led the SEC
not to adopt such a distinction (U.S. SEC 2010).
(13.) This assumption rules out an MMF rounding up its share price
to $1 and hence redeeming shares for more than their underlying value
("dilutive redemptions"). See section III for further
discussion.
(14.) We analyze these incentives more formally in a simple model
in section 4 of our working paper.
(15.) A money fund's shadow NAV is essentially the market
value of its portfolio divided by the number of its shares. Under
current rules an MMF can maintain a stable $1 NAV as long as its shadow
NAV does not deviate by more than one-half cent from $1.
(16.) Relaxing this assumption would generally increase the
advantages enjoyed by redeeming shareholders, so MMFs that allow
dilutive redemptions would need larger MBRs to reduce the threat of runs
than would funds that do not allow dilutive redemptions.
(17.) Strictly speaking, the MMF modeled in this section differs in
two respects from the status quo: it has a 0.5 percent NAV-stabilizing
buffer, and it allows no dilutive redemptions (it closes when losses
exceed the buffer).
(18.) In contrast, a comparison of investors' losses as a
percentage of the shares they hold at the time of a fund's closure
would fail to take into account the cash that redeeming investors have
removed from the fund. Thus, it would overstate the redeeming
investors' total losses as a share of their holdings at the time
they make the decision to redeem or remain invested.
(19.) In section IV.C we review empirical evidence suggesting that
this assumption about the cost of lost access to MMF shares is not
unreasonable (section 6.2 of our working paper discusses the evidence in
more detail). But the qualitative points we make here are important as
long as the liquidity cost is material to investors. Note that these
liquidity costs to investors whose MMF shares are unavailable for an
indefinite period after a fund's closure are distinct from the
costs that a still-open fund may incur to liquidate assets to meet
shareholders' redemptions.
(20.) This result does not depend on our assumption here that
preservation of liquidity is worth 0.5 percent to investors; any
nontrivial price for liquidity makes redeemers relatively better off.
(21.) In this example, because no other investor redeems, the
redeeming investor is effectively leveraged by the ratio of the
fund's assets to her assets when the fund's losses exceed its
capital buffer, up to the point at which the redeeming investor's
subordinated MBR is absorbed. This stark allocation of losses is
admittedly an extreme example. Data from the Investment Company
Institute (2012) show that monthly redemptions in MMFs from 2009 to 2011
averaged 45 percent of the funds' assets, so the likelihood that a
30-day period might pass in which only one or a few investors redeem
shares seems remote. Notably, the retail exemption discussed in section
II.C also would help ensure that small redemptions never lead to
subordination of those investors' MBRs.
(22.) Put differently, when many investors redeem, each redeeming
investor's MBR is less highly leveraged than the MBR of a single
redeeming investor if no one else redeems.
(23.) Figure 7 can also be used to illustrate the effect of
relaxing our assumption that all investors are small. Consider, for
example, the case in which no other investor redeems. Then, the loss
function of an investor who owns 25 percent of all outstanding shares in
the fund and who redeems all of her shares is the same as for the small,
fully redeeming investor when others redeem 25 percent. Because the
larger investor owns a greater portion of the fund, the subordination
creates less effective leverage for her MBR than it would for the MBR of
a smaller investor (in the limit, the loss function of an investor who
owns all the shares in a fund is unaffected by an MBR or subordination).
The loss function for the larger investor, if she does not redeem, is
the same as for the small, nonredeeming investor when others do not
redeem.
(24.) These points are developed more formally in a simple model in
section 4 of our working paper. Although our focus here is on
investors' expected losses, we believe that the key insights of the
section would be similar if we considered other moments of the loss
distribution.
(25.) Diana B. Henriques, "Money Funds Could Face More
Changes," New York Times, January 7, 2012.
www.nytimes.com/2012/01/08/business/mutfund/money-market-funds-may-soon-face-more- changes.html?pagewanted=all&_r=0.
(26.) The SEC's 2010 rule amendments for MMFs introduced new
requirements for disclosure of support that should assist in estimating
the value of such interventions. Even so, precise estimates of the
real-time value of support actions are likely to remain elusive.
(27.) The Primary Fund's losses were caused largely by its
$785 million in holdings of Lehman debt obligations (1.3 percent of the
fund's assets) at the time of Lehman's bankruptcy. RCMI, the
adviser to the fund, announced at about 4 pm on Tuesday, September 16,
2008, that the NAV of the fund's shares had dropped by 3 percent,
to 97 cents, presumably because large redemptions had further eroded the
NAV. However, a June 2009 court order regarding distribution of the
Primary Fund's assets indicated that the value of those assets
ultimately would allow shareholders to receive 98.4 cents per share,
although this amount included income earned on the assets after the
Primary Fund was closed. See the plaintiffs complaint in SEC v. Reserve
Management Company, Docket no. 09-cv-4346, U.S. District Court for the
Southern District of New York, May 5, 2009, p. 3,
www.sec.gov/litigation/complaints/2009/ comp21025.pdf, and the court
order in the same case, June 8, 2009, p. 35, www.sec.gov/spotlight/
reserve_primary_fund_investors/gardephe_order.pdf. Some statements by
the fund's sponsor have referred to the portion of the fund's
assets--some of which lost significant value--that have been returned to
investors as part of the fund's liquidation process, rather than to
investors' principal losses as claimants upon those assets. An
example is the following, quoted in Anderson (2010) from a Reserve press
release: "Including this seventh distribution, $50.7 billion, or
approximately 99.04% of Fund assets as of the close of business on
September 15, 2008, will have been returned to investors."
(28.) In addition, Moody's (Moody's Investors Service
2010) found that between 2007 and 2010, 21 MMF sponsors spent at least
$12.1 billion to maintain stable NAVs for their funds, although that
figure includes support for some European funds and some nonregistered
investment pools. Moody's totals were not stated as shares of the
supported funds' NAVs.
(29.) The Treasury's temporary guarantee program was announced
on September 19, but some funds provided data for shadow NAVs on dates
before the program's inception.
(30.) This total could exclude MMFs that received direct cash
infusions from sponsors or benefited from sponsors' outright
purchases of securities from the fund at above-market prices.
(31.) Here we assume that the investor can take out such a loan. An
investor who faces borrowing constraints presumably would have larger
liquidity costs.
(32.) Since we lack sufficient data to estimate reliably the
density function of realized losses in the event that an MMF breaks the
buck, we use the exponential distribution as a means of capturing the
relatively high frequency of extreme returns in financial market data.
Our aim is to calibrate an MBR of sufficient size to provide stability
for the typical MMF in distress. The investor's decision to redeem
or not must come before that loss is known, since a realized loss
exceeding 0.5 percent would lead to the fund's closure and preclude
further redemptions. Our calibration also assumes that the investor
knows only that losses are drawn from the industry-wide distribution
described here. More realistically, an investor in a given MMF would
have information about the size of the fund's exposure to
distressed assets and could base her decision on that more specific
information.
(33.) Because other investors' redemptions can provide a
protective (subordinated) buffer in an MMF with a strong MBR rule, the
assumption that other investors do not redeem generally has relatively
minor effects on our calibration. Section 6.3 of our working paper
examines how changes in these assumptions affect our estimates of the
appropriate size of the MBR.
(34.) For further discussion of these externalities, see FSOC
(2012b), section VI.
(35.) Raising the cost of short-term borrowing could be a desirable
outcome of reform, given that such borrowing itself may have negative
externalities (see, for example, Brunnermeier and Oehmke 2013).
(36.) Comments on the FSOC's proposed recommendations can be
found at www.regulations.
gov/#!docketBrowser;rpp=50;po=0;D=FSOC-2012-0003.
(37.) Less regulated substitutes for MMFs already exist and hold
sizable portfolios. For example, data from iMoneyNet indicate that
"offshore" MMFs that denominate their shares in dollars had
about $400 billion in assets under management at the end of 2012, and
"enhanced cash" funds that rely on exemptions from the
Investment Company Act to avoid MMF rules had about $200 billion in
assets in mid-2012. In general, such substitutes are available only to
institutional investors. For more on potential shifts of assets to MMF
substitutes, see U.S. SEC (2012).
(38.) A prerequisite for these benefits is that the share prices of
MMFs actually fluctuate on a regular basis. Under current rules MMFs can
round their share prices to the nearest cent, so any variations of less
than 0.5 percent in the value of an MMF's portfolio are rounded
away. The values of MMF portfolios typically vary only by a few
hundredths of I percent, so share prices almost never vary. One proposal
for floating NAVs would allow MMFs to maintain $10 NAVs and round to the
nearest cent, so variations of less than 0.05 percent still would be
rounded away. That approach likely would preserve stable share prices
and undermine the potential benefits of a floating NAV.
(39.) The sources cited here mention only that MMFs may be seen as
an impediment to easing of policy; they do not focus in detail on those
concerns.
(40.) MMFs pay their expenses (for example, for managing
portfolios, processing transactions, and maintaining shareholder account
data) out of the yields they earn on portfolio securities. Under current
practices a fund that maintains a stable NAV and charges expenses that
exceed portfolio yields would experience a destabilizing decline in the
underlying value of its shares. MMFs have avoided this option, so the
very low interest rates that have prevailed in recent years have
diminished the revenue that MMFs can feasibly earn. Recently, however,
stable-NAV money funds have explored novel options for handling low or
even negative rates on short-term instruments. For example,
euro-denominated funds have announced plans to pay expenses by
decreasing the number of shares that investors own, rather than charging
fees that reduce the value of those shares (see Moody's Investors
Service 2012a, 2012b).
(41.) The effect of capital on ex ante risk mitigation would depend
on how the capital is financed. If capital were raised by creating a
subordinated class of shares, the investors who purchased those shares
would face strengthened incentives to monitor risks (BlackRock 2011,
Hanson and others 2012). In contrast, if a small buffer were raised by
retaining a portion of the fund's own income over many years (as
proposed by Goebel and others 2011), the effect on incentives for
monitoring risks is less clear. A sponsor-provided capital buffer
presumably would reduce incentives for risk taking, although the
considerable record of sponsors already providing implicit support
("ex post" capital) for their money funds clearly does not
provide incentives adequate to prevent MMFs from taking risks that pose
threats to financial stability.
(42.) Prime MMFs accounted for 58 percent of the industry's
assets at the end of 2012. Two other types of MMFs account for the rest:
government MMFs generally hold securities issued by the U.S. Treasury,
federal agencies, and government-sponsored enterprises such as Freddie
Mac and Fannie Mae, as well as repos backed by such securities; and
tax-exempt MMFs hold municipal securities.
(43.) Tax-exempt MMFs, especially those sold to institutional
investors, also experienced substantial outflows in September 2008, but
the magnitude of the decline was far smaller than that for prime MMFs.
(Weekly data from the Investment Company Institute indicate that assets
in institutional tax-exempt MMFs fell 12 percent from September 10 to
October 1, 2008, while assets of institutional prime funds plummeted 29
percent in the same period.) Government MMFs also have experienced
strains at times: one such fund operated by Reserve experienced very
heavy redemptions in 2008, and many government funds had heavy outflows
in the summer of 2011 amid concerns about the federal debt ceiling
impasse (FSOC 2012b).
(44.) Alternatively, the size of the MBR could depend on the
composition of the fund's portfolio. Both the FSOC's proposed
recommendations and Hanson and others (2012) suggest such an approach in
determining the required size of a capital buffer.
(45.) In our working paper we call this adjustment the
"effective MBR rule." We show that an effective rule that caps
subordination at 40 percent of the MBR, in combination with an MBR of 5
percent, would achieve about the same degree of stability as a strong
MBR rule (one that allows all of the MBR to be subordinated) and an MBR
of 3 percent.
(46.) Funds with assets greater than $1 billion accounted for over
80 percent of institutional prime MMF assets. Data on minimum initial
investments are from iMoneyNet.
(47.) For example, the SEC found in 2005 that "one of the
biggest obstacles to preventing short-term trading is the existence of
omnibus account platforms" (U.S. SEC 2005, p. 49) and that "a
number of the market timing abuses identified through our investigations
reveal that certain shareholders were concealing abusive market timing
trades through omnibus accounts" (U.S. SEC 2005, pp. 6-7).
(48.) Section 6 of our working paper provides more details of that
analysis, including sensitivity analyses to address the uncertainties of
estimating expected losses in a distressed MMF and the challenges of
pinpointing liquidity costs to investors who lose access to shares in a
closed fund.
(49.) The outflows in 2011 occurred despite the fact that the
European exposures caused no losses for MMFs (see FSOC 2012b, Chernenko
and Sunderam 2013). In contrast, in August 2007, as the asset-backed
commercial paper (ABCP) crisis unfolded and many MMFs suffered
substantial losses due to holdings of distressed ABCP, institutional
investors generally did not redeem MMF shares (McCabe 2010).
Table 1. Minimum Shadow NAVs of Reporting Money Market Funds,
September 5 to October 17, 2008 (a)
Average minimum
No. of reported shadow NAV
MMFs (dollars per share)
All reporting MMFs 72 0.989
MMFs reporting a minimum shadow NAV
under $0.995 29 0.978
MMFs reporting a minimum shadow NAV
between $0.95 and $0.995 26 0.985
Memorandum: Minimum reported shadow
NAV for any MMF 1 0.903
Sources: U.S. Department of the Treasury and U.S. Securities and
Exchange Commission.
(a.) Reported shadow NAVs exclude the effects of guarantees from
sponsors but may include the effects of some other forms of sponsor
support, such as direct cash infusions to the fund or outright
purchases of securities from the fund at above-market prices.