Risk preference estimation in the nonlinear mean standard deviation approach.
Saha, Atanu
I. INTRODUCTION
Under uncertainty, individuals' economic decisions and their
responses to price or income changes are significantly influenced by
their risk attitudes. As a result, it is difficult to assess the merits
and consequences of alternative economic incentives without information
about the risk preferences of the targeted population. Also, in
analytical uncertainty models, unambiguity in a decision maker's
response to price or income changes is often secured by risk preference
restrictions as in Sandmo [1970; 1971], Batra and Ullah [1974], and Pope
[1980]. Whether such analytical results are meaningful depends, in part,
on the validity of the preference restrictions on which they rest.
A sustained stream of applied research has focused on estimating risk
preferences using economic data. Two distinct yet related strands of
literature can be identified. The first infers agents' risk
attitudes by testing restrictions on optimal decisions implied by
alternative risk preference structures. For example, constant absolute
risk aversion (CARA) and constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) imply
that optimal choices are invariant to changes in initial wealth and in
scale of wealth, respectively (Sandmo [1977]). A representative, though
partial, list of such studies includes Cohn et al. [1975], Landskroner
[1977], Siegel and Hoban [1982], Morin and Suarez [1983], Bellante and
Saba [1986], Chavas and Holt [1990], and Pope and Just [1991]. The
studies in the second stream attempt to directly estimate utility
functional forms or risk aversion coefficients from data on
individuals' choices. Some studies in this area are Friend and
Blume [1975] Weins [1976], Hansen and Singleton [1983], Wolf and Pohlman
[1983], Szpiro [1986], Love and Buccola [ 1991 ], and Saha et al.
[1994].
This paper belongs to the second stream. It proposes a method that
allows joint estimation of the degree or absence of risk aversion,
structure of risk preference, and technology. Section II motivates the
paper by arguing that the Arrow-Pratt measure of risk aversion imposes a
priori restrictions on risk preference depending on the choice of the
utility functional form. In section III, a flexible utility function in
the nonlinear mean-standard deviation framework is proposed. The
proposed form nests alternative risk preference structures as refutable special cases. Section IV applies the estimation method to a competitive
firm model under price risk. Firm-level data from Kansas is used in the
empirical analysis. Section V contains estimation results. The findings
suggest that Kansas producers' risk preferences are characterized
by decreasing absolute risk aversion. While small producers exhibit
increasing relative risk aversion, the null hypothesis of constant
relative risk aversion is not refuted in the case of large producers.
The findings provide little support for the widely used linear
mean-variance framework. Evidence also suggests that ignoring risk and
risk preferences can result in substantial overestimation of the supply
and demand elasticities of a firm.
II. ESTIMATION METHODS IN THE EXPECTED UTILITY FRAMEWORK
An advantage of testing behavioral restrictions implied by risk
preference structures is that it does not require functional form
assumptions about underlying utility. Often, however, empirical findings
from studies in this approach preclude definite inference about risk
preferences. Consider, for example, the comparative static result from
the Sandmo [1971] model of a firm facing price risk: under nonincreasing
absolute risk aversion (NIARA), optimal output is increasing in expected
price. Observe, this preference restriction of NIARA is sufficient, but
not necessary, for the result. Consequently, if estimation results show
that output supply is indeed positively related to price, very little
can actually be inferred about risk preferences. It is possible to
conclude definitely that the sample individuals do not exhibit NIARA
preferences only if estimation results show a negative relation between
output supply and expected price.
This problem of ambiguity in inference obviously does not arise in
studies that directly estimate a utility function. However, a feature
common to studies in this stream is that risk parameter estimates are
conditional. That is, the coefficient of absolute or relative risk
aversion is estimated conditional upon a specific risk preference
structure implied by the assumed functional form. For example, negative
exponential utility - used by Love and Buccola and by studies employing
the linear mean-variance approach such as Weins or Friend and Blume -
imposes CARA and increasing relative risk aversion (IRRA). The power
utility function (used by Hansen and Singleton, among others) imposes
decreasing absolute risk aversion (DARA) and CRRA. Thus, commonly used
utility functional forms allow data to reveal only the degree of risk
aversion and not its structure: the latter is imposed by the utility
functional form chosen. Furthermore, these functions, being
intrinsically nonlinear in wealth, do not admit risk neutrality as a
testable special case.
In this context, two relatively "flexible" functional forms
warrant comments. The hyperbolic absolute risk aversion or HARA class of
utility functions proposed by Merton [1971] and used by Wolf and Pohlman
among others, has the flexibility to exhibit decreasing, constant or
increasing relative risk aversion depending on parameter values.
However, a utility function in the HARA family cannot exhibit CARA. In a
recent article Saha [1993] proposed the expo-power (EP) utility function
which has the flexibility to exhibit decreasing, constant, or increasing
absolute risk aversion. But EP utility function is incapable of
exhibiting CRRA under meaningful parameter values. Thus, even the
relatively "flexible" functional forms impose a priori
restrictions to the extent they preclude certain risk preference
structures.
Because HARA and EP utilities are also intrinsically nonlinear, their
parameter estimates can be used to test risk neutrality locally, but not
globally. Consider, for example, the EP utility: u(w) = 1 - Exp[-a
[multiplied by] [w.sup.b]], where w denotes wealth, and a and b are
parameters. The second derivative of EP utility has the same sign as [a
- a [multiplied by] b [multiplied by] [w.sup. b] - 1]; consequently, the
parameter restriction implied by risk neutrality can be tested only at a
particular level of w and not globally. Similar comments apply for the
HARA class of utility functions. Although risk aversion is often
accepted as a "stylized fact," its preclusion as a testable
special case certainly limits the generality of a utility functional
form.
A priori preclusion of certain risk preference structures by commonly
used utility functional forms does not stem from their restrictive
structures alone. It reflects a more general problem of the Arrow-Pratt
measures of risk aversion within the expected utility approach. To
elaborate, denote the Arrow-Pratt measures of absolute and relative risk
aversion by A(w) = -[u[double prime](w)/u[prime](w)] and R(w) = w
[multiplied by] A (w), where primes denote derivatives. Differentiation
of R(w) yields
(1) R[prime](w) = A(w) + w [multiplied by] A[prime](w).
TABLE I
Alternative Risk Preference Configurations Using Arrow-Pratt
Measures
DRRA CRRA IRRA
DARA feasible feasible feasible
CARA not feasible not feasible feasible
IARA not feasible not feasible feasible
A number of restrictions on risk preference configurations follow
immediately from the above equation. For example, if u(w) exhibits CARA,
i.e., A[prime](w) = 0, the u(w) must exhibit increasing relative risk
aversion, since R[prime](w) = A(w) [greater than] 0; CRRA or DRRA are
precluded. Thus, in the Arrow-Pratt framework, irrespective of the
degree of its flexibility, a utility function can either exhibit CARA or
CRRA, never both. This explains the preference preclusion in HARA and EP
utility functions noted above. Furthermore, it is evident from equation
(1) that under CRRA or DRRA, since A[prime](w) [less than or equal to] -
A(w)/w [less than] 0, the only compatible preference is DARA; CARA and
IARA are both infeasible. These restrictions on risk preference
configurations are summarized in Table I. Restrictions implied by
Arrow-Pratt measures seem particularly severe in the face of ambiguous
empirical evidence on the nature of risk aversion. Several empirical
studies, including that of Wolf and Pohlman, have concluded that the
hypotheses of "either increasing absolute or constant absolute risk
aversion cannot be rejected" [1983, 847]. Evidence on the nature of
relative risk aversion has also remained mixed. For example, Cohn et
al., Szpiro, and Wolf and Pohlman report results in support of
decreasing, constant and increasing relative risk aversion,
respectively. To further complicate matters, analysts have argued that
Arrow's justification of increasing relative risk aversion based on
bounding conditions of the utility function "may be economically
empty" (Friend and Blume [1975, 901]). It appears, therefore,
neither empirical evidence nor analytical arguments are compelling
enough to rule out configurations like CARA and DRRA or CARA and CRRA,
though they are infeasible in the expected utility framework. Therefore,
an alternative risk aversion measure is needed that can incorporate all
possible risk preference configurations (i.e., all nine cells in Table
I) as refutable special cases. This observation provides the central
motivation for our study.
III. RISK PREFERENCE STRUCTURES IN THE NONLINEAR MEAN-STANDARD
DEVIATION FRAMEWORK
The nonlinear mean-standard deviation utility (U([Mu], [Sigma]))
framework provides flexibility in representing alternative risk
preferences. The U([Mu], [Sigma]) decision criterion hypothesizes that
an agent's optimal choices are made by ranking alternatives through
a preference function defined over the first two moments of random
payoff, [Mu] and [Sigma].
To our knowledge, the U([Mu], [Sigma]) decision criterion was first
proposed by Fisher, in 1906. However, this decision framework gained
prominence since the studies by Markowitz [1952] and Tobin [1958] and
has been widely used in the analytical as well the empirical risk
literature. Rosenzweig and Binswanger [1993] provide a recent empirical
application. Sinn [1983] and Meyer [1987] have shown that neither
normally distributed random payoff nor quadratic utility for
agent's preference is necessary for the preference ordering under
the expected utility and U([Mu], [Sigma]) maximization approaches to be
consistent. The consistency condition is met when the choice set is
composed of random variables that belong to a "linear class"
within which all distributions can be "transformed into one another
merely by a shift and a proportional extension" (Sinn [1983, 56]).
Equivalently, the consistency condition is satisfied when the
"choice set [is]... composed of random variables which differ from
one another only by location and scale parameters" (Meyer [1987,
422]).
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED]
Although the U([Mu], [Sigma]) and expected utility approaches are
analytically equivalent under the consistency condition, they differ
significantly in their empirical tractability and their flexibility in
representing alternative risk preferences. We proceed by formalizing an
agent's risk attitude and choices in the U([Mu], [Sigma])
framework.
Consider a decision maker whose utility function, U, is defined over
the mean and the standard deviation of her random wealth, denoted by M
and S; that is: U([Mu], [Sigma]) [equivalent to] U(M, S). Her risk
attitude is reflected by
(2) A(M,S) [equivalent to] - ([U.sub.S]/[U.sub.M])
where subscripts denote partial derivatives. A(M, S) is the slope of
the indifference locus in the S-M space. Meyer has shown that, under the
location and scale condition, various hypotheses concerning risk
aversion measures in the expected utility setting can be translated into
equivalent properties concerning A(M, S). In particular:
1. risk aversion, neutrality and affinity correspond to A(M, S)
[greater than] 0, = 0, and [less than] 0, respectively;
2. the magnitude of A([center dot]), when positive, reflects the
degree of aversion to risk;
3. decreasing (constant, increasing) absolute risk aversion
corresponds to [A.sub.M] [less than] 0 (= 0, [greater than] 0);
4. decreasing (constant, increasing) relative risk aversion is
reflected by [A.sub.t](tM, tS) [less than] 0 (= 0, [greater than] 0),
respectively, for t [greater than] 0.
The foregoing restrictions provide the basis for proposing the
following flexible utility function:
(3) U(M, S) = [M.sup.[Theta]] - [S.sup.[Gamma]]
where [Theta] and [Gamma] are parameters and it is assumed throughout
that [Theta] [greater than] 0. We will call this the mean-standard
deviation utility function or MSU. Under MSU, the risk attitude measure,
A, is given by
(4) A(M, S) [equivalent to] - ([U.sub.S]/[U.sub.M]) [equivalent to]
([Gamma]/[Theta]) [M.sup.1-[Theta]] [S.sup.[Gamma]-1].
It can be verified that MSU exhibits
1. risk aversion, neutrality, and affinity as [Gamma] [greater than]
0, = 0, and [less than] 0;
2. decreasing, constant, and increasing absolute risk aversion as
[Theta] [greater than] 1, = 1, and [less than] 1; and
3. decreasing, constant, and increasing relative risk aversion as
[Theta] [greater than] [Gamma], [Theta] = [Gamma], and [Theta] [less
than] [Gamma].
The various risk preference configurations under MSU are summarized
in Table II. MSU's flexibility is evident from the comparison of
Tables I and II. Also note that MSU embeds the widely used linear
mean-standard deviation model as a refutable special case wherein
[Gamma] = 1 and [Theta] = 1.
IV. ESTIMATION OF TECHNOLOGY AND PREFERENCES UNDER MSU
In this section we develop an empirical framework for the joint
estimation of a firm's risk preference and production technology
using MSU. Consider a single-product competitive firm's decision
problem under price risk. The firm's random wealth, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted], is defined as follows:
(5) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is the random output price, Q
denotes output, C denotes the cost function, r is a vector of input
prices, and w is exogenous wealth (initial endowment). The wealth
structure defined in (5) implies that "all random alternatives
available to the firm are positive linear transformations of the given
random variable [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and hence are related
to one another by location and scale parameters" (Meyer [1987,
427]). That is, consistency between expected utility and U([Mu],
[Sigma]) maximization holds in the competitive firm model under price
risk. Observe that nothing has been assumed about the distribution of
random price. The consistency condition is satisfied solely by the fact
that the firm's wealth function is linear in [Mathematical
Expression Omitted].
Assume that the firm observes past realizations of random price to
form its perception about the mean and standard deviation of the price
distribution, denoted by [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and
[[Sigma].sub.p]. The firm's opportunity set is described by
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
S = [[Sigma].sub.p] [multiplied by] Q.
In the U([Mu], [Sigma]) decision framework the firm's output
choice problem is
(6) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
Under the assumption that the producer's utility function is
given by MSU, the first-order condition of the problem in equation (6)
can be written as
(7) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
If the firm is risk neutral, i.e., [Gamma] = 0, the right-hand side
of equation (7) is zero and the above first-order condition simply
equates expected output price to marginal cost, [C.sub.Q]([center dot]).
Taking logarithms, equation (7) can be rewritten in implicit estimation
form as
(8) [Mathematical Expression Omitted].
The subscript i corresponds to the ith observation, [[Epsilon].sub.i]
denotes error in optimization and [Beta] is the set of technology
parameters embedded in the cost function whose specific form is assumed
to be known through prior estimation. For efficiency gain, equation (8)
can be estimated with the cost and/or production functions as a system
of equations with correlated errors. The estimation will provide joint
estimates of the technology and utility function parameters which we
denote by the vector [Omega] [equivalent to] {[Beta], [Theta], [Gamma]}.
The estimation equation (8) is quite general and can be used for any
underlying technology by substituting the appropriate marginal cost
term, [C.sub.Q].
Furthermore, estimation of equation (8) is fairly straightforward and
does not pose onerous problems. In contrast, in the expected utility
framework, unless a simple discrete probability density is assumed for
the distribution of random wealth or a linear mean-variance framework is
posited, the first-order conditions typically involve integrals.
Consequently, estimation requires computer software that can perform
numeric integration within a numeric optimization routine as in Saha et
al. [1994]. Estimation of MSU-based equations as in equation (8) is
considerably simpler. In fact, all estimations in this paper were
undertaken using SHAZAM, a widely used econometrics software package.
The Data Set
The firm-level data used in this study come from the computerized
farm accounting records of the Farm Management Data Bank at the
Department of Agricultural Economics, Kansas State University (Langemeier [1990]). The producers were selected from the Data Bank by
the criterion that in each year at least 95% of row crop acreage was
devoted to wheat. Consequently, the selected producers were
predominantly single-product firms. The data set comprised 60
observations on 15 producers for the period 1979 to 1982.
Data included expenditures incurred and/or estimates of rental values
for a wide array of inputs and crop output quantities. The data also
included government payments received and nonfarm asset income. Because
prices paid for inputs were not available from the firm-level data set,
Kansas state-level price data, compiled by Robert Evenson and his
associates at Yale University, were used as proxies for input prices.
Major sources of their data were the U.S. Department of
Agriculture's Agricultural Statistics, Agricultural Prices,
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] Field Crops Production Disposition
and Value, and State Farm Income and Balance Sheet Statistics, and the
Chicago Board of Trade's Statistical Annual.
The Kansas wheat producers were assumed to use two inputs: capital
([x.sub.1]) and materials ([x.sub.2]). Summary statistics for the data
used in estimation are presented in Table III. Expenditures on capital
inputs, [x.sub.1], included an interest charge on land and building
equity, cash farm rent, building and machinery depreciation, and real
estate taxes. The materials category, [x.sub.2], included machinery and
machinery hire, fertilizer, pesticides, seed, and miscellaneous cash
expenses. All price aggregates were computed as geometric means using
expenditure or revenue shares as the weights. Nonfarm asset income was
used as a proxy for producers' wealth endowment, w. The data on the
mean of wealth M was generated by adding expected farm profits to non
farm asset income.
In addition to the data set on all firms, two additional data sets
corresponding to small and large producers were created. To create these
data subsets, all firms were first ranked according to average annual
output (the ranking on the basis of average expected wealth, M, was
identical). The top nine firms were then categorized as large and the
remaining six constituted the small category. The summary statistics for
the two groups of producers are reported in Table II.
Estimation Details
Generation of data on the mean and standard deviation of price
moments, [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and [[Sigma].sub.p], warrants
a few comments. Observe that the optimization problem in equation (6)
was set out in a "timeless" framework since it is essentially
a static problem and, therefore, the same in each period. Furthermore,
it was assumed that the firm's optimal output choice in each period
is based on subjectively formed price moments. Clearly, data on the
moments cannot be collected directly. Therefore, a Nerlovian
"quasi-rational expectations" approach was adopted. Nerlove et
al. [1979] proposed that forecasts from an ARIMA (autoregressive
integrated moving average) process can be used to generate data on
expectations.
A series of tests based on the method of Box and Jenkins [1976] were
performed using annual data on Kansas state-level wheat prices for the
period 1955 to 1982. The autocorrelation function of the price series
showed gradual decay, while the partial autocorrelation function
indicated a clear "cutoff" after the second lag, typical of an
AR(2) process. Based on these diagnostics, the Kansas wheat price
process was assumed to have the following structure:
(9) [p.sub.t] = [[Phi].sub.0] + [[Phi].sub.1] [p.sub.t-1] +
[[Phi].sub.2][p.sub.t-2] + [e.sub.t]
where [Mathematical Expression Omitted], for all t = 1, ... T.
In the AR(2) model above a producer's forecast of the
conditional mean price at period t (i.e., conditional upon the
information available up to period t-1) is given by
(10a) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where [[Gamma].sub.t-1] denotes the information set at period t-1. If
nothing more is assumed about the random variable [p.sub.t] in equation
(9), then its conditional variance is simply [Mathematical Expression
Omitted] which is a time-invariant constant. Thus, an AR specification
alone is not adequate to model producers' forecast of price
variance.
Following Engle [1982], we use an autoregressive conditional
heteroskedastic (ARCH) framework to model the time-varying variance
forecasts where changes in forecasts are induced by past information. In
particular:
(10b) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where equation (9) has been used to substitute for [e.sub.t-1] in
equation (10b). The specification in equation (10b) corresponds to an
exponential ARCH(l) model discussed in Harvey [1993, 275-80].(1) The
exponential ARCH or EARCH, proposed by Nelson [1991], has the advantage
of ensuring that [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is strictly positive
for all finite parameter values and price realizations.
Assuming Gaussian errors,(2) maximization of the following log
likelihood function (with omitted constants)
(10c) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
provides the maximum likelihood (ML) estimates of the parameters
[[Phi].sub.0], [[Phi].sub.1], [[Phi].sub.2], [a.sub.0], and [a.sub.1].
Estimation was undertaken using Kansas state-level wheat price data for
the period 1955 to 1982. The ML estimates of the parameters in equation
(10c) are reported in Table IV. Using these parameter estimates and the
expressions in equations (10a) and (10b), data on price moments for
1979-1982 - the four-year period for which data on other variables are
available - were generated.
The underlying assumption of the foregoing process of generating data
on price moments is that, in each period, the decision maker observes
past price realizations to form perceptions about price moments, which
are then taken as parameters in the optimal output choice problem. In
other words, the price moment formation is exogenous to the decision
problem in equation (6). Furthermore, since state-level time series on
wheat prices were used in estimating the parameters in equation (10c),
all producers in the sample were assumed to face the same price.
To determine the technology structure of sample producers, the
translog, generalized Leontief, quadratic and Cobb-Douglas production
functions were estimated using the firm-level data. The value of the
estimated log likelihood functions, with appropriate Jacobian
correction, and the number of parameters for each functional form are
presented in Table V.(3) Using Pollack and Wales's [1991]
likelihood dominance criterion for testing non-nested hypotheses, the
Cobb-Douglas (CD) was found to dominate the quadratic and generalized
Leontief functions. The same conclusion followed from Akaike's
information criterion of model selection. The Translog nests the CD as a
special case. The hypothesis that all the higher order terms in the
Translog function are jointly equal to zero was not rejected, suggesting
again that CD is the appropriate form. The following are CD production
and cost function estimation equations:
(11a) ln [Q.sub.it] = [[Beta].sub.0] + [[Beta].sub.1] ln
[x.sub.[1.sub.it]] + [[Beta].sub.2] ln [x.sub.[2.sub.it]] +
[[Epsilon].sub.1it]
(11b) ln [C.sub.it] = ln K + 1/([[Beta].sub.1] + [[Beta].sub.2])
[[[Beta].sub.1] ln [r.sub.lit] + [[Beta].sub.2] ln [r.sub.2it] + ln
[Q.sub.it]] + [[Epsilon].sub.2it]
where
K = [[[Beta].sub.0].sup.-(1/[[Beta].sub.1] + [[Beta].sub.2])]
[[([[Beta].sub.1]/[[Beta].sub.2]).sup.([[Beta].sub.2]/[[Beta].sub.1] +
[[Beta].sub.2])] + [([[Beta].sub.2]/[[Beta].sub.1]).sup.([[Beta].sub.1]/[[Beta].sub.1] + [[Beta].sub.2])]
TABLE IV
ML Estimates of Parameters of the Price Distribution
Parameter Estimate
(standard error)
Mean Parameter(*)
[[Phi].sub.0] 0.8579
(0.2268)
[[Phi].sub.1] 0.9121
(0.1102)
[[Phi].sub.2] -0.2334
(0.1290)
Variance Parameter(**)
[a.sub.0] -1.1572
(0.2858)
[a.sub.1] -0.9452
(0.6964)
* See equation (10a) in text.
** See equation (10b) in text.
[r.sub.k] is the price of the kth input, denoted by [x.sub.k], k = 1,
2, and subscripts i and t denote the ith producer and the tth time
period, respectively. Marginal cost structure corresponding to CD
technology was substituted for the term [C.sub.Q] in equation (8) to
yield the following estimation equation:
(11c) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where 0 on the left-hand side of equation (11c) denotes a vector of
zeros. The three equations, (11a), (11b) and (11c), were jointly
estimated as system of nonlinear equations, with correlated errors.
Since equations (11b) and (11c) contain endogenous elements, the
nonlinear three stage least squares (3SLS) procedure was adopted in
estimating equations (11a) through (11c), with the input prices and the
price moments being the exogenous variables in the system.
V. ESTIMATION RESULTS
The nonlinear 3SLS estimates of production technology
([[Beta].sub.0], [[Beta].sub.1], [[Beta].sub.2]) and utility function
([Theta], [Gamma]) parameters for all firms and for the two categories
are presented in Table VI. All parameter estimates are significant at
the 1% level. In particular, observe that the estimate of the utility
function parameter, [Mathematical Expression Omitted], is highly
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE V OMITTED] significant in each case, clearly
rejecting the null hypothesis of risk neutrality. The measure of risk
aversion, A [equivalent to] [U.sub.S]/[U.sub.M], evaluated at sample
means, shows that the degree of risk aversion does differ by producer
category and its pattern is consistent with decreasing absolute risk
aversion. Not unexpectedly, the null hypothesis of CARA preferences is
refuted for all firms and for the two categories in favor of DARA. Also,
the null hypothesis of a linear mean-standard deviation model,
[H.sub.0]: [Theta] = [Gamma] = 1, is clearly rejected in favor of a
nonlinear specification for all three categories.
The finding on the nature of relative risk aversion is less
homogeneous. In the case of small and all producers, [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] is positive and statistically significant at the 1%
level, suggesting a preference structure characterized by increasing
relative risk aversion. However, for large producers [Mathematical
Expression Omitted] is negative and the null hypothesis of constant
relative risk aversion, [H.sub.0]: ([Gamma] - [Theta]) = 0, is not
rejected. This finding that risk preferences vary by firm size
underscores the importance of a flexible utility structure. Under EP
utility, for example, this result would have been precluded since EP
does not admit constant relative risk aversion.
Our findings on relative risk aversion are, in the main, consistent
with the results in previous studies. It may be recalled from the
discussion in section I that the evidence on the nature of relative risk
aversion is mixed. Findings supporting decreasing (Cohn et al.),
constant (Szpiro), and increasing (Wolf and Pohlman) risk aversion have
been reported. It should be noted, however, that most prior studies have
not investigated whether the nature of relative risk aversion preference
differs according to wealth levels.
The estimate of A(M, S) furnishes an additional piece of information
that does not have its direct counterpart in the expected utility
framework. Under MSU, the derivative of A([center dot]) with respect to
S has the same sign as [Gamma]([Gamma] - 1). Under [Gamma] [greater
than] 0, [A.sub.S]([center dot]) conveys how aversion to risk changes as
the wealth distribution becomes more risky. It is evident from Table VI
that for all three categories [Gamma] is significantly greater than one
and, therefore, [A.sub.S]([center dot]) is positive. This accords with
intuition since individuals' aversion to risk is likely to increase
with increased volatility of wealth.
Turning now to technology parameters, observe that estimates suggest
returns to scale of 0.9238, 1.1961, and 0.9599 for all, small and large
firms, respectively. In each case constant returns to scale is rejected
at the 1% level of significance. Also, the technology parameters are
highly significant for all three categories.
Table VII contains the estimates and the standard errors of output
supply and input demand elasticities for all producers. The computation
method for these elasticities warrants a few comments. Even under as
simple a production technology as the CD, the first-order conditions in
equation (7) cannot be solved explicitly for optimal output level
[Q.sup.*]. The absence of a closed form solution precludes direct
estimation of the output supply function to recover the supply
elasticities with respect [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE VI OMITTED] to
[Mathematical Expression Omitted], r, or w. However, since the
functional forms as well as the parameters of the utility and production
functions have been estimated, the elasticities can be directly computed
from the analytical comparative static expressions. For example, optimal
output response to expected price is
(12) [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
where
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]
by the second-order sufficient condition of equation (6). All terms
in the right-hand side of equation (12) are known functions of the
parameter estimates [Mathematical Expression Omitted] and data
variables. For example, [U.sub.M] [equivalent to]
[Theta][M.sup.[Theta]-1], [U.sub.S] [equivalent to]
[Gamma][S.sup.[Gamma]-1], etc. Thus, one can directly compute
[Mathematical Expression Omitted] and hence the supply elasticity
[Mathematical Expression Omitted]. The standard error of the elasticity
can then be calculated from [Mathematical Expression Omitted] using the
delta method, since [Mathematical Expression Omitted] is a nonlinear
function of [Mathematical Expression Omitted].(4) This analytic
expression-based method was also adopted for computing the price
elasticities for inputs. The output supply and input demand elasticity
estimates (evaluated at the sample means) and their standard errors are
reported in Table VII. All elasticities have the expected signs and,
with few exceptions, are significant at the 1% level.
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE VII OMITTED]
To understand the inferential consequences of ignoring risk effects,
the first-order condition of profit maximization under certainty
(equating output price to marginal cost), the CD production and cost
functions were estimated as a system of equations using the same data
set. Using the certainty model parameter estimates, output supply and
input demand elasticities were computed. Note, under CD technology in a
risk-free setting the output supply and input demand elasticity
estimates follow directly from the production function parameter
estimates. For example, output supply elasticity in a risk free setting
is ([[Beta].sub.1] + [[Beta].sub.2])/(1 - [[Beta].sub.1] -
[[Beta].sub.2]). These estimates are presented in Table VIII.
The returns to scale estimates under the two settings show a
statistically significant difference (the t-statistic is 4.2463). More
importantly, it is evident from the comparison of output supply and
own-price input demand elasticities that ignoring risk effects yields a
substantially more elastic price response. The differences in elasticity
estimates are statistically significant at least at the 5% level. This
was found to be true also for the cross-price elasticities (which are
not reported in the interest of brevity). In models of uncertainty, any
parameter change has two effects on optimal choices: a direct or
"substitution" effect and an indirect or "income"
effect attributable to the change in wealth induced by the parameter
change as discussed, for example, in Chavas and Pope [1985]. The latter
effect is absent under certainty, risk neutrality or constant absolute
risk aversion. Since, in the empirical application, risk neutrality and
constant absolute risk aversion were clearly rejected, the difference in
the elasticity estimates under the two settings stems, in part, from the
[r.sub.1], [r.sub.2], and [Mathematical Expression Omitted]
change-induced wealth effects that are ignored in the risk-free setting.
The elasticity difference is also explained by the difference in the
estimates of technology parameters, [[Beta].sub.0], [[Beta].sub.1], and
[[Beta].sub.2], under the two settings.
Observe in Table VIII that the estimated standard errors for all
three technology parameters from the uncertainty model are about 50%
smaller than their counterparts in the risk-free setting. This suggests
that the joint estimation of technology and utility function parameters
may be more efficient than the separate estimation of technology.
VI. CONCLUDING COMMENTS
I have proposed a method for jointly estimating the degree or absence
of risk aversion, structure of risk preference, and production
technology in the nonlinear mean-standard deviation approach. I argue
that the Arrow-Pratt measures of risk aversion and commonly used utility
functional forms, including those in the HARA family, impose a priori
restrictions on risk preference. As an alternative, I propose a flexible
utility function in the nonlinear mean-standard deviation approach. This
utility function nests alternative risk preference structures, including
risk neutrality, as refutable special cases. The method was applied to a
competitive firm model under price risk. Empirical [TABULAR DATA FOR
TABLE VIII OMITTED] estimation used farm-level data from Kansas. The
findings suggest that Kansas producers' risk preferences are
characterized by decreasing absolute risk aversion and that the nature
of relative risk aversion varies by size category. While small firms are
found to exhibit increasing relative risk aversion, the null hypothesis
of constant relative risk aversion is not refuted in the case of large
firms. Despite its ubiquity in applied research, the linear
mean-variance framework is also unambiguously refuted.
Finally, evidence suggests that ignoring risk and risk preference can
result in substantially overestimated supply and demand elasticities. I
hasten to add, however, that given the relatively small sample size,
caution is warranted in drawing general conclusions from these findings.
Further research, especially with larger data sets, can ascertain
whether the same conclusion holds for finns in other industries and for
other technologies. I believe that the main contributions of the present
study lie not in its findings but in suggesting a flexible utility
function and in proposing a general, yet tractable, empirical framework
for the joint estimation of technology and risk preferences. It is hoped
that the proposed utility function and estimation procedure will find
other applications in emerging areas of the risk literature. In
particular, extending the analytical and the empirical model to the
multi-output firm setting may provide further insights.
ABBREVIATIONS
NIARA: Non-increasing absolute risk aversion HARA: Hyperbolic
absolute risk aversion EP: Expo-power utility function MSU:
Mean-standard deviation utility function CD: Cobb-Douglas production
function
I wish to thank two anonymous referees for their useful suggestions,
Arthur Havenner for his insightful comments and Larry Langemeier for
providing the data set used in the paper.
1. Higher order ARCH models were also estimated. But these models
were dominated by the ARCH(1) specification under standard model
selection criteria.
2. Test for normality of the price distribution was conducted using
Kansas state-level prices for 1955 through 1982. The test procedure is
described in Kiefer and Salmon [1983]. The Waid [[Chi].sup.2] test
statistic (for the null hypothesis of normality) was 3.454 (P-value =
0.179), not rejecting the null.
3. The dependent variable in the translog and Cobb-Douglas
specifications is log of output, log([Q.sub.i]), whereas in the
quadratic and generalized Leontief specifications it is output,
[Q.sub.i]. Therefore, the Jacobian term, [Sigma] log (1/[Q.sub.i]), was
added to the translog and Cobb-Douglas log likelihood values, ensuring
comparability across specifications.
4. If F[[Omega]] denotes a function of the parameter vector [Omega],
the variance-covariance matrix of F[[Omega]] is approximated by
[G.sup.T] V[[Omega]]G, where [Mathematical Expression Omitted],
V[[Omega]] is the variance-covariance matrix of [Omega], and T denotes
transpose.
REFERENCES
Arrow, K. J. "The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation
of Risk Bearing." Review of Economic Studies, April 1964, 91-6.
Batra, R. N., and A. Ullah. "The Competitive Firm and the Theory
of Input Demand under Price Uncertainty." Journal of Political
Economy, May/June 1974, 537-48.
Bellante, D., and R. P. Saba. "Human Capital and Life-Cycle
Effects on Risk Aversion." Journal of Financial Resources, Spring
1986, 41-51.
Box, G. E. P., and G. M. Jenkins. Time Series Analysis: Forecasting
and Control. San Francisco: Holden-Day, 1976.
Chavas, J. P., and M. T. Holt. "Acreage Decisions under Risk:
The Case of Corn and Soybeans." American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, August 1990, 529-38.
Chavas, J. P., and R. Pope. "Price Uncertainty and Competitive
Firm Behavior: Testable Hypotheses from Expected Utility
Maximization." Journal of Economics and Business, August 1985,
223-35.
Cohn, R. A., W. G. Lewellen, R. C. Lease, and G. G. Schlarbaum.
"Individual Investor Risk Aversion and Investment Portfolio
Composition." Journal of Finance, May 1975, 605-20.
Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller. "Distribution of the Estimators
for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root." Journal of the
American Statistical Association, June 1979, 427-31.
Engle, R. F. "Autoregressive Conditionally Heteroskedasticity
with Estimates of the Variance of UK Inflation." Econometrica, July
1982, 987-1008.
Evenson, R. E., and W. E. Huffman. "State Level Data Set for
U.S. Agriculture, 1949-1982." Yale University, New Haven, Conn.:
1986.
Fisher, I. The Nature of Capital and Income. London: Macmillan, 1906.
Friend, I., and M. E. Blume. "The Demand for Risky Assets"
American Economic Review, December 1975, 900-22.
Hansen, L. P., and K. J. Singleton. "Stochastic Consumption,
Risk Aversion, and the Temporal Behavior of Asset Returns." Journal
of Political Economy, April 1983, 249-65.
Harvey, A. C. Time Series Models. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1993.
Kiefer, N., and M. Salmon. "Testing Normality in Econometric Models." Economics Letters, June 1983, 123-28.
Landskroner, Y. "Nonmarketable Assets and the Determinants of
the Market Price of Risk" Review of Economic Studies, November
1977, 482-514.
Langemeier, L. N. "Farm Management Data Bank
Documentation." Department of Agricultural Economics Staff Paper
No. 90-10, Kansas State University, April 1990.
Love, A., and S. T. Buccola. "Joint Risk Preference-Technology
Estimation with a Primal System." American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, August 1991, 765-74.
Markowitz, H. "Portfolio Selection." Journal of Finance,
March 1952, 77-91.
Merton, R. C. "Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a
Continuous-Time Model." Journal of Economic Theory, December 1971,
373-413.
Meyer, J. "Two-Moment Decision Models and Expected Utility
Maximization" American Economic Review, June 1987, 421-30.
Morin, R. A., and A. F. Suarez. "Risk Aversion Revisited."
Journal of Finance, September 1983, 1201-16.
Nelson, D. B. "Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns:
A New Approach." Econometrica, March 1991, 347-70.
Nerlove, M., D. Grether, and J. L. Carvalho. Analysis of Economic
Time Series: A Synthesis. New York: Academic Press, 1979.
Pollak, R. A., and T. J. Wales. "The Likelihood Dominance
Criterion, A New Approach to Model Selection." Journal of
Econometrics, February/March 1991, 227-42.
Pope, R. D. "The Generalized Envelope Theorem and Price
Uncertainty." International Economic Review, February 1980, 75-86.
Pope, R. D., and R. E. Just. "On Testing the Structure of Risk
Preferences in Agricultural Supply Analysis." American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, August 1991, 743-8.
Rosenzweig, M. R., and H. P. Binswanger "Wealth, Weather Risk
and the Composition and Profitability of Agricultural Investments."
The Economic Journal, January 1993, 56-78.
Saha, A. "Expo-Power Utility: A 'Flexible' Form for
Absolute and Relative Risk Aversion." American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, November 1993, 905-13.
Saha, A., C. R. Shumway, and H. Talpaz. "Joint Estimation of
Risk Preference Structure and Technology Using Expo-Power Utility."
American Journal of Agricultural Economics, May 1994, 173-84.
Sandmo, A. "The Effect of Uncertainty on Savings
Decisions." Review of Economic Studies, July 1970, 353-60.
-----. "On the Theory of the Competitive Firm under Price
Uncertainty." American Economic Review, March 1971, 65-73.
-----. "Portfolio Theory, Asset Demand and Taxation: Comparative
Statics with Many Assets." Review of Economic Studies, June 1977,
369-79.
Siegel, F. W., and J. P. Hoban, Jr. "Relative Risk Aversion
Revisited" Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1982, 481-7.
Sinn, H. W. Economic Decisions under Uncertainty. 2nd edition.
Amsterdam, New York, and Oxford: North Holland Publishing Company, 1983.
Szpiro, G. G. "Measuring Risk Aversion: An Alternative
Approach." Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1986,
156-9.
Tobin, J. "Liquidity Preference as Behavior Towards Risk"
Review of Economic Studies, 67, 1958, 1-26. Reprinted in Risk Aversion
and Portfolio Choice, edited by D. D. Hester and J. Tobin, 1967, 242-71.
U.S. Department of Agriculture Agricultural Prices. Washington, D.C.:
annual series.
-----. Agricultural Statistics. Washington, D.C.: annual series.
-----. Field Crops Production, Disposition and Value. Washington,
D.C.: annual series.
-----. State Farm Income and Balance Sheet Statistics. Washington,
D.C.: annual series.
U.S. Department of Commerce. Statistical Abstract of the United
States. Washington, D.C.: Bureau of the Census, annual series.
-----. Agricultural Statistics. Washington, D.C.: annual series.
-----. Field Crops Production, Disposition and Value. Washington,
D.C.: annual series.
-----. State Farm Income and Balance Sheet Statistics. Washington,
D.C.: annual series.
Weins, T. B. "Peasant Risk Aversion and Allocative Behavior: A
Quadratic Programming Experiment." American Journal of Agricultural
Economics, November 1976, 629-35.
Wolf, C., and L. Pohlman. "The Recovery of Risk Preferences from
Actual Choices." Econometrica, May 1983, 843-50.
Saha: Senior Economist, Micronomics Inc., Los Angeles Calif., Phone
1-213-629-2655, Fax 1-213-688-8899 E-mail
[email protected]