Empirical evidence on FTC enforcement of the merger guidelines.
Coate, Malcolm B. ; Mcchesney, Fred S.
The Justice Department's 1982/1984 merger guidelines identify
various factors-- concentration, entry barriers, ease of collusion,
efficiency--that would thereafter determine whether the government will
challenge a merger. Analysts have criticized enforcement agencies,
however, for not following the guidelines, and criticize the guidelines
themselves for not identifying the weights attached to the factors.
Using a 1982-86 sample of seventy horizontal mergers, we examine which
factors influenced Federal Trade Commission decisions to challenge
mergers. The relative importance of the guidelines and other factors in
merger challenges is measured, and related empirical issues are also
explored.
I. INTRODUCTION
The 1982/1984 "merger guidelines" adopted by the
Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice (DOJ) and followed by
the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) marked important antitrust policy
changes by the Reagan administration. The Herfindahl index replaced the
fourfirm ratios used in the old (1968) guidelines as the measure of
concentration. Other non-concentration factors (barriers to entry, ease
of collusion) were elevated in importance. In the 1984 revision of the
1982 guidelines, efficiency considerations were for the first time
generally included as a relevant factor.
However, commentators who applauded the newer guidelines have
complained subsequently that the Reagan administration did not apply
them. The objections of two veteran academic antitrusters, Krattenmaker
and Pitofsky [1988, 232], are typical:
Certainly, in many respects, the announced merger guidelines are a
substantial accomplishment .... This accomplishment, however, has
been almost completely undercut by the Administration's behavior in
ignoring those guidelines in practice and instead enforcing, without any
public explanation, a merger policy that was not only exceptionally
lenient but substantially at odds with professed standards.
In an earlier paper (Coate et al. [1990]), we, along with coauthor Richard Higgins, tested one hypothesis why merger policy (at least at
the FTC in 1982-86) has departed from mere enforcement of the
guidelines: politics. We showed how external pressures imposed on the
Commission by Congress to block mergers, independent of the factors
identified in the guidelines as meriting a merger challenge, are a
statistically significant factor in the FTC's decision whether to
challenge a merger.
In the present paper, we use the same data--seventy horizontal
mergers from 1982 to 1986--to examine in greater detail the charges that
the FTC has not followed the guidelines, plus several related issues not
considered in our earlier article. These include the extent to which
various guidelines factors are either necessary or sufficient for the
Commission to vote to challenge a merger, and the role of the new
efficiency criterion in merger evaluation. An econometric model is
presented as one approach to determine how the FTC balances the various
guidelines factors. This allows an estimate of the relative importance
and influence of lawyers and economists in the evaluation process.
Finally, the data also permit an appraisal of the extent to which a
structuralist or Chicago approach to competition issues dominated merger
votes at the FTC during the relevant period.
Section II discusses briefly the factors identified in the merger
guidelines and the process by which the Commission determines whether to
oppose a proposed merger. That section also identifies several testable
hypotheses concerning the Commission's reliance on the guidelines
variables. Section III then explains the data to be used for testing.
Section IV, the bulk of the paper, presents empirical evidence
concerning the FTC's use of the guidelines and related issues.
II. EVALUATING MERGERS AT THE FEDERAL
TRADE COMMISSION
The Merger Guidelines
The Federal Trade Commission enforces (along with the Justice
Department) the federal antitrust laws, including those applicable to
mergers. The Commission takes formal action through a majority vote of
the sitting (ordinarily five) commissioners. Commissioners vote whether
to challenge a merger on the basis of formal staff memoranda that the
lawyers of the Bureau of Competition (BC) and the economists of the
Bureau of Economics (BE) prepare and submit separately. The memoranda
are based in turn on data submitted to the Commission by wouldbe merging
partners as required by the Hart-Scott-Rodino Act, and on information
developed independently by FTC staff lawyers and economists. Mergers
that raise greater anticompetitive concerns usually elicit a
supplemental FTC demand for more information, known as a
HartScott-Rodino "second request." The parties to the merger
also may present their own analyses to the staff, and thus may influence
either the Bureau of Competition or Bureau of Economics evaluation.
In analyzing a prospective merger, the FTC claims that its own
process follows the Department of Justice merger guidelines.[1] The
current guidelines were promulgated in June 1982 (and fine-tuned
somewhat in 1984), replacing the guidelines issued in 1968. They focus
on preventing a price increase from enhanced market power due to a
merger, particularly when no countervailing efficiencies are present. To
determine whether such a price increase is likely, the guidelines call
for examination of several factors: concentration (including definition
of relevant markets), entry barriers, ease of collusion, efficiency, and
failing-firm status.[2]
Concentration analysis, based on the Herfindahl-Hirschman index
(HHI), is probably the guidelines' best known aspect. The 1984
version establishes three index classifications:
1. Where the post-merger Herfindahl index is under 1000, the merger
will be challenged only "in extraordinary circumstances."
Thus, a Herfindahl index of 1000 is a safe harbor; mergers falling below
that level will rarely be challenged.
2. If the post-merger Herfindahl index is between 1000 and 1800 and
the merger increases the Herfindahl by 100 points, the government is
"likely" to challenge these transactions unless other factors
suggest "the merger is not likely substantially to lessen competition."
3. Finally, for a post-merger index value over 1800, a challenge is
"likely" if the merger increases the index by over 50 points,
unless other factors suggest "the merger is not likely
substantially to lessen competition." However, there will be a
challenge in all but "extraordinary circumstances" if the
merger raises the Herfindahl index by over 100 points to a level
substantially above 1800.
The remaining (non-concentration) factors in the guidelines
influence the decision within each Herfindahl index class. Ease of entry
will prevent current rivals from raising price for any extended period,
and so lowers the likelihood of a merger challenge. Entry is considered
easy if a new firm can break into the market within two years of a
merger, and difficult if entry would take longer. The guidelines note
that likelihood of entry is a function of sunk assets, industry growth
rate, economies of scale, and the specific capital needed to compete.
But no quantitative measures of these entry determinants are provided,
leaving one with the practical two-year standard.
The guidelines analyze ease of collusion or dominant-firm pricing
(for reasons other than entry barriers) through proxies: product
homogeneity, spatial similarities of merging firms, information
available in the market, ease of fringe expansion, market conduct, and
past performance. No weights for those proxies are given. AIthough
consideration of collusion would appear necessary in all cases to tell
an economically-plausible anticompetitive story, the guidelines state
that the collusion factors will be most important when the merger
decision is a close call. (For simplicity, we refer to these other
factors under the heading "collusion," although they may
sometimes refer to dominantfirm behavior.)
Greater efficiency (scale economies or lower transportation costs,
for example) was generally excluded from consideration in the 1968
guidelines. But the 1984 guidelines listed efficiency gains as a factor
that may save a merger that otherwise would be challenged. Efficiencies
must be shown by "clear and convincing" evidence, a higher
standard than that for anticompetitive factors (high concentration,
entry barriers and ease of collusion).3
The final guidelines factor discussed is merger with a failing
firm. If one merging firm will soon exit the market anyway, fewer
competitive concerns arise. Since the Supreme Court has accepted this
argument as a legal defense, antitrust regulators are unlikely to
challenge a merger with a failing firm.
Empirical Issues
The merger guidelines are supposed to structure merger regulation
to make enforcement decisions consistent, increasing predictability and
lowering private transaction costs. Subsequent application of the
guidelines, however, has resulted in two general types of complaint.
Failure to Follow Stated Guidelines. Many commentators complain
that antitrust enforcers do not follow their own guidelines. Some, such
as Leddy [1986] and White [1987], claim that the Justice Department and
the FTC have ignored mergers in the concentration ranges that the
guidelines label as likely to elicit challenge and have targeted only
those with greater Herfindahl index numbers.4 Similarly, Krattenmaker
and Pitofsky state [1988, 226], "What is clear, but is very
difficult to document by people who lack access to the confidential
H-S-R [Hart-ScottRodino] reports and DOJ and FTC internal memoranda, is
that the agencies have...not enforced the guidelines." As described
below, access to the documents Krattenmaker and Pitofsky refer to
permits us to evaluate their claims.
Likewise, questions have been raised about whether some finding of
important barriers to entry is required before a merger will be
challenged. Almost all economists would deem the existence of
significant entry barriers a necessary condition for mergers to reduce
welfare appreciably. But the guidelines leave it unclear whether
barriers are necessary for a merger challenge, stating that "[t]he
more difficult entry into the market is, the more likely the Department
is to challenge the merger." Indeed, because the guidelines state
that significant mergers in concentrated markets will be challenged in
all but extraordinary circumstances, enforcers presumably believe entry
to be almost impossible in those cases.
The role of the other (non-entry) collusion factors also merits
attention. The guidelines state that these factors "are most likely
to be important where the Department's decision to challenge a
merger is otherwise close." This suggests that these factors would
affect the occasional case, but would not be a systematic consideration
in decisions to challenge mergers. The role of both entry barriers and
perceived ease of collusion can both be evaluated using the internal FTC
data at our disposal.
Use of the new efficiency criterion has also drawn criticism. Some
(e.g., Lande [1988]) claim that efficiency has been elevated to a
favored position in merger analysis, dominating the more traditional
concentration and non-concentration criteria. The data permit an
evaluation of this claim as well.
The Relative Importance of Different Factors.
A second set of questions concerns the trade-offs among the
different guideline factors. The guidelines leave to the discretion of
antitrust enforcers how to weigh the different concentration and
non-concentration factors. This is another feature that has been
criticized: "Where everything is relevant, nothing is
determinative" (Krattenmaker and Pitofsky [1988, 220]). If one
factor (high concentration, for example) is a necessary but not
sufficient condition for a merger challenge, how are high Herfindahl
numbers traded off against other factors, such as entry barriers and
perceived ease of collusion?
A related issue concerns the different agency roles of lawyers and
economists. One feature frequently noted about antitrust in the Reagan
years was that "staff economists at the Commission and the DOJ have
gained considerable influence" (Salop [1987, 3]). Their antitrust
assessments are said to differ from those of lawyers, particularly
because lawyers have greater incentives to litigate in order to increase
their human capital for subsequent careers in private practice (Posner
[1969, 86]; Clarkson and Muris [1981, 300]). If so, the ultimate
trade-off made by the Commission among guideline factors would depend on
the differing evaluations by the two groups and their relative influence
in Commission votes. Both issues can be examined with the available FTC
data.
A final issue concerning FTC application of the different
guidelines factors can be addressed with the data. The intellectual
battles in antitrust for the past generation have pitted more
traditional structuralists against partisans of the Chicago school of
antitrust. In some areas of antitrust law, Chicago-school learning has
gained ascendency among academicians and even in the courts. It is not
clear, however, to what extent antitrust enforcers themselves have
adopted a Chicagostyle approach. The differences between the two models,
however, are registered largely in terms of the relative importance of
the variables (concentration, entry barriers, collusion) identified by
the guidelines, meaning that our data can be used to determine which
model better predicts Commission decisions.
III. DATA
To explore the empirical issues noted above, we used a data set of
seventy merger investigations at the FTC from June 14, 1982 (the date of
the new merger guidelines) to January 1, 1987. The sample includes every
important horizontal merger that came to the FI?C at that time, as
indicated by the fact that it merited a "second request" for
data under the HartScott-Rodino Act.s In forty-three of the cases, the
Commission allowed the merger, while in twenty-seven the Commission
voted to challenge the merger.6
For each proposed merger in the sample, we reviewed the separate
lawyers' and economists' memorandum-evaluations of the
different guidelines factors. Markets were defined and concentration
data were available in all proposed mergers, and we noted the various
estimates of the Herfindahl index and the change in the index for both
the lawyers in the Bureau of Competition and the economists in the
Bureau of Economics- Entry barrier data were available in most of the
memos, with sixty-five observations for the Bureau of Economics and
sixty-six for the Bureau of Competition. We follow the general
interpretation of the guidelines, treating evidence that entry would
require at least two years as indicating that important barriers exist,
and evidence that entry could occur within two years as evidence that
entry was easy. Evidence on the perceived ease of collusion was sparser.
We found analysis of an anticompetitive effect in thirty-seven of the
Bureau of Economics memos and in a somewhat different group of
thirty-seven Bureau of Competition memos; information was obtained from
at least one bureau in forty-six cases. We required the memo explicitly
to explain how the collusion-based factors did or did not produce an
anticompetitive effect before counting the analysis as information sent
to the Commission. Efficiency and failing-firm factors were even more
rarely considered or discussed. The Bureau of Economics addressed
efficiencies in twenty-eight memos and the Bureau of Competition in
twenty-three. Finally, the Bureau of Competition raised the failing firm
defense in four of the reports.
Before these data are used to answer the questions about FTC merger
enforcement presented above, one issue must be addressed. Guidelines
factors could conceivably not be evaluated on their merits, but might
instead be manipulated to push a result that the FTC staff has decided
(for whatever reason) it wishes the Commission to take. If so, the
guidelines themselves would afford no predictability in evaluating
mergers. It is important to determine, therefore, whether the individual
guidelines factors are analyzed on their own merits.
One way to check is to look at the correlations between each pair
of guidelines factors. If the factors are not independently evaluated,
there should be high correlation among them.? We calculated the simple
correlations among the concentration, entry barriers and ease of
collusion variables, and found no significant correlation between any
pair of variables, as they were evaluated by either lawyers or
economists. Apparently, then, variables are evaluated independently and
pressure to make or close a case does not generally lead to
"cooking" the data.8
IV. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Role of Individual Guidelines Factors
Concentration. The internal FTC evidence allows one to determine if
the Commission is actually following the guidelines with respect to
concentration. Table I presents a classification for the Bureau of
Competition estimates of the Herfindahl indices and changes in index
values for the seventy cases. (The Bureau of Economics data is
distributed similarly.) As the table shows, in twenty-two of the
twenty-seven cases filed the Herfindahl index was over 1800; twelve had
index numbers over 3000. There were no complaints when the Herfindahl
index increased less than 100 points, and only five when it increased
less than 200. In eleven complaints, the increase exceeded 500 points.
There is, however, a surprisingly similar pattern for the forty-three
closed cases. Twenty-nine cases were not brought even when the
Herfindahl index exceeded 1800; in eleven of those cases, the index
increased by more than 500 points.
Thus, the FTC's practice from 1982-86 does not corroborate the
guidelines' claim that a challenge will be made in all but the most
"extraordinary circumstances" when the post-merger Herfindahl
index is over 1800 and the change is greater than 100. There were eight
cases in which the merger was abandoned when the second request was
issued (and thus could not be included in the sample here). Even if all
eight involved high concentration and would have resulted in merger
challenges, this would mean thirty merger challenges and twenty-seven
closed cases in highly concentrated industries with changes of over 100
points. It is hard to believe that truly "extraordinary
circumstances" could exist in almost half the cases? Thus, it would
appear that the guidelines have been implicitly revised, with the term
"challenge" replaced by "investigate."
By comparison, the data indicate that the Commission has not
implicitly raised the lower bound for an investigation from the
Herfindahl index level of 1000 stated in the guidelines. Five complaints
were filed when the Herfindahl index did not exceed 1800. Fourteen cases
with index numbers below 1800 were investigated, although closed upon
further analysis. Of these, five involved Herfindahls under 1400; five
had changes in the index of less than 200 points.
By itself, the table suggests that levels and changes in the
Herfindahl numbers may not matter in the FTC vote. Cases were brought in
all the Herfindahl classifications, from between 1000 and 1400 to over
3000. Moreover, cases were closed in all these classifications. The
relatively small number of cases in most of the cells of Table I makes
statistical testing difficult. However, index data can be aggregated
into three cells (under 1800, 1800-3000, over 3000) and separated into
complaints and closings. In a test of the hypothesis that the decision
on a merger is independent of the Herfindahl level, the chisquare
statistic is 2.14 well below the critical level necessary to reject the
hypothesis of independence. The same test for Herfindahl change yields
the same inference, with a chi-square of 1.97. These results should be
interpreted with care, given the aggregation necessary to run the test.
The data are also useful for evaluating the guidelines'
assertion that the government is "more likely than not" to
challenge a merger when the Herfindahl index is under 1800 but
"other factors" support issuance of a complaint. If the other
factors are taken to mean both entry barriers and ease of collusion,
there were six cases (using the Bureau of Competition's
evaluations) in which a challenge should have been "more likely
than not." In fact, the Commission challenged four of those
mergers.
Barriers to Entry. The evidence suggests that entry barriers are
virtually a necessary condition for a merger challenge. In the
Commission's twenty-seven complaints, the Bureau of Competition
claimed barriers would block entry for at least two years in twenty-six
cases and the Bureau of Economics agreed in twentytwo of them. The
evidence also suggests, however, that entry barriers were not a
sufficient condition. There were sixteen cases in which the Bureau of
Competition found both low Herfindahl index numbers and difficult entry.
The Commission issued complaints in only five of these cases. Moreover,
in the forty-three cases where the FTC voted not to challenge, the
Bureau of Competition noted high barriers for thirty-one mergers; the
Bureau of Economics claimed barriers were high for twenty. Evidently,
the FTC has required evidence beyond entry barriers to vote a complaint.
Nor does the Herfindahl statistic interact predictably with entry
barriers to generate a complaint. The Bureau of Competition reported
entry barriers for twenty of the twenty-eight (71 percent) closed cases
with Herfindahls over 1800 and changes of over 50, and for eleven of the
fifteen (73 percent) closed cases where the Herfindahl index was
below 1800 (or change was less than 50). Figures for Bureau of Economics
findings of high barriers were also similar: eleven of twenty-one (52
percent) for high-Herfindahl closed cases and nine of twenty-two (41
percent) for low-Herfindahl mergers.
Ease of Collusion. The guidelines indicate that ease of collusion
will be particularly important in marginal cases. In marginal cases,
difficulty of collusion should result in case closings, and ease of
collusion should cause complaints to be filed. To evaluate this
assertion, one must define marginal cases. For example, a marginal case
could be a merger with an Herfindahl index under 1800 or a change in the
index of under 200.
The evidence indicates that collusion has not played the role
indicated in the guidelines. For marginal cases resulting in complaints,
the Bureau of Competition presented evidence of feasible collusion in
five of eight mergers. The Bureau of Economics staff found collusion
plausible in just two of ten marginal cases ending as complaints; the
Bureau of Economics even thought collusion difficult in three of the
ten. In the marginal cases ultimately closed, the Bureau of Competition
found collusion difficult in only four of nineteen cases, but collusion
easy in five. The Bureau of Economics found collusion difficult in ten
of twenty-one marginal cases that closed, and collusion allegedly easy
in only two.
The evidence thus contradicts the claim that perceived ease of
collusion is a tiebreaker in marginal cases. For the Bureau of
Competition, collusion seems to explain some complaints, but it cannot
explain the numerous closings of marginal cases. Conversely, the Bureau
of Economics collusion evaluations help explain closings but not
complaints. Overall, no predictive pattern emerges from the data on
collusion.
Efficiency. The internal FTC data also permit evaluation of the
claim that the new efficiency criterion has come to dominate other
considerations in merger policy. If efficiency considerations have
really affected merger policy, one would expect to see otherwise
anticompetitive transactions excused because of expected resource
savings. In particular, one would expect in numerous closed cases to
find efficiency explanations and evidence suggesting complaints would be
favored but for the efficiency argument.
The Bureau of Economics and Bureau of Competition claims of
efficiencies can be contrasted with the Commission's final decision
on the merger. Perhaps surprisingly, efficiency claims were made more
frequently in challenged cases, with the Bureau of Economics claiming
efficiencies existed in 33 percent of the complaints filed and the
Bureau of Competition in 26 percent. But the Bureau of Economics found
efficiencies in only 21 percent and the Bureau of Competition in 7
percent of the closed cases. Obviously, this evidence suggests that the
legal and economic staff's efficiency defenses are not generally
successful.[10]
One can further explore the efficiency issue by comparing the
number of factors (Herfindahl index, barriers or collusion) either
favoring or disfavoring complaints in the closed cases where
efficiencies were found to those where no efficiencies were claimed. For
the Bureau of Economics, in the nine closed cases where efficiencies
were claimed, the staff found an average of 1.44 factors indicating the
merger would otherwise not have an anticompetitive effect. This is not
signficantly different (t- .25) from the average number of 1.38 factors
deemed not anticompetitive by the Bureau of Economics in the other
closed cases. Thus, a Bureau of Economics efficiency claim apparently
did not substitute for other guidelines factors that the Bureau of
Economics said supported letting a merger proceed, when the Commission
decided to close the case. For the Bureau of Competition, the inference
is the same. In the three closed cases for which the lawyers claimed
efficiencies existed, they found an average of 1.33 other factors
suggesting a problem could exist, as compared to the average of 1.68
factors thought to be at anticompetitive levels for the other cases.
This difference is also insignificant (t- .76). Again, at the margin the
efficiency factor seems unimportant in explaining FTC merger challenges.
Multivariate Analysis
Analyzing the role of a single guidelines factor without
controlling for other factors is potentially misleading. Multivariate
techniques may be more appropriate. Multivariate analysis is also useful
for investigating two issues in merger enforcement of interest to many:
the relative importance of the different guidelines factors, and the
differences between lawyers and economists in influencing Commission
votes.
Weights of Different Guidelines Factors. Using the internal FTC
data, we defined a probit model for the Commission's decisions on
merger challenges (Coate et al. [1990]). The dependent variable (VOTE)
equalled one if the Commission approved a complaint (including cases in
which the parties negotiated a settlement) and zero if the investigation
was closed with no action. We explained the merger vote as a function of
both the Bureau of Competition and Bureau of Economics analysis of the
Herfindahl, barriers to entry, and ease of collusion. To avoid extreme
multicollinearity problems, we transformed the Bureau of Competition and
Bureau of Economics concentration estimates into two dummy variables.11
For the Bureau of Competition, the concentration variable (BCHERFHI)
takes on the value of 1 if the Herfindahl is over 1800 and the change is
more than 50, and a value of 0 otherwise. The Bureau of Economics dummy
variable (BEHERFLO) was defined as a mirror image of the Bureau of
Competition variable, with a value of 1 if the Herfindahl was below 1800
or the change was less than 50 and 0 in all other cases.12
For the first non-concentration factor, entry barriers, we
constructed two dummy variables, the first (BCBARHI) with the value 1 if
the Bureau of Competition evaluated barriers to entry as high, and the
other (BEBARLO) equalling 1 if the Bureau of Economics thought serious
barriers did not exist. For the next nonconcentration factor, ease of
collusion, again we constructed two variables, one (BCCOLHI) with the
value 1 when the Bureau of Competition found collusion likely and the
other (BECOLLO) with the value 1 when Bureau of Economics found
collusion was unlikely. Finally, the legal failing-firm defense was
included by a variable (FAILFIRM) equal to 1 in those four cases in
which the Bureau of Competition claimed the defense applied.
Two political pressure variables are also included. The first
(CITES) is the number of Wall Street Journal articles about the merger
prior to the FTC's decision and is designed to measure the pressure
to block high-profile transactions. The second (HEARINGS) is a
twelve-month moving average of the number of times Congress summoned FTC
commissioners or politically-appointed staff to hearings to defend their
antitrust records.
The probit parameter estimates are shown as regression 1
("base model") in Table II. As expected, Bureau of Competition
analysis that concentration, entry barriers and collusion possibilities
are at worrisome levels significantly enhances the probability of a
complaint; Bureau of Economics evaluation that none of the guidelines
factors are worrisome significantly lowers the likelihood of a
challenge. The political, the Bureau of Competition and the Bureau of
Economics variables all pass independent chi-square tests, indicating
that each type of variable affects the Commission's decision
making.
As a test of the role of efficiencies, a variable not included in
the first model we now insert a dummy variable (EFFCY) equal to 1 for
any case in which either the Bureau of Competition or Bureau of
Economics claimed that efficiencies were present. As shown in regression
2 ("efficiency model") of Table II, efficiencies themselves
are an insignificant factor in FTC votes, and their inclusion in the
model has only trivial effects on the size and significance of the other
variables. With other guidelines factors controlled for, staff
efficiency claims have no apparent influence on a Commission merger
decision.
The model is robust with respect to other specifications. One
important issue concerns the missing values for the independent
variables. As noted above, for example, out of the seventy total cases,
the Bureau of Competition discussed collusion in only thirty-seven and
the Bureau of Economics in a somewhat different set of thirty-seven
mergers. Regressions 1 and 2 are based on a default coding of zero for
the Bureau of Competition and Bureau of Economics independent variables
when the bureau failed to mention a particular factor. But the results
are not sensitive to this coding option, as regression 3 ("recoded
model") in Table II indicates. Reversing the coding of the Bureau
of Economics variables to match the Bureau of Competition variables, so
the missing values would be treated identically, results in only minor
differences from the prior estimates. Finally, if the concentration
dummies for the Bureau of Competition and Bureau of Economics are
multiplied by the Herfindahl index estimated by each bureau so as to
create a truncated continuous variable, the estimated coefficients are
insignificant, as shown in regression 4 of Table II. This may suggest
that the FTC responds less to continuous Herfindahl changes than to
discrete changes in classification (e.g., a post-merger HHI above
1800).13
Using the first probit equation (regression 1) and holding the
political variables constant at their means, one can investigate the
relative importance of the merger guidelines factors in a Commission
decision to challenge a merger. If lawyers and economists agree that the
Herfindahl index, entry barriers and ease of collusion are all at levels
deemed worrisome under the guidelines, the probability of a merger
challenge is 97 percent. Suppose, next, that both the Bureau of
Competition and Bureau of Economics agree that one of the factors is not
a concern. If both bureaus find that the Herfindahl level is low, the
probability of an FTC challenge falls from 97 to 43 percent, a
statistically significant decline. Since every merger in the 1982-86 FTC
sample had an Herfindahl index above 1000 and all but three increased
the index by at least 100 points, it is interesting that the Commission
would challenge only 43 percent of those mergers, even when both entry
barriers and an ability to collude allegedly were present.
The Herfindahl index was apparently of less importance to the
Commission during this time than other guideline measures. Although
there is still a 43-percent chance the Commission will challenge a
merger when lawyers and economists agree that the Herfindahl is low (and
the two other factors are high), bureaucratic agreement that either of
the other guideline factors is low reduces the probability of a merger
challenge even more. When both bureaus agree that the Herfindahl is high
and collusion likely, but also that entry barriers are low, there is
only a 21 percent probability of a merger challenge. Likewise, when
concentration and barriers are judged high, but collusion is thought
unlikely, the probability of a complaint is only 27 percent. Ceteris
paribus, satisfying the FTC staff that the Herfindahl is under 1800
(or its change is less than 50) appears less likely to shield a merger
from challenge than a bureaucratic finding that entry barriers or the
likelihood of collusion are low. (Of course, the best way to prevent a
merger challenge under the guidelines is to show that the Herfindahl
index is below 1000.)
These results are consistent with the conclusion above that,
despite the guidelines, the Commission was not "likely to
challenge" but rather "likely to investigate" mergers
pushing the Herfindahl index over 1800. Even if the Herfindahl is
assumed to be high, the decision whether the merger will be challenged
depends heavily on the evaluation of the other guidelines factors.
Indeed, the regression model shows, if concentration alone were judged
high but barriers judged low and collusion difficult, a complaint would
have no measurable chance of success.
Bureau of Competition and Bureau of Economics Agreement on
Guidelines Factors. Table III notes the positions taken by both the
Bureau of Economics and Bureau of Competition with respect to the
Herfindahl index, barriers, ease of collusion and efficiencies. There
was considerable agreement among lawyers and economists concerning the
facts presented to the Commission, ranging from 83 percent on the
Herfindahl index to 61 percent on the ease of collusion. Disagreements
occurred almost exclusively when the Bureau of Competition thought a
variable indicated anticompetitive problems, but the Bureau of Economics
did not.
However, the data mask some disagreements, such as differences in
market definition or market share. Only 59 percent of the Herfindahl
statistics were absolutely identical. Moreover, missing values indicated
large potential for further disagreement between the Bureau of Economics
and Bureau of Competition. Counting as disagreements any situation where
one bureau ventured an opinion and the other did not lowers the
agreement rate to 73 percent for barriers, 37 percent for ease of
collusion, and 52 percent for efficiencies.
The table indicates that when presented with the same facts,
attorneys are more likely than economists to claim that a merger raises
issues of antitrust concern. This finding is consistent with the
hypothesis that different career incentives induce lawyers to support
cases more often than economists. This hypothesis can be tested
directly. The internal files reveal that the Bureau of Competition staff
supported a complaint in 54.3 percent of the sample cases, while the
Bureau of Economics staff supported a complaint in only 30.0 percent.
This difference is statistically significant at the 1-percent level.
The effects of bureaucratic disagreement tend to indicate that
lawyers have greater influence over the ultimate Commission vote. Table
IV (estimated from regression model 1 of Table II with political
variables held constant at their means) presents the effects of bureau
disagreements over the Herfindahl index, entry barriers and ease of
collusion under alternative assumptions concerning evaluation of each of
these factors. Suppose hypothetically that both groups at first agree
that one variable--the Herfindahl, barriers to entry, or likelihood of
collusion--is low while the other two are high. Then let the lawyers
change their opinion and also evaluate the first variable as high. As
shown in line 1 of Table IV, the probability of a challenge rises by 40
to 64 percent, depending on the variable. Suppose alternatively that
both the Bureau of Competition and Bureau of Economics initially find
that all merger guidelines factors are high, but that the economists
then re-evaluate one of these factors as low. Line 2 of Table IV
indicates that the probability of a challenge falls by 12 to 14
percent.[14]
In short, under our econometric model of Commission decision making
the lawyers' evaluation of the merger guidelines variables
apparently have had a greater impact than those made by economists.
Moreover, all the predicted probability changes for lawyers are
statistically significant at the .05 and .10 levels. The estimated
effects for economists are not significant.[15]
Structuralist vs. Chicago Approaches at the FTC
The probability models above use econometric techniques to
determine the simultaneous impact of particular variables on FTC merger
decisions. That approach is usually the only one available, because
economic theory itself does not specify a priori the exact relationship
between the dependent and explanatory variables. In this case, theory
suggests two deterministic models that can be constructed with data on
Herfindahls, entry barriers and ease of collusion to model FTC merger
decisions.
Economists differ on those conditions necessary for a merger to be
anticompetitive, although entry barriers would probably be given by all
as a necessary condition. If barriers are present, evaluation of a
merger hinges on how easily one believes firms could coordinate their
actions. So-called "Chicago school" economists typically
maintain that something other than mere concentration is necessary for
successful, long-term collusion. "Structuralists," on the
other hand, tend to hold that once entry barriers have been shown, high
concentration can substitute for evidence of the ease of collusion as a
sufficient predictor of anticompetitive effect.
The debate is a long-running one. It is interesting, therefore, to
use the FTC data on merger challenges to see whether the Chicago-school
or structuralist model better predicts FTC merger challenges. We used
two definitions that fit the competing theories. A Chicago-school
approach would require evidence of all three of the principal
guidelines factors: high Herfindahl index, entry barriers and ease of
collusion. If any of these factors was missing, a Chicagoan would likely
infer that the merger could not be anticompetitive. But a structuralist
approach would deem a merger anticompetitive if, in addition to entry
barriers, either the Herfindahl index was high or collusion was
perceived to be easy. Neither of these approaches is the same as the
probit model set out in the regressions above. In that third model, the
bureaucracy's evaluation of mergers under its own guidelines is
treated as making no one factor either necessary or sufficient; external
pressure variables are included as significant predictors as well.[16]
The issue thus is which model better predicts Commission decisions,
the Chicago or structuralist model. We used each model to predict the
anticompetitive effect of a merger for both the Bureau of Competition
and Bureau of Economics data.[17] Under the Chicago model, a challenge
would be predicted whenever (under the Bureau of Competition and Bureau
of Economics data, alternatively) all three factors were deemed
worrisome: concentration, entry barriers and ease of collusion. Under
the structuralist model, a challenge is predicted when barriers and
either high concentration or ease of collusion is posited.
It is useful to separate the sample into three periods. The first,
from the announcement of the 1982 merger guidelines to the 1984
revision, contains sixteen cases. The second period (with twenty-seven
cases) runs from the revision to the resignation of FTC Chairman James
C. Miller III. A question naturally of interest to economists is whether
the FTC evaluated mergers differently during the tenure of Miller, the
only professional economist ever to chair the Commission. The third
period (also twenty-seven cases) runs from Miller's resignation to
the end of the sample.
Table V compares, for all three subperiods, the predictive success
of each model. The structuralist model with the Bureau of Competition
data predicts Commission merger decisions 67 percent of the time, while
the Chicago model is correct 74 percent of the time. Similar results are
found by using the Bureau of Economics data with either model. Thus, the
deterministic models of Commission decision making do not show that
lawyers have more influence than economists on enforcement decisions.
Among the three subperiods,[18] one finds that the Chicago model
seemingly outperformed the structuralist model while the 1982 guidelines
were in effect, but again there was no significant difference. When the
1982 guidelines were revised, the Chicago model's predictive
success fell for both the Bureau of Competition and Bureau of Economics
data, with the Bureau of Economics decline being statistically
significantly (t= 1.90). However, the opposite result occurred following
Chairman Miller's departure, with the increase in the Bureau of
Economics's predictive ability again significant (t=3.53).[19]
The predictions of the Chicago and structuralist models can be
compared to the results obtained from the bureaucraticpolitical probit
model (regression 1 of Table II). Assuming a fitted probability from the
regression of over (under) 50 percent predicts a complaint (closing),
the probit model correctly forecasted the Commission's decision
with 84 percent accuracy. Figures for the three subperiods are 88, 81
and 85 percent, respectively. The probit model generally outperforms the
Chicago and structuralist models, not a surprising result since the
probit model incorporates significant political variables.
V. CONCLUSION
As the merger wave of the 1980s rolled on, commentators alleged
that antitrust agencies had tacitly revised the merger guidelines,
challenging only extreme increases in concentration. Also, efficiencies
supposedly had been elevated above the other guidelines factors.
Moreover, there were rumors that economists were actually taking part in
antitrust enforcement decisions.
It is useful to look back and separate fact from fiction. Our data
on Federal Trade Commission merger challenges from the mid-1980s provide
evidence that for the most part the merger guidelines have not been
applied as written. The use of concentration measures is perhaps the
best example. However, the data do not reveal an increase in the
critical Herfindahl levels. Instead, the evidence suggests simply that
concentration has not been used to establish a presumption of guilt.
Rather, it has served to determine which cases should be investigated.
The cases appear to be examined on their merits and some proof of
anticompetitive effect-beyond mere concentration numbers-often required
before a complaint is issued. In that respect, the FTC's approach
thus has been consistent with economic theory: concentration has been a
necessary but not sufficient condition for a merger challenge.
As for non-concentration factors, there is considerable evidence
that a finding of barriers to entry was a necessary but not sufficient
condition for a merger challenge. On the other hand, there is no
evidence (despite critics' claims to the contrary) that explicit
inclusion of efficiencies in the guidelines has made any difference.
Closed cases where efficiencies were allegedly present in 1982-86
presented competitive concerns similar to those in which no efficiency
claims were made.
Moreover, both economist and attorney evaluations of guidelines
factors appear to have an impact. At the margin, attorneys seem to have
more influence at the Commission if one accepts the econometric model.
Finally, both the structuralist and Chicago models predict the
Commission's decisions reasonably well over the sample period. But
both are inferior to the probability model, shown to be rather robust
here, that includes political variables as predictors of FTC merger
decisions.
REFERENCES
Clarkson, Kenneth W., and Timothy J. Muris. 'Commission
Performance, Incentives, and Behavior," in The Federal Trade
Commission Since 1970: Economic Regulation and Bureaucratic Behavior,
edited by Kenneth W. Clarkson and Timothy J. Muris. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1981, 280-306.
Coate, Malcolm B., Richard S. Higgins, and Fred S. McChesney.
"Bureaucracy and Politics in FTC Merger Enforcement. Journal of Law
and Economics, October 1990, 463-82.
Cooter, Robert D., and Daniel L. Rubinfeld. "Economic Analysis
of Legal Disputes and Their Resolution." Journal of Economic
Literature, September 1989, 1067-97.
Demsetz, Harold. "Barriers to Entry." American Economic
Review, March 1982, 47-57. Krattenmaker, Thomas G. and Robert Pitofsky.
'Antitrust Merger Policy and the Reagan Administration."
Antitrust Bulletin, Summer 1988, 211-32. Lande, Robert H. "The Rise
and (Coming) Fall of Efficiency as the Ruler of Antitrust."
Antitrust Bulletin, Fall 1988, 429-65.
Leddy, Mark. "Recent Merger Cases Reflect Revolution in
Antitrust Policy." Legal Times, 3 November, 1986, p. 2.
McChesney, Fred S. "Be True to Your School: Conflicting
Chicago Approaches to Antitrust and Regulation," Cato Journal,
Winter 1991, 775-98.
Posner, Richard A. |The Federal Trade Commission." University
of Chicago Law Review 37(1), 1969, 4789.
Priest, George L., and Benjamin Klein. "The Selection of
Disputes for Litigation." Journal of Legal Studies, January 1984,
1-55.
Rogowsky, Robert A. "The Justice Department's Merger
Guidelines: A Study in the Application of the Rule." Research in
Law and Economics, 6, 1984, 135-66.
Salop, Steven C. "Symposium on Mergers and Antitrust."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 1987, 3-12.
U.S. Department of Justice. "Merger Guidelines" (1968,
1982 and 1984 versions), in Horizontal
Mergers: Law and Policy, Section of Antitrust Law, American Bar
Association, 1986, 264-336. White, Lawrence J. "Antitrust and
Merger Policy: A
Review and Critique." Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall
1987, 13-22.