Political and economic determinants of interest rate behavior: are central banks different?
Johnson, David R. ; Siklos, Pierre L.
I. INTRODUCTION
Do politicians manipulate the instruments of macroeconomic policy to
improve their electoral prospects or in response to the preferences of
their own party? These questions are addressed, but not yet resolved, by
the literature on political business cycles.(1)
To generate a political business cycle, politicians must control the
instruments of macroeconomic policy. Monetary policy plays an important
role in the determination of inflation, output and employment, the
objects of concern to politicians and voters. Yet, politicians do not
directly control the instruments of monetary policy in industrialized countries. Instead, these instruments are controlled by the central
banks, which vary widely across countries in their degree of statutory
independence. We wish to examine empirically whether monetary policy is
influenced by the timing of elections or a change in the party in power
after controlling for unexpected changes in economic fundamentals. Our
paper assesses, therefore, one aspect of independence, namely whether a
central bank makes monetary policy decisions without measurable
political influence.(2)
In this study we attempt to look at what central banks actually do as
opposed to what they are legislated to do, to distinguish between the
form and substance in discussions of central bank independence as in
Mayer [1976].(3) Our paper enlarges and improves on Cowart [1978] and
Woolley [1983], both of whom studied the role of political factors in
monetary policy for a sample of industrialized countries. Our
methodology is to compare the responsiveness of interest rate changes to
economic and political factors in seventeen countries. As we discuss
below, there are differences in opinion about whether an interest rate
variable or a monetary aggregate is a better representation of monetary
policy actions.
We compare the results of qualitative measures of differences in
central bank design - e.g., rankings of banks in order of independence
as determined by legislative criteria - with the results of a
quantitative comparison of differences in central bank behavior. This
exercise should help identify the important qualitative features in the
reform of existing central banks or in the design of new central
banks.(4)
In our empirical work the relevant relationships are estimated with a
recursive vector autoregression technique to control for temporal instability in the economy between 1960 and 1990 and the endogeneity of
the variables in question. This methodological innovation has important
consequences for the understanding of reaction functions and, more
generally, for measuring the impact of macroeconomic shocks on monetary
policy. We also stress results for separate subsamples of fixed and
flexible exchange rates as well as for the full sample. Our methodology
measures the influence of politics on monetary policy relative to the
choices and information actually available to the central bank when the
monetary policy decision was made.
Our study does not measure the influence of politics on the
instruments of fiscal policy as in Alesina et al. [1991]. Our study also
does not measure the direct influence of fiscal variables on the
instruments of monetary policy, although there is some evidence on this
issue in, for example, Parkin [1986] and Burdekin and Wohar [1990].
Burdekin and Wohar estimate the relationships between deficits, money
base growth and inflation for a sample of countries and time period
comparable to ours. All these studies find some evidence that central
banks do accommodate fiscal policy by financing deficits via money
growth, especially since the end of Bretton Woods. We return to the
issue of fiscal policy in considering the interpretation of our results
but stress that the effects of fiscal policy are partly captured in our
specifications because we measure monetary policy relative to the state
of the economy.(5)
A brief review of the literature which measures statutory central
bank independence is given in section II. We discuss issues in measuring
the role of political factors in monetary policy in section III. The
lessons of that literature are used in specifying the econometric model in section IV. Results are presented and discussed in section V. Section
VI concludes.
II. QUALITATIVE MEASURES OF CENTRAL BANK INDEPENDENCE: A REVIEW
The aim of this literature is to describe institutional arrangements
of central banks and how these arrangements influence economic
performance. Fair [1980] lists, for twenty central banks, the wide
variation in legislated goals, procedures to resolve conflicts with
politicians, terms of office of central bank governors and board of
directors, accountability to the legislature, and ownership of the
shares. Bernanke and Mishkin [1992] also use the case-study approach to
examine central bank behavior in six industrialized countries that are
included in our sample. They conclude that central banks do not follow
consistent targets in the short-run for either money or interest rates,
a result similar in spirit to our results.
Several studies quantify the differences between central bank
institutional arrangements. In the most comprehensive study of central
bank institutional arrangements, Cukierman, Webb and Neyapti [1992]
create an index of independence based on differences in central bank
laws for a very large sample of countries. The work continues in
Cukierman [1992, ch. 19] to encompass even more countries and to refine
the earlier indices of central bank independence. Walsh [1993]
criticizes this work for the lack of robustness in the supposed
(negative) correlation between inflation and central bank independence
and the failure to adequately define what is meant by independence.
Goodhart [1994] criticizes Cukierman's work because it suggests
that central bank independence is determined by a large number of
characteristics when, empirically, this does not seem to be the case.
Moreover, Fischer [1994] finds an apparent conflict between expert
opinion which tends to place less emphasis on the role of legislation in
influencing inflation rates and the independence index which stresses
the negative correlation between inflation and statutory independence.
Parkin [1986], Grilli, Masciandaro and Tabellini [1991], and Burdekin
and Willett [1991] also create indices of central bank independence
based on institutional characteristics. Grilli et al. define
independence as the degree to which a central bank enjoys the freedom to
accomplish a specified objective of monetary policy free from political
influence.(6) Four such rankings appear in Table I. These rankings have
been used to consider two important questions. Parkin [1986] and
Burdekin and Laney [1988] ask: Is a more independent central bank
associated with a lower government deficit? Cukierman [1992], Burdekin
and Willett [1991], Alesina [1988], and Alesina and Summers [1993] use
rankings to argue that average inflation rates are lower when central
banks are more independent.
There is a significant literature which discusses the usefulness of
these rankings (see the survey in Pollard [1993]). Fischer [1994] argues
for a distinction between goal independence, which is a function of how
precisely defined central bank objectives are, and instrument
independence, which is obtained when a central bank has full discretion
over the conduct of monetary policy. These papers argue that the absence
of goal independence is a key determinant of inflation performance for
the same set of countries considered by Grilli et al. Thus, for example,
the Reserve Bank of New Zealand has no goal independence, because it
must adhere to a rigid inflation objective, while the Swiss National
Bank has considerably more such independence because its objectives are
much broader. Although Alesina and [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED]
Summers [1993] conclude that more independent central banks deliver
lower inflation, they also find no relationship between statutory
independence and real economic performance. The latter result is similar
in nature to our findings. Alesina and Grilli [1991] stress the
importance of such qualitative factors in designing a European central
bank. However, Cargill [1989], after comparing the U.S. and Japanese
experiences, points out the dangers of focusing too narrowly on the
legislation governing central bank behavior as a guide to predicting
economic performance. However formal the mechanism which grants some
degree of independence to a central bank, there exist less formal but
equally powerful mechanisms to override such constraints. The Coyne
affair in the history of the Bank of Canada is a particularly
fascinating example (Gordon [1961]). A second example, the Bundesbank,
has its independence constrained by virtue of the decentralized nature
of its policymaking body rather than by its legal structure vis-a-vis
the government (Hochreiter [1990]). This feature has implications for
the institutional design of the proposed European Central Bank.
As Table I makes clear, there is relatively little agreement in the
rankings across the four studies, except that Switzerland and Germany
are viewed as the two most independent central banks in all these
studies.(7) An additional difficulty with rankings dominated by
inflation performance is that statutorily dependent central banks such
as Japan's perform almost as well as legally independent banks such
as those of Germany and Switzerland with respect to inflation.(8) These
issues motivate our study to try to measure what central banks do in
response to political events as a means of providing information about
central bank independence.
III. POLITICAL INFLUENCE ON CENTRAL BANK BEHAVIOR: THE REACTION
FUNCTION APPROACH
There is a long history, beginning with Reuber [1964], of estimating
and interpreting central bank reaction functions (see also Alt and
Chrystal [1983, ch. 6]). A reaction function measures how the
instruments of monetary policy, the vector [I.sub.t], react to the
central bank's information about the economy as of period t-1, a
vector labelled [Z.sub.t-1], and political factors, [P.sub.t]. The
equation
(1) [I.sub.t] = B(L)[Z.sub.t-1] + C(L)[P.sub.t]
can be derived formally from an optimal control problem where the
policymaker has quadratic preferences over economic outcomes and a
linear model of the economy. It is important to note that the
coefficients in the reduced form B(L) are a combination of coefficients
incorporating the policymaker's model (the relationships between
[Z.sub.t] and [I.sub.t], the central bank's information and its
policy instruments), as well as the policymaker's weights on
achieving different objectives, and even the values of the objectives.
Early researchers (Christian [1968] or Havrilesky [1967]) stressed the
temporal instability of the reaction function. Also, since (1) is a
reduced form, its estimation does not directly reveal policymakers'
preferences. This identification problem, and the problem of temporal
instability, makes reaction functions difficult to interpret. Khoury
[1990], who examines forty-two previously estimated reaction functions
for the Federal Reserve, found them to be sensitive to arbitrary details
of the specification. Beck [1990] finds that although a politically
motivated monetary cycle exists, it is not easy to find an econometric specification which can consistently be used to determine the
significance of such cycles.
In spite of these difficulties, reaction functions have been used to
ascertain the impact of political influence on central bank behavior.
Our study combines two approaches used by others in measuring the
influence of political factors, in reaction functions.(9) Nordhaus
[1975] argues that monetary policy is looser before an election to
increase the probability of re-election. Hence, [P.sub.t] is a dummy
variable active several quarters before elections. A second approach,
suggested by Hibbs [1977] asks: Does a politically influenced central
bank react more to increases in unemployment and less to increases in
inflation during periods of "left-wing" government than in
periods of "right-wing" government? Such a possibility
presumes both that the central bank is open to political influence and
that left-wing and right-wing parties are different so that the
coefficients in the political function vary with the party in power.
Chappell and Keech [1986] estimate and simulate such a model for the
United States.
The significance of electoral and political variables in equations
like (1) varies widely. Most of the literature deals with the behavior
of the U.S. Federal Reserve and its response to political factors. Allen
[1986] finds no influence from a variety of political and electoral
variables on the growth of the monetary base. Beck [1984; 1987]
considers both the behavior of the federal funds rate and the growth of
base money and finds little evidence of pre-election loosening of the
instruments of monetary policy.
There is slightly more evidence of looser monetary policy during
Democratic (left-wing in the American context) presidential
administrations. Havrilesky [1987; 1988] finds higher monetary growth
under Democratic presidents. It is important to be cautious in
interpreting reaction functions where the instrument of monetary policy
is money growth. For most central banks, money growth is not the direct
instrument of monetary policy - at most it is a target.(10) Beck [1987],
Hamburger and Zwick [1981], and Fair [1978] provide some evidence that
the appearance of a political cycle in the money supply is a result of
Federal Reserve accommodation of fiscal policies which differ by
presidential administration. Hakes [1990], in studying the minutes of
the Federal Open Market Committee, presents evidence that Federal
Reserve policy is influenced by both the Federal Reserve chairperson as
well as the U.S. President.
Overall, the evidence in favor of political influence on monetary
policy variables directly controlled by the Federal Reserve is mixed.
Woolley [1983, 335] refers to this finding as the "macropolitics
paradox." Thus, while there is considerable belief in political
influence on macroeconomic outcomes, empirical evidence for direct
political influence on monetary policy is not conclusive.
There are relatively fewer studies which measure the extent of
political influence on central banks other than the Federal Reserve. A
sampling of such works includes Frey and Schneider [1981] who find some
evidence of Bundesbank accommodation of an expansionary fiscal
policy.(11) Cowart [1978] finds some evidence that, when measured by
changes in the discount rate, socialist (left-wing) European governments
respond more to unemployment. Hodgman and Resek [1983] estimate
comparative reaction functions for Germany, France, Italy and the United
Kingdom. Political factors are not explicitly considered, but there is
some analysis of politically motivated subsamples. Woolley [1983] does
add political factors to this analysis, and he finds more effect of
political factors in France and the United Kingdom than in Germany. Our
study extends the non-American evidence to a larger sample of countries,
a longer time period, and a wider variety of exchange rate arrangements.
We consider the interest rate as the instrument of monetary policy, are
more careful about informational considerations, and control for the
state of the economy.
IV. ECONOMETRIC SPECIFICATION
Background
Three issues stand out in estimating a central bank reaction
function: the choice of an instrument of monetary policy and the
objectives of monetary policy; the issue of temporal instability; and
the specification of political and electoral variables. One of our
special concerns is to have specifications which allow comparability
across countries.
A market-determined short-term interest rate is chosen as the central
bank's instrument of monetary policy. Our second choice was the
central bank discount rate, used in two of the seventeen countries,
Ireland and New Zealand, where no market-determined rate was available
for the whole sample.(12) The central bank is assumed to achieve its
desired average interest rate within a quarter. We considered and
rejected several other monetary instruments as possibilities for this
study. Narrow or broad monetary aggregates which include the liabilities
of the commercial banking system are clearly not controlled by the
central bank within the one-quarter sampling frequency used in this
study. In many countries, fluctuations in interbank clearings, bank
crises, and seasonality mean that even the monetary base is not fully
under central bank control in the short term. Studying the monetary base
would also require considerable institutional knowledge of all changes
in reserve requirements or reserve accounting procedures in each
country, an awkward task in a comparative study. The short-term interest
rate is, however, generally comparable across countries.(13) Using the
level or the rate of change of the exchange rate as a measure of
monetary policy across countries was also rejected. There is no adequate
model of the "normal" exchange rate, from which to assess the
tightness of policy. Although central banks often manage exchange rate
intervention, governments choose the exchange rate regime. The
importance of the exchange rate varies with the openness of the economy,
making intercountry comparisons difficult. Since we control for the
influence of world interest rates on the domestic short-term interest
rate, this may also give some information about the desired exchange
rate. Therefore we believe that the signal-to-noise ratio on the stance
of monetary policy is highest for an interest rate instrument. Put
differently, individuals, interest groups and politicians are likely to
focus on interest rate behavior, and not the state of money supply
growth, in evaluating central bank or government actions (see also
Bernanke and Blinder [1992]).(14)
We hypothesize that the central bank responds to unexpected changes
in the unemployment rate and the rate of inflation. Both objectives
appear in the legislated objectives for most central banks and are of
concern to politicians. The instrument of policy, the short-term nominal
interest rate, affects both unemployment and inflation as well as the
electoral prospects of the party in power. In addition, studying
interest rate behavior allows us to measure of the influence of the rest
of the world on national monetary policy, an influence which we would
expect to be stronger if nominal exchange rates are fixed. More
importantly, perhaps, the dynamic relationships between inflation,
unemployment and nominal interest rates are unlikely to be stable over
time. Our response to this concern is the estimation of the model with a
recursive vector autoregression. In each recursion a new observation is
added and the model is reestimated but old observations are not
discarded. Thus, the coefficients describing the time-series behavior of
unemployment, inflation and interest rates are not assumed to be
constant over the sample. The advantage of this methodology is that,
unlike in previous studies of this kind, the central bank reacts to
unexpected inflation and unemployment shocks using only information
available at the time policy was made.
The question we consider empirically then is whether changes in
interest rates are related to unexpected changes in inflation or
unemployment rates, as well as to purely political events such as
elections or partisan changes in government. We develop these ideas
formally below.
The Conceptual Framework
We assume that the following vector autoregressive representation
(VAR) characterizes the central bank's information about the
economy:
(2) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The VAR generates reduced-form forecasts of the inflation rate,
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], the unemployment rate, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], and the short-term interest rate, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], as the fitted values of the VAR using coefficients
estimated with information available as of period t - 1. Seasonal
variables and a trend were also added to the VAR. Political effects are
omitted precisely because we ask how economic variables would be
forecast from only their past history. The VAR represents the central
bank's use of past information in a way which imposes relatively
few restrictions on the data. The VAR methodology also recognizes the
endogeneity of the variables in (2). To the extent that changes in
lagged fiscal policy change lagged interest rates, unemployment rates
and inflation rates, the effects of fiscal policy (other than its
contemporaneous effects) are incorporated into the study. More direct
fiscal policy proxies, comparable across countries and at the quarterly
frequency, are not available for most of the countries in our sample
(see also note 5 above). The impact of lagged monetary policy through
lagged interest rates changes on inflation and on unemployment is also
captured. More importantly, the coefficient estimates in (2) are
permitted to vary over time and are produced only from the sample of
information known by the monetary authority at the time policy is
carried out.(15) This is the principal attraction of the recursive
regression approach since the estimates provide evidence about how
central banks react to information they actually had and not to
information which was unavailable. Most reaction functions are estimated
simply using the full sample period, a procedure which gives the central
bank too much information.(16)
The reaction function estimated is
(3) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Equation (3) specifies that the nominal interest rate is a
difference-stationary process and its innovation, the change in
short-term interest rates, measures changes in central bank policy. To
the extent that the inflation process exhibits considerable persistence
- a phenomenon widely agreed to exist - changes in short-term rates are
changes in both real and nominal interest rates.
In equation (3) central banks react to lagged forecast errors because
contemporaneous inflation and unemployment rate data are not available
at the time of a central bank decision on current interest rates. If
[Delta][R.sub.t] [greater than] 0, the central bank raises interest
rates in response to the new information. Since the model is estimated
with quarterly data, restricting the information set for the forecasts
to t-1 provides less information than is actually available to market
participants from monthly observations of inflation, unemployment and
interest rates; some of this data would be available within the quarter.
Whether central banks and economic agents act immediately upon receiving
new information is a separate question. Thus, we preferred to err on the
side of providing perhaps slightly less information than would actually
be available to central banks.(17)
If the lagged forecast errors from the VAR, [Mathematical Expression
Omitted], are greater than zero, inflation would be higher than expected
given the information at the time. The sum of the coefficients in the
lag operator [Alpha](L) would be positive if the central bank reacts to
higher-than-expected inflation by tightening monetary policy. The
treatment of unemployment forecast errors is similar. If lagged forecast
errors in unemployment, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], are greater
than zero, the sum of the coefficients in [Beta](L) is expected to be
negative if interest rates are lowered in response to increases in
unemployment. Moreover, equation (3) permits political events, captured
by the variable [P.sub.t], to possibly influence interest rates in a
manner to be described below. Finally, the response of domestic interest
rates to world interest rates is measured by [Delta](L). There are three
exchange rate regimes in our sample. Following 1973 most European
countries have operated under a quasi-fixed exchange rate system; the
remaining countries have operated under a managed float regime (the
amount of management varies widely). Before 1973, under the
Bretton-Woods regime, fixed but adjustable exchange rates are the rule.
Initially, in all three regimes, we proxy influence of the
"world" interest rate ([R.sup.w]) by the simple average of the
German, U.S., and Japanese interest rates. For the latter three
countries the world interest rate is defined as the simple average of
the interest rate in the other two countries.(18) For the European
countries we then considered the possibility that the German interest
rate alone might be a better proxy for the world rate, while for Canada
and Australia, the U.S. interest rate alone was used. Estimates were
generated for both measures of the world interest rate, only the second
set of results is included in the empirical section. The size of
[Delta](L), the response of domestic interest rates to the world
interest rate, should, of course, depend on the exchange rate
regime.(19)
Political Variables
Political and electoral variables are then added to the reaction
functions. For each of the specifications we ask: Do the political or
electoral variables help explain the behavior of the monetary
authorities beyond their reaction to lagged forecast errors in inflation
and unemployment? If so, there is some evidence that the monetary
authority is influenced by political forces and is, in this sense, less
independent than a monetary authority not influenced by political
events.
Two types of political events are considered. In the first type
[P.sub.t] is a dummy variable active around elections. In the Nordhaus
[1975] model, everything else being equal, we should find that a
dependent central bank would reduce interest rates in the months before
an election to aid in the re-election of the governing party. This is
implemented with a dummy variable (Eprior) equal to 1 in the election
quarter and in the two previous quarters. For a politically motivated,
less-independent central bank the coefficient on such a dummy should be
negative. A second dummy variable (Etmp), equal to 1 in the election
quarter and in the two previous quarters and equal to -1 in the two
subsequent quarters, was also added to the reaction functions. A
politically motivated central bank may defer an increase in interest
rates until after an election. This variable partly handles the issue of
a pre-election fiscal expansion, if such an expansion raised inflation
and lowered unemployment, since the politically motivated central bank
would try to defer the necessary interest rate increases. A significant
positive sign on this variable would capture the temporary nature of the
election-oriented monetary policy. The election dummy Etmp is
distinguished from the election dummy Eprior, for with the latter
variable the election effect is permanent. A zero or a significant
positive sign on either election dummy is evidence of independence,
while a negative sign on either is evidence of dependence. We
experimented with versions of these variables active for more quarters
than described above with no impact on the conclusions.
The second type of political influence focuses on the political
preferences of the party in power. Alesina and Roubini [1990] argue that
a switch from a right-wing to a left-wing government would be associated
with expansionary monetary policy.(20) A dummy representing this switch
measures, given past unexpected inflation and unemployment, whether a
new left-wing government lowers nominal interest rates. If a new
right-wing government dislikes inflation more than its left-wing
predecessor, monetary policy will be tightened and interest rates
increased.(21) A dummy variable Drpta2 (Drpta4) takes on a value of +1
in the election quarter and two (four) quarters after the election of a
new right-wing government (we also specified a dummy eight quarters in
length with no effect on the conclusions). The variable is set equal to
-1 for the same time period following the election or appointment of a
new left-wing government. Consequently, the reaction of interest rates
to governing party is positive since a right-wing government (+1) would
want to raise interest rates if the central bank were dependent while a
left-wing government (-1) would prefer lower interest rates with a
dependent central bank, other things being equal.
One complication is the fact that, in several of the countries in our
sample, election timing is endogenous. The case in which a dependent
central bank reduces interest rates before an election and the case
where an election is called because of a series of interest rate
reductions are observationally equivalent and cannot be distinguished
with our test. We find little evidence, however, of election-timing
effects on interest rate behavior in any country. Central banks are
equally independent across countries in this sense. To the extent that
elections are called for reasons beyond favorable economic
circumstances, ends of terms, scandals, votes of confidence or
leadership changes, these exogenous events should provide inference concerning the effect of political timing on central bank activity. We
return to the endogeneity issue in the discussion of the empirical
results.
Considerations of fiscal policy can also produce complications. In
the case of partisan changes, if a new left-wing government expanded
fiscal policy, and if the central bank accommodated the expansion so
that interest rates did not rise, a zero coefficient on the party dummy
is evidence of dependence. A negative coefficient could, in principle,
reflect a fiscal contraction by a newly elected right-wing government.
Nevertheless, it is important to recognize that this issue may not be of
much practical importance, since it is difficult to imagine actual
changes in fiscal policy enacted within a quarter of a new government
taking office.
We also implement a second test of the partisan model that is more
straightforward and perhaps more telling. Reaction function (3) is
estimated separately where in one sample the data are taken from the
period where the left-wing government is in power; in a second sample we
use data only from the period when the right-wing government is in
power. If the coefficients of the reaction function are significantly
different by partisan regime, then this may be viewed as substantial
evidence in favor of the joint hypothesis that the central bank is
influenced by the party in power and that the two parties do in fact
have different preferences over their response to the forecast errors in
inflation and unemployment. If the coefficients do not differ
significantly, it is not possible to know which part of the joint
hypothesis is rejected - either the central bank is independent or the
political parties do not differ.
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Forecast Errors and Reaction Functions
Summary statistics by country for the full sample, as well as for two
subsamples defined as the Bretton Woods or fixed exchange rate period
(denoted BW in the tables) and the post-Bretton Woods sample (denoted
PBW) of managed floating exchange rates for some countries, or
quasi-fixed exchange rates for others, revealed some interesting results
as did data for each country where the full sample (1960-1990) is split
to compare the inflation, unemployment and interest rate records of
left- and right-wing governments.(22) Dates for the end of the Bretton
Woods period were found from information contained in various issues of
the International Monetary Fund's International Financial
Statistics. Partisan change and electoral data were taken from Alesina,
Cohen, and Roubini [1991] and updated.
Average inflation rates in all countries except Japan are higher
during the post-Bretton Woods period. For all but Japan and Switzerland
average nominal interest rates are also higher. It appears that
virtually all countries took advantage of flexible exchange rates to run
higher inflation rates. The average unemployment rate in the
post-Bretton Woods period is higher for all seventeen countries.
Comparing the partisan records, average inflation is higher under
left-wing governments in ten of the fifteen countries shown (Japan and
Switzerland are defined as not having experienced partisan changes);
average nominal interest rates are higher under right-wing governments
in five of fifteen countries. This includes two cases, Canada and the
United Kingdom, where inflation under right-wing governments was lower,
so right-wing governments had higher ex post real interest rates.
Unemployment rates are higher under right-wing governments in nine of
fifteen countries.
Separate estimates of equation (3) according to the exchange rate
regime as well as estimates for the full sample are presented. In
traditional macroeconomic models fixed exchange rates can generate a
loss of independence for monetary policy except, of course, for the
reserve currency country. However, if capital controls exist between
financial markets, interest rate differentials can arise and persist.
Our sample, however, covers a period of rapid developments in capital
markets and improving capital mobility and, therefore, reinforces the
need to use recursive estimation to address the issues considered here.
By contrast, under managed or flexible exchange rates, there is more
scope for independent monetary policy. Thus, exchange rate regimes may
produce differences in central bank behavior, a possibility generally
ignored or downplayed in discussions of central bank independence.
Neither exchange rate regime is pure of course. The Bretton Woods period
incorporates several discrete changes in the "fixed" exchange
rate; the post-Bretton Woods period incorporates a wide variety of
exchange rate arrangements including some periods where there were
important limits on exchange rate changes within the European Community.
The null hypothesis that the coefficients in each equation of the VAR
are stable between the Bretton Woods and post-Bretton Woods samples (not
shown) is strongly rejected. Each VAR (equation (2)) was estimated with
six lags of inflation, unemployment, the interest rate, a constant,
seasonal dummies and a trend.(23)
Other preliminary statistical work revealed the following other
important conclusions. First, having all the information matters. The
standard deviations of the regression residuals using data for the whole
sample (or for either exchange rate regime) are significantly lower than
those of either a recursive VAR, a random walk forecast or a rolling
regression forecast (see the discussion in note 19). Whatever the means
by which a central bank generates "forecasts" from the full
sample, it clearly uses information not available when the actual policy
decisions were made. Second, the forecast errors for all three
forecasting models possess means that are not significantly different
from zero. It is also the case that these forecast errors have
substantial and significant positive serial correlation in most cases.
Finally, the recursive VAR forecasts always outperform the random walk
forecasts, while the rolling VAR forecasts do not always outperform the
random walk forecasts. Space limitations lead us to present results for
reaction function (3) using the forecast errors generated from the
recursive VAR.
Table II presents the estimates of equation (3) omitting the
political variables. Estimates for the first lag only of the inflation
and unemployment estimates are shown to conserve space. If all central
banks are equally independent, then the response of interest rates to
the forecast errors in inflation, unemployment, and the response to the
exogenous change in the world interest rate provide an objective
description of central bank behavior in these countries. Table II shows
that the change in the world interest rate is a statistically
significant determinant of changes in the domestic interest rates in
many countries - in six of seventeen during the Bretton Woods period,
and seven of seventeen during the post-Bretton Woods period. In the
latter period, the world interest rate variable matters for France,
Germany, Belgium, and the Netherlands, all key participants of the
European Monetary System. World interest rate changes also played a role
in Canada, Sweden and Switzerland in the post-Bretton Woods period.
While it may be surprising that, particularly in the Bretton Woods
period, the world interest rate did not play a larger role in the
determination of the timing of domestic interest rate changes it must
also be remembered that many countries had capital controls. The results
also suggest that some of the countries successfully sterilized capital
flows under fixed exchange rates.(24) It is clear then that some
countries were able to use domestic monetary policy to manoeuvre around
the world interest rate while other countries chose not to, were unable
to (e.g., Canada), or were simply not integrated with leading financial
markets during the Bretton Woods period (e.g., Japan, Australia and New
Zealand), at least in the short run.
The coefficients which measure the reaction of monetary policy to
inflation or unemployment forecast errors do yield some useful
information, particularly when compared across exchange rate regimes.
First, only in Austria is the coefficient which measures the reaction of
interest rate changes to an inflation forecast error or unemployment
forecast error significant during the Bretton Woods period. This
suggests that the general adoption of fixed exchange rates did restrict
the policy activities of other central banks. Some caution should be
taken with the results for the Bretton Woods sample for two reasons.
First, there are some serious measurement problems with 1960s data,
especially for the unemployment rate. Second, because each recursive
regression must begin with some minimum sample, we have provided central
banks with more information than they would have had in the early
portion of the Bretton Woods sample. The estimates for the post-Bretton
Woods period avoid this problem entirely.
The post-Bretton Woods period does yield more information on the
comparison of central bank behavior across countries. A central bank is
often thought to be "independent" if it reacts to an
unexpected increase in inflation by increasing nominal interest
rates.(25) By this measure, central banks in Japan, Switzerland and
Sweden are independent. Central banks in the United States, Japan and
Austria respond to an increase in unemployment with looser monetary
policy. There is, however, a perverse case, since the central bank in
the Netherlands responds to an increase in unemployment by raising
interest rates. How can our findings be squared with observed
differences in inflation performance in the countries in our sample?
Based on the data in Table II there is a close association between
inflation differentials vis-a-vis the U.S. and interest rate
differentials relative to U.S. interest rates. Nevertheless, the
correlation between these differentials is substantially higher in the
post-Bretton Woods sample (.88 versus .76), suggestive perhaps of
greater interdependence in interest rate policies among the OECD countries in our sample. This view is reinforced by the findings in
Table II which show that the responsiveness of domestic interest rate
changes to world interest rate changes is substantially higher in the
post-Bretton Woods period in five countries (Canada, France, the
Netherlands, Ireland and Germany) out of the fourteen for which we can
make such comparisons; only two countries (Austria and Norway) show less
dependence on the world interest rate in the post-Bretton Woods era.
There is no statistical difference for the remaining seven countries,
although the coefficients are larger in the post-Bretton Woods period
for four of the seven in this category. It should also be pointed out
that whereas only one central bank (Austria) reacts significantly to
either inflation or unemployment shocks in the Bretton Woods period,
seven central banks (in the U.S., U.K., Denmark, Sweden, Japan,
Switzerland, and New Zealand) react to such shocks in the post-Bretton
Woods period, an indication that central banks became more responsive to
macroeconomic conditions after exchange rates floated more freely.
Overall, however, forecast errors in inflation and unemployment have
comparatively little explanatory power for interest rate changes for
most countries as one can tell by looking at the [R.sup.2]. This may
suggest some weakness in our approach to modelling monetary policy.
However, this weakness occurs over a wide variety of institutional and
legal arrangements for monetary policy and over a variety of
specifications.(26) Despite the weakness of these results, we find
little cross-country difference in central banks' reactions to
inflation or unemployment shocks. Thus the results in Table II cannot,
in the very influential Barro-Gordon [1993a; 1993b] framework (a model
that was part of our prior), explain the differences between average
national inflation rates through measurable ways in which the different
central banks reacted to unexpected changes in inflation and
unemployment.(27)
Electoral Variables
Table III investigates the effect of election timing on interest rate
changes in the context of reaction function (3) through the election
dummies (Eprior and Etmp). In eight countries - Canada, Sweden, Ireland,
Austria, the Netherlands, Germany, Japan and Norway - for either the
full sample or one of the subsamples, the central bank allows an
election to affect the [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] timing of
interest rate changes. In four countries - Sweden, Ireland, Canada and
Italy - the sign is not inconsistent with that of an independent central
bank; that is, the pre-electoral period involves either a temporary or
permanent increase in interest rates as opposed to the decrease
predicted by the political business cycle literature. In nine countries
- the U.S., the U.K., France, Italy, Switzerland, Belgium, Australia,
New Zealand and Denmark - there is no statistical effect of election
timing on interest rate changes, a result which could be interpreted as
evidence of independence. In Germany and Austria, interest rate
reductions take place before elections and are reversed after elections.
Only in the Netherlands are elections preceded by permanent reductions
in interest rates. It is noteworthy in this context that the central
banks in Germany, Austria and the Netherlands appear in Table I among
the most independent central banks. However, when the separate Bretton
Woods and post-Bretton Woods samples are examined, the pre-electoral
effect for the Netherlands disappears, and the temporary effect on
German and Austrian interest rates is seen to be a feature of the
post-Bretton Woods sample only. In the Austrian case, the post-Bretton
Woods effect is significant only at the 10 percent level of
significance. Overall then, the effect of elections on interest rate
changes is weak for all the countries considered.
It is interesting to compare these results with those reported by
Alesina, Cohen and Roubini [1991] who consider the effect of the
pre-electoral period on monetary growth. They find, for a similar set of
countries in a panel, that unexpected monetary growth does increase
before elections. In individual country results, they find only New
Zealand and Australia exhibit significant excessive monetary growth
before elections. They also find that in New Zealand, Austria and Norway
monetary growth before elections differs [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III
OMITTED] by political party (more for left-wing than for right-wing
governments). There is at least one difficulty in comparing our results
with theirs. In using monetary growth as the measure of monetary policy,
the dependent central bank could accommodate expansionary pre-election
fiscal policy and not allow interest rates to rise. In their study this
would be expansionary monetary policy (central bank dependent), in our
study this would not be expansionary monetary policy (central bank
independent). A positive pre-election effect on interest rates would be
revealed as evidence of independence in our study but not theirs. These
issues highlight the need not only to be careful about defining what is
meant by an independent central bank (see also Goodhart [1994] in this
connection) but also the complications [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE IV
OMITTED] that arise because of the connection between fiscal and
monetary policies even if central banks are primarily responsible for
monetary policy only.
Partisan Variables
Tables IV and V present results which investigate the role of
partisan politics in the reaction functions. Partisan variables are
defined as in Alesina and Roubini [1990]. The simplest description of
partisan effects argues that a new right-wing (left-wing) government
tightens (loosens) monetary policy because it inherits a
higher-than-desired rate of inflation (unemployment). This result is
found only in the full sample for the United States and in Sweden in the
post-Bretton Woods sub-sample. The effect is not found in the United
States in the Bretton Woods sub-sample. The Federal Reserve is the most
politically dependent central bank over the full sample by this measure.
In four other countries, France, Ireland, Italy, and New Zealand, there
is some evidence of a temporary partisan effect. But the effect is not
the effect described above. In these countries the election of a new
right-wing government lowers interest rates and the election of a
left-wing government raises interest rates. This is more difficult to
interpret as a political event. One story would have the central bank
accommodating a reduction in inflationary expectations and allowing
nominal interest rates to fall in the right-wing case and rise in the
left-wing case. By this measure six central banks exhibit some political
dependence, four from the bottom of the usual rankings.(28) Even with
five banks indicating some partisan response for at least one subsample or the full sample, that leaves nine other central banks all equally
independent by this measure. Two central banks, Japan and Switzerland,
did not face partisan changes in government in the sample.
TABLE V
Test of Coefficient Stability in the Reaction Function, Equation
(3), across Partisan Classification of Government(a)
Full Sample Post-Bretton Woods
Country R L Prob. R L Prob.
Canada 36 82 .05(*) 29 54 .16
United States 73 45 .40 59 16 .24
United Kingdom 76 41 .65 56 19 .31
France 105 13 .00(*) 55 13 .00(*)
Germany 94 24 .19 INS INS INS
Denmark 39 31 .62 29 31 .62
Sweden 24 94 .02(*) 24 48 .10(**)
Belgium 59 59 .30 33 39 .53
Netherlands 90 28 .06(**) 58 21 .04(*)
Australia 50 44 .49 29 39 .76
Austria 37 53 .60 31 41 .24
New Zealand 79 34 .00(*) 35 31 .13
Norway 53 52 .74 26 45 .97
Ireland 65 53 .77 19 46 .98
Italy CT CT CT CT CT CT
a For sample details, see notes to Table II. The null hypothesis
that the coefficients of the reaction function estimated in Table
II are constant between samples drawn from right-wing and left-wing
governments is tested. This tests the joint null hypothesis that
political parties have different preferences over monetary policy
and that the central bank is politically dependent. R denotes the
number of quarters the right-wing government was in power, L the
number of quarters the left-wing government was in power.
* indicates statistically significant at the 5% level; + at the
10% level.
Table V presents estimates, when available, of reaction function (3)
for subsamples with different political parties in power. Left-wing
(denoted L) and right-wing (denoted R) governments are assumed to have
the same preferences over time for their preferred responses to the
unemployment, inflation, and world interest rate shocks. Under the null
hypothesis that the central bank is independent, coefficients in the
reaction functions should be the same across partisan regimes. The
probability values reported in Table V present the significance levels
for the test of coefficient stability across partisan regimes. Thus, a
low probability value indicates rejection of the null. In the
post-Bretton Woods period, two probability values, those of France and
the Netherlands, are less than 5 percent. The probability value for
Sweden is significant at the 10 percent level. For the full sample,
central banks in New Zealand, Sweden, Canada and France are found
responsive to partisan changes at the 5 percent level while the
Netherlands central bank would reject the joint null at 6 percent. No
other central bank changes its behavior significantly with a change in
the party in power. The five central banks which appear dependent by
this measure never appear in the top three most independent banks in
Table I. This indicates some correlation between behavior and the
rankings according to legislative provisions. There are no partisan
changes in Switzerland or Japan to consider. There are only short
periods of partisan change in Italy.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
'The goal of this research was to provide a quantitative
assessment of the independence of central banks from political influence
for a sample of seventeen OECD countries, as measured by central bank
interest rate responses. We also compared our model estimates to the
usual rankings based on legislative factors. However, it proved
difficult to generate consistent reactions of central banks in any
country to forecast errors from VAR's estimated with the
information the central bank actually had at the time the policy was
made. One possibility, which cannot be disproved, is that the
methodology simply does not identify any substantial economic shocks to
which monetary policy would have reacted. Central banks are doing
something else or the models specified in this paper are too simple to
capture what central banks are actually doing.
If the framework is accepted as identifying interesting economic
shocks to inflation, unemployment and world interest rates to which
central banks might or should have responded, the evidence in this paper
is suggestive in four ways. First, central bank responses to these
shocks are not closely associated with their position in the usual
qualitative rankings of central bank behavior. Of the central banks
ranked as very independent (see Table I), that is, Germany, Switzerland
and the United States, only the Swiss central bank responds to an
unexpected increase in inflation with tighter monetary policy. However,
similar behavior is exhibited by the central banks in Japan and Sweden,
which appear lower in the usual rankings. There is no obvious
correlation between responses to unemployment shocks and a bank's
position in the qualitative rankings for the central banks in other
countries considered.
Second, for Germany and Austria there is some evidence that interest
rate increases are deferred until after elections in the post-Bretton
Woods period. These two central banks are frequently considered to be
relatively independent of political influence.
Third, the strongest quantitative evidence for the usual rankings of
central bank independence based on qualitative factors is found for New
Zealand, France, Sweden, Canada and the Netherlands. In these countries
a change in the partisan classification of the party in power does
influence the reaction function of the central bank. These same five
countries are not listed among the most independent central banks in the
sample based on central bank laws.(29) This is our strongest support of
the usual rankings, and our interpretation is that this is modest but
not overwhelming support of the hypothesis of partisan political
influence on central bank interest rate policies.
Fourth, for many of the central banks around the world, only the
change in the world interest rate has a strong impact on
interest-rate-setting behavior. Neither electoral nor partisan factors
were found to have widespread or large effects on interest rate policies
among the central banks we considered. The design of a central
bank's constitution and the degree of its statutory independence
may thus not be as important as commonly considered, particularly when
there are close international links between financial markets. External
factors have tended to be ignored or downplayed in most discussions of
central bank independence.
At this point it is not possible to conclude that the legislated
differences in central bank independence generate easily observed
variations in interest-rate-setting behavior of central banks in either
their reaction to economic events, their pre- and post-electoral
behavior or their responses to a change in government. The search for
any simple characterization of central bank behavior with respect to
political influence continues. Future research, however, might expand
the model of this paper to include a fiscal policy measure or possibly
consider other instruments of monetary policy, a monetary aggregate and
even the exchange rate. After all, just as reaction functions are known
to be temporally unstable, as has been demonstrated again in this paper,
similarly the choice of a monetary policy instrument can and does change
over time in ways that cannot be captured completely in the short-run
via the interest rate instrument alone.(30)
1. See Alesina [1988] for a survey, or recent contributions by
Alesina and Roubini [1990], and Alesina, Cohen and Roubini [1991].
2. Our study parallels, to some extent, the discussion of monetary
policy and political influence in Alesina, Cohen and Roubini [1991].
They study monetary growth (relative to its immediate history) rather
than interest rate changes, our proxy for central bank policy actions.
3. An additional problem is the possibility of two-way causation. A
population which fears inflation imposes an effective constraint on the
political system through the central bank, which manifests itself in a
low-inflation performance but appears to be "caused" by
central bank independence. Cukierman, Webb and Neyapti [1992] also
recognize this problem and indeed find evidence of two-way causality between inflation and the turnover rate of central bank governors, which
they use as a proxy for independence.
4. New Zealand recently undertook a substantive reform of its central
bank towards more independence. Similar proposals are being contemplated
for Canada and the United Kingdom. The European Community is in the
process of designing an independent European central bank.
5. One important reason we do not include in this study the
interaction of fiscal variables and monetary policy instruments is that
we have no confidence in the consistency or comparability of data on
government debt for the full sample of seventeen countries from 1960 to
1984. The OECD Main Economic Indicators does not publish a consistent
data series for either government debt or the deficit back to 1960. The
deficit data in the International Financial Statistics (usually line 80)
are subject to numerous changes in definitions, and are available since
1960 for only nine of the seventeen countries. The accounting
conventions differ across countries where there is a full sample of
data. Finally, the wide differences in political structures in the
countries examined in this paper (e.g., federal versus unitary)
complicate greatly the proper measurement of fiscal policy. In our
methodology, if expansionary fiscal policy were to reduce unemployment
and increase inflation, the central bank would take this into account in
setting monetary policy.
6. They also construct a separate index which measures the freedom a
central bank has to choose the instruments of monetary policy.
7. Rank correlations between the rankings are low and fall rather
substantially when Switzerland, Germany, and the U.S. are omitted.
8. As a referee pointed out, however, the negative correlation
between inflation and an index of central bank independence remains even
if Japan is classified as dependent (e.g., as in the Burdekin and
Willett ranking).
9. A third variant of the political variables, found in Frey and
Schneider [1981], asks if policy responds to the popularity of the
government as measured by polls. This kind of political variable is not
considered in the present study.
10. The experience of different countries with monetary growth
targets is discussed in Bernanke and Mishkin [1992].
11. Vaubel [1994] conducts non-parametric tests of the connection
between M1 growth and the monetary policy preferences of the government
in Germany. He concludes that there is a pre-electoral acceleration of
monetary growth when the government has a political majority in the
Bundesbank Council.
12. This choice is less desirable because the role of the discount
rate varies from country to country. It is clear from the reports of the
central bank of Ireland that the discount window in Ireland is active
and that the discount rate varies with market rates. There was less
information on the role of the discount window in New Zealand. There was
no market-determined short-term interest rate for New Zealand available
for the full sample period.
13. If a central bank or other branch of the government operates
through credit allocation, then a shortage of credit to a sector should
increase the interest rate in the market-determined sector. This was the
reason for using a market-determined rate where possible. See Aftalion
[1983] for a description of the Bank of France's activities in
credit allocation. Such effects may also occur in other countries.
14. Beck [1987] and Willett and Keen [1990] also used an interest
rate as a measure of monetary policy actions. Indeed, our approach can
be said to take up Willett's suggestions about exploring the
connection between interest rates, economic fundamentals and political
effects on central bank behavior.
15. We do not consider the issue of data revisions. For the variables
in (2), data revisions are less important than for some other variables
such as, for example, measures of output or monetary aggregates.
Estimation of (2) also proceeds as if each series is stationary. This is
an uncontroversial assumption for all the series except possibly the
interest rate. However, in most sub-samples for all countries,
individual series did not appear to contain a unit root once a trend is
permitted.
16. This may be a slight exaggeration since central banks probably
receive economic information in advance of the public. The question is
whether this information is used immediately in evaluating interest rate
policy. Clearly, we cannot control for this possibility since we are
using quarterly data.
17. The two-step procedure employed here could be open to the
"generated regressor" problem despite the resort to recursive
estimation. However, as the original model (2) is a VAR, the generated
regressor problem does not arise. In any event, in a few cases we
estimated reaction functions (3) using Generalised Least Squares with no
impact on our conclusions.
18. There is a clear problem with simultaneity for the three
countries. The reaction functions for these three countries were also
estimated without the world interest rate and yield similar results.
Other methods could have been implemented to capture world interest rate
effects, such as using a proxy for the world real interest rate, but our
results would then be open to the criticism that the ex post real
interest rate does not adequately measure ex ante real interest rates.
19. A second type of reaction function (4) is representative of the
existing literature on reaction functions, as in Woolley [1988]. The VAR
is constrained to be a random walk and the reaction function becomes
(4) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
We found that the recursive VAR clearly outforecast the random walk
specification.
In addition we also estimated the reaction function
(5) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
In (5) the policy variable is [Mathematical Expression Omitted], the
deviation of the short-term nominal interest rate in period t from the
value which would have been forecast with nonpolitical information
available in t - 1. This variable is the error term, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], from the VAR (equation (2)). The information sets
in (5) and in the VAR (2) are not identical; the innovation in interest
rates in period t uses slightly more information than the forecast
errors dated t-1 and earlier. The innovation in interest rates as of
period t-l, the proposed policy instrument in (5), is uncorrelated with
the least squares residual with six lags in these same variables, as of
information in period t-1. It need not, in theory, be uncorrelated with
six lags of the same variables as of period t-2, t-3 up to the length of
the [Alpha](L) and [Beta](L) coefficients. In practice the correlations
between this version of the policy variable and the lagged forecast
errors were very low and the reaction function proposed in (5) simply
did not yield many interesting results.
20. The definitions of "right-wing" and
"left-wing" follow Alesina and Roubini [1990] and Alesina,
Cohen and Roubini [1991]. A general difficulty with the specification of
both versions of the political dummy variable is that previous studies
do not use a statistical criterion to determine how long the dummies
should remain active. If, for example, monetary policy acts with long
and variable lags, then existing specifications may be misspecified.
21. A referee correctly points out that a central bank could be
viewed as being (somewhat) independent if the interest rate change is
less than "desired" by politicians. Unless we have a model of
notional interest rates by, say, political party we cannot, strictly
speaking, measure degrees of independence.
22. It has been pointed out to us that since we are estimating (2)
recursively it might be interesting to examine how the coefficients in
the reaction functions change over time. Given the number of countries
and coefficients to be estimated it is impractical to display all such
results. However, we found that the exchange rate regime had the
greatest effect on the recursive coefficient estimates.
23. We also estimated VARs with four lags and the conclusions were
unaffected. Although it may be preferable to select some optimal lag
length for each country's data based on some criterion such as
Akaike's Information Criterion (AIC), there is the danger that
different VARs for different countries would produce results which are
not comparable. Moreover, we would be left asking why information sets
differ across countries, a task beyond the scope of this study. Also, we
are restricted in the choice of lags because of considerations of
degrees of freedom. Finally, an econometric model should not be chosen
on the basis of a single criterion. Thus, a model chosen according to
Akaike's criterion may be inferior according to another criterion.
There are tradeoffs when estimating any econometric model. Nevertheless,
we experimented with a variety of specifications and lag lengths. The
conclusions reached in this study are generally robust to these choices.
24. The evidence on the ability of central banks to sterilize is
mixed.
25. This assumes, of course, that the government prefers to defer an
increase or disagrees with the belief that higher future inflation is
imminent. However, the complete freedom to act and to do so based on
anticipations of inflation rather than past inflation does serve to
reinforce the perception that the central bank is acting independently
of government influence. Nevertheless, even an independent central bank
might occasionally postpone an interest rate change for nonpolitical
reasons (e.g., wait and see if a perceived increase in inflation is
likely to occur). Even in this case, however, what is important for our
purposes is that interest rate effects be independent of political or
partisan factors.
26. It is possible that we chose the wrong instrument of monetary
policy and that money growth, deficits or exchange rates would have
produced "better" results than interest rate changes. It is
also possible that other specifications with different information
structures could have produced "better" results. We do not
explore these questions further in this paper.
27. See Canzoneri [1993, 143] who argues that "the Barro-Gordon
model is just not up to the task. It does not discuss governments or
political processes."
28. There could be, as usual, a contemporaneous fiscal policy effect
if actual or expected fiscal policy changes with the change in
government. A left-wing (right-wing) fiscal expansion (contraction)
which is accompanied by unchanged monetary policy would raise (lower)
interest rates. This would represent evidence of independence for the
central banks of France, Ireland, Italy and New Zealand.
29. It has been suggested to us that partisan changes as usually
defined in the literature are well-defined only for the U.S. It is
possible that for other countries partisan changes are far more subtle
than can be captured by the dummy variables used in this study.
30. As one referee put it, interest rate policies might be just
inconsistent enough to reveal the macroeconomic responses reported in
this paper, as opposed to ones which might otherwise have been expected.
REFERENCES
Aftalion, Florin. "The Political Economy of French Monetary
Policy," in The Political Economy of Monetary Policy, edited by D.
Hodgman. Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1983, 7-25.
Alesina, Alberto. "Macroeconomics and Politics," in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, edited by Stanley Fischer. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1988, 13-52.
Alesina, Alberto, G. D. Cohen, and N. Roubini. "Macroeconomic
Policy and Elections in OECD Democracies." National Bureau of
Economic Research Working Paper No. 3830, September 1991.
Alesina, Alberto, and Vittorio Grilli. "Establishing a Central
Bank." Paper presented at the European Central Bank Conference,
Reshaping Monetary Politics in Europe. Georgetown University, 1991.
Alesina, Alberto, and Nouriel Roubini. "Political Cycles:
Evidence from OECD Economies." Review of Economic Studies, October
1990, 663-88.
Alesina, Alberto, and Lawrence H. Summers. "Central Bank
independence and Macroeconomic Performance." Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, May 1993, 151-62.
Allen, Stuart D. "The Federal Reserve and the Electoral
Cycle." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, February 1986, 88-94.
Alt, James E., and K. Alex Chrystal. Political Economics. Berkeley:
University of California Press, 1983.
Barro, R. J., and D. B. Gordon. "A Positive Theory of Monetary
Policy in a Natural Rate Model." Journal of Political Economy,
August 1983a, 589-610.
-----. "Rules and Discretion and Reputation in a Model of
Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary Economics, July 1983b,
101-22.
Beck, Nathaniel. "Domestic Political Sources of American
Monetary Policy 1955-82." Journal of Politics, August 1984,
787-817.
-----. "Elections and the Fed: Is There a Political Monetary
Cycle?" American Journal of Political Science, February 1987,
194-216.
-----. "Political Monetary Cycles," in The Political
Economy of American Monetary Policy, edited by Thomas Mayer. Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1990, 115-30.
Bernanke, Ben, and Allan S. Blinder. "The Federal Funds Rate and
the Channels of Monetary Transmission." American Economic Review,
September 1992, 901-21.
Bernanke, Ben, and Frederic Mishkin. "Central Bank Behavior and
the Strategy of Monetary Policy: Observations from Six Industrialized
Countries," in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1992, edited by Olivier
J. Blanchard and S. Fischer, Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1992, 183-227.
Burdekin, Richard C. K., and Mark E. Wohar. "Monetary
Institutions, Budget Deficits and Inflation." European Journal of
Political Economy, 1990, 531-551.
Burdekin, Richard C. K., and Thomas D. Willett. "Central Bank
Reform: The Federal Reserve in International Perspective." Public
Budgeting and Financial Management, no. 4, 1991, 619-50.
Canzoneri, Matthew B. "Central Bank Independence, Growth,
Investment, and Real Rates: A Comment." Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, December 1993, 141-46.
Cargill, Thomas F. "Central Bank Independence and Regulatory
Responsibilities: The Bank of Japan and the Federal Reserve."
Solomon Brothers Center for the Study of Financial Institutions,
Monograph Series in Finance and Economics, Monograph 1989-2, 1989.
Chappell, Henry, and William Keech. "Party Differences in
Macroeconomic Policies and Outcomes." American Economic Review, May
1986, 71-4.
Christian, James W. "A Further Analysis of the Objectives of
American Monetary Policy." Journal of Finance, 23(3), 1968, 465-77.
Cowart, Andrew T. "The Economic Policies of European
Governments, Part I: Monetary Policy." British Journal of Political
Science, July 1978, 285-311.
Cukierman, Alex S. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility and
Independence. Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1992.
Cukierman, Alex S., S. B. Webb, and B. Neyapti. "The Measurement
of Central Bank Independence and Its Effect on Policy Outcomes."
World Bank Economic Review, 6(3), 1992, 353-98.
Fair, D. E. "Relations Between Government and Central Bank: A
Survey of Twenty Countries," in Appendices, Committee to Review the
Functioning of Financial Institutions. London: Her Majesty's
Stationery Office, 1980.
Fair, R. C. "The Sensitivity of Fiscal Policy Effects to
Assumptions about the Behavior of the Federal Reserve."
Econometrica, September 1978, 1165-79.
Fischer, Stanley. "Modern Central Banking." Presented at a
Symposium on Central Banking Held in Honour of the Tercentenary of the
Bank of England, June 1994.
Frey, B., and F. Schneider. "Central Bank Behavior: A Positive
Empirical Analysis." Journal of Monetary Economics, May 1981,
291-315.
Goodhart, Charles A. E. "Game Theory for Central Bankers: A
Report to the Governor of the Bank of England." Journal of Economic
Literature, March 1994, 101-14.
Gordon, H. S. "The Bank of Canada in a System of Responsible
Government." Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science,
February 1961, 122.
Grilli, Vittorio, Donato Masciandaro, and Guido Tabellini.
"Political and Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies
in the Industrial Countries." Economic Policy, October 1991,
342-92.
Hakes, David R. "The Objectives and Priorities of Monetary
Policy under Different Federal Reserve Chairmen." Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking, August 1990, 327-37.
Havrilesky, Thomas. "A Partisanship Theory of Fiscal and
Monetary Regimes." Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, August
1987, 308-25.
-----. "A Test of Monetary Policy Action." Journal of
Political Economy, June 1967, 299-304.
Hibbs, Douglas A., Jr. "Political Parties and Macroeconomic
Policy." American Political Science Review, December 1977, 1464-87.
Hochreiter, Eduard. "The Austrian National Bank Act: What Does
It Say About Monetary Policy?" Konjunkturpolitik, 36(4), 1990,
245-56.
Hodgman, Donald R., and Robert W. Resek. "Determinants of
Monetary Policy in France, The Federal Republic of Germany, Italy and
the United Kingdom: A Comparative Analysis," in The Political
Economy of Monetary Policy, edited by D. R. Hodgman. Boston: Federal
Reserve Bank of Boston, 1983, 147-70.
Khoury, Salwa S. "The Federal Reserve Reaction Functions: A
Specification Search," in The Political Economy of American
Monetary Policy, edited by Thomas Mayer. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 1990, 27-50.
Mayer, Thomas. "Structure and Operations of the Federal Reserve
System," in Compendium of Papers Prepared for the Financial
Institutions and the Nation's Economy Study, Committee on Banking,
Currency and Housing, 94th Congress, Second Session. Washington:
Government Printing Office, 1976.
Nordhaus, W. "The Political Business Cycle." Review of
Economic Studies, April 1975, 169-90.
Parkin, Michael. "Domestic Monetary Institutions and
Deficits," in Deficits, edited by James M. Buchanan, Charles K.
Rowley, and Robert D. Tollison. London: Basil Blackwell, 1986, 310-37.
Pollard, Patricia S. "Central Bank Independence and Economic
Performance." Review of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
July/August 1993, 21-36.
Reuber, Grant L. "The Objectives of Canadian Monetary Policy
1949-61: Empirical 'Trade-Offs' and the Reaction Functions of
the Authorities." Journal of Political Economy, April 1964, 109-32.
Vaubel, Roland. "A Public Choice Analysis of the German
Bundesbank." Manuscript, University of Mannheim, 1994.
Walsh, Carl E. "Central Bank Strategies, Credibility, and
Independence: A Review Essay." Journal of Monetary Economics,
November 1993, 287-302.
Willett, Thomas D., and Edward Keen. "Studying the Fed: Toward a
Broader Public-Choice Perspective," in The Political Economy of
American Monetary Policy, edited by Thomas Mayer. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1990, 13-25.
Woolley, John T. "Partisan Manipulation of the Economy: Another
Look at Monetary Policy with Moving Regression." Journal of
Politics, May 1988, 335-60.
-----. "Political Factors in Monetary Policy," in The
Political Economy of Monetary Policy, edited by D. R. Hodgman. Boston:
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1983, 177-203.