Teaching tools: should we teach microeconomic principles before macroeconomic principles.
Lopus, Jane S. ; Maxwell, Nan L.
Economics departments offering courses in both microeconomic and
macroeconomic principles must make decisions relating to the sequencing
of these courses. Although many economists have strong opinions on this
subject, no broad consensus exists on the efficacy of teaching one
course before the other. While many departments stipulate that one
course must (or should) serve as a prerequisite for the other, other
departments do not specify an ordering. As well, little research exists
on whether student learning is influenced by the order in which micro
and macro principles are presented.
In this paper we report the current sequencing requirements of 25
top-ranked research universities, 25 top-ranked liberal arts colleges,
and 20 comprehensive universities. We also report the current sequencing
patterns in 20 principles textbooks. We then empirically address the
issue of whether student learning is affected by the ordering of the
two-course principles of economics sequence using a new nationwide
economic education data base. Specifically, we ask whether students
learn more in macroeconomic principles courses if they have already
taken a course in micro principles and/or whether they learn more in
microeconomic principles courses if they have already taken a course in
macro principles.
We find that although most of the colleges and universities in our
study require microeconomics before macroeconomics when specifying an
ordering, most textbooks present macroeconomic topics before
microeconomic topics. Our regression results indicate that students
score significantly higher on a post test in principles of
microeconomics if they have a prior course in principles of
macroeconomics. In contrast, students who have a prior course in
principles of microeconomics do not score significantly higher on a post
test in their macroeconomic principles class.
I. BACKGROUND
Since student learning of economics is clearly a goal of the
principles course, one relevant dimension to the sequencing question is
the "intellectual" basis for sequencing decisions provided by
learning theory. Saunders [1990, 67-72] has identified four generally
accepted propositions of the basic learning process that have
implications for learning college economics: (1) students have a limited
capacity to process information; (2) prior experiences are important;
(3) motivation is important; and (4) visual information dominates verbal
information.
While propositions 2, 3, and 4 have implications for the micro/macro
sequencing decision,(1) the implications are conflicting. That is, these
propositions could be interpreted to justify requiring no specific
ordering of economic principles, or teaching either macro first or micro
first. For example, if micro and macro principles overlap, the
"importance of prior experience" suggests that sequencing is
irrelevant because students who already know some micro will perform
better in macro, and vice versa. However, if macroeconomics creates
greater motivation than microeconomics by focusing on current events,
proposition 3 implies that macroeconomics should be placed first.
Alternatively, if microeconomics includes more visual aids or
"pictorial representations" than macroeconomics, student
learning may be enhanced by teaching microeconomics first. Thus,
learning theory does not appear to provide concrete conclusions about
the optimal sequencing of microeconomic and macroeconomic principles,
unless unambiguous assumptions can be made about propositions 2, 3, and
4. This comports with Saunders's assessment [1990, 62] that there
is no "single, generally accepted theory of learning that can be
used as an infallible guide to teaching."
The ambiguity in learning theory is probably not a major issue in the
sequencing decision since it is probably safe to assume that few
economists examine learning theory prior to structuring their classes.
Economists may, however, examine the theoretical underpinnings of
microeconomics and macroeconomics that have implications for sequencing.
Once again, we find that arguments can be made on both sides of the
sequencing issue.
Academics who favor teaching micro before macro point to theoretical
and conceptual foundations of microeconomics in macroeconomics. For
example, understanding price theory and supply and demand models from
microeconomics may facilitate learning aggregate macroeconomic models of
price levels and output. In keeping with this point of view, Michael
Boskin [1988, 157] comments that "(h)ow anyone can be serious about
teaching macro to students who have not had micro, and simultaneously
avoid repeating much of what is taught in the micro half of the course,
is becoming increasingly incomprehensible."(2) This line of
reasoning implies that prior knowledge of microeconomics is essential to
learning macroeconomics.
The grounding of macroeconomics in microeconomic theory is also
addressed by Weintraub [1979] in his book Microfoundations: The
Compatibility of Microeconomics and Macroeconomics. Although the book
focuses on the consistency of the two disciplines rather than
sequencing, by showing that macroeconomics has microeconomic foundations
Weintraub perhaps implies that micro should precede macro, or that the
two subjects should be melded together. He concludes that "(t)here
is not now any model which successfully integrates micro and macro
theory" [159-160] and that relevant microfoundations of macro
"would look different to different kinds of economists" [157].
Alternatively, it is argued that microeconomics has macrofoundations,
rather than the other way around. A recent paper by David Colander
contends that from a New Keynesian perspective, "...talking about a
micro foundation of macro, independent of institutional context, is
meaningless... (B)efore there is any hope of undertaking meaningful
micro analysis, one must first determine the macro context within which
that micro decision is made... Thus establishing appropriate
macrofoundations of micro must logically be done before one establishes
any microfoundations of macro and any micro analysis independent of a
macrofoundation is irrelevant game-playing" [1993, 451;
Colander's italics]. This line of reasoning provides a theoretical
argument for teaching macro before micro. An understanding of
macroeconomic institutions and models would motivate students to learn
microeconomics by providing a relevant framework for understanding
microeconomic models based on individual choice. Since students are
constantly bombarded with macroeconomic issues in the news, they may be
aware of its pertinence to their lives. By emphasizing institutions and
understanding the "big picture," macroeconomics could give
students a working economics vocabulary and insights that would lead to
a better understanding of microeconomics.
If macroeconomics is more relevant to students than microeconomics,
teaching macro first may increase enrollment in economics classes as
well as facilitate learning. To quote Blinder,
(s)uppose teaching micro first is sounder but macroeconomics brings
in the crowds. Then putting micro first would mean that fewer students
would be getting a slightly better education. Teachers of economics
believe that some exposure to economics is good for students. So which
is better: giving more students less, or giving fewer students more? The
answer is not obvious, but it is obvious that we need quantitative
information even to begin to make an intelligent decision [1991, 253].
We begin our quantitative assessment by examining how economics
departments actually sequence their principles courses. Using the
Carnegie Foundation categories to classify schools,(3) we investigated
the sequencing requirements in twenty-five highly ranked
"research" economics departments following Golden et al.
[1987], twenty-five highly ranked "liberal arts" colleges
following Morse [1990], and the twenty "comprehensive" schools
in the California State University (CSU). There are essentially four
options in sequencing principles. Departments could offer two courses
and not specify an ordering, offer two courses and require micro first
or macro first, or offer a one-course principles class. Our
determination of which course sequencing scheme existed was made by
examining current university catalogs when available, or by calling the
economics departments.
As Table IA shows, 40 percent of the research departments do not
specify an ordering for micro/macro principles while another 40 percent
require micro first. A slightly different story unfolds when examining
liberal arts schools (Table IB). Although "no ordering" and
"micro first" still dominate, 44 percent of the schools do not
specify an ordering while only 24 percent require microeconomics
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] first. Also, more liberal arts
colleges than research departments require macroeconomics first (12
percent as opposed to 4 percent). Most comprehensive universities in the
CSU (Table IC) do not require a specific course sequencing (55 percent),
although when an ordering is specified twice as many require micro
before macro (30 versus 15 percent), the same ratio as liberal arts
colleges.
Because Stiglitz points out [1988, 177] that there may be a
simultaneous determination of course content and text content, we also
examined the sequencing of subject matter in twenty principles of
economics textbooks.(4) In contrast to the ordering by academic
departments but consistent with Stiglitz [1988, 171], Table II shows
that most textbooks (65 percent) place macroeconomic topics before
microeconomic topics. This was the content order chosen by Samuelson in
the first edition of his best-selling text, which served as a model for
subsequent textbooks. It may appear puzzling that the content ordering
in textbooks (Table II) does not reflect the content ordering in
practice (Table I).(5) Walstad and Watts [1990, 146-7] suggest that
textbook publishers may lag behind departments in the sequencing debate.
They report that "the micro first proponents have been gaining
ground in recent years" but most textbooks "have yet to change
to a micro-than-macro format..."
The inconsistencies and ambiguities in both theory and practice point
to a need for empirical analysis on the effects of sequencing. Somewhat
surprisingly, only two recent quantitative studies have examined this
issue and, unfortunately, were both done at single universities. One
study was conducted by Brasfield et al. [1993] from fall 1987 to spring
1990 with 1119 students at Murray State University. Using grades as the
learning measure, sequencing was found to be insignificant in increasing
learning. Specifically, students who took micro before macro or macro
before micro performed better than students who had no prior college
economics courses. However, in another study conducted at the University
of Wisconsin, Eau Claire, using a version of the Revised Test of
Economic Understanding (RTUCE)(6) as the measure of learning, Fizel and
Johnson [1986] found that students who took micro before macro out
performed those who took macro before micro. Results of this study,
which involved a total of 328 freshmen randomly assigned to take either
micro first or macro first, appear robust with respect to model
specification and measurements of learning.
As indicated in Becker et al. [1991], these one-university studies
must be replicated before economics departments use the findings to
determine their course sequencing. Fizel and Johnson note [1986, 94-97]
that there is a specific need to study the effects of micro/macro
sequencing using a multi-university sample. Siegfried and Fels [1979,
955] emphasize that one-university studies may lack the variability
necessary to sort out complicated economic education relationships. Our
study circumvents this problem by using a broad-based national data set.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED]
II. DATA AND ESTIMATION MODEL
To empirically assess the effect of sequencing on student learning we
use a database developed by Saunders [1994] from the national norming
sample of the Third Edition of the Test of Understanding in College
Economics (TUCE III). TUCE III is a standardized multiple choice test
consisting of a 30-question microeconomics test and a 30-question
macroeconomics test (with three optional international questions)
designed to test learning in college principles classes. Both sets of
questions may be administered as pretests to assess initial knowledge
and as post tests to examine achievement during the class. Saunders
[1991] provides a thorough discussion of TUCE III.
The TUCE III data were collected from 53 colleges and universities
during the 1989-90 academic year with a total of 2,888 students taking
both a pretest and post test in macroeconomics, and 3,052 students
taking both a pretest and post test in microeconomics.(7) In addition to
test scores, the data include over 200 variables with background
information on students and their professors.
To assess the effect of different combinations of sequencing on
learning, we adopt a standard ordinary least squares (OLS) regression
model of economic achievement. For both macroeconomics and
microeconomics, we use the macro or micro 30-question TUCE III as a
pretest to estimate the effect of the alternative principles course on
students' knowledge when they enter their current principles class.
We then use the same TUCE III as a post test (controlling for the
pretest score) to estimate the effect of the alternative principles
course on the learning that takes place in the current principles
class.(8)
In the questionnaire accompanying TUCE III, students were asked
whether they had taken courses in economics prior to the current course.
Students who indicated that they had taken prior courses were asked to
identify the course content of the prior course.(9) If having a prior
course in macroeconomics increases initial knowledge and/or learning in
micro, or if having a prior course in microeconomics increases initial
knowledge and/or learning in macro, we would conclude that sequencing
makes a difference. If, however, having a prior principles course
increases initial knowledge and learning in the current course
regardless of whether it is micro or macro, we would conclude that
sequencing is irrelevant.
Thus, we estimate the following ordinary least squares (OLS)
regression models:
(1) MICRO PRETEST = [f.sub.1](MACRO, PREPARATION and ABILITY,
UNIVERSITY, GENDER and ETHNICITY)
(2) MICRO POST TEST = [f.sub.2](MACRO, PREPARATION and ABILITY,
ENVIRONMENT and UNIVERSITY, TIME USE, GENDER and ETHNICITY, INTEREST)
(3) MACRO PRETEST = [f.sub.3](MICRO, PREPARATION and ABILITY,
UNIVERSITY, GENDER and ETHNICITY)
(4) MACRO POST TEST = [f.sub.4](MICRO, PREPARATION and ABILITY,
ENVIRONMENT and UNIVERSITY, TIME USE, GENDER and ETHNICITY, INTEREST).
In addition to the sequencing variables (MACRO, MICRO), we include
control variables for the student's academic preparation and
ability, type of university, gender and ethnicity, and, in the post test
model, for the class environment, the student's time use, and
interest in economics. We measure preparation and ability for economics
courses by the number of quarter hours of calculus.(10) grade point
average (GPA), and by the TUCE III pre-test score in the post test
model. The type of university is captured by a series of dummies,
consistent with Carnegie classifications, for a research institution, a
liberal arts college, and a two-year college. (The comprehensive
university is the omitted category). Class environment is measured by
class size and the percentage of time the instructor spent lecturing. We
measure student time use by the number of course hours the student is
currently undertaking and the number of hours per week spent in study
and at work. Interest is measured by student response to a survey
question that ranks the "interest of subject matter" from 1
(lowest) to 5 (highest). All variables are defined in Appendix Table I.
III. RESULTS
Table IIIA reports the OLS regression results from Equations 1 and 2,
which test for the effects of prior macroeconomics on initial knowledge
(pretest) and learning (post test, controlling for pretest) in
microeconomic principles classes. Table IIIB reports results from
Equations 3 and 4, which test for effects of prior micro on initial
knowledge and learning in macro principles classes. Results (Table IIIA)
show that there is a positive, statistically significant association
between a prior course in principles of macroeconomics and both pretest
scores and post test scores in the principles of microeconomics course.
However, a prior course in principles of microeconomics is not
statistically associated with either the macro pretest score or the
macro post test score, ceteris paribus, as shown by the insignificant
coefficient on the micro variable in Table IIIB.(11)
These results indicate that, within the TUCE III sample, student
learning is enhanced by teaching macroeconomics before microeconomics.
Perhaps, at the principles level, instructors emphasize concrete,
institutional macro foundations of micro more than theoretical
microfoundations of macro. Another possible explanation may be found in
the quotation from Michael Boskin that was cited earlier. When a course
in macro principles is taught before a course in micro principles,
instructors may teach core micro concepts such as supply and demand in
the macro course. That is, perhaps instructors who teach macro first do
not "avoid repeating much of what is taught in the micro half of
the course..." If microeconomic principles are taught in macro
courses, this could explain why micro pretest and post test scores are
higher for students who have had a prior macro course.(12) As well,
because many students take only one of the courses in the principles
sequence, the integration of micro principles into macro may present a
further rationale for teaching macro first. Students who take only a
macro course may be taught core micro concepts, whereas students who
take only a micro course may not have been taught core macro concepts.
Assuming that some exposure to both micro and macro is desirable,
non-continuing students may be better [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III
OMITTED] off taking only macro if it also includes some micro.
For the most part, the signs and significance of other variables in
Equations 1-4 are as expected. A possible exception is that the class
size variable (Number Students) is positive and significant in both
macro and micro classes. This could indicate that large classes are
efficient, that higher quality institutions in the TUCE III sample offer
larger classes, or that higher quality instructors are assigned to teach
larger classes.(13) It is perhaps noteworthy that the percentage of
class time the instructor spends lecturing (Percent Lecture) has a
significantly negative effect on the microeconomics post test.
Instructors may be advised to investigate alternative pedagogical techniques to lecturing. It is also interesting that gender and
ethnicity both significantly affect the TUCE III score. Further research
in each of these areas is warranted.
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
Because most academic economics departments must make decisions about
micro/macro sequencing, this study empirically estimates the effects of
sequencing on learning principles of economics using the recently
established TUCE III database. We find that students in microeconomic
principles classes score significantly higher on both a pretest (initial
knowledge) and post test (learning) if they first take a course in macro
principles. In contrast, students in macroeconomic principles classes do
not score significantly higher on a pretest or a post test if they first
take a course in micro principles. These results indicate that, ceteris
paribus, macro principles should precede micro principles if student
learning is a goal of the course. While this is the sequencing format
adopted by most textbooks, top-ranked academic departments that mandate
sequencing tend to place microeconomics before macroeconomics.
The suggestion that we should teach macro first may appear
counter-intuitive, if, as Blinder suggests (1991, 253), most economists
believe that teaching micro first is better "intellectually."
It may well be that at more advanced levels (i.e., intermediate or
graduate theory) the microfoundations of macroeconomics are more
relevant and that transferral of knowledge between micro and macro may
best be served by offering micro first. At the principles level,
however, macro instructors may focus on institutions or an overview of
the economy rather than on underlying theory relating to individual
choice. This conceivably renders the microfoundations less important in
learning macro principles, and may render the macrofoundations more
important for learning micro principles. Students, especially foreign
students, may gain familiarity with economic institutions and vocabulary
in macroeconomic courses. This familiarity, enhanced by the emphasis on
macroeconomic events in the media, may facilitate learning microeconomic
principles and may argue toward teaching macro first.
[TABULAR DATA FOR APPENDIX TABLE I OMITTED]
1. The proposition that humans have a limited capacity to process
information has implications for the principles of economics class, but
probably not for the sequencing decision specifically. According to Saunders [1990, 67-68], this proposition implies that instructors should
attempt to reduce the content of the principles course to "settle
for a few things done well" rather than trying to cover the entire
field.
2. Boskin also comments that the "traditional micro/macro
division... is becoming decreasingly sensible in teaching
principles..." [1988, 157]. Thus he should probably not be
characterized as a strong "micro first" advocate.
3. Boyer [1990] discusses teaching and scholarship differences at
each type of higher education institution and his appendix provides a
detailed description of the classifications used here.
4. Our sample of textbooks is not random and is, no doubt,
incomplete. We do, however, include a sampling of textbooks from
different perspectives and at different levels, consistent with the
approach used in Walstad and Watts [1990].
5. Reviewers of this paper have offered several explanations for the
content ordering in textbooks, most of which relate to the motives of
profit maximizing publishers. The reasons behind textbook content
ordering decisions, along with an historical investigation tracing
trends in sequencing decisions in both textbooks and departments, would
be interesting topics for future research.
6. See Saunders [1981] for a detailed description of the test. RTUCE
contained two macro tests, two micro tests, and two tests containing
both micro and macro questions. Fizel and Johnson used the
"hybrid" forms. As an aside, it is interesting to note that in
the RTUCE manual and on the "hybrid" tests, macro questions
precede micro questions.
7. Missing data on the student questionnaire reduced the original
matched sample to 1489 (micro) and 1397 (macro) for our analysis.
However, when compared to the original sample, the subsamples used here
do not appear to contain any systematic bias that affects the reported
results.
8. We use the post test score as the dependent variable and control
for the pretest score rather than using the difference between these
scores as the dependent variable, as recommended in Hanushek [1986,
1157n].
9. Since most students take principles before any other economics
classes, we make the assumption that a prior economics class covering
micro (macro) was a course in principles of microeconomics
(macroeconomics).
10. Although math classes other than calculus may be more relevant
for principles of economics students, no other data are available.
11. It should be noted that the coefficient on Microeconomics from
Equation 3 has a t-score of 1.913. Also, this variable appears to be
somewhat sensitive to changes in sample size and model specification
with respect to the macro pretest score.
12. Thanks to Phil Saunders for insights here.
13. The positive association between class size and TUCE III scores
may also indicate that students in large classes have more experience
taking multiple-choice exams, such as TUCE III. Students in smaller
classes may have more practice with essay and other types of
non-objective exams. This additional practice may affect test scores.
REFERENCES
Bach, George Leland with Robert Flanagan, James Howell, Ferdinand
Levy, and Anthony Lima, Economics: Analysis, Decision Making, and
Policy. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall, 1987.
Baumol, William J., and Alan S. Blinder. Economics: Principles and
Problems. San Diego: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1991.
Becker, William, Robert Highsmith, Peter Kennedy, and William
Walstad. "An Agenda for Research on Economic Education in Colleges
and Universities." American Economic Review, May 1991, 26-32.
Blinder, Alan. "Research in Economic Education and the Teaching
of Economics." Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1991, 251-53.
Boskin, Michael J. "Observations of the Use of Textbooks in the
Teaching of Principles of Economics." Journal of Economic
Education, Spring 1988, 157-64.
Bowden, E. V. Economics: The Science of Common Sense. Cincinnati:
South-Western Publishing, 1992.
Boyer, Ernest L. Scholarship Reconsidered: Priorities of the
Professorate. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990.
Brasfield, David W., Dannie E. Harrison, and James P. McCoy.
"The Impact of High School Economics on the College Principles of
Economics Course." Journal of Economic Education, Spring 1993,
99-111.
Byrns, Ralph T., and Gerald W. Stone. Economics. New York: Harper
Collins, 1992.
Case, Karl E., and Ray C. Fair. Principles of Economics. Englewood
Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1992.
Colander, David. "The Macrofoundations of Micro." Eastern
Economic Journal, Fall 1993, 447-57.
Dillingham, Alan E., Neil T. Skaggs, and J. Lon Carlson. Economics:
Individual Choice and its Consequences. Boston: Allyn and Bacon, 1992.
Ekelund, Robert B., and Robert D. Tollison. Economics. New York:
Harper Collins, 1991.
Fizel, John L., and Jerry D. Johnson. "The Effect of Macro/Micro
Course Sequencing on Learning and Attitudes in Principles of
Economics." Journal of Economic Education, Spring 1986, 87-98.
Golden, John, Fred Carstensen, and Paul Weiner. "An Evaluation
of 50 'Ranked' Economics Departments: Comment." Southern
Economic Journal, July 1987, 212-15.
Gwartney, James D., and Richard L. Stroup. Economics: Private and
Public Choice. San Diego: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1990.
Hanushek, Eric. "The Economics of Schooling." Journal of
Economic Literature, September 1986, 114-177.
Heilbroner, Robert L., James K. Galbraith, and Thomas Beveridge. The
Economic Problem, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1990.
Lipsey, Richard G., Paul N. Courant, Douglas D. Purvis, and Peter O.
Steiner. Economics. New York: Harper Collins, 1992.
Mansfield, Edwin. Economics. New York: W. W. Norton and Co., 1992.
McConnell, Campbell R., and Stanley L. Brue. Economics. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1993.
McEachern, William A. Economics: A Contemporary Introduction.
Cincinnati: South-Western Publishing, 1991.
Miller, Roger LeRoy. Economics Today. New York: Harper Collins, 1991.
Morse, Robert J. "Behind the Rankings." U.S. News and World
Report, 15 October 1990, 116-34.
Parkin, Michael. Economics. Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1993.
Ruffin, Roy J., and Paul R. Gregory. Principles of Economics. New
York: Harper Collins, 1993.
Samuelson, Paul A., and William D. Nordhaus. Economics. New York:
McGraw-Hill, 1992.
Saunders, Phillip. Revised Test of Understanding in College
Economics: Interpretive Manual. New York: Joint Council on Economic
Education, 1981.
Saunders, Phillip. "Learning Theory and Instructional
Objectives," in The Principles of Economics Course, edited by
Philip Saunders and William B. Walstad. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1990,
62-85.
Saunders, Phillip. "The Third Edition of the Test of
Understanding College Economics." Journal of Economic Education,
Summer 1991, 255-72.
Saunders, Phillip. The TUCE III Data Set: Background Information and
File Codes. New York: National Council on Economic Education, 1994.
Schiller, Bradley. The Economy Today. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1991.
Siegfried, John J., and Rendigs Fels. "Research on Teaching
College Economics: A survey." Journal of Economic Literature,
September 1979, 923-69.
Spencer, Milton H. Contemporary Economics. New York: Worth, 1986.
Stiglitz, Joseph. "On the Market for Principles of Economics
Textbooks: Innovation and Product Differentiation." Journal of
Economic Education, Spring 1988, 171-77.
Stiglitz, Joseph. Economics. New York: W. W. Norton, 1993.
Walstad, William B., and Michael Watts. "The Principles of
Economics Textbook: History and Content," in The Principles of
Economics Course, edited by Phillip Saunders and William B. Walstad. New
York: McGraw-Hill, 1990, 141-60.
Weintraub, Sidney. Microfoundations: The Compatibility of
Microeconomics and Macroeconomics, Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1979.
JANE S. LOPUS and NAN L. MAXWELL, California State University,
Hayward. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the June 1993
Western Economic Association Meetings in Lake Tahoe. We would like to
thank Scott Campbell for research assistance and participants in the
Research in Economic Education session at the WEA meetings, an anonymous
referee, and Phil Saunders for helpful comments. We would also like to
thank Phil Saunders for providing the TUCE III data.