首页    期刊浏览 2025年02月12日 星期三
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Measuring financial inclusion: explaining variation in use of financial services across and within countries.
  • 作者:Demirguc-Kunt, Asli ; Klapper, Leora
  • 期刊名称:Brookings Papers on Economic Activity
  • 印刷版ISSN:0007-2303
  • 出版年度:2013
  • 期号:March
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Brookings Institution
  • 摘要:As documented in section II, there is a strong correlation between national income and financial inclusion. However, policy innovations may still be able to bring about more inclusive financial systems even at low levels of income. The Global Findex database allows us to observe how public and private sector-led initiatives might change how people engage with the formal financial system.
  • 关键词:Financial inclusion;Mobile banks;Technological innovations

Measuring financial inclusion: explaining variation in use of financial services across and within countries.


Demirguc-Kunt, Asli ; Klapper, Leora


IV. Mobile Money, Branchless Banking, and Beyond

As documented in section II, there is a strong correlation between national income and financial inclusion. However, policy innovations may still be able to bring about more inclusive financial systems even at low levels of income. The Global Findex database allows us to observe how public and private sector-led initiatives might change how people engage with the formal financial system.

The success of mobile money illustrates the transformative potential of technical progress and innovation to promote financial inclusion. Mobile money--sometimes considered a form of branchless banking--has allowed people who are otherwise excluded from the formal financial system to perform financial transactions in a relatively cheap, secure, and reliable manner (Jack and Suri 2011). Individuals using mobile money maintain a type of account that allows them to make deposits and withdrawals through cash transactions at a network of retail agents. They can then transfer money or pay bills using text messages. Many mobile money accounts--such as those provided by M-PESA in Kenya or GCash in the Philippines--are not connected to an account at a financial institution, but the providers are often required to store the aggregate sums of the accounts in a bank. Customers are ordinarily charged a fee for sending money to others or making a withdrawal from their account.

Mobile money has achieved the broadest success in sub-Saharan Africa, where 16 percent of adults report having used a mobile phone in the past 12 months to pay bills or send or receive money (figure 14). The share of adults using mobile money is less than 5 percent in all other regions, but a few countries, including Haiti and the Philippines, are notable exceptions to the pattern.

The degree to which mobile money is capturing the unbanked market differs across countries. In Kenya 43 percent of adults who report having used mobile money in the past 12 months do not have a formal account. In Sudan the figure is 92 percent. This heterogeneity may reflect the varied and fast-evolving regulations surrounding mobile money. When M-PESA was launched in Kenya, it had no association with the formal banking sector, and mobile banking customers there were exempt from the documentation requirements imposed by banks. But governments are increasingly favoring bank-led models in which mobile money providers have partnerships with or are formed directly through banks (Consultative Group to Assist the Poor 2010).

[FIGURE 14 OMITTED]

In recent years the proliferation of branchless banking has also received growing attention as a way to increase financial access in developing countries, particularly among underserved groups (see Mas and Kumar 2008). One mode of branchless banking centers on bank agents, who often operate out of retail stores, gas stations, or post offices. By capitalizing on existing infrastructure and client relationships, operators can expand financial access in a more cost-efficient manner. Bank agents themselves can also be mobile, making daily or weekly rounds among clients. Few account holders currently report relying on bank agents (whether over the counter at a retail store or some other person associated with their bank) as their main mode of withdrawal or deposit. But in several Asian countries--including Bangladesh, Laos, Nepal, and the Philippines--more than 10 percent of account holders already report using bank agents.

There is also enormous scope for the public sector to bring about transformative change in how adults around the globe interact with the formal financial sector. Increasingly, governments are using formal accounts to disburse transfer payments. In Brazil the government allows recipients of conditional cash transfers (as part of its Bolsa Familia program) to receive payments via no-frills bank accounts, although many more choose to receive payments via a virtual account that does not allow deposits or indefinite storage (Consultative Group to Assist the Poor 2011). Still, according to Findex data, 20 percent of adults in Brazil report receiving government transfers via a bank account, one of the highest proportions in the developing world. In India the government recently began depositing government pension and scholarship payments directly into the bank accounts of almost 250,000 people in 20 districts. Officials plan to expand the program and hope it will prevent corruption as well as expand financial access. (23) The data provide suggestive evidence that these types of reforms may have the potential to dramatically expand the reach of the formal financial sector to the poorest individuals.

V. Conclusion

For most people around the world, having an account at a financial institution serves as an entry point into the formal financial sector. A formal account can encourage saving and open access to credit. It can also make it easier to transfer wages, remittances, and government payments. Broadbased access to accessible and affordable formal accounts is a hallmark of an inclusive financial system, the absence of which can contribute to persistent income inequality and slower economic growth.

Yet until now little was known about the global reach of the financial sector and financial inclusion--the extent of account ownership and the use of formal payments, saving, and credit--or about the degree to which groups such as the poor are excluded from formal financial systems. Systematic indicators of the use of different formal and informal financial services were lacking for most countries.

As the first public database of indicators that consistently measure people's use of financial products across countries and over time, the Global Findex database fills a big gap in existing data on financial inclusion. The data show wide gaps in account penetration between high-income and developing countries and between the poor and the rich within countries. Also, the data show variation in the use of formal and informal saving and credit mechanisms. By enabling policymakers to identify segments of the population excluded from the formal financial sector, the data can help provide insights for the design and prioritization of reforms.

APPENDIX A

Selected Questions from the Global Findex Survey

The text of this appendix is taken verbatim from the survey.

This next section is about banks and financial institutions. We are trying to understand how people across the world use financial institutions and how available they are to people. Please remember that all information you provide is completely confidential.

--Do you, either by yourself or together with someone else, currently have an account at any of the following places? An account can be used to save money, to make or receive payments, or to receive wages and remittances. Do you currently have an account at [surveyor reads A and B]? (24)

1 Yes

2 No

A A bank or credit union (or other formal financial institution, where applicable, like a cooperative in Latin America)

B A post office

--A debit card, sometimes called an ATM card, is a card that allows you to make payments, get money, or buy things and the money is taken out of your bank account right away. Do you have a debit card?

1 Yes

2 No

--A credit card is like a debit card but the money is not taken from your account right away. You get credit to make payments or buy things, and you can pay the balance off later. Do you have a credit card?

1 Yes

2 No

--In a typical month, about how many times is money deposited into your personal account(s)? This includes cash or electronic deposits, or any time money is put into your account(s) by yourself or others. [surveyor reads 1 through 4 and codes one response only]

1 0

2 1-2 times

3 3-5 times

4 6 times or more

--In a typical month, about how many times is money taken out of your personal account(s)? This includes cash withdrawals, electronic payments or purchases, checks, or any other time money is removed from your account(s) by yourself or others. [surveyor reads 1 through 4 and codes one response only]

1 0

2 1-2 times

3 3-5 times

4 6 times or more

--When you need to get cash (paper or coins) from your account(s), do you usually get it ...? [surveyor reads 1 through 4 and codes one response only; respondents can also answer that they do not withdraw cash (coded as 5)]

1 At an ATM

2 Over the counter in a branch of your bank or financial institution

3 Over the counter at a retail store

4 From some other person who is associated with your bank or financial institution

--When you put cash (paper or coins) into your account(s), do you usually do it ...? [surveyor reads 1 through 4 and codes one response only; respondents can also answer that they do not withdraw cash (coded as 5)]

1 At an ATM

2 Over the counter in a branch of your bank or financial institution

3 Over the counter at a retail store

4 From some other person who is associated with your bank or financial institution

--In the past 12 months, have you used your account(s) to ...? [surveyor reads A through D]

1 Yes

2 No

A Receive money or payments for work or from selling goods

B Receive money or payments from the government

C Receive money from family members living elsewhere

D Send money to family members living elsewhere

--Please tell me whether each of the following is a reason why you, personally, DO NOT have an account at a bank, credit union or other financial institution. [surveyor reads and rotates A through G]

1 Yes

2 No

A They are too far away

B They are too expensive

C You don't have the necessary documentation (ID, wage slip)

D You don't trust them

E You don't have enough money to use them

F Because of religious reasons

G Because someone else in the family already has an account

--In the past 12 months, have you saved or set aside any money?

1 Yes [surveyor continues with next question]

2 No [surveyor skips to question 74]

--In the past 12 months, have you saved or set aside any money by ...? [surveyor reads A and B]

1 Yes

2 No

A Using an account at a bank, credit union, or microfinance institution

B Using an informal savings club or a person outside the family (insert local example)

--In the past 12 months, have you borrowed any money from ...? [surveyor reads A through E]

1 Yes

2 No

A A bank, credit union, or microfinance institution

B A store by using installment credit or buying on credit

C Family or friends

D Employer

E Another private lender

--Do you currently have a loan you took out for any of the following reasons? [surveyor reads A through E]

1 Yes

2 No

A To purchase your home or apartment

B To purchase materials or services to build, extend, or renovate your home or apartment

C To pay school fees

D For emergency/health purposes

E For funerals or weddings

--In the past 12 months, have you used a mobile phone to ...? [surveyor reads A through C]

1 Yes

2 No

A Pay bills

B Send money

C Receive money

APPENDIX B
Account Penetration by Country

Percent of adults with an account at a formal financial institution

                            All     Poorest   Richest
Country                    adults     20%       20%

Afghanistan                   9         0        20
Albania                      28         7        43
Algeria                      33        22        50
Angola                       39        31        40
Argentina                    33        19        55
Armenia                      17        16        24
Australia                    99        97       100
Austria                      97        93        99
Azerbaijan                   15        13        25
Bahrain                      65        64        60
Bangladesh                   40        33        54
Belarus                      59        37        75
Belgium                      96        92        96
Benin                        10         5        24
Bolivia                      28        12        50
Bosnia and Herzegovina       56        35        69
Botswana                     30        12        48
Brazil                       56        33        71
Bulgaria                     53        29        76
Burkina Faso                 13         6        25
Burundi                       7         3        23
Cambodia                      4         0        12
Cameroon                     15        14        22
Canada                       96        91        98
Central African Republic      3         1         9
Chad                          9         6        26
Chile                        42        19        68
China                        64        39        83
Colombia                     30         9        62
Comoros                      22         9        40
Congo, Dem. Rep.              4         0        18
Congo, Rep.                   9         1        20
Costa Rica                   50        30        69
Croatia                      88        75        94
Cyprus                       85        76        89
Czech Republic               81        70        88
Denmark                     100        99       100
Djibouti                     12         4        34
Dominican Republic           38        19        62
Ecuador                      37        22        61
Egypt                        10         5        25
El Salvador                  14         1        32
Estonia                      97        94        99
Finland                     100        99       100
France                       97        96       100
Gabon                        19         4        38
Georgia                      33        25        50
Germany                      98        97       100
Ghana                        29        17        61
Greece                       78        75        85
Guatemala                    22         8        52
Guinea                        4         2        10
Haiti                        22         4        49
Honduras                     21        15        47
Hong Kong                    89        78        98
Hungary                      73        58        86
India                        35        21        56
Indonesia                    20         8        48
Iran                         74        63        80
Iraq                         11         5        13
Ireland                      94        88        97
Israel                       90        88        92
Italy                        71        61        81
Jamaica                      71        71        67
Japan                        96        94        96
Jordan                       25        16        33
Kazakhstan                   42        30        55
Kenya                        42        19        85
Korea, Rep.                  93        86        94
Kosovo                       44        24        59
Kuwait                       87        86        90
Kyrgyz Republic               4         1        11
Laos                         27        16        27
Latvia                       90        82        95
Lebanon                      37        20        54
Lesotho                      18         8        29
Liberia                      19         3        41
Lithuania                    74        66        87
Luxembourg                   95        97        94
Macedonia                    74        66        85
Madagascar                    6         1        19
Malawi                       17         9        36
Malaysia                     66        45        82
Mali                          8         4        18
Malta                        95        93        96
Mauritania                   17         7        43
Mauritius                    80        66        94
Mexico                       27        12        58
Moldova                      18         6        36
Mongolia                     78        68        89
Montenegro                   50        34        67
Morocco                      39         0         0
Mozambique                   40        21        56
Nepal                        25        15        39
Netherlands                  99        98        99
New Zealand                  99       100        99
Nicaragua                    14         4        31
Niger                         2         0         6
Nigeria                      30        12        62
Oman                         74        63        92
Pakistan                     10         5        19
Panama                       25        18        44
Paraguay                     22         4        51
Peru                         20         6        47
Philippines                  27         4        54
Poland                       70        60        82
Portugal                     81        64        87
Qatar                        66        47        80
Romania                      45        25        69
Russia                       48        34        61
Rwanda                       33        23        42
Saudi Arabia                 46        32        51
Senegal                       6         4        13
Serbia                       62        47        70
Sierra Leone                 15         4        30
Singapore                    98        98        98
Slovak Republic              80        66        85
Slovenia                     97        92       100
Somalia                      31        12        58
South Africa                 54        35        78
Spain                        93        91        92
Sri Lanka                    69        52        87
Sudan                         7         4        15
Swaziland                    29        12        44
Sweden                       99        99       100
Syria                        23        20        28
Taiwan                       87        77        90
Tajikistan                    3         1         6
Tanzania                     17         3        45
Thailand                     73        64        87
Togo                         10         2        18
Trinidad and Tobago          76        70        85
Tunisia                      32        14        63
Turkey                       58        46        72
Turkmenistan                  0         0         1
Uganda                       20         7        37
Ukraine                      41        21        59
United Arab Emirates         60        57        58
United Kingdom               97        97        97
United States                88        74        90
Uruguay                      24         7        49
Uzbekistan                   23        15        27
Venezuela                    44        27        54
Vietnam                      21         6        35
West Bank and Gaza           19         8        34
Yemen                         4         0         9
Zambia                       21         8        50
Zimbabwe                     40        22        63

Source: Global Findex.


ACKNOWLEDGMENTS We thank Franklin Alien, Oya Pinar Ardic Alper, Thorsten Beck, Massimo Cirasino, Robert Cull, Pascaline Dupas, Maya Eden, Tilman Ehrbeck, Michael Fuchs, Xavi Gine, Markus Goldstein, Ruth Goodwin-Groen, Rafil Hernandez-Coss, Richard Hinz, Jake Kendall, Aart Kraay, Alexia Latortue, Sole Martinez Peria, Ignacio Mas-Ribo, Jonathan Morduch, Nataliya Mylenko, Mark Napier, Douglas Pearce, Bikki Randhawa, Liliana Rojas-Suarez, Richard Rosenberg, Armida San Jose, Kinnon M. Scott, Peer Stein, Gaiv Tata, Jeanette Thomas, Klaus Tilmes, Asli Togan Egrican, Augusto de la Torre, Rodger Voorhies, and Alan Winters for their valuable and substantive comments during various stages of the project. The team is also appreciative of the excellent survey execution and related support provided by Gallup, Inc., under the direction of Jon Clifton. We are especially grateful to the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation for providing financial support that made the collection and dissemination of the data possible. This paper was prepared with outstanding assistance from Atisha Kumar and Douglas Randall. This paper's findings, interpretations, and conclusions are entirely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, their executive directors, or the countries they represent. The authors report no potential conflict of interest.

References

Allen, Franklin, Ash Demirguc-Kunt, Leora Klapper, and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria. 2012. "The Foundations of Financial Inclusion: Understanding Ownership and Use of Formal Accounts." Policy Research Working Paper no. 6290. Washington: World Bank.

Ashraf, Nava, Diego Aycinena, Claudia Martinez A., and Dean Yang. 2010. "Remittances and the Problem of Control: A Field Experiment among Migrants from El Salvador." University of Michigan.

Aterido, Reyes, Thorsten Beck, and Leonardo Iacovone. 2011. "Gender and Finance in Sub-Saharan Africa: Are Women Disadvantaged?" Policy Research Working Paper no. 5571. Washington: World Bank.

Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster, and Cynthia Kinnan. 2010. "The Miracle of Microfinance? Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation." MIT Bureau for Research and Economic Analysis of Development Working Paper no. 278. Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

Beck, Thorsten. 2009. "FinAccess 2009: Trends, Analysis and Policy Conclusions." Consultant report for FSD Trust Kenya, Nairobi.

Beck, Thorsten, and Martin Brown. 2011. "Use of Banking Services in Emerging Markets: Household-Level Evidence." European Banking Center Discussion Paper no. 2011-024. Tilburg University, the Netherlands.

Beck, Thorsten, Ash Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine. 2007. "Finance, Inequality, and the Poor." Journal of Economic Growth 12, no. 1: 27-49.

Beck, Thorsten, Ash Demirguc-Kunt, and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria. 2007. "Reaching Out: Access to and Use of Banking Services across Countries." Journal of Financial Economics 85, no. 2: 234-66.

--. 2008. "Banking Services for Everyone? Barriers to Bank Access and Use around the World." World Bank Economic Review 22, no. 3: 397-430.

Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Norman Loayza. 2000. "Finance and the Sources of Growth." Journal of Financial Economics 58, no. 1: 261-300.

Campbell, John. 2006. "Household Finance." Journal of Finance 61, no. 4: 1553-1604.

Chawla, Mukesh, Gordon Betcherman, and Anne Banerji. 2007. From Red to Gray: The "Third Transition" of Aging Populations in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union. Washington: World Bank.

Chen, Shaohua, and Martin Ravallion. 2010. "The Developing World Is Poorer Than We Thought but No Less Successful in the Fight against Poverty." Quarterly Journal of Economics 125, no. 4: 1577-1625.

Clausen, Bianca, Aart Kraay, and Zsolt Nyiri. 2011. "Corruption and Confidence in Public Institutions: Evidence from a Global Survey." World Bank Economic Review 25, no. 2: 212-49.

Cole, Shawn, Thomson Sampson, and Bilal Zia. 2011. "Prices or Knowledge? What Drives Demand for Financial Services in Emerging Markets?" Journal of Finance 66, no. 6: 1933-67.

Collins, Daryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Rutherford, and Orlando Ruthven. 2009. Portfolios of the Poor: How the World's Poor Live on Two Dollars a Day. Princeton University Press.

Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP). 2010. "Technology Program Focus Country: India." Washington.

--. 2011. "CGAP G2P Brazil Country Report." Washington.

Cull, Robert, Ash Demirguc-Kunt, and Jonathan Morduch. 2013. Banking the World: Empirical Foundations of Financial Inclusion. MIT Press.

Deaton, Angus 2008. "Income, Health, and Well-Being around the World: Evidence from the Gallup World Poll." Journal of Economic Perspectives 22, no. 2: 53-72.

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Leora Klapper. 2012. "Measuring Financial Inclusion: The Global Findex Database." Policy Research Working Paper no. 6025. Washington: World Bank.

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, and Ross Levine. 2009. "Finance and Inequality: Theory and Evidence." Annual Review of Financial Economics 1: 287-318.

Demirguc-Kunt, Asli, Leora Klapper, Peter Van Oudheusden, and Luigi Zingales. 2013. "Trust in Banks." Working paper. Washington: Development Research Group, World Bank.

De Soto, Hernando. 2000. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Random House.

Djankov, Simeon, Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei Shleifer. 2007. "Private Credit in 129 Countries." Journal of Financial Economics 2, no. 84: 299-329.

Dupas, Pascaline, and Jonathan Robinson. 2009. "Savings Constraint and Microenterprise Development: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Kenya." Working Paper no. 14693. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.

--. 2011. "Why Don't the Poor Save More? Evidence from Health Savings Experiments." Working Paper no. 17255. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.

European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 2011. Life in Transition: After the Crisis. London.

Financial Action Task Force (FATF). 2011. FATF Guidance on Anti-Money Laundering and Terrorist Financing Measures and Financial Inclusion. Paris: FATF/OECD.

Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). 2011. FDIC National Survey of Unbanked and Underbanked Households. Washington.

Hallward-Driemeier, Mary, and Tazeen Hasan. 2013. Empowering Women: Legal Rights and Economic Opportunities in Africa. Development Forum Series. Paris: Agence Francaise de Developpement, and Washington: World Bank.

Honohan, Patrick. 2008. "Cross-Country Variation in Household Access to Financial Services." Journal of Banking and Finance 32: 2493-2500.

International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2011. Global Financial Stability Report: Grappling with Crisis Legacies, September 2011. Washington.

Jack, William, and Tavneet Suri. 2011. "Mobile Money: The Economics of M-PESA." Working Paper no. 16721. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Johnston, Don, and Jonathan Morduch. 2008. "The Unbanked: Evidence from Indonesia." World Bank Economic Review 22, no. 3: 517-37.

Karlan, Dean, and Jonathan Zinman. 2010. "Expanding Credit Access: Using Randomized Supply Decisions to Estimate the Impacts." Review of Financial Studies 23, no. 1: 433-64.

King, Robert G., and Ross Levine. 1993. "Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right." Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, no. 3: 717-37.

Klapper, Leora, and Inessa Love. 2011. "The Impact of the Financial Crisis on New Firm Registration." Economics Letters 113: 1-4.

Klapper, Leora, Luc Laeven, and Raghuram Rajan. 2006. "Entry Regulation as a Barrier to Entrepreneurship." Journal of Financial Economics 82: 591-629.

Mas, Ignacio, and Kabir Kumar. 2008. "Banking on Mobiles: Why, How, for Whom?" Focus Note no. 48. Washington: Consultative Group to Assist the Poor.

Ratha, Dilip. 2006. "Leveraging Remittances for Development." In Migration, Trade, and Development, proceedings of a conference sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, The Tower Center for Political Studies, the Department of Economics at Southern Methodist University, and the Jno E. Owens Foundation (October).

Sacks, Daniel, Betsey Stevenson, and Justin Wolfers. 2010. "Subjective Well-Being, Income, Economic Development and Growth." Working Paper no. 16441. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Stevenson, Betsey, and Justin Wolfers. 2008. "Economic Growth and Subjective Well-Being: Reassessing the Easterlin Paradox." BPEA, no. 1: 1-102.

--. 2011. "Trust in Public Institutions over the Business Cycle." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 101, no. 3: 281-87.

Warnock, Veronica C., and Francis E. Warnock. 2008. "Markets and Housing Finance." Journal of Housing Economics 17, no. 3: 239-51.

World Bank. 2008a. Finance for All? Policies and Pitfalls in Expanding Access. Washington.

--. 2008b. Global Purchasing Power Parities and Real Expenditures: 2005 International Comparison Program. Washington.

Yikona, Stuart, Brigitte Slot, Michael Geller, Bjarne Hansen, and Fatima el Kadir. 2011. Ill-Gotten Money and the Economy: Experiences from Malawi and Namibia. Washington: World Bank.

Comments and Discussion

COMMENT BY PASCALINE DUPAS

The new Global Findex data set that Ash Demirguc-Kunt and Leora Klapper are introducing in this paper is arguably among the most important multicountry, repeated-cross-sectional data sets being collected in this decade. It provides much-needed statistics on the use of financial services around the world at a time when interest in such services is peaking. Indeed, almost 40 years after Muhammad Yunus made the first microloan--the first of many exciting developments in financial services for the poor--only now are we beginning to see concerted research efforts to map the reach and effect of these tools on households around the world.

Country-specific micro-level studies have suggested that financial inclusion today may be much lower than what an informed observer would suppose from the ubiquitous media accounts. For example, recent randomized trials suggest that at best a quarter of households take up available loans from microfinance institutions in India, Mexico, and Morocco (Banerjee and others 2013, Crepon and others 2011, Angelucci, Karlan, and Zinman 2012). Dupas and coauthors (forthcoming) document that only 20 percent of households in rural western Kenya have a bank account, and ongoing censuses in Uganda and Malawi reveal comparable rates (see Dupas, Karlan, and Robinson 2013). But such micro studies tend to be clustered in a few countries or areas, and absent more wide-reaching data, it is difficult to understand how representative and applicable these results are. Efforts to date to provide more-exhaustive survey evidence have remained limited: the FinScope survey sponsored by the U.K. Department for International Development covers only 15 countries (14 of them in Africa), and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development's Life in Transition Survey covers only 35 countries in Europe and Central Asia.

Given the lack of survey evidence, until the Global Findex data set was introduced, the most extensive efforts to estimate rates of financial inclusion worldwide had to rely on triangulation exercises between aggregate banking data from bank regulators and microfinance institutions (to get absolute numbers of accounts, loans, and the like) and population counts. Thorsten Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine (2007) focus on the formal banking sector and estimate that across the 54 countries in their sample, the median number of deposit accounts per 1,000 people is 529, and across a subset of 44 of those countries, the median number of loans per 1,000 people is 80. Patrick Honohan (2008) builds on this effort and proposes a "composite indicator" of access to both formal and semiformal financial services. This indicator is constructed from estimates of the number of bank accounts and the size of deposits relative to the total population. These estimates are generated as functions of the number of microfinance accounts and GDP per capita, respectively; these functions in turn are based on correlations observed in the few countries with enough available data.

The first thing that can be done with the Global Findex database is to check the accuracy of such extrapolation exercises. Because the Honohan (2008) estimates are from 5 to 8 years before the Global Findex measures, one should not expect a perfect correlation between the two, but after downloading both sets of measures, I found the correlation to be surprisingly high: 0.85 between Honohan's estimate of "access to financial services" (Honohan 2008, table 2) and the share of the population that "has an account at a formal financial institution" in the Global Findex database (see figure 3 in the paper). What is more, further calculations by Alberto Chaia and coauthors (2009) based on Honohan's figures find that (as their title states) "half the world is unbanked," which is also a key finding from the Global Findex. I found this high rate of consistency across the two types of sources to be very good news: it means that estimation exercises like those of Beck and others (2007), Honohan (2008), and Chaia and others (2009) are relatively accurate in providing comparable cross-country measures.

But gauging and analyzing covariates of cross-country variation can take one only so far toward a better understanding of financial inclusion worldwide. A key advantage of the Global Findex is that it provides information on within-country distributions, as well as on basic individual-level covariates of financial inclusion such as income, attitudes toward formal banks, and self-reported reasons for using or not using a given financial tool or service. The paper highlights a few of the many interesting patterns that the data uncover. For example, the authors report that 13 percent of unbanked adults worldwide mention lack of trust as a reason for not saving with a formal institution. This suggests that reliability and quality concerns about the supply side, as also highlighted for the specific context of western Kenya in Dupas and others (2012), are relevant in a number of other countries, especially in Africa and South Asia. Another stunning statistic from the Global Findex is the extremely low (6 percent) rate of coverage with rainfall, crop, or livestock insurance among those in developing economies whose livelihood is farming, fishing, or forestry. Yet another interesting finding is that mobile money services are, at least initially, disproportionately used by those already banked. (In Kenya, the pioneer in terms of mobile money, 57 percent of mobile money users have a formal bank account, compared with a population mean of 42 percent.) Having access to such basic statistics will help shape the financial inclusion research agenda for years to come.

The other extremely appealing feature of the Global Findex data is that they are set to be collected triennially for at least three rounds. The first round, analyzed in this paper, took place in 2011, and two rounds will follow in 2014 and 2017. The timing is particularly fortuitous: the first round was collected before the mobile money "revolution" really took hold: the survey reveals that as of 2011, only 16 percent of African adults had ever used mobile money, and fewer than 5 percent of adults in all other regions had. By 2014 this percentage will likely have increased considerably. The Global Findex data set will therefore provide a series of snapshots over a tremendously exciting decade, during which the definition of financial inclusion itself may change as new tools such as mobile phone-based savings accounts are further developed and adopted. Among other things, the data will help advance research into how these new financial tools interact with the more established tools and services.

The data set is a major advance, but there remains scope for improvement in the next round of surveying. One such improvement would be to add some measurement of "financial fragility." In a recent Brookings Paper, Annamaria Lusardi, Daniel Schneider, and Peter Tufano (2011) examined this issue for U.S. households by looking at households' capacity to raise $2,000 in 30 days. The authors found that nearly half of the households surveyed would probably not be able to do so. Adding a similar question to the Global Findex survey would enable researchers to examine how financial inclusion correlates with financial fragility. In the existing Global Findex survey, households are not asked whether they are credit rationed, nor are they asked anything about the size of their current savings. Asking people directly how much they have in savings may be too sensitive and prone to underreporting, but asking whether and how they could access a given sum (which would have to be adjusted to the context, for example by keeping the ratio to the local poverty line constant) would be a great, if indirect, way to get a sense of how deep financial inclusion is. In ongoing work, some colleagues and I asked such a question of unbanked rural households in Kenya, Malawi, and Uganda between 2010 and 2012. The results, presented in table 1, show that most of the poor households in our various samples have very limited savings, and that an individual's financial resources are to a great extent a function of the depth of that individual's social network.

The data reported in table 1 resonate with the present paper's finding that 65 percent of non-account owners mention "not having enough money to use one" as one reason for not using a bank account (with close to half of them reporting it as their only reason). Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper interpret this as evidence that "under current circumstances, the costs of having an account outweigh its benefits" (emphasis in the original). They also write that this finding "speaks to the fact that having a formal account is not costless in most parts of the world and that individuals with small or irregular income streams might view an account as an unnecessary expense, given the relatively high cost." I would like to qualify this interpretation. Work that coauthors and I have done in Kenya and other parts of East Africa suggests that individuals reporting "not having enough money" to use an account would not necessarily immediately start using accounts provided to them completely free of charge. In Kenya, Jonathan Robinson and I have found that very few bicycle-taxi drivers actively took up (that is, made at least two deposits within a year in) accounts that they could open at no cost to themselves, whereas about 40 percent of market vendors did (Dupas and Robinson 2013a). More generally, only 18 percent of a representative sample of unbanked households actively used accounts that were free to open and maintain (Dupas and others 2012). Replication studies ongoing in Uganda and Malawi suggest rates no higher than 30 percent. The fact that these accounts have withdrawal fees may be part of the explanation for the low take-up, but many households do not report fees as a barrier, instead simply stating that they do not have enough money to save. But when provided with lockboxes (a simple metal box with a deposit slit on top and a lock and key), the same Kenyan households mentioned above made very regular deposits and saved in just 3 months as much as would have taken them 18 months to save in an account. Thus, households were in fact able to save more than they themselves thought they could. This may be due to a feature that lockboxes offer that formal accounts may not. In essence, access to these in-house savings tools make people pennywise: they provide a place to store amounts that are too small to warrant a trip to the bank, thus safeguarding funds that would otherwise be kept close at hand and so be at risk of being frittered away on unplanned small expenditures, such as sweets for the children or soda for visitors. (1)

What this all means is that not having enough money to warrant a trip to the bank to deposit it is itself a function of financial inclusion, defined more broadly to encompass use of informal financial tools that facilitate the day-to-day management of even very small sums, helping to grow them into bankable lump sums. The stunning findings from the Global Findex suggest that a better understanding of what type of tools can help unbanked households save as much as they need in order to become "bankable" is an important avenue for future research. Demirguc-Kunt and Klapper have provided the scientific community a much needed database and tool, and I hope that they will make each wave of data easily available online through a one-click download.

REFERENCES FOR THE DUPAS COMMENT

Angelucci, Manuela, Dean Karlan, and Jonathan Zinman. 2012. "Win Some Lose Some? Evidence from a Randomized Microcredit Program Placement Experiment by Compartamos Banco." J-PAL working paper. Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

Banerjee, Abhijit, Esther Duflo, Rachel Glennerster, and Cynthia Kinnan. 2013. "The Miracle of Microfinance? Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation." Working paper. Massachusetts Institute of Technology and Northwestern University.

Beck, Thorsten, Ash Demirguc-Kunt, and Ross Levine. 2007. "Finance, Inequality and Poverty: Cross Country Evidence." Journal of Economic Growth 12, no. 1: 211-52.

Chaia, Alberto, Aparna Dalal, Tony Goland, Maria Jose Gonzalez, Jonathan Morduch, and Robert Schiff. 2009. "Half the World is Unbanked." Framing Note. Financial Access Initiative. www.microfinancegateway.org/gm/document1.9.40671/25.pdf.

Crepon, Bruno, Esther Duflo, Florencia Devoto, and William Pariente. 2011. "Impact of Microcredit in Rural Areas of Morocco: Evidence from a Randomized Evaluation." J-PAL working paper. Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

Dupas, Pascaline, and Jonathan Robinson. 2013a. "Savings Constraint and Microenterprise Development: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Kenya." American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 5, no. 1: 163-92.

--. 2013b. "Why Don't the Poor Save More? Evidence from Health Savings Experiments." American Economic Review 103, no. 4:1138-71.

Dupas, Pascaline, Dean Karlan, and Jonathan Robinson. 2013. "Expanding Access to Formal Savings Accounts in Malawi, Uganda, Chile, and the Philippines." New Haven, Conn.: Innovations for Poverty Action. www.poverty-action.org/ project/0477.

Dupas, Pascaline, Sarah Green, Anthony Keats, and Jonathan Robinson. Forthcoming. "Challenges in Banking the Rural Poor: Evidence from Kenya's Western Province." In NBER Volume on African Economic Successes, edited by S. Johnson, S. Edwards, and D. Weil. University of Chicago Press.

Honohan, Patrick. 2008. "Cross-Country Variation in Household Access to Financial Services." Journal of Banking and Finance 32: 2493-2500.

Lusardi, Annamaria, Daniel Schneider, and Peter Tufano. 2011. "Financially Fragile Households: Evidence and Implications." BPEA (Spring): 83-134.

(1.) Dupas and Robinson (2013b) show that similar boxes enable households to reach a given savings goal much faster.
Table 1. Survey Evidence on Financial Fragility in Kenya,
Malawi, and Uganda Percent of respondents

                                      "If you had an emergency that
                                       required [indicated amount]
                                        urgently, where you would
                                                 get the money?"

                                         Kenya             Malawi
                                    (1,000 shillings   (1,000 kwacha
                                     [approximately    [approximately
Answer (a)                          equal to]  $12)    equal to] $7)

Would borrow from friends or               43               39
  relatives
Would sell agricultural products           14                3
Would work more                            14               21
Would sell assets                          14                7
Would exclusively use savings              13                7
Would borrow from savings club              6                3
Would not be able to find the               0               18
  money

                                    "If you had an emergency that
                                     required [indicated amount]
                                      urgently, where you would
                                           get the money?"

                                                Uganda
                                          (10,000 shillings
                                            [approximately
Answer (a)                                  equal to] $5)

Would borrow from friends or                      50
  relatives
Would sell agricultural products                   9
Would work more                                    9
Would sell assets                                 14
Would exclusively use savings                     15
Would borrow from savings club                     2
Would not be able to find the                      0
  money

Source: Household survey data collected by the author and
Jonathan Robinson along with Anthony Keats (Kenya, 2010),
Dean Karlan, and Diego Ubfal (Malawi and Uganda, 2011) for
ongoing projects.

(a.) Respondents could give more than one answer.


COMMENT BY LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ

This paper by Ash Demirguc-Kunt and Leora Klapper makes an important contribution to the literature by making public, and providing the first analysis of data from, the Global Findex, a new World Bank database comprising a variety of indicators on the use of financial products by individuals around the world. The database was constructed from 2011 survey data collected in interviews by Gallup, Inc., with selected adults in 148 countries.

Before Global Findex, the available data on the characteristics of populations excluded from formal financial institutions remained scarce and limited to a few regional efforts. (1) Despite widespread recognition of the welfare and efficiency benefits associated with improved financial inclusion, and despite the large number of initiatives, public and private, already in place around the world aiming to increase the percentage of the population (households and firms) with access to financial services, (2) cross-country analyses faced severe constraints due to lack of comparable data.

In my view, one cannot overstate the importance of this new database. Not only does it open up wide-ranging possibilities for future research, but it also supports the efforts of policymakers, multilateral organizations, and private donors, who now have a new tool to guide their policies and activities for improving financial inclusion. In this regard, the authors' plans to update the survey in a couple of years are of particular importance.

This paper is part of a series of analytical papers by the authors and their colleagues that utilize the Global Findex database. The authors present and analyze some key stylized facts derived from the survey, with a significant focus on within-country differences in financial inclusion based on individual characteristics. Their results are consistent with previous (scattered) evidence, and from that perspective they validate a number of policymakers' concerns. For example, as expected, the authors find that the percentage of individuals in developing countries who have an account at a formal financial institution increases by income quintile; this is not the case in most developed economies, where a large majority of the population at all income levels have access to such financial products. Moreover, across the developing world, the percentage of adult women with an account at a formal financial institution is significantly below that for men, and this gender gap persists across income levels (quintiles) within a given country.

The Global Findex data can be used for many other kinds of analysis. My own research has already benefited from the availability of this new database. Like the authors, I am interested in understanding the determinants of the use of financial products, and I have gained some further insights by focusing on the cross-country behavior of variables at the macro (aggregate) level. These findings, which I will summarize here, complement the authors' results.

The existing literature allows one to identify four categories of obstacles to financial inclusion at the country level, which affect either the demand for or the supply of financial services or both (see Rojas-Suarez and Gonzales 2010 and Rojas-Suarez and Amado forthcoming): socioeconomic constraints, macroeconomic factors, characteristics of the operations of the formal financial system, and institutional deficiencies. Here I will present and discuss some simple correlations between these obstacles and one of the Global Findex indicators of financial inclusion, namely, the percentage of the adult population with an account at a formal institution.

With regard to the first category, it is generally expected that countries that score high on indicators of social development, such as access to high-quality health and education services, will also enjoy high levels of financial inclusion. As discussed by Stijn Claessens (2005), financial exclusion is often part of a broader social exclusion, which is related, among other factors, to differences in education, type of employment, and training. Income inequality has also been cited as a socioeconomic factor influencing financial inclusion. Yet another factor, one that affects both the demand for and the supply of financial services, is the percentage of the population classified as middle class (see Rojas-Suarez and Amado forthcoming for further discussion).

My figure 1 shows the correlation between financial inclusion and an index of social development, constructed by equally weighting the first two of the three components of the Human Development Index (HDI) of the United Nations, which relate to health and education (the third relates to income). The figure shows a strong positive correlation: as expected, the developed countries display the highest values of both financial inclusion and social development. The very high correlation between our social development variable and GDP per capita (0.84) supports the authors' finding that the latter explains a significant part of the variation in account penetration across countries.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

Turning to the second category affecting financial inclusion, namely, macroeconomic factors, I show in figure 2 the correlation between the volatility of inflation (measured as the coefficient of variation of inflation during 1990-2010) and financial inclusion. High volatility of inflation captures well the adverse effects of macroeconomic instability on the willingness of the population to hold accounts in formal financial institutions. In economies with very high and volatile inflation, depositors have experienced significant losses in their real wealth. It is therefore not surprising that Argentina and Ukraine, both of which suffered from hyperinflation in the 1990s, are among the countries with the lowest rates of financial inclusion. By contrast, in Thailand, which has a history of low inflation volatility, the share of the adult population with an account at a formal financial firm is similar to that in the developed countries.

The policy lesson is straightforward: stimulating demand for financial services requires that individuals have trust that the real value of their payments and savings instruments will be preserved. If this trust is lacking, not only will the use of financial services remain dismal, but deposits in financial institutions will tend to be short-term as depositors stand ready to withdraw their funds at the first sign of financial system difficulties.

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

A wide variety of characteristics pertaining to financial firms' conduct of their operations are included in the third category of obstacles to financial inclusion. Among these are inefficiencies in collection and information processing, which may cause prohibitively high documentation requirements; insufficient numbers of branches, ATMs, points of sale, and other forms of financial firms' penetration, especially in small rural communities; and high administrative costs, which tend to increase the fixed costs of extending loans and maintaining accounts. The authors have discussed this type of obstacles extensively both in this paper and elsewhere (see, for example, Allen and others 2012).

As an example at the country level, figure 3 shows the negative correlation between financial inclusion and a commonly used measure of banking system inefficiency: the ratio (in percent) of bank overhead costs to total assets. As expected, developed economies display the lowest ratios.

Another potential obstacle to financial inclusion relates to the concentration of the banking system. High levels of bank concentration may deter banks from lending to individuals and to small and medium-size enterprises, since there are no competitive incentives to assess the quality of relatively riskier potential borrowers. Since the extension and repayment of bank loans are usually conducted through deposits in bank accounts, this argument could find support in a negative correlation between bank concentration and the share of adults with a formal financial account.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

However, recent studies have argued that, in a given country, the relationship between bank concentration and financial inclusion is strongly affected by the quality of its institutions--the fourth category. (See, for example, Claessens 2005 and Rojas-Suarez and Amado forthcoming.) Financial systems can develop more fully and reach a larger segment of the population in countries with adequate observance and enforcement of the rule of law, political stability, and respect for creditors' and debtors' rights. In particular, when contracts between creditors and debtors are observed and enforced, depositors have a stronger incentive to entrust their savings to banks and other formal financial institutions. How do bank concentration and the quality of institutions interrelate to affect financial inclusion? In countries with weak institutions, where the enforcement of contracts is very difficult, the oligopolistic power arising from a highly concentrated banking system leads to greater discrimination against riskier borrowers (who tend to be low-income individuals and smaller firms), and financial inclusion suffers. Such discrimination is not as commonly seen in a more competitive banking system.

Figure 4 illustrates these relationships. The top panel shows a negative, but low, correlation between bank concentration, measured as the percentage of total system assets held by the country's three largest banks, and financial inclusion (the correlation coefficient is only -0.2). However, a very different picture arises in the bottom panel, where the bank concentration variable is adjusted by an additional variable measuring the quality of institutions. This variable, called "rule of law," is taken from the World Bank's Worldwide Governance Indicators and measures agents' confidence in and commitment to abiding by the rules of the society; the quality of contract enforcement, police, and the courts; and the likelihood of crime and violence. (I have rescaled the original variable to range from zero to 100.) The adjusted bank concentration variable is obtained simply by multiplying it by the rule of law variable.

Taken together, the two panels of figure 4 suggest that although bank concentration might impinge on financial inclusion directly, it exerts its most important effect through the quality of institutions. Two examples will clarify this point. First, it is clear from the top panel that the developed countries are distributed across the whole range of bank concentration, and thus little can be said about any differences in concentration between developed and developing countries (except that the negative relationship in the figure is driven by the latter). However, when the bank concentration variable is adjusted by the quality of institutions (bottom panel), most of the developed economies migrate toward the upper right corner of the scatterplot. For this group of countries as a whole, the relatively high level of institutional quality seems a more relevant factor than bank concentration for understanding the behavior of financial inclusion.

Second, consider Malaysia and Nicaragua. These two developing countries share similar ratios of bank concentration (top panel), but the quality of institutions is much higher in Malaysia than in Nicaragua. Therefore, when bank concentration is adjusted for institutional quality, Malaysia lies well to the right of Nicaragua. This is fully consistent with a higher level of financial inclusion in the former country than in the latter.

Although correlations such as these provide valuable insights, fully understanding the obstacles to financial inclusion requires a deeper analysis. The first column of my table 1 reports results of an ordinary least squares regression in which financial inclusion (as defined above) is the dependent variable. Consistent with the discussion above, I include as explanatory variables the five variables that appear on the horizontal axes in figures 1 through 4. In addition, the regression includes two dummy variables: the first identifies developed economies (again, those classified by the World Bank as high-income countries), and the second emerging markets (those classified as upper-middle-income countries). (3) The regression was estimated for a sample of 116 countries.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

Except for the coefficient on the bank overhead costs variable (which had a p value of 0.18), all the estimated coefficients were statistically significant. The regression's [R.sup.2] was 0.8359. For each country category, the last three columns of table 1 show the implied contributions of the various obstacles to financial inclusion, calculated by multiplying each variable's estimated coefficient by the variable's average value.

To illustrate how to interpret the table, consider the group "other developing countries." According to the table, if all factors affecting financial inclusion identified in the regression were absent, this group would enjoy, on average, a financial inclusion ratio (a share of adults holding a formal financial account) of 55 percent (the value of the constant). With the obstacles present, however, the predicted financial inclusion ratio for this group of countries reaches only 25 percent. Similarly, absent the identified obstacles, 66 percent of the adult population in emerging markets would have an account in a formal financial institution (the sum of the constant and the coefficient on the dummy for emerging markets). However, because of the obstacles, the predicted ratio is only 43 percent.

The most important conclusions to be drawn from the table are as follows. First, the degree of social development matters greatly. The low level of social development in developing countries on average, and to a lesser extent in emerging markets, hampers financial inclusion through both demand and supply factors. Second, only in the developed economies does the high level of institutional quality at least partly offset the adverse effect of bank concentration on financial inclusion (the sum of the implied contributions for the bank concentration variable alone and for the bank concentration x rule of law interaction is positive). In contrast, in emerging markets and other developing countries on average, low institutional quality cannot counteract the financial exclusion effects of bank concentration. Third, relative to the other factors, inflation volatility and banking inefficiencies play smaller roles as obstacles to financial inclusion.

My discussion here provides just a taste of the potential uses of the Global Findex database and is intended as a complement to the authors' analysis and their ongoing research. The authors are to be congratulated not only for this paper but for their rich research agenda on financial inclusion.

REFERENCES FOR THE ROJAS-SUAREZ COMMENT

Allen, F., A. Demirguc-Kunt, L. Klapper, and M. S. Martinez Peria. 2012. "The Foundations of Financial Inclusion: Understanding Ownership and Use of Financial Accounts." Policy Research Working Paper no. 6290. Washington: World Bank.

CAF Banco de Desarrollo de America Latina. 2011. Servicios Financieros para el Desarrollo: Promoviendo el Acceso en America Latina. Reporte de Economia y Desarrollo series. Caracas. publicaciones.caf.com/publicacion?id=1502.

Claessens, Stijn. 2005. "Universal Access to Financial Services: A Review of the Issues and Public Policy Objectives." Presented at the OECD-World Bank Fifth Services Experts Meeting, Paris (February).

Rojas-Suarez, Liliana, and Maria Alejandra Amado. Forthcoming. "Improving Access to Financial Services in Latin America: Policy Implications and Lessons from Worldwide Experiences." Washington: Center for Global Development.

Rojas-Suarez, Liliana, and Veronica Gonzales. 2010. "Access to Financial Services in Emerging Powers: Facts, Obstacles and Policy Implications." Paris: OECD Development Center (March) www.oecd.org/dev/pgd/45965165.pdf.

(1.) As the authors note, two of the best-known household surveys that include data on the use of financial services are FinScope, a private sector initiative funded by the U.K. Department for International Development, which collects data for 14 African countries and Pakistan, and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development's Life in Transition Survey, which covers 35 countries in Europe and Central Asia. To these may be added the recent survey by CAF Banco de Desarrollo de America Latina (2011) that covers 17 major Latin American cities.

(2.) Ongoing initiatives go beyond microfinance activities and include innovations to improve the use of payments, savings, and insurance products. Two of the best-known initiatives are Kenya's M-PESA money transfer service (operated by a mobile phone provider) and the nonbank correspondent model in Brazil, which allows banks to reach remote populations through the use of existing nonbank networks, such as retail stores and post offices. A common characteristic of these two initiatives is that they rely heavily on technological advances in connectivity.

(3.) The third group of countries (omitted in the regression) consists of all other developing countries (those classified as lower-middle-income and low-income countries).
Table 1. Obstacles to Financial Inclusion: Implied
Contributions from Regression Analysis (a)

                                Regression
Independent variable            coefficient

Social underdevelopment         -36.29 ***
Bank concentration               -0.29 ***
Bank concentration x rule
  of law                          0.004 ***
Volatility of inflation          -3.11 **
Ratio of bank overhead costs
  to assets                     -28.33
Dummy for developed
  economy                        37.94 ***
Dummy for emerging market        10.61 **
Constant                         55.3 ***

                                Contribution (b) (percentage points)

                                                            Other
                                Developed     Emerging    developing
Independent variable            economies     markets     countries

Social underdevelopment          -4.1         -8.2        -14.5
Bank concentration              -17.3        -17.1        -17.8
Bank concentration x rule
  of law                         19.2         10.1          7.1
Volatility of inflation          -2.9         -4.9         -4.0
Ratio of bank overhead costs
  to assets                      -0.8         -1.5         -1.3
Dummy for developed
  economy                        37.94         0            0
Dummy for emerging market         0           10.61         0
Constant

Source: Author's regressions.

(a.) The dependent variable is the percentage of the adult
population with a bank account in a formal institution.
Asterisks indicate statistical significance at the
*** p < 0.01 or the ** p < 0.05 level.

(b.) Measured as the regression coefficient for the
indicated obstacle multiplied by that obstacle's average
value in the indicated country group.


GENERAL DISCUSSION

While sympathetic to nonstandard approaches based on behavioral economics, information asymmetry, and the like, Christopher Carroll wondered whether the problem of financial inclusion might not be better addressed using the textbook approach that assumes perfect rationality. Looking at the list of countries with lowest participation in the banking sector--Argentina, Greece, and Italy, for example--was enough to suggest that many people around the world might have good reason not to hold bank accounts. Financial inclusion, Carroll thought, might turn out to be a good overall indicator of the quality of a country's institutions: low inclusion could correlate with the degree to which a society and its institutions are dysfunctional. If that was the case, efforts to increase the penetration of bank account ownership would not address the underlying cause of noninclusion.

Donald Kohn added that any deliberate effort to increase financial inclusion would surely bring in people who are not well educated and who lack familiarity with financial products. Encountering a sophisticated modern financial system for the first time, these individuals might not understand the risks they are taking or, worse, might suffer exploitation. Kohn observed that this danger was not limited to developing countries: the subprime episode in the United States could be viewed as an attempt at financial inclusion that ended badly. The U.S. response has been mainly to increase disclosure and transparency, but there have also been proposals aimed, in a sense, at disinclusion by restricting the types of financial instruments available to the general public. Kohn asked whether the authors had investigated whether the newly banked individuals in their samples actually understood what they were getting, particularly on the credit side, and whether their findings pointed to any measures that could be taken to improve their understanding.

David Romer, also following up on Carroll's comment, cited some specific findings in the paper that could be interpreted as rational behavior on the part of the nonincluded. For example, the paper reported that a large fraction of the nonincluded chose not to have a bank account because they had too little money to make it worthwhile. That seemed to Romer a plausibly rational response. Others said that they had a relative with a bank account, so that in effect they did have access to financial services even though they were counted as excluded. Still others cited long distances to the nearest bank branch as a reason for not having an account. Was that a market failure, or was it an equilibrium outcome? These questions needed to be sorted out, Romer argued, before useful policy interventions could be proposed. Romer also asked the authors to clarify their distinction between an individual's explicit choice of how much to save and the standard definition of the same individual's saving as simply income minus consumption.

Ricardo Reis suggested that the present degree of inclusion in the banking system in some countries might actually be too high, in the sense that many people have bank accounts but lack access to other financial services that are arguably more important to their welfare, such as insurance against catastrophic shocks and vehicles for retirement saving.

Following up on Rojas-Suarez's discussion and Kohn's comment, Reis reminded the Panel that in the United States for much of the 19th century, a bank was an extremely risky place to keep one's savings: the history of banks in that largely unregulated era was rife with fraud. If bank regulation today in some developing countries is comparably weak, that argued against pushing for greater inclusion. On a similar note, Reis observed that, according to the paper, 78 percent of Greeks still had bank accounts in 2011, well into that country's financial crisis. That indicated to him a failure on the account holders' part to appreciate the risks they were taking.

For Benjamin Friedman, one of the paper's most interesting findings was that many people lack bank accounts because they do not trust the banks. He suspected, however, that their distrust could arise for different reasons. One might be the fear of bank fraud or recklessness that Reis had mentioned, but another might be fear of government expropriation: many Cambodians, for example, are wary of banks because they remember when the Pol Pot regime closed all the country's banks overnight and simply expropriated all the accounts. An entirely different potential motivation was the fear that the bank would not keep one's affairs secret. One needed to distinguish among these different reasons before deciding what sort of policy intervention was called for.

Michael Klein pointed out that people might choose to remain unbanked for transactional reasons as well as because of lack of savings or for other reasons. In countries where only cash is widely accepted, the transactions-related features of a bank account--checkwriting and debit cards, for example--would have little value.

Justin Wolfers remarked that the literature on financial access seemed to take it as given that financial access was a good thing, and indeed, to those who have it, it clearly is. But its benefits might be less obvious to those who have never had it. Wolfers also identified what he saw as a possible problem with the authors' empirical strategy. The paper claimed to be measuring access to financial services, meaning the ability to use those services if one wanted to, but what it really measured was an equilibrium quantity: those who, given the equilibrium price of holding a bank account, and taking into account all costs, actually used one. Just as not everyone who has access to spinach at the supermarket eats spinach, so, too, not everyone who has access to banking services opens a bank account.

Responding to the discussion, Leora Klapper answered Romer's question by saying that she and her coauthor were interested not in the quantity of saving as such but in the behavioral decision to save: what people did with the money that they were deliberately putting aside for a specific purpose, such as for a large purchase or for retirement. What the authors found was that these savings were typically placed in informal ROSCAs (rotating savings and credit associations) or under the mattress. Since the former are plagued by fraud and the latter is extremely unsafe, it seemed to the authors natural to suppose that a formal bank account, or at least a lockbox at a bank, was a better place to hold that money. Klapper also noted that in some countries such as Bangladesh, microfinance institutions are important sources of formal savings and credit, used by many people who do not have bank accounts.

Klapper also acknowledged that the histories of some countries, including some in Eastern Europe, provided their citizens ample reason to be distrustful of banks, and that lack of understanding of bank terms and conditions could result in exploitation or cause people to make poor use of their accounts. As an example, the failure of small savers to understand the concept of a minimum balance often leads to their savings being eroded. Klapper therefore emphasized that greater financial literacy was a necessary complement to sound regulation and consumer protection: it could contribute not only to broadening the use of safer financial services, but also to building trust in the financial system in countries with a history of financial scandal and expropriation.

Asli Demirguc-Kunt sought to clarify that the paper was not claiming or assuming that more people around the world should have bank accounts. Rather, she and Klapper were interested in identifying the perceived barriers to holding bank accounts among those who might want to use them. They believed that if market failures are indeed preventing broader access to bank accounts, the result was to limit people's ability to save for education or for other worthwhile purposes, and to limit businesses' access to capital for growth and expansion. In presenting their findings to policymakers, they took pains to emphasize the importance of responsible access. It was true that a majority of their respondents chose not to hold bank accounts because they did not have enough money to make it worthwhile, and some fraction of these presumably would see no need for an account even if they had more money. But a large fraction of the rest--30 percent of the total sample--identified other barriers such as high costs, remoteness, or instruments whose design does not conform with the potential user's religious beliefs. These were issues that a well-crafted policy might be able to remedy.

ASLI DEMIRGUC-KUNT

World Bank

LEORA KLAPPER

World Bank

(1.) See, for example. King and Levine (1993), Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2007), Beck, Levine, and Loayza (2000), Demirguc-Kunt and Levine (2009), Klapper, Laeven, and Rajan (2006), and World Bank (2008a).

(2.) For a detailed literature review see World Bank (2008a) and the references therein. Campbell (2006) also provides an overview of the household finance field.

(3.) The Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation funded three triennial rounds of data collection through the complete questionnaire. The next data collection will be in 2014.

(4.) The database and the full questionnaire are available at www.worldbank.org/global findex. Appendix A reproduces selected questions relevant to this paper. The questionnaire is also available in 15 languages at go.worldbank.org/5XL9LXK6B0.

(5.) In a few instances, surveyors and their supervisors reported that respondents were somewhat taken aback at the series of questions, given the personal nature of the topic. This concern was particularly relevant in countries with large security risks, such as Mexico and Zimbabwe, and in countries where personal finance is widely regarded as a private matter, such as Cameroon, Italy, and Portugal. There were also reports from the field that the terminology and concepts used in the survey were entirely new to some respondents. Although efforts were made to include simple definitions of such terms as "account" and "debit card," the unfamiliarity and complexity of the topic were still reported to be a hurdle in several countries, including Afghanistan, Cambodia, Chad, and rural Ukraine. Overall, however, the rate of "don't know" or "refuse" answers was very low. For the core questions (those not conditioned on the response to other questions), "don't know" or "refuse" responses made up fewer than 1 percent of the total and no more than 2 percent in any world region.

(6.) The worldwide aggregates omit countries for which Gallup excludes more than 20 percent of the population in the sampling either because of security risks or because the population includes non-Arab expatriates.

These excluded countries are Algeria, Bahrain, the Central African Republic, Madagascar, Qatar, Somalia, and the United Arab Emirates. Iran is also excluded because the data were collected in that country using a methodology inconsistent with that used for other countries (the survey was carried out by phone from Turkey). The exclusion of Iran has a nontrivial effect on regional aggregates because its population is larger and wealthier than the populations of most other countries in the Middle East and North Africa. For example, account penetration in the region is estimated to be 18 percent when Iran is excluded, but 33 percent when it is included.

(7.) In some countries oversamples are collected in major cities or areas of special interest. In addition, in some large countries, such as China and Russia, sample sizes of at least 4,000 are collected.

(8.) For details on the data collection dates, sample sizes, excluded populations, and margins of error, see www.worldbank.org/globalfindex.

(9.) The exact question in the LITS survey is "Does anyone in your household have a bank account?"

(10.) On the provider side, the International Monetary Fund collects indicators of financial outreach such as the number of bank branches and automated teller machines (ATMs) per capita and per square kilometer, as well as the number of loan and deposit accounts per capita, directly from country regulators. These data sets are important sources of basic cross-country indicators developed at a relatively low cost. Yet indicators based on data collected from financial service providers have several important limitations. First, data are collected from regulated financial institutions only and thus provide a fragmented view of financial access. Second, aggregation can be misleading because of multiple accounts or dormant accounts (see Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Martinez Peria 2008 for a discussion). Most important, this approach does not allow disaggregation of financial service users by income or other characteristics. That leaves policymakers unable to identify those segments of the population with the lowest use of financial services, such as the poor, women, or youth.

(11.) Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Greece, Hungary, Poland, Singapore, and the Slovak Republic are the only high-income countries included where phone coverage is less than 80 percent.

(12.) The Kish grid is a table of numbers used to select the interviewee in each household. First, the interviewer records the name, sex, and age of all permanent household members aged 15 and above, whether or not they are present, and then numbers them starting with the oldest and ending with the youngest. Second, the interviewer finds the column number of the Kish grid that corresponds to the last digit of the questionnaire number, and the row number for the number of eligible household members. The number in the cell where column and row intersect determines the person selected for the interview. In countries where cultural restrictions dictate matching interviewer and interviewee by sex, respondents are randomly selected using the Kish grid from among all eligible adults of the interviewer's sex.

(13.) In the latest-birthday method an interview is attempted with the adult in the household who had the most recent birthday.

(14.) According to the latest available data from the World Bank's World Development Indicators, there are 5.08 billion adults aged 15 and above worldwide.

(15.) Exceptions include Italy (with an account penetration of 71 percent) and the United States (88 percent).

(16.) See, for example, Chawla, Betcherman, and Banerji (2007), who provide an overview of the challenges of aging populations in Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union.

(17.) Because of the sensitivity of household finances and the inhibitions brought about by face-to-face surveys, the Global Findex survey did not probe deeply into the practices of "under the mattress" saving in the home.

(18.) The Gallup World Poll collects information on the ownership of credit cards but not their use.

(19.) Data on the main purpose of outstanding loans were gathered only in developing countries, because Gallup, Inc., enforces a time limit for phone interviews conducted in high-income countries, limiting the number of questions that can be added to the core questionnaire. Respondents were asked to choose from a list of reasons for borrowing, so it is possible that reasons not listed (borrowing to start a business, for example) are also common.

(20.) Among all respondents, 12 percent chose none of the given reasons for not having an account.

(21.) The institutional barriers to financial inclusion are further analyzed in Allen and others (2012).

(22.) For more on documentation requirements and safeguards against money laundering, see Yikona and others (2011) and Financial Action Task Force (2011).

(23.) Gardiner Harris, "India Aims to Keep Money for Poor Out of Others' Pockets," New York Times, January 5, 2013.

(24.) For all questions the choices of "don't know" and "refused" are also included as possible responses (results not shown).
Table 1. Country-Level Regressions Explaining Financial Inclusion (a)

                                   Dependent variable

                   Percent of adults reporting having an account at a
                              formal financial institution
Independent
variable              1-1           1-2           1-3           1-4

Logarithm of        0.105 ***                   0.122 ***     0.157 ***
  GDP per          (0.014)                     (0.014)       (0.012)
  capital (d)
Low-income                       -0.436 ***
  country                        (0.106)
  (1) (e)
Lower-middle-                    -0.442 ***
  income                         (0.079)
  country
  (2) (e)
Upper-middle-                    -0.325 ***
  income                         (0.053)
  country
  (3) (e)
Domestic                                        0.185 ***
  credit to the                                (0.037)
  private sec
  tor (percent
  of GDP) (d)
Gini index (d)                                               -0.488 **
                                                             (0.190)
Constant                          0.203        -0.606 ***    -0.582 ***
                                 (0.241)       (0.093)       (0.126)
No. of            134           134           123           110
  observations
  (countries)
[R.sup.2]           0.772         0.783         0.747         0.662
p value of
  F statistic
  [H.sub.0]:
    (1) = (2)                     0.904
  [H.sub.0]:
    (2) = (3)                     0.015

                     Dependent variable

                                  Percent
                    Percent      reporting
                   reporting      use of
                    formal        formal
Independent        saving (b)    credit (c)
variable              1-5           1-6

Logarithm of
  GDP per
  capital (d)
Low-income         -0.316 ***    -0.063 ***
  country          (0.027)       (0.014)
  (1) (e)
Lower-middle-      -0.313 ***    -0.052 ***
  income           (0.025)       (0.013)
  country
  (2) (e)
Upper-middle-      -0.276 ***    -0.039 ***
  income           (0.024)       (0.013)
  country
  (3) (e)
Domestic
  credit to the
  private sec
  tor (percent
  of GDP) (d)
Gini index (d)

Constant            0.407 ***     0.135 ***
                   (0.017)       (0.009)
No. of            139           139
  observations
  (countries)
[R.sup.2]           0.622         0.160
p value of
  F statistic
  [H.sub.0]:
    (1) = (2)       0.931         0.443
  [H.sub.0]:
    (2) = (3)       0.127         0.310

Source: Authors' regressions using Global Findex and World
Development Indicators data.

(a.) Each column reports results of a single ordinary least squares
regression. Standard errors are in parentheses. Asterisks denote
significance at the *** 1 percent, ** 5 percent, and * 10 percent
level.

(b.) Percent of adults reporting having saved or put aside money at a
formal financial institution in the past 12 months.

(c.) Percent of adults reporting having borrowed from a formal
financial institution in the past 12 months.

(d.) Data are for 2011 or the most recent year available.

(e.) Dummy variable equal to 1 when the country is a member of the
indicated country income group, and zero otherwise. High-income
countries are the omitted category.

Table 2. Individual-Level Probit Regressions Explaining Financial
Inclusion (a)

                         Dependent variable and country income group

                             Has an account at a formal financial
                                         institution

Within-country                        Lower-      Upper-
income quintile            Low        middle      middle       High

Bottom (1)              -0.133 ***  -0.185 ***  -0.239 ***  -0.051 ***
                        (0.009)     (0.014)     (0.019)     (0.007)
Second (2)              -0.113 ***  -0.148 ***  -0.177 ***  -0.037 ***
                        (0.009)     (0.013)     (0.016)     (0.007)
Third (3)               -0.090 ***  -0.103 ***  -0.135 ***  -0.019 **
                        (0.007)     (0.011)     (0.014)     (0.008)
Fourth (4)              -0.050 ***  -0.079 ***  -0.075 ***  -0.004
                        (0.008)     (0.010)     (0.010)     (0.008)
No. of observations       25,369      34,144      35,820      30,681
p value of F statistic
  [H.sub.0]: (1) = (2)   0.02 **     0.00 ***    0.00 **     0.02 **
  [H.sub.0]: (2) = (3)   0.02 **     0.00 ***    0.00 ***    0.01 *
  [H.sub.0]: (3) = (4)   0.00 ***    0.02 **     0.00 ***    0.10

                         Dependent variable and country income group

                           Saved at a formal financial institution
                                    within last 12 months

Within-country                        Lower-      Upper-
income quintile            Low        middle      middle       High

Bottom (1)              -0.084 ***  -0.110 ***  -0.152 ***  -0.208 ***
                        (0.010)     (0.011)     (0.012)     (0.018)
Second (2)              -0.075 ***  -0.090 ***  -0.116 ***  -0.137 ***
                        (0.006)     (0.013)     (0.007)     (0.013)
Third (3)               -0.049 ***  -0.070 ***  -0.085 ***  -0.087 ***
                        (0.006)     (0.008)     (0.008)     (0.013)
Fourth (4)              -0.032 ***  -0.045 ***  -0.052 ***  -0.032 ***
                        (0.006)     (0.006)     (0.010)     (0.012)
No. of observations       25,369      34,144      35,820      30,681
p value of F statistic
  [H.sub.0]: (1) = (2)   0.34        0.01 ***    0.00 ***    0.00 ***
  [H.sub.0]: (2) = (3)   0.00 ***    0.10 *      0.00 ***    0.00 ***
  [H.sub.0]: (3) = (4)   0.03 **     0.00 ***    0.00 ***    0.00 ***

                        Dependent variable and country income group

                             Borrowed from a formal financial
                             institution within last 12 months

Within-country                        Lower-      Upper
income quintile            Low        middle      middle     High

Bottom (1)              -0.035 ***  -0.036 ***  -0.044 ***  -0.011
                        (0.013)     (0.008)     (0.010)     (0.009)
Second (2)              -0.038 ***  -0.034 ***  -0.036 ***  -0.012
                        (0.010)     (0.010)     (0.007)     (0.009)
Third (3)               -0.033 ***  -0.018 ***  -0.034 ***   0.000
                        (0.008)     (0.007)     (0.008)     (0.007)
Fourth (4)              -0.021 ***  -0.014 ***  -0.022 **    0.002
                        (0.007)     (0.005)     (0.009)     (0.007)
No. of observations       25,369      34,144      35,820    30,681
p value of F statistic
  [H.sub.0]: (1) = (2)   0.72        0.75        0.27        0.90
  [H.sub.0]: (2) = (3)   0.41        0.02 **     0.83        0.12
  [H.sub.0]: (3) = (4)   0.11        0.48        0.09        0.73

Source: Authors' regressions using Global Findex and World
Development Indicators data.

(a.) Each column reports results of a single probit regression of the
indicated financial inclusion measure (a dummy variable equal to 1 if
the respondent meets the indicated criterion, and zero otherwise) on
country fixed effects, the respondent's within-country income
quintile (the top quintile is the omitted category), and the
following individual characteristics: sex, age, age squared, rural
versus urban residence, education, log of household size, marital
status, and whether employed. All regressions account for
stratification and clustering in the survey design. Data are for 2011
or the most recent year available. Standard errors are in
parentheses. Asterisks denote significance at the *** 1 percent, ** 5
percent, and * 10 percent level.

Figure 1. Formal Account Penetration, by Country Income Group

Country income group (a)

               Adults with an account at a formal
               financial institution (percent)

Low                           24%
Lower-middle                  29%
Upper-middle                  57%
High                          89%

Source: Authors' calculations using Global Findex data.

(a.) Low-income countries are those with gross national income
per capita less than $1,025 in 2011; lower-middle-income countries,
$1,026-$4,035; upper-middle-income countries, $4,036-$12,475;
high-income countries, $12,476 or more.

Note: Table made from bar graph.

Figure 5. Formal Account Penetration in the Poorest Quintile,
Selected High-Income Countries

Percent of adults without
a formal account

United States         25.78
Gin (a) = 37.8

United Kingdom         3.05
Gini = 34.5

Australia
Gini = 33.6            2.90

Canada
Gini = 32.4            8.83

Source: Authors' calculations using Global Findex and Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) data.

(a.) A higher Gini index indicates greater income inequality.

Note: Table made from bar graph.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有