Attendance rates, political shirking, and the effect of post-elective office employment.
Lott, John R., Jr.
ATTENDANCE RATES, POLITICAL SHIRKING, AND THE EFFECT OF POST-ELECTIVE
OFFICE EMPLOYMENT
I. INTRODUCTION
Political shirking--the degree to which a politican's actions
deviate from the wishes of his constituents--can take many different
dimensions. Economists (e.g., Amacher and Boyes [1978], Davis and
Porter [1989], Dougan and Munger [1989], Kalt and Zupan [1984], Lott
[1987d], Nelson and Siberberg [1987], and Peltzman [1984]) have debated
whether shirking exists in how a politician votes when he does vote.
This divergence is measured through some particular "special
interest" voting ratings (e.g., American Conservative Union,
Americans for Democratic Action, etc.). However, shirking can obviously
take as many forms as there are outputs that a politician produces.
Besides how he votes, he also produces services for his constituents
involving everything from being personally available to listen to the
constituents' grievances to ensuring effective handling of case
work by his staff (see, for example, Fiorina [1977], Fenno [1978], and
Cain et al. [1987]). (1) One dimension that has not been sufficiently
examined is the extent to which politicians shirk by failing to vote on
pending legislation. (2) No attention has been given to which
mechanisms will make this particular type of shirking relatively more
costly.
Most economists agree that opportunitic behavior by politicians is
limited by the threat of reelection (e.g., Amacher and Boyes [1978],
Barro [1973], Kalt and Zupan [1984], Nelson [1976], and Telser [1976]).
(3) By implication, the level of shirking should be the greatest when a
politician decides to leave office. However, this opportunistic behavior might be reduced to the extent that political parties or
constituencies impose costs for shirking through affecting
politicisns' post-elective office career or the careers of their
children. Thus, a politicians' last term in elective office may
not represent his "last period" in any meaningful sense.
The next section outlines the differing views on how politicians
act when they no longer face the threat of reelection. Section III
describes some empirical evidence on what mechanisms may prevent this
last-period problem. The final section discusses the impliactions of
these results.
II. THE LAST PERIOD
Whether economists view politicians as ideologues (e.g., Kau and
Rubin [1979] and Kalt and Zupan [1984]) or as simply attempting to
maximize political support (e.g., Barro [1973], Ferejohn [1986], Nelson
[1976], and Peltzman [1984]), the threat of reelection is seen as
preventing shirking. As Kalt and Zupan [1984, 298] phrase it, "it
appears that the proximity of the next election inhibits ideological
shirking."
Even those who do not view the last period as affecting how a
politician votes argue that it will affect how often he votes. Lott
[1987a; 1987b] has argued that if voters can determine and elect
politicians that have ideological preferences corresponding exactly to
the wishes of constituents, politicians' voting patterns should
continue to reflect those values even when the cost of shirking, in
terms of forgone future votes, is low. The penalty to ideologues of not
votingfor their constituency in the last period when they no longer face
reelection is the forgone utility from not doing what they personally
value. Assuming that politicians also desire leisure, politicians
should continue to vote for what they believe in, but they should vote
less frequently since they no longer receive the additional return of
larger future support.
Mechanisms to overcome this last-period problem have been suggested
by Becker and Stigler [1974, 9-10]. They argue that opportunistic
behavior can be controlled if officeholders face the loss of a pension
(or, equivalently, a posted bond) in the event of opportunistic behavior
in their last term. However, the actual pension system does not
effectively eliminate the last period for politicians, since retirement
payments are not based on cheating in the last period. Such a system
may only increase the cost of cheating in earlier periods. However,
since retirement annuities for Congress are calculated at only 2.5
percent of the average yearly salary for the last three years of
employment times the number of years of service, even this effect is
probably not very large. Another type of bond can involve the loss of
valuable brand name. However, since politicians have only very limited
means of selling their political brand name (Lott [1987a; 1987d]),
politicians are different than firms in that the reduced value of their
brand name in their last period can have only a very limited impact on
their wealth.
Barro [1973] has suggested that political parties might offer
future appointments to jobs as an inducement for good last-period
performance. While intuitively quite believable, this proposition has
never been tested. Eckert [1981] provided the interesting finding that
51 percent of all former Civil Aeronautics Board, Federal Communications
Commission, and Interstate Commerce Commission commission members took
private sector jobs in the related regulated industry after leaving
their commission posts. However, he produced not direct evidence that
the lure of private sector employment affected commission members'
behavior while they were on the commission. (4) This paper tests to see
how effective post-elective employment and other mechanisms are in
reducing the return to one particular type of shirking through looking
at how often a congressman votes when he no longer faces reelection.
III. ATTENDANCE RATES: THE EVIDENCE
When a legislator is in his last term in office, the cost to him of
shirking in terms of forgone future political support is relatively low.
One dimension that this shirking can take is that of not voting on
pending legislation and thus not representing the preferences of his
district. The lower the cost of shirking, the more he should shirk and
consume leisure on the job. (5)
Retiring politicians are defined as those who neither run for
reelection nor for any other political office in 1978. We assume that
politicians know when they will retire. (6) Table I provides a first
look at this problem by showing the mean percentage attendance rates and
their standard deviations for both congressmen who retired at the end of
the 95th Congress 1977-78) and for those who did not. The data were
obtained from the Congressional Quarterly. Section 1 of the table
reports that the voting rate for congressmen is lower in the term they
retire, though it is neither statistically significantly nor below the
rate for nonretiring politicians in the 95th Congress. Given that many
congressmen retire due to illness and that this will also make it more
costly for them to vote, section 2 of the table also gives the values
for the two groups excluding those who are ill or have serious illnesses
or deaths in their families. The means for both groups rise; not
surprisingly, the mean for retiring politicians rises the most since
they were most likely to have been ill, thus leaving an even smaller and
less significant difference between the two groups.
Obviously, other determinants of congressional voting rates must be
controlled for. To do this, an attempt was made to see whether the
attendance rate for congressmen retiring in 1978 fell between the 95th
and 94th Congresses (their last and second-to-last terms in elected
office) relative to the change for nonretiring congressmen between the
two periods. This was done by estimating the following regression
across all congressmen who had been in office for both the 95th and 94th
Congresses using ordinary least squares:
CHANGE IN ATTENDANCE RATES = [a.sub.0] + [a.sub.1] LAST TERM +
[a.sub.2] CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS + [a.sub.3] ILLNESS DURING 95th
CONGRESS + [a.sub.4] ILLNESS DURING 94th CONGRESS + [a.sub.5] REPUBLICAN
+ [a.sub.6] TENURE + [a.sub.7] TENURE + [a.sub.7] AGE + [a.sub.8]
ANOTHER OFFICE + [a.sub.9] CHANGE IN GENERAL ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES +
[a.sub.10] CHANGE IN PRIMARY ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES + [a.sub.11]
STATE.
The variables are defined as follows:
CHANGE IN ATTENDANCE RATES = the percentage point change in the
total voting rates from the 94th to the 95th Congresses;
LAST TERM = dummy variable which equals one if the politician
retires in 1978, zero otherwise;
CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS = dummy variable that is one when a
retired congressman engages in either lobbying for pay or takes a job
with the government and/or when his offspring go into politics, work for
the government, or lobby for clients dealing with the government, zero
otherwise;
ILLNESS DURING ith CONGRESS = dummy variable that is one if the
congressman was absent one day or more due to illness, zero otherwise,
where i represents either the 95th or 94th Congresses;
REPUBLICAN = dummy variable that is one if the candidate is a
Republican, zero otherwise;
TENURE = the congressman's tenure in office (in years);
AGE = the congressman's age (in years);
ANOTHER OFFICE = dummy variable that is one if the congressman is
retiring from congress to run for another elective office, zero
otherwise;
CHANGE IN GENERAL ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES = the change in
percentage vote margins between the congressman and his challengers in
the 1978 and 1976 general elections, which is zero if he did not run for
reelection in 1978;
CHANGE IN PRIMARY ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES = the change in
percentage vote margins between the congressman and his challengers in
the 1978 and 1976 primary elections, which is zero if he did not run for
reelection in 1978; and
STATE = a vector of state dummies excluding Wyoming.
If the last-period problem exists, the coefficient on LAST TERM
should be negative. However, the fact that a retiring congressman is
leaving office is an imperfect measure of whether he is really in his
last period. For instance, constituencies may hire retiring politicians
or their children, as liaisons to government bureaus, lobbyists, or
consultants. Strong political parties may reward loyal service with
appointments to government positions. If the salary that these
constituencies or political parties are willing to pay politicians
declines with the level of cheating, politicians will find it costly to
cheat. It is assumed that side payments take the form of jobs and not
direct pecuniary payments independent of any future work.
In an attempt to control for this type of payoff, twenty-five of
the twenty-seven congressmen who retired at the end of the 95th Congress
(see appendix) were interviewed. Since the remaining two congressmen
(Olin Teague and James Burke) had died, their widows were interviewed.
(7) If constituencies or political parties can impose costs upon
cheating politicians after they leave office through future employment,
the coefficient on CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS should be positive.
Politicians are assumed to have rational expectations with regards to
these costs. The size of these costs will determine how much of this
last-period problem can be mitigated.
Since the average voting are in the 95th Congress is below that for
the 94th Congress, illness during the 95th Congress should make this
negative difference larger, while illness during the 94th congress
should make it smaller. Larger values of the CHANGE IN GENERAL ELECTION
VOTE DIFFERENCES or CHANGE IN PRIMARY ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES indicate
that the congressman faced easier elections in 1978 than in 1976, and
should represent a lower opportunity cost of voting in terms of forgone
campaign time. (8) Likewise, the coefficient on ANOTHER OFFICE should
be negative if the returns to campaigning in areas in which the
candidate has not run before are larger. Increased TENURE lowers the
cost of not voting (i.e., shirking) if it is harder to defeat incumbents
who have more political brand name (see Lott [1986; 1987a]). However,
increased TENURE may also make voting more costly because of more and/or
higher-quality committee assignments. A negative coefficient here
implies either that the cost of shirking falls and/or the opportunity
cost of forgoing other activities increases with tenure.
Finally, this paper involves no strong prior beliefs on how the
opportunity cost of voting varies with AGE, nor on whether Republicans
or Democrats tend to vote more frequently over time. (9) Other articles
by Johnston [1978], Lott [1987a], and Welch [1974] find that the
marginal cost to acquiring campaign funds varies across political
parties, so possibly they face different opportunity cost of forgoing
fund arising to go vote. Neither the removal of AGE and/or REPUBLICAN
affects the following results. Data on these variables were obtained
from The Almanac of American Politics.
Some of the change in a congressman's attendance rates may
arise from how many of a year's issues are related to the economic
interests (based on income, geography, etc.) of his constituents. For
instance, a congressman's voters may not be interested in what part
of another state is designated as a national park, and thus in years
when a congressman's constituents are not directly affected by a
relatively large number of votes, his attendance rate should be
relatively low. I use the vector of state dummies as a proxy for these
differences. The dummy variable for the fiftieth state (Wyoming) was
excluded so that the intercept term represents that state.
The results for equation (1) are shown in column 1 of Table II.
The results indicate that politicians do behave differently in their
last period. The coefficient on LAST TERM reveals retiring politicians
vote 7.8 percentage points less often than nonretiring politicians, and
the coefficient is significant at the .004 level. Comparing two
hypothetical Democratic politicians from California (where the state
dummy is 4.6) who are sixty-five years old and have been in Congress for
twenty years, the reduction in voting participation for a retiring
politician equals -10.134 percentage points, which is 4.4 times greater
than that for a nonretiring politician (-2.296) for whom the CHANGE IN
GENERAL ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES equals zero and the CHANGE IN PRIMARY
ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES equals zero. Using the total attendance
levels shown in Table I, this result implies that while nonretiring
congressmen are absent for one out of every ten votes, retiring
congressmen are absent for one out of every five.
Interestingly, the coefficient for CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS
is of the predicted sign, but insignificant and not very large,
representing only one-quarter of the reduction in the attendance rates
that occurs in the last period. This result indicates that the future
careers of a politician and/or that of his children do not seem to
increase significantly the cost of shirking to retiring politicians.
All other coefficients are of the expected sign, with ILLNESS
DURING 95th CONGRESS, ILLNESS DURING 94th CONGRESS, CHANGE IN PRIMARY
ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES, and ANOTHER OFFICE being significant for
two-tailed t-tests, and TENURE and AGE being significant for one-tailed
t-tests. The results indicate that no significant difference exists
between the change in voting rates of Republicans and Democrats. The
coefficient on ANOTHER OFFICE implies that a politician reduces his
voting rate by 15 percentage points if he attempts to run for another
political office, because of the large returns to campaigning in areas
in which the candidate has not run before. Even though the coefficients
for illness in the 95th and 94th Congresses are quite significant, both
coefficients are relatively small when compared with the drop in
attendance associated with the last term of a congressman.
Columns 2, 3, and 4 in Table III attempt to reestimate equation (1)
by replacing CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS. Column 2 eliminates
CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS by controlling separately for the effects
of a retiring politician's own career after holding elective office
(OWN CAREER) and the careers of his children after he leaves office
(CHILDREN'S CAREER). OWN CAREER equals one if the retired
congressman either engages in lobbying for pay and/or takes a job with
the government, zero otherwise. CHILDREN'S CAREER equals one if
the retired congressman's children either attempt to run for public
office, work for the government, and/or engage in lobbying, zero
otherwise.
Column 3 replaces CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS with a variable
that multiplies the dummy variables CHILDREN'S CAREER and OWN
CAREER together (CHILDREN'S*OWN CAREERS). This new variable equals
one only when both the retiring politician and his offspring are
involved in politics after the politician leaves elective office. If a
shirking politician can be punished through both his own and his
children's careers after he leaves office, the coefficient on this
new variable should be both larger and more significant than the
coefficient on CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS or the coefficients on
either of the two dummies separately since it only examines those
politicians who face the greatest cost for cheating in terms of forgone
future employment.
Column 4 replaces CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS with a dummy
variable (LAST TERM*AGE 65) that equals one if a congressman is retiring
in 1978 and is less than sixty-five years of age, zero otherwise. If
the side payments to retiring congressmen take the form of jobs and not
direct pecuniary payments, it seems that the effectiveness of such
payments will be reduced for older politicians whose remaining careers
may be short or nonexistent. Alternatively, this variable could simply
measure how long a retired, cheating politician must endure the distain
of his former constituencies. If younger politicians expect to face
such costs for a longer period of time, since they can expect to remain
alive longer, younger politicians will find it more costly to shirk.
Both explanations predict that the coefficient on LAST TERM*AGE 65
should be positive.
The results for column 2 are almost identical to the results for
column 1. All of the coefficients are of the same sign, and all are
equally significant. The coefficients for the dummy variables
CHILDREN'S CAREER and OWN CAREER are still insignificant, though
the coefficient for CHILDREN'S CAREER is significant at the .10
level for a single-tailed t-test. The size of the coefficient for
CHILDREN'S CAREER implies that even if a retiring politician has a
child who will be going into political life, the politician's
attendance rate will decline by 3.8 percentage points during his last
term in office.
The results for column 3 indicate that for those retired
politicians who will pursue careers in government and/or lobbying and
whose children are also involved in careers with the government, there
is virtually no change in attendance rates during their last term in
office. The coefficient for CHILDREN'S*OWN CAREERS is significant
at the .09 level and slightly larger than what is needed to completely
offset the decline in attendance rates that normally arises during a
congressman's last term in elective office. This result implies
that forgone future employment opportunities are large enough to
eliminate any shirking in terms of attendance rates. The other
variables remain unchanged.
Finally, the results given in column 4 provide evidence that
congressmen who retire when they are less than sixty-five years old
reudce their attendance rates by only about hafl as much as retiring
congressmen who are sixty-five or older--or about 5 percentage points
less. LAST TERM*AGE 65 is significant at the .10 level for a two-tailed
t-test. The other variables are relatively unchanged except that AGE is
now significant at the .10 level for a two-tailed t-test.
One possible objection to the preceding results is that the LAST
TERM variable may be simultaneously determined with voting attendance
and, as a consequence, the ordinary least squares estimates that have
been presented yielded biased and inconsistent estimates. For instance,
one story could be that marginal congressmen, those most likely to quit
in anticipation of defeat (see Jacobsen and Kernell [1981, Chapter 5]),
may face lower voting rates because they spend more time back in their
districts deciding whether to run again. To some extent, this is
probably being picked up by such variables as CHANGE IN GENERAL ELECTION
VOTE DIFFERENCES and CHANGE IN PRIMARY ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCES.
However, if it is not, the question becomes to what degree those
incumbents who decide to retire during their final term in office
represent observations from the same model as those incumbents who made
the decision to retire prior to their last term.
To test the preceding hypothesis column 1 was reestimated using
two-stage least squares, assuming that the probability that a
congressman will retire is a linear function of
LAST TERM = f(ILLNESS 95th, CONGRESS, ILLNESS DURING 94th CONGRESS,
REPUBLICAN, TENURE, AGE, GENERAL ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCE 1976, PRIMARY
ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCE 1976), (2)
where GENERAL ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCE 1976 is the congressman's
margin of victory in the 1976 general election and PRIMARY ELECTION VOTE
DIFFERENCE 1976 is his margin in the 1976 primary. These results
correspond with column 1 in Table III. The coefficients on both LAST
TERM and CHILDREN'S OR OWN CAREERS both become slightly smaller and
less significant, with their respective coefficients becoming -7.173 and
1.923 and absolute t-statistics equally 2.809 and 0.634. The rest of
the variables also remain essentially unchanged. The estimates for
equation 2 were
LAST TERM = -.047 (1.601) REPUBLICAN + .0279 (0.631) ILLNESS DURING
95th CONGRESS -.005 (0.143) ILLNESS 94th CONGRESS + .0076 (3.948) TENURE
+ .0035 (2.215) AGE - .00134 (2.600) GENERAL ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCE
1976 - .00047 (0.884) PRIMARY ELECTION VOTE DIFFERENCE 1976 (3)
[R.sup.2] = .1267 F-ratio = 7.044,
where the absolute t-statistics are shown in parentheses. Not
surprisingly, AGE and TENURE have a significant positive effect on the
probability of retirement, while the closeness of the most recent
general election has a significant negative impact. The weakly
significant coefficient on the party dummy variable provides some
support for Jacobsen's and Kernell's [1983, 49-59] claim of
the importance of party affiliation in determining the probability of
retirement. Similar two-stage least squares estimates were made in
Table III for columns 2, 3, and 4 with relatively little change in the
estimates from the corresponding columns shown in Table II.
IV. IMPLICATIONS
Politicians do vote significantly less in their last period.
However, assuming that political parties or constituencies are actually
trying to control how often retiring congressmen vote through the
control of employment upon leaving office, it seems they are having only
modest success. Shirking is reduced or eliminated only when both the
retiring congressmen and their offspring continue to be involved in
politics after the congressmen leave office.
Of the twenty-seven retiring congressmen in the sample, eleen cases
had neither the retired congressmen nor their children take any
politically related jobs. Thus in only 59 percent of the cases examined
was there even a chance of influencing a congressman's attendance
rate through future employment. However, when these remaining sixteen
cases are taken as a whole, their attendance rates are virtually
indistinguishable from the original eleven.
Though shirking is eliminated for those congressmen for whom both
they and their children are involved in politics after the
congressmen's retirement from elective office, this subsample represents only 11 percent (three cases) of the sample of retiring
politicians and indicates the limited scope available to completely
eliminate opportunistic behavior through the control of postelective
careers. Not only are the effects insignificant when the future careers
of the politicians and their children are controlled for separately, but
they are only able to offset half of the reduction in attendance rates.
While the coefficients for the dummy variable representing the
careers of the politicians and their children are not significant when
they are taken separately, the results suggest that both the size and
significance of the effects increase when they occur simultaneously.
The greater the total cost imposed upon politicians, the greater seems
to be the response. (10)
Finally, it eems to be more costly for younger retiring politicians
to shirk. Whether this occurs as a result of future employment
opportunities or simply because young former politicians must endure the
wrath of disappointed constituencies for a longer period is not obvious,
Being young when retiring also did not completely eliminate shirking,
but reduced the last-period problem by about 50 percent. (11)
Given that this evidence examines only one complete cohort of
retiring congressmen, these results can be viewed as only suggestive.
They do, however, strongly indicate the presence of a last-period
problem for politicians in terms of attendance rates, and that this
shirking can be affected to some extent by post-elective employment. If
the theory presented here is correct, similar relationships are likely
to emerge when other dimensions of constituent services such as case
work are examined. Assuming that data on postelective office employment
are eventually gathered for the 96th Congress, an obvious extension of
this work would be see what effect such employment has on the measures
of constituency service examined by Cain et al. [1987]
(1) Some circumstantial evidence of constituent services'
importance is provided by Florida [1977, chapter 7], while Cain et al.
[1987, 176-89] provide direct empirical evidence of the role that such
services play in determining the probability by which a congressman and
a member of Britain's parliament will be reelected.
(2) Lott [1987b] is the only attempt I know of that tries to
explain how attendance rates for politicians change when they no longer
face reelection. While in general, a similar specification will be used
here, Lott [1987b] does not address the question of how post-elective
office employment of politicians and/or their children affect the cost
of shirking through attendance rates during their last term. While that
paper does investigate the effect of post-elective office employment on
how a politician votes when he does vote, it is not a "fair"
test of the usefulness of future employment in constraining shirking.
This is because if the ideology of politicians coincides sufficiently
closely to that of their constituents, no cheating will exist in terms
of how a politician votes and so there is nothing to constrain. As
section II points out, the question of how often a politician votes can
be fundamentally different from how he votes when he does vote (see also
Lott [1987a]).
(3) Becker and Stigler [1974, 11-12] and Barro [1973] were the
first to recognize explicitly that a premium may exist for holding
office, the threatened loss of which makes shirking by politicians
costly. Lott [1987a; 1987b] argues that opportunistic behavior by
politicians in terms of how they vote, when they do vote, can be solved
though ideology. Benson and Baden [1985] discuss the problems of
legislators monitoring the shirking or cheating behavior of bureaucra
Landes and Posner [1975] and Crain and Tollison [1979] discuss various
mechanisms used to guarantee "contracts" made with
special-interest groups. (See also Coats and Dalton [1989] and Van Beek
[1989] for recent work supporting my earlier findings.) The discussion
here focuses on how an alternative mechanism--post-elective office
employment--enforces implicit contracts made by legislators.
(4) As Eckert notes [1981, 120] his evidence is equally consistent
with future employment acting either as a bribe "for votes on the
bench that were favorable to the industry or a particular firm" or
as "the return on the investment in human capital that the
commissioner made by learning the details and politics of
regulation...."
(5) As the cost of shirking in terms of forgone future support is
reduced, politicians are expected also to purchase more leisure by
producing less output in the other dimensions mentioned earlier (e.g.,
case work). While it is hyothetically possible that a retiring
congressman votes less congressmen in their last term suddenly begin to
produce a different mix of output, this seems doubtful. First, it is
not clear why changes in voter preferences would be related to their
congressman's term in office. Second, given that retiring
incumbents do not have to run for reelection, it seems unlikely that the
increase in the amount of time necessary to produce these other outputs
would be so great that it not only absorbs the time savings from not
having to campaign but also requires a reduction in the time devoted to
voting on legislation.
(6) The appendix, based on questioning of the retired politicians
used in this sample, shows that 58 percent of the sample made their
"final" decision to retire at least by November 1976, and that
80 percent had made it by the end of 1977. The Congressional Quarterly
[1978, 33] reports that by January 7, 1978, seventeen congressmen had
announced their retirement. It is assumed here that congressmen who
died during the 95th Congress did not anticipate their death and thus
they were not included as retiring. Those who died early were not
included in the sample due to a lack of data on their voting patterns.
(7) Their telephone numbers were obtained from either (i) the
Association of Former Members of Congress, (2) old telephone directories
and directory assistance, or (3) other members of Congress for whom I
had telephone numbers. (See also Lott [1987b, 177-79].)
(8) Both the VD7876 and PD7876 variables assume a linear
relationship between changes in the level of shirking and changes in the
relative difficulty of reelection. Peltzman [1976, 214, equation 1]
makes a similar assumption when he assumes that politicians weight each
additional vote equally in their objective functions.
(9) There is no significant difference in the attendance rate level
between Republicans and Democrats in either the 94th or 95th Congresses.
(10) One question arises from the observation that since
politicians occasionally announce that an upcoming election will be
their last, as well as the existence of tenure limits for certain
offices, voters will at times know when the last period will occur (see
Fremling and Lott [1988] and Lott [1988]). If voters realize that
political lame ducks will represent their interests less energetically,
why would voters ever knowingly place politicians in this last period?
One possible explanation is provided in the discussion on sorting of
politicians by their ideological beliefs found in Lott [1987b]. There I
argued that a politician can produce a signal to convince constituencies
that he is an "ideologue" by engaging in activities the
constituencies desire to have continued once the last period arrives
nsee also section II of this paper). Since ideological politicians can
produce this investment (e.g., past voting records and/or "good
deeds") at a lower cost than nonideologues since they intrinsically
value the signal, competition to produce this signal will produce too
low a return to mimicking nonideologues. The longer this signal must be
produced, the greater the difficulty in mimicking. Thus, voters may be
more willing to put up with a politician that they are certain about
with respect to how he will vote when he does vote versus a less certain
prospect who will vote more often. After all, since retiring
politicians have been in office for appreciable periods of time, the
nonideologues who would cheat in terms of how they will vote in the last
period may have already already been weeded out.
(11) The weakly significant coefficients for TENURE also provide
some evidence consistent with the barrier to entry arguments discussed
in Lott [1987a]. However, as noted in those discussions, other
interpretations are also possible.
REFERENCES
Amacher, Ryan C, and William J. Boyes. "Cycles in Senatorial Voting Behavior: Implications for the Optimal Frequency of
Elections." Public Choice, 33, 1978, 5-13.
Barone, Michael and Grant Ujifusa, The Almanac of American
Politics, Washington, D.C.: National Journal, 1976, 1978, and 1980.
Barro, Robert. "The Control of Politicians: An Economic
Model." Public Choice, 14, 1973, 19-42.
Becker, Gary and George Stigler. "Law Enforcement,
Malfeasance, and the Compensation of Enforcers." Journal of Legal
Studies, January 1974, 1-18.
Benson, Bruce and John Baden. "The Political Economy of
Government Corruption: The Logic of Underground Government."
Journal of Legal Studies, June 1985, 391-410.
Cain, Bruce, John Ferejohn, and Morris Fiorina. The Personal Vote:
Constituency Service and Electoral Independence. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press, 1987.
Crain, W. Mark and Robert Tollison. "The Executive Branch in
the Interest-Group Theory of Government." Journal of Legal
Studies, June, 1979, 555-67.
Coats, R. Morris and Thomas R. Dalton. "Entry Barriers in
Politicis and Uncontested Elections." Nicholis State University
Working Paper, 1989.
Congressional Quarterly Weekly Report, Washington, D.C.:
Congressional Quarterly, Inc., 1976, 1977, 1978, 1979.
Davis, Michael and Philip Porter. "Identifying Pure and
Apparent Ideology in Congressional Voting." Public Choice,
February 1989, 101-11.
Dougan, William and Michael Munger. "The Rationality of
Ideology." Journal of Law and Economics, april 1989, 119-42.
Eckert, Ross. "The Life Cycle of Regulatory
Commissioners." Journal of Law and Economics, April 1981, 113-20.
Fenno, richard F., Jr. Home Style: House Members in Their
Districts. Boston: Little Brown, 1978.
Fiorina, Morris P. Congress--Keystone to the Washington
Establishment. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1977.
Feregohn, John. "Incumbent Performance and Electoral
Control." Public Choice, 50, 1986, 5-25.
Fremling, Gertrud and John R. Lott, Jr. "Televising
Legislatures: Some Thoughts on Whether Politicians Are Search
Goods." Public Choice, 58, 1988, 73-78.
Jacobson, Gary and Samuel Kernell. Strategy and Choice in
Congressional elections. New Haven: Yale University Press, 1981.
Johnston, R. J. "Campaign Spending and Votes: A
Reconsideration." Public Choice, 1978, 83-92.
Kalt, Joseph and Mark Zupan. "Capture and Ideology in the
Economic Theory of Politics." American Economic Review, June 1984,
279-300.
Kau, James and Paul H. Rubin. "Self-Interest, Ideology, and
Logrolling in Congressional Voting." Journal of Law and Economics,
October 1979, 365-84.
Laband, David and Bernard F. Lentz. "Favorite Sons:
Intergenerational Wealth Transfers Among Politicians." Economic
Inquiry, July 1985, 395-414.
Landes, William M. and richard A. Posner. "The Independent
Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective." Journal of Law and
Economics, December 1975, 875-901.
Lott, John R., Jr. "Brand Names and Barriers to Entry in
Political Markets." Public Choice, 51, 1986, 87-92.
Lott, john R., Jr. "The Effect of Nontransferable Property
Rights on the Efficiency of Political Markets: Some Evidence."
Journal of Public Economics, march 1987a, 231-46.
Lott, John R., Jr. "Political Cheating." Public Choice,
52, 1987b, 169-87.
Lott, John R., Jr. "Explaining Challengers' Campaign
Expenditures: The Importance of Sunk Nontransferable Brand Name."
Public Finance Quarterly, January 1989, 108-18.
Maddalla, G. S. Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1977.
Nelson, Douglas and Eugene Silberberg. "Ideology and
Legislator Shirking." Economic Inquiry, January 1987, 15-25.
Nelson, Phillip. "Political Information." Journal of
Law and Economics, August 1976, 315-36.
Peltzman, Sam. "Constituent Interest and Congressional
Voting." Journal of Law and Economics, January 1984, 181-210.
Telser, Lester. "Comment on Political Information."
Journal of Law and Economics, August 1976, 337-40.
Van Beek, James. "Does the Decision to Retire Increase the
Amount of Political Shirking?" Texas A&M University Working
Paper, 1989.
Welch, William P. "The Economics of Campaign Funds."
Public Choice, 27, 1974, 83-97.
Wright, Matthew. "Shirking, Political Support, and Agency
Costs in Political Markets." University of California at Los
Angeles mimeo, 1988.
Anderson Graduate School of Management. University of California
at Los Angeles. I would like to thank Mark Crain, Gertrud Fremling,
Russell Roberts, an anonymous referee from this journal, and
participants at the 1987 Western Economic Association meetings for their
helpful comments and Jim Van Beek for his research assistance. This
paper originally appeared as Hoover Institution working paper
#E-86-60/10. Any remaining errors are mine.