The minimum balance at risk: a proposal to mitigate the systemic risks posed by money market funds.
McCabe, Patrick E. ; Cipriani, Marco ; Holscher, Michael 等
ABSTRACT This paper introduces a proposal for money market fund
(MMF) reform to mitigate the systemic risk and externalities that arise
from the funds' vulnerability to runs and to protect shareholders
who do not redeem quickly when runs occur. Our proposal would require
that a small fraction of each MMF shareholder's recent balances,
called the "minimum balance at risk" (MBR), be available for
redemption only with a delay of 30 days. Most regular transactions in
the fund would be unaffected; the requirement would only affect
redemptions of the shareholder's MBR. In addition, in the rare
event that a fund suffers losses, the MBRs of investors who have
recently made large redemptions would absorb losses before those of
nonredeeming investors. This subordination of redeeming investors'
MBRs would create a disincentive to redeem if the fund is likely to have
losses, but would have little effect on incentives when the risk of loss
is remote. We use empirical evidence, including a novel data set from
the U.S. Treasury and the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission on MMF
losses in 2008, to calibrate an MBR rule that would reduce the
vulnerability of MMFs to runs.
**********
By many measures, money market funds (MMFs, or "money
funds") are a popular financial product. With $2.7 trillion in
assets under management at the end of 2012, MMFs represented over a
fifth of all U.S. mutual fund assets, according to the Investment
Company Institute. MMFs are key intermediaries of short-term funding and
hold large fractions of the short-term debt issued by financial
institutions in capital markets. (1) The popularity of money funds
largely reflects the attractiveness of their defining feature for many
investors: MMFs, unlike other mutual funds, typically maintain a stable
$1.00 share price (also known as the fund's "net asset
value," or NAV). Their stability of principal allows MMFs to serve
as an important cash management tool for individuals, firms,
institutions, and governments.
However, MMFs are vulnerable to runs, and given the size of the
money fund industry and its importance in allocating short-term funding
to financial institutions, this vulnerability poses considerable risk to
the financial system. The potentially dire consequences of a run on MMFs
were evident in September 2008, when the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy
caused one fund to "break the buck" (that is, its NAV fell
below $1, so its investors suffered principal losses) and triggered
massive and widespread redemptions from other MMFs. (2) These outflows
were a key factor in the virtual shutdown of short-term funding markets
and a broader curtailment of credit supply (see, for example, Federal
Open Market Committee 2008, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System 2009, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission 2009,
President's Working Group on Financial Markets 2010). The severity
of the damage to financial stability caused by the run in 2008 led to
unprecedented government interventions to support MMFs in order to halt
the run. Since then, the funds' vulnerability has continued to pose
risks to the financial system. The heavy exposures of MMFs to European
financial institutions, for example, have put the funds at risk of
transmitting strains from Europe very rapidly to U.S. short-term funding
markets (Financial Stability Oversight Council 2011, Chernenko and
Sunderam 2013). Yet policymakers have fewer tools available now to
address MMF runs than they did in 2008; in particular, the
Treasury's Temporary Guarantee Program for Money Market Funds,
which effectively halted the run in 2008, would no longer be possible
under current law: the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008
specifically prohibits the Treasury from reusing that mechanism. In
light of the systemic risk stemming from MMFs' susceptibility to
runs, calls for reform have come from government agencies (for example,
Schapiro 2010, 2011, 2012, President's Working Group on Financial
Markets 2010, Financial Stability Oversight Council 2011, 2012a, 2012b),
from academics (for example, Squam Lake Group 2011, Hanson, Scharfstein,
and Sunderam 2012), and from the financial industry (for example,
Mendelson and Hoerner 2011, Goebel, Dwyer, and Messman 2011).
This paper proposes a new approach to mitigating the vulnerability
of MMFs to runs by introducing a "minimum balance at risk"
(MBR) that could provide a disincentive to run from a troubled money
fund. (3) The MBR would be a small fraction (for example, 5 percent) of
each shareholder's recent balances that could be redeemed only with
a delay. The delay would ensure that redeeming investors remain
partially invested in the fund long enough (we suggest 30 days) to share
in any imminent portfolio losses or costs of their redemptions. However,
as long as an investor's balance exceeds her MBR, the rule would
have no effect on her transactions, and no portion of any redemption
would be delayed if her remaining shares exceed her minimum balance.
An MBR could be introduced in a manner that preserves the basic
features of MMFs. Funds could, for example, maintain stable $1 NAVs and
honor most transactions without any delay or restrictions. The loss
allocation rules that are central to the MBR concept would affect
shareholders' actual balances only in the event that a fund breaks
the buck and closes. Implementation would require an MMF to track just
two additional variables for each investor: her MBR and any portion of
her MBR that she has requested to redeem. Importantly, the MBR concept
could be introduced together with other reforms. In particular, we
suggest that an MBR would work well in tandem with a capital buffer
requirement for money funds.
An appropriately designed MBR would have several benefits. By
discouraging investors from redeeming from a troubled MMF, an MBR would
help prevent a run and its destabilizing and costly repercussions. This
not only would benefit the fund and its investors but also would
mitigate the externalities that result from an MMF's potential to
propagate strains throughout the financial system. An MBR also would
benefit investors who are not prone to redeem shares quickly at the
first sign of trouble for an MMF. In particular, retail investors
(small, typically individual investors, as distinct from institutional
investors such as corporate treasurers), who historically have been less
quick to run from distressed funds, would enjoy additional protections
because the MBR would prevent non-redeeming shareholders from
shouldering all losses in the event that a fund breaks the buck.
Moreover, by clarifying that investors cannot avoid imminent losses by
redeeming shares quickly in a crisis, an MBR should strengthen
incentives for early market discipline for MMFs and motivate investors
to identify potential problems in a fund long before any losses occur.
We begin in section I with a discussion of the structural
vulnerability of MMFs to runs and recent proposals for reform. Section
II outlines the MBR concept, and section III illustrates how an MBR
would counter investors' incentives to redeem shares in a troubled
MMF. Section IV reviews empirical evidence, including that from a novel
data set from the U.S. Department of the Treasury and the U.S.
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) on MMF losses during September
and October 2008, to calibrate an MBR rule that would reduce the
vulnerability of MMFs to runs. Section V discusses policy issues
relevant to the introduction of an MBR. Section VI concludes the paper.
I. Background, Policy Context, and Literature
The vulnerability of MMFs to runs can, in large measure, be traced
back to their stable $1 NAVs, to the characteristics of investors who
are attracted to stable-value funds, and to the methods that MMFs use to
maintain price stability. Like other mutual funds, MMFs provide maturity
and liquidity transformation by holding a combination of highly liquid
assets and less liquid, longer-dated securities while allowing
shareholders to redeem shares on demand. But unlike other mutual funds,
MMFs redeem shares at a price that almost never varies from $1 per share
(or, in a few MMFs, from $10 per share). Indeed, the historical success
of the funds in maintaining principal stability (only two money funds
have "broken the buck" since 1983, when the SEC adopted rule
2a-7 to govern MMFs) has attracted a large, highly risk-averse
shareholder base that includes many sophisticated institutional
investors. (4) These shareholders reportedly view principal stability as
the "hallmark" feature of MMFs (Investment Company Institute
2009, Stevens 2011) and hence are prone to pulling out of an MMF quickly
at any sign of trouble.
Although the stable NAV is critical for many MMF investors, no
capital buffer or insurance guarantees a money fund's $1 share
value. Instead, MMFs have relied on a combination of strict SEC rules on
portfolio composition, the ability to round their NAVs to the nearest
cent (see the previous footnote), and when all else fails, financial
support from their sponsors (investment management firms and their
affiliates) when they have the wherewithal to provide it (Moody's
Investors Service 2010, Rosengren 2012, Schapiro 2012, Brady, Anadu, and
Cooper 2012, Financial Stability Oversight Council 2012b). Importantly,
this support is voluntary and provided on a discretionary basis;
sponsors are not required to support an ailing fund, either by
regulation or by contract.
However, if shareholders begin to doubt the ability of these
mechanisms to prevent losses, they have strong incentives to redeem
shares before others do. Institutional shareholders appear to be
particularly attuned to these incentives (President's Working Group
on Financial Markets 2010, McCabe 2010, Chernenko and Sunderam 2013).
The imperative to be the first to exit means that any sign of serious
strains for an MMF--or concerns that other shareholders perceive such a
problem--may be enough to trigger a run.
The incentive to redeem before others do arises largely because
investors who redeem shares from a troubled MMF may benefit by imposing
costs on other shareholders. This uneven allocation of risks and losses
between redeeming and nonredeeming shareholders results from the same
money fund practices and features that help maintain the stable NAV.
Most importantly, because MMFs round their NAVs to the nearest cent, an
investor who redeems shares from a fund that has incurred a loss of less
than 0.5 percent can still obtain $1 per share. In effect, the fund
transfers a redeeming shareholder's pro rata share of the loss to
the fund's nonredeeming shareholders, as the loss is concentrated
over a shrinking number of shares.
MMFs' liquidity management practices also contribute to
principal stability while heightening the advantages for investors who
redeem quickly from troubled money funds. MMFs typically meet
redemptions by disposing of their more liquid assets, rather than by
selling a cross section of their holdings. Redeemers who receive $1 per
share thus bear none of the liquidity costs of their redemptions and
leave nonredeeming investors with claims on a less liquid portfolio.
MMFs' imperative to maintain a stable NAV (and comply with
rule 2a-7) also leads the funds to hold similar portfolios, a fact that
contributes to contagion risk among MMFs. That is, redemptions from one
MMF can hurt shareholders in other funds. Money funds generally can hold
only assets with the highest short-term ratings, and given the
relatively small number of private firms with such ratings, MMFs that
provide funding to private firms tend to have exposures to similar sets
of counterparties--mostly large financial institutions. As of September
30, 2012, for example, 50 private issuers accounted for 91 percent of
the nongovernmental investments of prime MMFs, which largely invest in
short-term debt instruments issued by private firms, and all but 4 of
these 50 issuers were financial firms. (5) Redemptions that force one
MMF to sell less liquid assets may put downward pressure on the prices
of these assets (particularly given the thinness of secondary markets
for many money market instruments), place other MMFs at risk of
suffering losses, and prompt shareholders in those funds to redeem
shares preemptively.
The severity of the run on MMFs in September 2008 and its broader
consequences prompted calls for reforms to mitigate the systemic risks
arising from MMFs' structural vulnerability to runs. Subsequent
concerns that the funds might transmit strains from the European debt
crisis to U.S. short-term funding markets provided further motivation
for reform (Financial Stability Oversight Council 2011, Schapiro 2011,
Rosengren 2012).
In 2010 the SEC adopted amendments to rule 2a-7 to make MMFs more
resilient to market disruptions by, for example, tightening liquidity,
maturity, credit quality, and disclosure requirements. Nonetheless, as
these reforms were adopted, SEC Chairman Mary Schapiro recognized a need
"to pursue more fundamental changes to the structure of money
market funds to further protect them from the risk of runs"
(Schapiro 2010). Later that year the President's Working Group on
Financial Markets (PWG) "agree[d] with the SEC that more should be
done to address MMFs' susceptibility to runs" and offered
eight options for reducing this vulnerability (PWG 2010, p. 1). (6) In
August 2012, however, Chairman Schapiro announced that the SEC would not
vote to propose further MMF reforms. A month later, Treasury Secretary
Timothy Geithner requested that the Financial Stability Oversight
Council (FSOC) use its authority to recommend that the SEC address the
systemic risks posed by MMFs. The FSOC issued proposed recommendations
in November 2012, including three alternatives for MMF reform: the first
would require MMFs to have a floating NAV, the second called for an MBR
paired with a small capital buffer, and the third proposed a larger
capital buffer, possibly combined with other measures (FSOC 2012b). In
June 2013 the SEC proposed two options for MMF reform: a floating NAV
for prime MMFs sold to institutional investors and a requirement that
funds impose or consider fees and restrictions for redemptions if their
liquid assets fall below a threshold (U.S. SEC 2013).
More generally, proposals for MMF reform have focused on three
possible alternatives to the MBR for mitigating the funds'
vulnerability to runs: a switch to floating NAVs, a mandate that funds
maintain capital buffers, and requirements that MMFs impose fees or
other (non-MBR) restrictions on redemptions. All three options have
merits and drawbacks. For example, the floating NAV, which has been
advocated by, among others, the Group of Thirty (2009), Jeffrey Lacker
(2011), the Wall Street Journal, (7) and Paul Volcker (2011), could
eliminate the destabilizing consequences of NAV rounding and remove the
discontinuity in MMF pricing--and some of the resulting
disruptions--when share values fall below the 99.5 cent threshold. But
MMFs with floating NAVs probably would remain at some risk of runs, in
part because the funds' liquidity management practices would
continue to give an advantage to early redeemers from funds with limited
liquid assets (see, for example, Hanson and others 2012, Gordon and
Gandia 2013). A full analysis of the relative merits of other reform
options is beyond the scope of this paper, but we discuss their pros and
cons in some detail in section V.
II. The Minimum Balance at Risk
The minimum balance at risk that we propose in this paper is a new
approach to MMF reform that would mitigate the risk of runs by limiting
the ability of redeeming investors to benefit by imposing risks, costs,
and losses on nonredeemers. The MBR would be a small fraction (for
example, 5 percent) of some measure of each investor's recent
balances. The investor could redeem her MBR only with a delay, which
would need to be sufficient (we suggest 30 days) to ensure that she
remains partially invested in the fund long enough to share in any
imminent portfolio losses or costs of her redemptions. The MBR would
have no effect on an investor's transactions in the fund as long as
her remaining shares exceed the MBR.
The MBR rule that we describe would impose no losses on any
investor unless that investor's MMF breaks the buck. In the rare
event that an MMF does break the buck and liquidate, the MBR rule would
allocate losses differently than under current rules, which divide
losses solely in proportion to each investor's shares in the fund
when it closes. Importantly, an MBR would make investors who otherwise
would have redeemed all of their shares shoulder some of a fund's
losses.
Conceptually, the MBR straddles the two main proposed approaches to
shoring up MMFs' stable NAVs: capital buffers and redemption
restrictions. By identifying a minimum portion of each investor's
balance that would be at risk for absorbing losses--whether or not the
investor redeems shares--the MBR essentially would serve a function
similar to that of capital. As a form of redemption restriction, the MBR
rule would always be in place, so investors could not redeem
preemptively to avoid the restriction. (In contrast, redemption
restrictions that are imposed only in times of stress may increase the
risk of MMF runs by creating an incentive to run before the restrictions
are imposed.) But even though the MBR would be in place at all times, it
would have no effect on most transactions in a fund, particularly during
normal times. Only when an MMF appears to be at risk of losses would the
MBR materially affect investors' incentives to redeem shares.
II.A. Basic Features
The MBR would be determined individually for each investor based on
his "reference amount" R, which might be his maximum balance
("high-water mark") in the fund over the previous 30 days or
his 30-day-average balance, or some other function of his recent
balances. Any reference amount should be calculated excluding any shares
that have been held back (that is, made subject to redemption with a
delay).
The MBR for investor i would be a fraction m of the investor's
reference amount. That is, [MBR.sub.i] = [mR.sub.i]. For illustration,
we discuss a rule with m = 5 percent; in any case, m should be large
enough to give investors confidence that, in a crisis, their MMF's
losses would not exceed its aggregate MBR, that is, the sum of all its
shareholders' MBRs.
An investor with a total balance B would have an available balance
equal to B-MBR. As long as the investor's requested redemption
would not bring his balance below his MBR, his transactions would be
unaffected by the MBR rule. However, when the investor places a
redemption request that would bring his balance below the MBR, any
shortfall relative to the MBR would be redeemed with a delay. We propose
a delay of 30 days.
Both the redemption delay and the period over which R is calculated
should be long enough to minimize the opportunity for preemptive runs.
If the delay is short, informed shareholders may continue to see
redemptions at the first sign of a problem as an effective way to obtain
full payment for all their shares before any losses are realized. The
MBR in that case might even be destabilizing, since such investors might
redeem all shares as fast as possible in the hope that the delay period
passes before any material losses are realized. The 30-day delay that we
propose should be long enough to minimize the effectiveness of such a
strategy. (8)
II.B. Creating a Disincentive for Shareholders to Redeem
To be effective in braking redemptions from a troubled MMF and
mitigating the externalities associated with runs, an MBR rule must
create a disincentive for redemptions that is strong enough to counter
investors' powerful reasons to redeem when an MMF is under strain.
Since the MBR works by affecting the allocation of losses only in the
event that a fund breaks the buck, a sensible way to create such a
disincentive is by stipulating that redeeming investors absorb losses in
the fund before other investors. The MBR rule that we propose would
cause some or all of a redeemer's MBR to be subordinated relative
to nonredeemers' MBRs. That is, if an MMF breaks the buck,
redeeming shareholders' MBRs would absorb losses before
nonredeemers' MBRs do. Thus, as long as losses do not exceed a
fund's aggregate MBR, redeeming shareholders would shoulder a
larger share of the losses than nonredeemers.
Specifically, the fraction of a redeeming investor's MBR that
is subordinated would be the fraction of his available shares that he
has redeemed. That is,
subordinated balance = MBR x (cumulative net redemptions/potential
redemptions).
Cumulative net redemptions are the investor's reference amount
less his current balance (zero if his balance exceeds his reference
amount). (9) For example, if the reference amount is defined to be the
investor's 30-day high-water mark, his cumulative net redemptions
would be the high-water mark less his current balance. Potential
redemptions are his reference amount less his MBR. Thus,
subordinated balance = MBR x (reference amount - current
balance/reference amount - MBR),
as long as the reference amount exceeds the current balance
(otherwise, the subordinated balance is zero). Hence, all that is needed
to compute the subordinated balance is the investor's reference
amount, his MBR (which is just a fixed proportion of his reference
amount), and his current balance. For example, if an investor redeems
all his available shares, his current balance is his MBR, the ratio of
cumulative net redemptions to potential redemptions is 1, and the
investor's entire MBR would be subordinated. If his net redemptions
total only half of his potential redemptions, then half of his MBR would
be subordinated.
Subordination of redeemers' MBRs has several advantages.
First, as mentioned above, creating a disincentive to redeem is
essential to achieving substantial reduction of the risk of runs on
MMFs. An MBR without subordination of redeemers' balances only
partly mitigates the incentive to run, and given the intensity of
incentives to redeem from a troubled MMF, investors without a
disincentive to run still should be expected to run. Second, the
automatic strengthening of the disincentive when an MMF encounters
trouble would allow the subordination rule to be in effect at all times
without imposing an undue burden on a fund and its investors. Only in
the event that a fund experiences problems would the disincentive become
large enough to offset incentives to redeem. Even then, the rule still
would allow redemptions, but investors would face a trade-off between
redeeming shares to preserve liquidity and remaining invested to
safeguard principal. Notably, the strengthening of the disincentive for
redemptions would not require intervention by a fund's board or by
government officials. Third, a disincentive based on subordination would
allocate losses among investors only when an MMF breaks the buck--that
is, in circumstances in which investors would lose money under current
rules, too--but losses would be allocated first to those who have
recently redeemed and who thus contributed most to strains on the fund.
Fourth, the MBR would strengthen incentives for early market discipline
for MMFs by clarifying that investors cannot quickly redeem all shares
from a fund during a crisis. Since investors would have strong
incentives to identify potential problems well before any losses are
realized, the market discipline encouraged by the MBR likely would be
based more on investors' assessments of the riskiness of a
fund's strategy or operations, rather than on headlines that
trigger runs. Thus, redemptions that result from incentives created by
the MBR probably would be diffuse rather than concentrated and
destabilizing.
II.C. A Retail Exemption
The MBR concept is quite flexible, and a variety of adjustments
could be made to accommodate normative concerns. For example, some
adjustments to the MBR rule may be desirable to protect investors who
make small, routine redemptions from triggering subordination of their
MBRs. One adjustment would exempt the first $50,000 of an
investor's redemptions from subordination. An investor who redeems
less than $50,000 still would be subject to the MBR, but none of her MBR
would be subordinated. (10) Specifically, the rule would be
subordinated balance = MBR x (cumulative net redemptions -
$50,000/potential redemptions),
for cumulative net redemptions in excess of $50,000, and zero
otherwise. (11)
Thus, any investor with a balance of under $50,000 would never have
any portion of her MBR subordinated, so the adjustment would exempt many
retail MMF accounts from subordination. This may be appropriate, given
that retail investors are generally much less prone to run from
distressed MMFs than are institutional investors. (12) Of course, a
$50,000 exemption for redemptions would reduce protections for
nonredeeming investors, especially in retail MMFs. However, investors
would continue to be protected by the MBR itself, which would ensure
that redeeming investors share proportionally in any losses of principal
as long as losses do not exceed the fund's aggregate MBR.
II.D. Loss Allocation Rules with an MBR
In the event that an MMF with an MBR rule suffers losses, we assume
that those losses would be allocated in the following order:
--Losses would be allocated first to a capital buffer (if any). The
MBR rule that we propose would work well in tandem with a capital
buffer, since a well-calibrated MBR rule would make liquidity-related
losses less likely for MMFs and hence make a buffer of any size more
effective. Moreover, a capital buffer would augment an MBR in mitigating
investors' incentives to redeem when a fund suffers a loss. We
assume that if losses exceed the capital buffer, the fund would be
liquidated and remaining losses would be distributed according to the
MBR rule. (13)
--Any losses in excess of the buffer would be absorbed on a pro
rata basis by the subordinated portions (if any) of shareholders'
MBRs.
--Any additional losses would be absorbed on a pro rata basis by
the remaining portions of shareholders' MBRs.
--Any remaining losses would be divided on a pro rata basis over
all other shares in the fund.
III. A Closer Look: Incentives to Redeem under Different MBR Rules
Here we use a stylized example to illustrate the MBR concept and
the relative effectiveness of different MBR rules in discouraging runs
on money funds. Specifically, we examine how an MBR would affect the
incentives of an MMF shareholder when she learns that her MMF is in
distress. We show that investors' decisions to redeem depend not
only on the principal losses that the fund might suffer, but also on the
liquidity costs associated with losing access to cash invested in an MMF
that closes. (14) We also explore how different MBR rules affect the
linkages between one investor's losses and other investors'
redemptions.
We consider an MMF with an MBR of 5 percent of investors'
recent high-water marks (their reference amounts), and we focus on
outcomes for small investors who each own 0.1 percent of the fund's
assets. To illustrate how an MBR might complement a small,
NAV-stabilizing capital buffer, we assume that the fund has a 0.5
percent (50 basis point) buffer, so that in normal times it maintains a
mark-to-market ("shadow") NAV of $1.005. (15) Losses are
absorbed first by this buffer, and as long as losses are smaller than
0.5 percent, the fund can remain open and no losses are imposed on
shareholders. Any losses exceeding the buffer force the closure of the
fund, however, and are allocated first to subordinated MBRs, then to
non-subordinated MBRs, and finally to other MMF shares, as described in
section II.D. The assumption that the fund must close if its shadow NAV
falls below $1 rules out dilutive redemptions (that is, investors
receiving $1 for shares when the shadow NAV falls below $1), which are
costly for nonredeeming shareholders. (16) Indeed, in part because the
NAV-stabilizing buffer can eliminate the rationale for allowing dilutive
redemptions, we suggest that an MBR be introduced with such a buffer and
that dilutive redemptions be banned.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
III.A. No MBB (Status Quo but with a 0.5 Percent Capital Buffer)
Figure 1 shows how individual shareholders' losses would vary
with the losses in an MMF without an MBR, a situation equivalent to the
status quo except that we assume that the fund also has a 0.5 percent
capital buffer. (17) We consider three investors: one who redeems all
shares just before the losses are realized (the "fully redeeming
investor"), one who redeems 25 percent of her shares, and one who
redeems no shares. Each investor's losses are plotted as a fraction
of her preredemption assets (which are assumed to be her reference
amount). (18) In showing losses for each investor, we also assume that
others' redemptions from the fund are trivial.
As long as the fund's losses do not exceed 0.5 percent, the
fund stays open and no investor incurs a loss. However, once losses
exceed 0.5 percent, stark differences emerge. The fully redeeming
investor bears no loss under any circumstance. The investor who redeems
nothing suffers losses in proportion to the fund's losses in excess
of 0.5 percent. For example, in the case illustrated by the dashed
lines, if the fund loses 5.5 percent, the nonredeeming investor loses 5
percent. The investor who redeems 25 percent of her available balance
just before the fund's loss experiences only 75 percent of the
losses that the nonredeeming shareholder suffers.
Figure 1 illustrates only part of investors' strong incentive
to run under current rules, even with the small, NAV-stabilizing buffer.
Those who redeem immediately before a loss is reflected in a fund's
share price are able to shield themselves from any loss of principal. A
second reason to run is that other shareholders' redemptions at $1
per share concentrate losses on the remaining shareholders. The losses
incurred by the nonredeeming investor thus depend on the behavior of
other investors. Figure 2 illustrates this point by relaxing the
assumption in figure 1 that redemptions by other investors are trivial.
In this case the losses for a nonredeeming investor grow (the
upward-sloping region of the loss function rotates to the left) as the
fraction of shares that others redeem rises from zero to 25 percent and
50 percent. In contrast, the fully redeeming shareholder's losses
are still unaffected by others' redemptions: that
shareholder's losses are zero in all cases. This sharp disparity in
outcomes for redeeming and nonredeeming investors highlights the problem
that, under current rules, when a fund is perceived to be in trouble,
investors have a strong incentive to rush for the exits before others
do.
A third reason to redeem quickly from an MMF in trouble is that
others' redemptions can force the fund to sell assets, which may be
costly for nonredeeming shareholders (this point is not illustrated in
our charts). For example, if a fund suffers losses because it must
dispose of illiquid assets to raise cash, nonredeeming investors
shoulder at least a portion of those losses and thus effectively
subsidize redeeming investors. Even if a fund has enough liquid assets
to raise cash without suffering losses, heavy redemptions leave
remaining investors with claims on a less liquid portfolio.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
A fourth reason for an MMF shareholder to redeem quickly is to
preserve her own liquidity if the fund closes. We examine the incentive
to preserve liquidity in section III.B.
III.B. The "Simple" MBR Rule: No Subordination
Under what we call the simple MBR rule, redeeming
shareholders' MBRs are not subordinated. Instead, as figure 3
shows, losses in excess of a fund's NAV-stabilizing buffer are
allocated in proportion to shareholders' total MBRs, as long as the
fund's losses do not exceed its buffer plus its aggregate MBR (for
a 5 percent MBR rule, that loss threshold falls at 5.5 percent of the
fund's preredemption assets). The figure depicts the losses of
investors who redeem none, 25 percent, and all of their available shares
in an MMF with a simple MBR rule. Whereas all of an investor's
shares are available for redemption in the absence of an MBR, only 95
percent of each investor's reference amount is available with a 5
percent MBR.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
The simple MBR rule is a notable improvement on the "status
quo" (that is, a fund with just an NAV-stabilizing buffer). Because
investors' varying redemptions do not immediately reduce their
MBRs, the simple MBR rule ensures that all investors' loss
functions lie atop one another--at least as long as the fund's
losses are less than its buffer plus its aggregate MBR. Hence, the
simple rule ameliorates the allocation of losses among investors and
reduces incentives to redeem.
However, the simple rule has a very serious limitation: it only
reduces the incentive to redeem shares in a troubled MMF; it does not
eliminate that incentive. Even with the simple MBR rule, investors in a
troubled MMF would have several good reasons to redeem. First, the fully
redeeming investor limits his losses to his MBR; any losses in excess of
a fund's buffer plus its aggregate MBR are shouldered exclusively
by nonredeeming shareholders. In the stylized example in figure 3, once
the fund's losses exceed 5.5 percent, nonredeeming
shareholders' losses exceed those of redeeming shareholders. Hence,
redeeming all MMF shares is beneficial if losses are large, and it does
not make the investor worse off if losses are small. Second, redeeming
investors still may be able to shift liquidity-related costs arising
from their own redemptions to other investors in the fund. These costs
may be especially important during episodes of financial strain, when
liquidity is likely to be at a premium.
Third, even with the MBR, shareholders have an incentive to redeem
to safeguard their own liquidity, because those who do not redeem from
an MMF that closes may lose access to their cash during a prolonged
liquidation phase. Figure 4 illustrates this point under the simple
assumption that shareholders would be indifferent between having their
investments locked up in a closed MMF during a liquidation phase of
indefinite duration and having to incur a 0.5 percent fee to obtain all
of their assets immediately. (19) The figure shows losses for investors
both excluding (reproduced from figure 3) and including this opportunity
cost of lost liquidity. The magnitude of this cost depends on whether
the fund must close and the value of the investor's remaining
shares in the fund if it does close. (If losses erode the value of an
investor's shares in a closed fund, the value of his lost liquidity
declines proportionally.)
The nonredeeming investor's loss function inclusive of
liquidity cost jumps up at the point when losses exceed 0.5 percent,
since at that point the fund must close and the investor's entire
balance is locked up for the duration of the fund's liquidation
process. Importantly, with a simple MBR rule, when liquidity costs are
taken into account, any loss large enough to cause fund closure causes
greater losses for nonredeeming than for redeeming investors. (20) In
this example the fully redeeming investor's liquidity loss is at
most 2.5 basis points (0.5 percent of 5 percent of assets), and it
declines as the investor's MBR is absorbed. Hence, for this
investor the line representing losses inclusive of liquidity cost lies
just a bit above the line for losses exclusive of that cost when the MMF
itself experiences losses of less than 5.5 percent.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
This example illustrates some of the pros and cons of the simple
MBR rule. This rule would reduce redeemers' first-mover advantage
and allocate any losses that a fund might suffer more equally. Hence, it
would have some benefit, for example, in protecting retail investors,
who have proved to be much less likely to run than institutional
investors. However, the simple rule leaves investors with strong
incentives to run from distressed MMFs, since a redeeming investor
incurs no additional cost but limits her losses to the size of her MBR,
preserves her liquidity, and possibly imposes some liquidity costs on
others. Nonredeeming shareholders would still be at greatest risk of
suffering losses. Hence, the simple MBR rule does not eliminate the
destabilizing allocation of risks and costs between redeeming and
nonredeeming shareholders. Under such a rule, MMFs--particularly those
with large institutional investors that may be highly motivated to
preserve liquidity--still would be vulnerable to runs and constitute a
source of systemic risk.
III.C The "Strong" MBR Rule: Adding Subordination
The strong MBR rule addresses the shortcomings of the simple rule
by subordinating the MBRs of redeeming investors to create a
disincentive to redeem. As outlined in section II.B, the fraction of an
investor's MBR that is subordinated would be equal to the fraction
of her available balance that she has redeemed. Figure 5 shows the
allocation of losses in a fund under the strong rule, again with the
assumptions that all other redemptions from the fund are trivial and
that liquidity costs due to losing access to shares in a closed fund are
zero. (For simplicity, we do not incorporate the retail exemption
discussed in section II.C.)
Under the strong rule, if the fund's losses are smaller than
its buffer plus its aggregate MBR, the fully redeeming investor fares
worse than the investor who redeems less or not at all. In this stark
example, the fully redeeming investor loses her entire MBR for MMF
losses just slightly larger than 0.5 percent, because other investors do
not redeem anything. By redeeming her entire available balance, she has
put her full MBR in a subordinated position, but without other
redemptions, her MBR is the fund's total subordinated MBR. (21)
Importantly, however, the fully redeeming investor still is better off
than others if the fund's losses exceed its buffer plus its
aggregate MBR.
Figure 6 adds consideration of the potential liquidity costs for
investors who may have their money locked up in a closed MMF through a
prolonged liquidation process. The figure shows that even when these
costs are taken into account, the strong rule can create a disincentive
to redeem.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
Figure 7 shows how a fully redeeming investor's losses depend
on the behavior of other investors under a strong MBR rule (for
simplicity, we again exclude the costs of lost liquidity). The fully
redeeming investor's losses are less extreme for small losses to
the fund when other investors redeem as well. That is, when other
investors redeem shares, they also contribute to the fund's
subordinated MBR, so each investor owns a smaller share of the aggregate
subordinated MBR. (22) At the same time, a nonredeeming investor's
losses are also smaller when other investors redeem, because the
subordinated MBRs of redeeming investors provide those who do not redeem
some protection from losses. (23)
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
By making redemptions from a distressed MMF potentially costly, the
strong MBR rule can help offset the incentives to redeem that arise from
investors' preference for liquidity and the concern that losses
might exceed a fund's capital buffer plus its aggregate MBR. The
cost of redemptions also may offset the liquidation costs that redeemers
impose on other investors. In addition, under this rule, redemptions
protect nonredeeming investors by providing a subordinated buffer to
absorb losses. In sum, the strong rule may offset and even reverse the
incentive to redeem from a troubled fund, and thus may help stabilize a
distressed MMF, allow it to weather a difficult period, and mitigate the
externalities associated with a run.
The benefits of the strong rule are evident in a comparison of
figures 2 and 7. Figure 2 shows that under current rules, an
investor's losses depend on other investors' behavior in a
destabilizing way. The more other investors are expected to redeem, the
greater the expected losses for non-redeeming investors. This dynamic
provides a strong incentive to redeem at the first sign of trouble,
before others do. In contrast, figure 7 shows that with a strong MBR
rule, an investor's losses depend on other investors' behavior
in a stabilizing way. Redeeming investors contribute to the fund's
subordinated MBR and provide more protection for nonredeeming investors.
This dynamic stabilizes the fund and benefits retail investors and
others who may not redeem quickly when MMFs encounter problems. Even so,
it is important to recognize that if expected losses are large enough
(or if the MBR is too small), investors may be better off if they redeem
shares.
IV. Calibrating an MBR
In this section we use empirical evidence to calibrate how large an
MBR would need to be to reduce the vulnerability of MMFs to runs, and we
provide some guidance on the appropriate delay for redeeming
shareholders' MBRs. When an MMF encounters strains and the
likelihood of losses increases, investors' decisions to redeem or
not depend on how the choice affects their expected losses (including
the value of lost liquidity) if the fund breaks the buck and closes.
That is, for a fund in distress, conditional expectations are critical,
and investors will redeem when doing so reduces their expected principal
and liquidity losses in a break-the-buck scenario. (24) Thus, as input
for our calibration, we examine historical evidence on the size of MMF
losses when they have occurred, including evidence from a novel and
important data set on MMF losses in 2008. We also study the value of
preserving liquidity in a crisis, which strengthens investors'
incentive to redeem from a fund in distress. Finally, we examine
evidence that can be helpful in setting the delay period for redemptions
of investors' MBRs.
IV.A. Previously Available Data on MMF Losses
Although hundreds of MMFs have suffered material losses at various
times over the last 30 years, information on the magnitude of those
losses is not readily available. The historical record of losses in MMF
portfolios has been obscured by fund sponsors' long-standing
practice of providing discretionary financial support to MMFs that were
in danger of breaking the buck, even though such support is not required
by either regulation or contract. SEC Chairman Schapiro reported in 2012
that sponsors had intervened more than 300 times to support MMFs since
they were introduced in the 1970s (Schapiro 2012). Moody's found
144 cases from 1989 to 2003 in which U.S. MMFs received such support
(Moody's Investors Service 2010). Steffanie Brady and others (2012)
report 123 instances of support for 78 different money funds between
2007 and 2011. MMF sponsors reportedly intervened as recently as
November 2011 to support their MMFs. (25)
We have no comprehensive data on the MMF losses that would have
occurred in the absence of sponsor support. Sponsors are not required to
disclose the value of their support for a distressed MMF at the time of
an intervention, and available data generally do not provide enough
information to estimate the magnitude of NAV declines that would have
occurred without interventions. (26)
Still, the historical record and recent research provide some
useful evidence. The two U.S. MMFs that have broken the buck since the
adoption of rule 2a-7 in 1983 provide a couple of observations: the
Community Bankers U.S. Government Money Market Fund lost 3.9 percent of
its value in 1994 (U.S. SEC 1999), and the Reserve Primary Fund lost
approximately 1.6 percent in 2008. (27) Brady and others (2012) document
31 MMFs that between 2007 and 2011 received sponsor support that
exceeded 0.5 percent of the fund's assets--enough, that is, that
the support was probably required to prevent those funds from breaking
the buck. Support was more than 2 percent of assets for 10 of these
funds and exceeded 3 percent for 4 funds. (28) Analysis by Moody's
showed that at the time of Lehman's bankruptcy, 15 MMFs held Lehman
obligations that ranged from 0.25 percent to 5.6 percent of fund assets
and averaged 1.9 percent--hence, the Reserve Primary Fund's
position (1.3 percent) was less than the average among funds that held
Lehman obligations at that time (Moody's Investors Service 2012c).
IV.B. New Data on MMF Losses
We analyze here a new data set that provides additional evidence on
the scale of losses that have occurred in MMFs. The data come from the
U.S. Department of the Treasury and the SEC, which collected information
about certain MMFs that participated in the Treasury's Temporary
Guarantee Program for Money Market Funds in 2008. MMFs with shadow NAVs
below $0.9975 were required to report information about their
portfolios, including what their NAVs would have been without
sponsor-provided guarantees, such as capital support agreements (U.S.
Department of the Treasury 2008). Even so, the NAV data do not reflect
the full extent of losses that might have occurred without sponsor
interventions, since the effects of some types of sponsor support, such
as direct cash infusions to a fund and outright purchases of securities
from a fund at above-market prices, are not excluded from reported
shadow NAVs. Of course, the data also do not reflect portfolio losses
that might have occurred in the absence of extensive government support
in 2008 for MMFs, short-term funding markets, and some financial
institutions.
The Treasury-SEC data include the shadow NAVs of reporting MMFs
(but not the funds' identities) from September 5 to October 17,
2008. (29) As the first row of table 1 shows, 72 funds reported their
shadow NAVs at some point over this period. The average of the minimum
shadow NAVs reported by each of these funds during this period was
$0.989; that is, the average loss was $0.011 per share (1.1 percent).
The second row indicates that 29 funds reported shadow NAVs that would
have fallen below $0.995--enough to break the buck--at some point during
this episode. (30) On average, these funds' shadow NAVs would have
dropped to $0.978 (a 2.2 percent loss) without sponsor support. Even
when three outliers (funds that reported minimum shadow NAVs of $0.935,
$0.929, and $0.903) are excluded, the average shadow NAV of funds that
would have broken the buck was $0.985 (third row of table 1).
IV.C. Liquidity Costs of Losing Access to Shares in a Closed MMF
As discussed above, when an MMF breaks the buck and closes, its
shareholders suddenly lose access to their cash for what may be a
prolonged liquidation process. Indeed, the Reserve Primary Fund, which
broke the buck on September 16, 2008, still had not completed the
distribution of all assets to shareholders more than 3 years later
(Schapiro 2012). Clearly, a fund's closure imposes a liquidity cost
on its shareholders.
There are many challenges in estimating this cost and thus in
assessing the strength of shareholders' incentives to redeem shares
in a distressed fund to avoid lost liquidity. The opportunity cost to
shareholders of an unplanned loss of access to cash could depend on a
number of factors, including shareholders' individual
circumstances, broader financial conditions, and the length of time over
which access is lost.
We use several approaches to estimate the value of
shareholders' lost liquidity (these are discussed in more detail in
our working paper). One is to examine the average net cost to an
investor who must take out a business loan from a bank to replace cash
in a closed MMF. We show that this net cost (the rate on the bank loan
less the yield on the investor's MMF shares until they are
liquidated) averaged about 2 percent at an annual rate during the
financial crisis. (31) Liquidity premiums for financial instruments,
particularly during periods of financial strain when investors most
likely would be motivated to run from MMFs, provide another perspective
on the costs of lost liquidity. Although these premiums are difficult to
estimate, various methods discussed in our working paper suggest that
premiums might range from 1 to 2 percent at an annual rate.
The cost of lost liquidity in a closed MMF also depends on the
length of time over which investors are likely to lose access to their
cash. Ideally, shareholders might expect to receive cash as the
securities held by their fund mature, although payments of subordinated
claims would have to wait until other claims have been paid. Among prime
MMFs, which largely invest in the debt securities of private firms, the
weighted-average life of portfolio holdings was 71 days in 2012, and the
longest-dated nongovernment security in each fund's portfolio
matured, on average, in 314 days. However, in practice, investors'
wait might extend for years, as the Reserve Primary Fund example shows.
The evidence we have reviewed indicates that the opportunity costs
of lost liquidity to investors in a closed MMF are probably significant.
Assuming that investors expect to lose access to shares in a closed MMF
for 6 months, we believe that an MBR should be designed to withstand
redemption pressures that incorporate investors' incentives to
avoid lost-liquidity costs of at least 0.5 percent of the value of their
MMF shares.
IV.D. How Large Should an MBR Be?
To calibrate the size of an MBR sufficient to create a disincentive
for investors to run from a distressed MMF, we draw on the empirical
evidence on historical MMF losses described in sections IV.A and IV.B
and assume that MMF losses are distributed exponentially, with an
unconditional mean of 1.5 percent, so that losses conditional on a fund
breaking the buck (that is, when losses exceed 0.5 percent of assets)
average 2 percent. (32) On the basis of the evidence discussed in
section IV.C, we also assume that the liquidity costs to an investor in
an MMF that closes are 0.5 percent of the value of the shares that the
investor cannot access. Finally, we assume that the fund has a small
(0.5 percent) capital buffer and that when it encounters distress, other
investors do not redeem. (33)
Figure 8 illustrates the calibration under these assumptions. Each
line in the chart shows how an investor's expected losses vary with
her own redemptions for an MBR of a given size. When the MBR is small--1
or 2 percent under our assumptions--these expected-loss curves slope
downward, so investors reduce their expected losses by redeeming more
shares. That is, if the MBR is too small, investors still have an
incentive to run from a fund in distress. With an MBR of 3 percent, the
expected-loss function slopes slightly upward, indicating that the
investor would be better off not redeeming. MBRs of 4 or 5 percent
provide more convincing disincentives to redeem. This exercise suggests
that an MBR of 3 percent, combined with a small, NAV-stabilizing buffer,
might be enough to protect MMFs from runs during a crisis. (In our
working paper, we examine the calibration issue in more detail and
conclude that an MBR of 3 to 4 percent might be needed.)
This exercise estimates only a minimum effective size for an MBR;
the appropriate size in practice would depend on broader criteria. Most
notably, the goal of internalizing the significant social costs of
redemptions in a crisis suggests that the optimal slope for the
investor's expected-loss function should be positive--that is, the
investor should face expected redemption costs that incorporate the
large externalities associated with runs from MMFs. (34)
[FIGURE 8 OMITTED]
IV.E. How Long a Delay for MBR Redemptions?
To be effective in mitigating MMFs' vulnerability to runs, the
delay period for redemptions of investors' MBRs must be long enough
to inhibit "preemptive" runs. With very short delays,
investors may expect that redeeming at the first sign of a problem will
allow them to recover their MBRs before any losses are realized. Because
this strategy would require an investor to exit a distressed fund
earlier than he would under current rules, a short delay might make MMFs
even more vulnerable to preemptive runs.
At the same time, delays should not be so long as to unnecessarily
impose liquidity costs on shareholders or impede market discipline for
MMFs. In particular, very long delays might inhibit investors from
pulling away from a fund with poor management, even long before the
emergence of any specific strains in its portfolio.
The events of September 2008 suggest that a very short delay, such
as 1 week, would not be enough to prevent preemptive runs on MMFs. Even
amid the run triggered by Lehman's bankruptcy early on Monday,
September 15, every MMF except the Reserve Primary Fund managed to
survive without breaking the buck until the end of the week, when the
Treasury introduced its temporary guarantee program and removed concerns
about losses. (As noted above, many funds avoided breaking the buck only
because they received considerable discretionary sponsor support.) With
an MBR delay of just a few days, an MMF shareholder who redeemed from a
fund even after Lehman failed might have avoided any loss and shifted
potential risks and losses to nonredeemers.
The maturities of MMF assets suggest an upper bound for the delay
period. Because any problems in a fund's portfolio at the time of
an investor's redemption should be resolved by the time the
fund's longest-lived asset matures, the delay period might be as
long as 397 days, the maturity limit for privately issued assets that
MMFs can hold. On average, as noted above, a prime MMF's
longest-dated security held in 2012 (excluding government securities)
matured in 314 days. Although the 30-day delay that we suggest is
relatively short in comparison, about half of prime MMFs' assets
(on average) mature within 30 days, so a delay of that length should
provide a reasonable amount of time to ensure that any problems with
assets at the time an investor redeems are resolved before disbursement
of her MBR.
Since MMFs must report on their websites detailed portfolio
holdings data on a monthly basis, a 30-day delay means that an MMF
usually would publish updated data at some point between an
investor's request for redemption of her MBR and her receipt of
payment. Hence, a 30-day delay would help ensure that investors who
request redemptions based on information about a problem that has
already occurred in an MMF's portfolio would not be paid before
updated information about the portfolio is publicly released.
V. Policy Considerations
This section first explores how the MBR rule would compare with
other proposals for MMF reform and then examines a number of practical
issues that might affect the implementation, operation, and
effectiveness of an MBR rule.
V.A. How Would an MBR Rule Compare with Other Options for MMF
Reform?
As described in section I, advocates of MMF reform have focused on
four basic approaches to reduce the funds' vulnerability to runs.
Besides the MBR, the alternatives include requiring the funds to have
floating NAVs, requiring them to have a capital buffer, and imposing
fees or (non-MBR) restrictions on redemptions.
The risks that MMFs pose to the financial system are externalities:
substantial social costs that redeeming MMF investors and other market
participants currently do not bear. Hence, any reform should aim at
internalizing these costs. Doing so, however, likely would cause a
reduction in the equilibrium size of the industry, might drive up
required returns for MMF investments, and could increase borrowing costs
in short-term funding markets. (35) For these reasons, all serious MMF
reform options are unpopular with MMF shareholders, with the firms that
offer MMFs, and with those that borrow from MMFs. Comments from market
participants on the FSOC's proposed recommendations on MMF reform
have overwhelmingly opposed all three of the alternatives put forth by
the council. (36)
MMFs offer market-based yields that reflect the risk of the
securities they hold, while at the same time offering principal
stability and redemption on demand. This combination is inherently
unstable, and all effective reform alternatives would diminish the
attractiveness of MMFs by taking something off the table: capital
buffers would diminish yields, a floating NAV would reduce principal
stability, and any redemption restriction would limit liquidity (FSOC
2012b). The net benefits of reform will depend not only on the extent to
which it succeeds in stabilizing MMFs, but also on how market
participants respond. Reforms that drive institutional investors into
lightly regulated or unregulated MMF substitutes may be less effective
at improving systemic stability than alternatives that preserve some of
the attractive features of today's MMFs. (37) Although the focus in
this paper is on the potential benefits of an MBR for money funds, the
most effective reform strategy might be one that creates different types
of MMFs with different risk mitigation features, so investors can choose
the MMFs that best suit their preferences rather than move money to
unregulated vehicles. For example, reforms might allow for funds with
MBRs as well as funds that are exempt from MBR rules because they have
substantial capital buffers or hold only Treasury securities.
A FLOATING-NAV REQUIREMENT A requirement that all MMFs have
floating NAVs has considerable appeal among policymakers, academics, and
others for its simplicity, elimination of NAV rounding, and potential to
improve investors' understanding of MMF risks. A floating NAV would
partially internalize the cost of redemptions by ensuring that investors
who exit a fund that has incurred a loss do not receive $1 per share. It
would also make fluctuations in the value of an MMF portfolio more
transparent in share prices, could help investors become more cognizant
of MMF risks, and might reduce the ex ante incentives of portfolio
managers to take risks, since those risks would result in greater (and
more observable) share price volatility. (38)
However, unlike investors in MMFs with an MBR, investors in
floating-NAV money funds would still have a strong incentive to redeem
quickly during crises (FSOC 2012b, Hanson and others 2012, Gordon and
Gandia 2013). As mentioned above, MMFs typically meet net redemptions by
disposing of their more liquid assets, rather than by selling a cross
section of all of their holdings. Such liquidity management practices
help funds avoid realizing losses from sales of less liquid investments.
But these practices essentially subsidize redeeming investors by leaving
the remaining investors with claims on a less liquid portfolio. The
subsidy may be immaterial in normal times, but during periods of market
strain, when liquidity is at a premium, the incentive to redeem grows.
Indeed, some empirical research suggests that floating-NAV money funds
in Europe were as vulnerable to runs as stable-NAV funds during the
financial crisis (Gordon and Gandia 2013), although other work finds
that stable-NAV funds were indeed more vulnerable (Witmer 2012).
An additional concern is that implementing the floating-NAV option
would be tantamount to "eviscerating" MMFs (Investment Company
Institute 2009). Opponents of a floating NAV have cited several concerns
about its potential impacts on MMF investors, including tax and
accounting complications that might substantially diminish the
funds' appeal (see, for example, Investment Company Institute
2013). Because lightly regulated substitutes for MMFs would continue to
offer stable NAVs, any reform that forced all MMFs to have floating NAVs
might lead to a large migration of assets to these less regulated
vehicles.
The floating-NAV option would offer additional flexibility to MMFs
in an environment of very low interest rates. Some commentators have
suggested that the easing of monetary policy could be constrained by
concerns that very low interest rates might put MMFs out of business
(see, for example, Sellon 2003, Keister 2011, Coeure 2012). (39) A money
fund with a floating NAV might prove less vulnerable to low rates
because it could charge expenses that exceed its earnings on portfolio
securities without opening a gap between the share price and the
underlying value of its shares. (40)
A CAPITAL BUFFER REQUIREMENT Like the MBR rule, capital creates a
buffer to absorb potential MMF losses. Each approach has advantages and
disadvantages.
A capital buffer would give MMFs some capacity to absorb losses
without breaking the buck. This could allow the funds to operate without
disruption even after suffering material losses and could eliminate the
possibility of dilutive redemptions. An MBR, in contrast, would not
prevent funds that suffer losses from breaking the buck.
A substantial capital buffer--one comparable in magnitude to the
MBR that we recommend--could have two additional advantages over an MBR
rule. First, capital might allow a more efficient allocation of risk
among investors. Presumably the owners of the capital would have greater
tolerance for risk than investors in a stable-NAV money fund (Hanson and
others 2012). An MBR primarily would clarify the allocation of risks
among MMF investors, although it is possible that MMF investors would
contract with more risk-tolerant third parties to bear the risk of an
MBR. Second, a substantial capital buffer could help curtail the MMF
industry's historical reliance on voluntary sponsor support, which
poses considerable systemic risk (McCabe 2010, PWG 2010, FSOC 2012b).
However, a capital buffer that is too small to absorb reasonably
foreseeable losses would not offer these advantages.
Some disadvantages of a capital buffer arise from the challenges of
raising the large sums that would be needed. As of the end of 2012, each
percentage point of capital as a share of industry-wide MMF assets would
have required more than $25 billion in funding, depending on the scope
of the capital requirement (for example, whether it applied to MMFs
investing only in Treasury securities). At least three possible funding
sources have been suggested. First, MMFs might retain income that
normally would be distributed to shareholders (see, for example, Goebel
and others 2011). However, this process would require many years to
build a substantial buffer unless the net yields paid to investors are
reduced very sharply, and the incentives to protect the buffer would be
unclear. Second, a buffer might be raised from third-party investors in
capital markets (see, for example, BlackRock 2011, Hanson and others
2012). This would facilitate an efficient allocation of MMF risks by
shifting them to investors who are more willing and able to take risks.
However, it would require the creation of a market for a new, untested
type of security and might entail significant underwriting and other
costs. Third, a buffer could be financed by the MMF sponsors themselves
(see, for example, BlackRock 2010). Although this approach would be
simpler than obtaining funding in the capital markets, it could lead to
further consolidation of the MMF industry among the affiliates of large,
systemically important financial institutions. Hence, sponsor-funded
capital could further concentrate systemic risks.
One clear advantage of a strong MBR over a capital buffer is that
subordination creates a disincentive to run. Indeed, with such an MBR,
investors can be better off not redeeming, even if they recognize that a
fund's losses might exceed the size of its aggregate MBR. In
contrast, capital only reduces the incentive to run from a fund at risk:
investors still would have good reason to exit if the danger exists that
losses might exceed the capital buffer. Thus, an MBR might do more to
mitigate the vulnerability of MMFs to runs than a capital buffer of the
same size.
A capital buffer and an MBR rule also would have different
implications for investor incentives. By shielding MMF investors from
some losses, a meaningful capital buffer would shift the incentives for
ex ante risk management from the MMF's shareholders to the owners
of the capital buffer, who might be well suited to this task (Hanson and
others 2012). (41) But an MBR should improve ex ante risk management as
well, because an MBR would be, in effect, a buffer provided by the MMF
shareholders themselves. By removing investors' option to redeem
shares quickly when losses appear imminent, an MBR rule would strengthen
shareholders' incentives to monitor the funds' risk taking
well before problems materialize.
Both the MBR and a capital buffer might reduce shareholder demand
for MMFs, but for different reasons. The costs of the capital buffer
presumably would be funded in the same way as other MMF expenses and
hence would reduce the net yields that MMFs pay to investors. The MBR,
in contrast, would reduce the liquidity of MMF shares.
Because the strengths of a capital buffer and an MBR rule
complement one another, we suggest that an MBR would be particularly
effective if paired with a capital buffer. The MBR could bolster a
capital buffer by creating a disincentive to redeem from an MMF in
distress; this would lower the likelihood that capital might be eroded
by redemption-driven fire sales of assets. A more substantial capital
buffer could help reduce the importance of voluntary sponsor support for
MMFs and make funds more resilient to losses. But even a small buffer
could provide a means to eliminate dilutive redemptions. Notably,
Alternative Two of the FSOC's proposed recommendations on MMF
reform includes an MBR in tandem with a small capital buffer (FSOC
2012b).
REDEMPTION FEES AND NON-MBR RESTRICTIONS An MBR, if implemented,
would be in place at all times. Proposals for other types of
restrictions or fees for redemptions that are always in place appear
less promising. For example, although a delay in disbursement of all
redemptions would provide some extra time for an MMF to raise cash to
meet heavy redemptions in a crisis, it would not reduce investors'
incentive to redeem, nor would it halt the dynamics of a run. Moreover,
imposition of a significant delay on all redemptions would eliminate
much of the utility of MMFs for cash management. A fee on all
redemptions would be an even more substantial departure from principal
stability than a floating NAV, since investors would lose money on every
redemption.
Conditional fees or restrictions for redemptions--that is, fees or
restrictions that are not always in place--have garnered significant
support from the MMF industry as an alternative to other options (see,
for example, HSBC Global Asset Management 2011, BlackRock 2012,
Investment Company Institute 2013). Such "standby"
arrangements would allow MMFs to function much as they currently do in
normal times but would halt or penalize redemptions when MMFs are under
strain. For example, recent proposals would "gate" (that is,
halt) redemptions if a fund's liquid assets fell below a threshold
and then would charge a fee for any redemptions until the fund's
liquidity was restored.
Conditional fees and restrictions might actually increase the risk
of preemptive runs on MMFs in distress and speed up the spread of runs
to other funds. The possibility that fees or gates might be imposed
would heighten investors' incentives to redeem quickly from
troubled MMFs, especially if they suspect that other investors will do
so (FSOC 2012b, Hanson and others 2012). In contrast to running from a
distressed MMF with a strong MBR rule, exiting an MMF with conditional
fees or restrictions immediately before they are imposed would be
essentially costless to the redeeming investor. In addition, given the
similarity of MMF portfolios, news that one fund has halted redemptions
could spark runs on other funds (Rosengren 2013).