Fiscal structures and economic growth: international evidence.
Miller, Stephen M. ; Russek, Frank S.
I. INTRODUCTION
A large and growing body of literature searches for the determinants
of economic growth employing cross-country regression analysis (e.g.,
Kormendi and Meguire [1985], Grier and Tullock [1989], Barro [1990;
1991; 1992], Romer [1989; 1990], Levine [1991], and Levine and Renelt
[1992]).(1) The cross-country regression approach implicitly assumes
that the growth process possesses similar structural properties across
the countries in the sample. Structural differences, be they political,
economic, social, or other, between countries, therefore, do not
condition the growth process. Or if they do, then the effects are
randomly distributed with zero mean. If structural differences between
countries do matter significantly and non-randomly in the growth
process, then the existing cross-country research is potentially flawed.
Attempts are sometimes made to control for such differences by including
dummy variables for different regions of the world (e.g., dummy
variables for African, Latin American, and other groups of countries).
Within the literature on the determinants of economic growth, some
papers (e.g., Landau [1983; 1985; 1986], Kormendi and Meguire [1985],
Ram [1986], Koester and Kormendi [1989], Barth, Keleher, and Russek
[1990], Easterly and Rebelo [1993], and Fischer [1993]) consider the
effects, if any, of government expenditure and revenue on economic
growth. Overall, the findings of these studies paint a mixed picture;
the relationship between growth and government is sometimes significant
and positive, sometimes significant and negative, and sometimes not
significant. Although these studies consider many different fiscal
variables, they do not as a rule examine the effects of these fiscal
variables in a systematic way that controls for the mode of financing.
They generally overlook, for example, how an increase in government
consumption expenditure is financed. Is it with higher taxes, and which
taxes? Or is it with lower spending, and which spending? Finally, is it
with a larger deficit? Controlling for these factors may lead to
different findings about the effect of an increase in government
consumption expenditure on economic growth.
Borrowing from some work on the effect of fiscal structure on
national economic growth within the United States in Helms [1985],
Mofidi and Stone [1990], and Miller and Russek [1993], we introduce the
government budget constraint into the regression equations that examine
the determinants of economic growth. As a result, we directly address
the three financing questions raised in the previous paragraph. In this
framework, we consider the growth process using pooled times-series,
cross-section data and comparing the results from fixed- and
random-effects econometric techniques.(2) These techniques attempt to
accommodate structural differences between countries and across time. We
also compare the performance of the more-standard ordinary least squares
regression approach with that of the fixed- and random-effect models.
II. AN OVERVIEW OF INTERNATIONAL FISCAL STRUCTURES
Before presenting our model and statistical findings, a brief
overview of the growth and fiscal characteristics of the countries in
our sample provides some additional information for those not familiar
with the data, which otherwise would not be revealed by our analysis.(3)
This information can contribute in a limited way to the debate about the
effects of government on economic growth, although it is not a
substitute for modeling the growth process.
For the sample as a whole, the growth rate of real per capita gross
domestic product (GDP) averaged 1.35% per year during 1975 to 1984, with
a coefficient of variation of 3.52. By comparison, the average growth
rate in the United States was 1.45%. The five fastest growth countries
were Botswana (6.72), Indonesia (4.19), Korea (6.32), Sri Lanka (3.20),
and Thailand (4.31). The five slowest growth countries were El Salvador (-1.74), Iran (-2.16), Liberia (-2.78), Venezuela (-2.21), and Zambia
(-3.33).
The average fiscal position of the countries in our sample was a
deficit relative to GDP of 2.71%, with a coefficient of variation of
1.72. This average was slightly less than the 2.78% average deficit
experienced by the United States. The five countries with the worst
fiscal positions were Belgium (7.95), Israel (11.27), Morocco (10.71),
Sri Lanka (9.52), and Zambia (9.78). Nine countries had surpluses
instead of deficits, with the largest five surpluses relative to GDP
appearing in Botswana (5.56), Brazil (3.16), Luxembourg (1.61),
Swaziland (2.19), and Venezuela (3.05).
Total central government revenue averaged 28.3% of GDP, with a
coefficient of variation of 0.39. The five countries with the highest
revenue-GDP ratios were Belgium (43.74), Botswana (44.64), Israel
(59.81), Luxembourg (48.92), and the Netherlands (49.81). Eight
countries had ratios below 20%. The five with the lowest were Costa Rica
(18.69), El Salvador (13.26), Korea (17.26), Paraguay (11.08), and
Thailand (14.18).
Finally, total central government expenditure averaged 31.01% of GDP,
with a coefficient of variation of 0.39. The five countries with the
highest spending-GDP ratios were Belgium (51.69), France (39.89), Israel
(71.08), Luxembourg (47.31), and the Netherlands (53.15). The five with
the lowest were Brazil (19.93), El Salvador (16.12), Korea (16.58),
Paraguay (10.94), and Thailand (17.80). These were also the only
countries with spending less than 20% of GDP.
The largest share of total revenue, on average, was collected as
revenue from domestic taxes on goods and services (24.55%). In
descending order of quantitative importance, the other six sources of
revenue are individual income tax revenue (16.48), non-tax revenue
(15.34), social security tax revenue (14.57), international trade tax
revenue (13.24), corporate income tax revenue (11.17), and all other tax
revenue (4.65). Of these, the ones with the largest and smallest
coefficients of variation, respectively, were corporate income tax
revenue (1.15) and revenue from domestic taxes on goods and services
(0.52).
The largest share of total spending, on average, was allocated to
social security and welfare (23.61%). In descending order of
quantitative importance, the other six categories of spending are other
expenditure (20.32), economic affairs and services expenditure (19.12),
education expenditure (12.10), defense expenditure (9.32), health
expenditure (7.86), and transportation and communication expenditure
(7.67). Of these, the ones with the largest and smallest coefficients of
variation, respectively, were defense expenditure (0.88), and education
(0.50) and economic affairs and services (0.50) expenditures.
III. THE MODEL AND ECONOMETRIC METHOD
Our modeling of national economic growth borrows from some work on
state and local economic growth within the United States in Helms
[1985], Mofidi and Stone [1990], and Miller and Russek [1993]. We begin
by defining the growth rate of gross domestic product per capita (g) as
follows:
(1) [g.sub.ct] = ln[y.sub.ct] - ln[y.sub.ct-1],
where y is real gross domestic product per capita, ln is the natural
logarithm operator, and c and t indicate the country and time period.
Let [X.sub.ct] = ([[x.sup.1].sub.ct], [[x.sup.2].sub.ct], ...
[[x.sup.n].sub.ct]) represent those observable factors (e.g.,
investment, tax and spending patterns, and so on) that can influence
national economic growth. Thus, we model national economic growth as
follows:
(2) [g.sub.ct] = [Alpha] + [summation over] [[Beta].sub.i]
[[x.sup.i].sub.ct] where i = 1 to n + [v.sub.ct].
where [v.sub.ct] is the error term.
The error term [v.sub.ct] incorporates the influences of omitted
variables. Classical regression analysis assumes that omitted variables
are independent of the included [x.sub.ct] and are independently and
identically distributed. When using pooled cross-section, time-series
data, however, the omitted variables can be further classified into
three groups - country-varying, time-invariant; time-varying,
country-invariant; and country- and time-varying variables.(4) The
country-varying, time-invariant variables differ across countries, but
are constant within a given country over time (i.e., [C.sub.c] give
essentially constant country-specific information). Time-varying,
country-invariant variables differ over time, but are constant at a
point in time across countries (i.e., [T.sub.t] give essentially
constant time-specific information). Examples of the former variables
include geography and climate, while examples of the latter include
world economic conditions such as Euro interest rates. Finally, the
country- and time-varying variables differ across both countries and
time. Thus, the error term [v.sub.ct] can be written as follows:
(3) [v.sub.ct] = [Delta][C.sub.c] + [Mu][T.sub.t] + [[Phi].sub.ct],
where [Delta] and [Mu] measure the effects of [C.sub.c] and [T.sub.t]
on [v.sub.ct].
Substituting equation (3) into (2) gives the following:
(4) [g.sub.ct] = [Alpha] + [summation over]
[[Beta].sub.i][[x.sup.i].sub.ct] where i=1 to n + [Delta][C.sub.c]
[Mu][T.sub.t] + [[Phi].sub.ct],
Estimation of equation (4) with ordinary least squares and without
consideration of possible country-specific or time-specific effects can
lead to serious errors. Hsiao [1986, 7] provides illustrations of
misleading results. Problems emerge when either the unobservable
country-specific or time-specific variables correlate with the included
variables [x.sub.ct]. Two alternative, but related, approaches exist for
addressing these problems - fixed- and random-effect models.
Fixed-Effect Models
Suppose that omitted country-specific variables that are correlated
with the included [x.sub.ct] constitute the problem. Then adjusting the
dependent and independent variables by subtracting the mean of each
variable over time solves the problem.(5) Since the unobserved
country-specific variables and the intercept do not change over time,
the subtraction of their respective means over time drops these
variables out of the regression equation. If this is the only problem in
the estimation of equation (4), then the regression adjusted for the
means across time provides unbiased and consistent estimates of
[[Beta].sub.1]. Without this adjustment, the ordinary least squares
estimates are biased and inconsistent.
Similarly, if time-specific variables correlate with the included
[x.sub.ct], then a similar solution adjusts the dependent and
independent variables by subtracting the mean of each variable over
countries. Since each country faces the same time-specific effects,
subtracting the means over countries drops the intercept and the
time-specific effects out of the revised regression equation. Once
again, the revised regression provides unbiased and consistent estimates
of [[Beta].sub.i].
Of course, both country- and time-specific effects may correlate with
the included [x.sub.ct]. In this case, we can adjust for the means over
countries and time.
Random-Effect Models
The fixed-effect model assumes that the differences across units -
either countries or time - reflect parametric shifts in the regression
function. Such a view becomes more appropriate when the problem uses the
whole population rather than a sample from it. If the problem examines
only a sample from a larger population, then the fixed-effect model can
be properly interpreted as applying only to the differences within that
sample. Our problem considers a sample of countries. Therefore, the
random-effect model needs consideration.
Random-effect models treat the country-specific ([e.sub.c]) and
time-specific ([e.sub.t]) effects as random variables. Thus, the error
term [v.sub.ct] is viewed as having three random components - [e.sub.c],
[e.sub.t], and [[Epsilon].sub.ct]. These error terms have the following
properties:
(5) E [e.sub.c] = E [e.sub.t] = E [[Epsilon].sub.ct] = 0;
E [e.sub.c] [e.sub.t] = E [e.sub.c] [[Epsilon].sub.ct] = E [e.sub.t]
[[Epsilon].sub.ct] = 0;
E [e.sub.c] [e.sub.i] = [[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.C], if c = i; 0
otherwise;
E [e.sub.t] [e.sub.j] = [[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.T], if t = j; 0
otherwise;
E [[Epsilon].sub.ct] [[Epsilon].sub.ij] =
[[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.[Epsilon]], if c = i
and t = j; 0 otherwise; and [e.sub.c], [e.sub.t],
and [[Epsilon].sub.ct] are each uncorrelated with [x.sub.ct].
The variance of the growth rate of real per capita GDP conditional on
the explanatory variables is given from equation (4) as follows:
(6) [[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.G] = [[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.C] +
[[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.T] + [[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.[Epsilon]],
where [[[Sigma].sup.2].sub.G] is the variance of the growth rate of
gross domestic product per capita left unexplained by the explanatory
variables [x.sub.ct]. As a consequence, this formulation - the
random-effect model - is frequently called a variance-components
(error-components) model.
If we know the variance components, then the estimation of the
random-effect model using generalized least squares (GLS) merely
requires the transformation of the dependent and independent variables
using the variance components in the appropriate way. Absent knowledge
of the variance components, then we must first provide estimates of
these components and apply a feasible GLS procedure to estimate the
equation.
The Government Budget Constraint and the Interpretation of Results
As discussed above, our method borrows from the empirical literature
on the effect of state and local government taxes and spending on state
and local economic growth within the United States. That research
presents a mixed picture; no consensus exists even on the signs of the
effects. Helms [1985, 577] provides a rationale for the divergent
results - "... it is not meaningful to evaluate the effects of tax
or expenditure changes in isolation: both the sources and uses of funds
must be considered." In other words, the regression equations need
to include all but one of the possibilities for sources and uses -
various revenues, various expenditures, and the surplus. Some uses may
raise growth when associated with some sources, but not when associated
with others.
We generate a taxonomy of results by excluding, in turn, different
revenue and expenditure categories and the surplus from the regression
equations. This approach follows the work of Miller and Russek [1993] on
state and local economic growth.(6) This more thorough analysis deals
explicitly with the overall fiscal structure and may lead to findings
not revealed by the more limited approach of including fiscal variables
on a more ad hoc basis, as has been the norm in the cross-country growth
literature to date.
IV. REGRESSION EQUATIONS AND HYPOTHESES
Our regression equations fall into two distinct categories -
equations that do not disaggregate total revenue and expenditure and
equations that do. Each of these two sets of regressions includes a set
of conditioning variables that have been found to be important in other
cross-country growth regressions, including lagged real per capita GDP,
the rate of growth of population, the investment share of GDP, the
import plus export share of GDP, and the GDP implicit price deflator inflation rate. These two types of regression equations are given as
follows:
(7) [g.sub.ct] = [a.sub.1] + [a.sub.2][y.sub.ct-1] + [a.sub.3]
[n.sub.ct]
+ [a.sub.4] [inv.sub.ct] + [a.sub.5] [opn.sub.ct] + [a.sub.6]
[p.sub.ct]
+ [a.sub.7] [rev.sub.ct] + [a.sub.8] [exp.sub.ct] + [a.sub.9]
[sur.sub.ct] + [v.sub.ct],
and
(8) [g.sub.ct] = [b.sub.1] + [b.sub.2][y.sub.ct-1] + [b.sub.3]
[n.sub.ct]
+ [b.sub.4] [inv.sub.ct] + [b.sub.5] [opn.sub.ct] + [b.sub.6]
[p.sub.ct]
+ [b.sub.7] [rci.sub.ct] + [b.sub.8] [rii.sub.ct] + [b.sub.9]
[rss.sub.ct]
+ [b.sub.10] [rdgs.sub.ct] + [b.sub.11] [rtrd.sub.ct] + [b.sub.12]
[rot.sub.ct]
+ [b.sub.13] [rnt.sub.ct] + [b.sub.14] [edfs.sub.ct] + [b.sub.15]
[eed.sub.ct]
+ [b.sub.16] [ehlh.sub.ct] + [b.sub.17] [ess.sub.ct] + [b.sub.18]
[eeas.sub.ct]
+ [b.sub.19] [etc.sub.ct] + [b.sub.20] [eoe.sub.ct] + [b.sub.21]
[sur.sub.ct] + [v.sub.ct],
where g is the growth rate of real per capita GDP, y is real per
capita GDP, n is the rate of growth of population, inv is the investment
share of GDP, opn is the import plus export share of GDP, p is the GDP
implicit price deflator rate of inflation, rev is total government
revenue to GDP, exp is total government expenditure to GDP, sur is the
government surplus to GDP (i.e., rev - exp), tci is corporate income tax
revenue to GDP, rii is individual income tax revenue to GDP, rss is
social-security tax revenue to GDP, rdgs is domestic goods and services
tax revenue to GDP, rtrd is international trade tax revenue to GDP, rot
is other tax revenue to GDP, rnt is non-tax revenue to GDP, edfs is
defense expenditure to GDP, eed is education expenditure to GDP, ehlh is
health expenditure to GDP, ess is social-security and welfare
expenditure to GDP, eeas is economic affairs and service expenditure to
GDP, etc is transportation and communication expenditure to GDP, and eoe
is other expenditure to GDP.
How do we interpret the coefficients on the fiscal variables in these
two equations? Consider the revenue, expenditure, and surplus
coefficients ([a.sub.7], [a.sub.8], and [a.sub.9]) in equation (7).
Because of the underlying identity, only two of these coefficients can
be estimated in the same regression, the third is automatically implied.
Moreover, at least two of the variables associated with these
coefficients must be included to control for the sources and uses of
funds. Excluding sur allows the surplus to change freely and the
coefficient [a.sub.7] measures the effect on economic growth of an
increase in the revenue share of GDP, assuming no change in the
expenditure share. In other words, the additional revenue reduces
(increases) the deficit (surplus). Similarly, [a.sub.8] measures the
effect of an increase in the government expenditure share of GDP,
assuming no change in revenue relative to GDP. Of course, this implies
that the expenditure was debt-financed. Excluding rev or exp from
equation (7) rather than the sur implies that [a.sub.9] measures the
effect on economic growth of an increase in the surplus financed by a
change in the excluded variable. Thus, it does not matter which of the
three variables is excluded, so long as only one is excluded.
Similar interpretations carry over to equation (8), where the
components of revenue and expenditure appear instead of the aggregates.
Excluding sur causes the corporate income tax coefficient [b.sub.7] to
measure the effect on economic growth of an increase in the surplus
financed entirely by an increase in corporate tax revenue relative to
GDP. Similarly, [b.sub.14] measures the effect on economic growth of a
debt-financed increase in defense spending relative to GDP. If this
increase in defense spending were instead financed by an increase in
corporate taxes relative to GDP, then the effect on economic growth is
measured by the sum of [b.sub.7] and [b.sub.14], assuming no change in
the government surplus.
In sum, three regression results for equation (7) can be calculated
for the cases where rev, exp, and sur are deleted in turn. Fifteen
regression results for equation (8) can be calculated for the cases
where individual revenue items, individual expenditure items, and sur
are deleted in turn. In fact, only two independent regression equations
exist - one for equation (7) and one for equation (8). We report only
the regression results that eliminate the surplus.(7)
The specifications shown for equations (7) and (8) were modified in
several ways before estimation to develop a richer and more robust set
of findings. Some concern may emerge that when we use annual data
instead of data averaged over time, the fiscal coefficients in equations
(7) and (8) capture cyclical rather than long-term trend effects. This
issue is difficult to address fully because of the constraints imposed
by our sample coverage.(8) Nevertheless, we adopt the strategy of adding
the lagged value of the dependent variable as another regressor. With
this modification, the long-run effects are gauged by dividing the
fiscal coefficient estimates by one minus the coefficient of the lagged
dependent variable.
The commingling of information from developed and developing
countries may also appear troublesome to some, especially if the
determinants of economic growth differ over different stages of
development. Consequently, we break our sample into developed and
developing countries and redo all the econometric work. These new
findings are reported alongside the results for the full (all-country)
sample.(9)
Finally, because of the interaction between government budgets and
economic conditions, one criticism of these equations - and of most of
the existing literature - is that variations in growth may be
incorrectly attributed to variations in fiscal variables when
correlations exist without causation. As one attempt to address this
issue, we estimate equations (7) and (8) using once-lagged values of all
fiscal variables.(10)
V. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
All specifications of equations (7) and (8) discussed above were
estimated with fixed-and random-effect models, in addition to ordinary
least squares (OLS) estimation.(11) Then, three tests were used to
determine the appropriate specification in each case. An F-test compares
the fixed-effect model and the OLS model as in Greene [1990, 484]. A
Lagrange-Multiplier test due to Breusch and Pagan [1980] compares the
random-effect model with the OLS model as in Greene [1990, 49192]. And a
Wald criterion due to Hausman [1978] compares the random-effect model
with the fixed-effect model as in Greene [1990, 495].
The tests of alternative specifications convey a generally consistent
story, at least for the fixed- and random-effect models that account for
differences between countries and over time. In all cases, the
fixed-effect model dominates the OLS model; the random-effect model does
not. In addition, the fixed-effect model dominates the random-effect
model specified between countries and over time. The one anomaly is that
the random-effect model occasionally dominates the fixed-effect [TABULAR
DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] model when changes over time are not isolated.
This occasional inconsistency in the three tests may suggest that the
fixed-effect model between countries alone is sometimes misspecified.
Thus, we report in Tables I and II only the fixed-effect models between
countries and over time.(12)
Several findings stand out.(13) The non-fiscal (conditioning)
variables tell a generally consistent story, and a story reasonably
consistent with the existing literature. First, the coefficient of
lagged real per capita GDP is significantly negative in all regressions,
supporting the conditional convergence hypothesis.(14) Second, the
investment share of GDP is significantly positive in all cases. Levine
and Renelt [1992] report this result as a "robust" finding,
appearing consistently across the empirical studies of the determinants
of economic [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] growth. Third, the
inflation rate generally has a significant negative effect, although
sometimes this effect is not significant.(15) Fischer [1993] finds a
significant negative effect. While Levine and Renelt [1992] find the
inflation rate effect to be fragile; they do find it to be consistently
negative. Other authors such as Kormendi and Meguire [1985] and Grier
and Tullock [1989] report some evidence of a negative effect of
inflation on economic growth. Grier and Tullock's strongest
evidence is for the African countries, a few of which are in our sample.
When spending and taxes are disaggregated, however, the significant
negative effect only emerges for developing countries; developed
countries' growth rates are not significantly affected by
inflation. Finally, the population growth and openness (imports plus
exports to GDP) variables have coefficients that are negative and
positive, respectively, but generally insignificant. A negative sign for
the coefficient of population implies that real output growth adjusts at
less than one-to-one with population growth. Levine and Renelt [1992]
report a robust positive effect of a country's openness on the
investment share of GDP; the effect of openness on real per capita
growth was fragile, but positive.
Focusing on the effects of aggregate taxes and spending for the
all-country results, several observations emerge. First, the effect of
government expenditure on economic growth depends crucially on the
method of financing. Tax-financed increases in government expenditure
stimulate economic growth (i.e., the positive coefficient of government
revenue significantly exceeds in absolute value the negative coefficient
of government expenditure), while debt-financed increases in government
expenditure retard economic growth. Second, reducing the government
deficit stimulates economic growth. Reducing expenditure while holding
revenue constant (i.e., a lower government deficit) or increasing
revenue while holding expenditure constant (i.e., also a lower
government deficit) both stimulate economic growth. Moreover, the
tax-financed reduction in the government deficit has a larger effect
than the expenditure-financed reduction. Both Easterly and Rebelo [1993]
and Fischer [1993] report similar findings.
The effects of aggregate government spending and revenue differ
between the developed and developing country regressions. A
debt-financed increase in government spending produces a significant
decrease in economic growth for developing countries, but an
insignificant effect for developed countries. On the other hand,
substituting revenue for debt issue significantly increases economic
growth in developing countries, but reduces growth in developed
countries. Finally, a revenue-financed increase in government spending
increases the real per capita growth rate in developing countries, but
reduces growth in developed countries. These findings argue for more
tax-financed government spending in developing countries, but for less
tax-financed spending in developed countries.
When we disaggregate government spending and taxes into their
component parts, other interesting findings emerge. First, debt-financed
increases in defense spending generally reduce economic growth for
developing countries across all specifications, but increase growth for
developed countries in those regressions that include lagged fiscal
variables. Second, a debt-financed increase in education spending raises
economic growth in developed countries across all specifications, but
reduces growth in developing countries, according to the specification
that uses contemporaneous fiscal variables. Third, a debt-financed
increase in health spending or social security spending reduces economic
growth in developing countries according to all specifications, but
generally has no significant effect in developed countries, although the
sign is negative.
VI. CONCLUSION
We examine the effects of national fiscal structures on national
economic growth, using an international sample of developed and
developing countries and alternative econometric techniques. We adopt
the method of Helms [1985], Mofidi and Stone [1990], and Miller and
Russek [1993], who considered the determinants of state and local
economic growth in the United States. The approach incorporates the
government budget constraint into the growth regressions so that we can
clearly identify how a particular change in fiscal policy is financed
(e.g., the effect of a debt-financed increase in defense spending).
We can succinctly state our findings concerning the effects of fiscal
structure on economic growth. First, the method of financing government
expenditure plays an important role in determining the effect of that
expenditure on economic growth. We find that for developing countries,
debt-financed increases in government expenditure retard economic growth
and tax-financed increases lead to higher growth, while for developed
countries, debt-financed increases in government expenditure do not
affect economic growth and tax-financed increases lead to lower growth.
The differences between these developed and developing country results
may reflect differences in the effect of money-financed and
bond-financed spending increases. If developing countries when faced
with the need to debt-finance spending more frequently use money rather
than bonds, then these differences suggest that money-financed spending
retards economic growth while bond-financed spending does not. Of
course, we have not examined this issue. Future research may follow this
path.
Second, different expenditure categories affect growth differently.
Debt-financed increases in defense, health, and social security and
welfare expenditures retard growth in developing countries. On the other
hand, debt-financed increases in education expenditure stimulate growth
in developed countries. Such findings may suggest that defense, health,
and social security and welfare expenditures represent too large a share
of the government budget in developing countries while education
expenditure represents too small a share of the government budget in
developed countries, at least when considering economic growth. Future
research may want to consider whether for particular expenditure
categories optimal shares of government expenditure exist for promoting
economic growth.
Before closing, one caveat needs mention. Examination of the
literature on the determinants of growth strongly suggests that any one
study does not make a case. Results are sensitive to the variables
included as noted by Levine and Renelt [1992] as well as to the
countries and time periods covered as noted by Clark [1993].
APPENDIX
Our data come from two sources. First, we use information on real and
nominal gross domestic product, population, imports and exports of goods
and non-financial services, gross domestic investment, and the base year
PPP convergence factor from 1975 to 1984, which come from the World Bank
data tape. Second, we use information on central government revenue and
spending from 1975 to 1984, which was compiled by the International
Monetary Fund and distributed in the Government Finance Statistics (GFS)
data tape. Revenue categories include total revenue and grants; income,
profit, and capital gains tax revenue broken out by corporate and
individual classes; social-security tax revenue; domestic taxes on goods
and service revenue; international trade tax revenue; and total tax
revenue. From these items, we construct as residuals other tax and
non-tax revenue. Expenditure categories include total expenditure;
defense expenditure; education expenditure; health expenditure;
social-security and welfare expenditure; economic affairs and services
expenditure; and transportation and communication expenditure. We
construct as a residual other expenditure.
Preliminary examination of the GFS data suggested that only 44
countries had the detailed information identified in the previous
paragraph. Moreover, this data for these countries had to be restricted
to 1975 to 1984. After downloading the data, we discovered that Cyprus,
the Solomon Islands, and Uganda were missing one of the needed data
series for at least part of the sample period. These countries were
deleted from the sample. Finally, after examining the summary
statistics, we discovered two additional countries with problems in the
other tax and other expenditure variables. Mexico collects taxes on
behalf of state governments. This money is rebated to state governments.
Thus, our constructed other tax revenue variable turned out to be
negative for Mexico. In the Philippines, the data are adjusted to a cash
basis between the reporting of expenditure sub-categories and total
expenditure. Thus, the other expenditure category in the Philippines was
negative. We deleted both Mexico and the Philippines from our final
sample.
Finally, as noted by Easterly and Rebelo [1993], who also use the GFS
data, this data possess two additional shortcomings. One, few countries
provide information on revenue and expenditure of local governments or
public enterprises. Thus, we use central government data, as do Easterly
and Rebelo. Even here, our country coverage and time series length is
restricted because of the break-out of expenditure and revenue
categories; many countries do not report sufficient detail for our
interest. Two, the IMF's data are sometimes based on budget data.
An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 1993 Western
Economic Association meetings in Lake Tahoe. We acknowledge the helpful
comments of Mark Wohar, the discussant at the Western meetings. This
early version was also presented at the University at Auckland and the
University of Sydney. This paper was most recently presented at the 1995
Finance and Macroeconomics Meetings at Taichung, Taiwan. The views
expressed are the authors', and do not necessarily reflect those of
the Congressional Budget Office or its staff.
1. Typically, the data for each country are averaged over the
time-series sample (e.g., the average growth rate of real gross domestic
product per capita for a number of years).
2. Grier and Tullock [1989] and Barro [1992] come the closest to our
method. Both divide their samples into five-year subperiods and
calculate average growth rates over these subperiods. Thus, they have a
pooled cross-section, time-series data base. Moreover, for their OECD findings, Grier and Tullock include dummy variables for each time
period, save one, producing fixed-effect results across time. For their
non-OECD findings, Grier and Tullock include dummy variables for time
periods as well as for some geographic regions (i.e., Africa and the
Americas), approximating fixed-effect results across time and regions
(but not across countries). Barro, on the other hand, includes
geographic dummy variables (i.e., sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America),
approximating fixed-effect results across regions.
3. We employ a panel of 39 countries with annual data for 1975 to
1984. The data appendix discusses how the countries and sample years
were chosen. Summary statistics for all countries and for all variables
are not printed to conserve space. Tables are available on request.
4. Since our study uses pooled cross-section, time-series data, we
shall be referring to the method associated with pooled estimation. Our
discussion draws on Hsiao [1986] and Greene [1990].
5. An alternative procedure is to estimate the first-differenced
regression. Lagging equation (4) one period and subtracting the lagged
equation from equation (4) causes the intercept and the state-specific
terms to drop out.
6. Space limitations preclude the reporting of results that exclude
fiscal variables other than the surplus. These other results are
available on request.
7. Other results are available on request.
8. Our sample from 1975 to 1984 includes several oil price shocks
that the reader needs to keep in mind when evaluating our findings.
9. The developed country subsample includes Australia, Austria,
Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Iceland, Luxembourg,
the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the
United States, 16 countries. The remaining 23 countries in our
all-country sample are in the developing country sub-sample.
10. The timing of fiscal data reporting across countries varies
slightly in response to differences in fiscal years - some fiscal years
end in June, one or two in September, others in December, and still
others in March.
11. The transformations for the various fixed- and random-effects
models are documented in Judge et al. [1985, 521, 524, 532, and 535].
12. These tables include results for all countries and for countries
subdivided into developed and developing categories as well as results
that include and exclude the once-lagged dependent variable. Table I and
II report the findings for aggregated and disaggregated fiscal
variables, respectively. Space limitations prevent the reporting of
similar findings for these specifications using once-lagged fiscal
variables, both aggregated and disaggregated. Tables that include these
additional findings are available on request.
13. Unless otherwise stated, the discussion of findings relate to
Tables I and II as well as to the similar results (not reported) when
once-lagged fiscal variables are used. See footnote 12 for more details.
14. We also performed several tests (not reported) of conditional and
unconditional convergence absent the fiscal variables to place our
findings in the context of the existing literature. These results
(available on request) support conditional but not unconditional
convergence, the standard result in the literature such as in Barro
[1991] and Levine and Renelt [1992]. Researchers find evidence of
unconditional convergence when the sample includes only developed
countries, as in Mankiw, Romer, and Weil [1992]. Our sample includes
both developed and developing countries.
15. Clark [1993, 23] considers the relationship between growth and
inflation in cross-country regressions and concludes that "the
cross-country relationship between long-term growth and inflation is, at
best, tenuous." The results are sensitive to the sample of
countries as well as the time period.
REFERENCES
Barro, Robert J. "Government Spending in a Simple Model of
Endogenous Growth." Journal of Political Economy, January 1990,
part 2, 103-25.
-----. "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries."
Quarterly Journal of Economics, May 1991, 407-44.
-----. "Human Capital and Economic Growth." Policy for
Long-Run Economic Growth, Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank, 1992,
199-216.
Barth, James R., Robert E. Keleher, and Frank S. Russek. "The
Scale of Government and Economic Activity." The Southern Business
& Economic Journal, April 1990, 142-83.
Breusch, T. S., and A. R. Pagan. "The Lagrange Multiplier Test
and Its Applications to Model Specification in Econometrics."
Review of Economic Studies, January 1980, 239-53.
Clark, Todd E. "Cross-Country Evidence on Long-Run Growth and
Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Research Working
Paper 93-05, May 1993.
Easterly, William, and Sergio Rebelo. "Fiscal Policy and
Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation." Journal of Monetary
Economics, December 1993, 417-58.
Fischer, Stanley. "The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in
Growth." Journal of Monetary Economics, December 1993, 485-512.
Greene, William H. Econometric Analysis. New York: Macmillan, 1990.
Grier, Kevin B., and Gordon Tullock. "An Empirical Analysis of
Cross-National Economic Growth, 1951-1980." Journal of Monetary
Economics, September 1989, 259-76.
Hausman, Jerry A. "Specification Tests in Econometrics."
Econometrica, November 1978, 69-85.
Helms, L. Jay. "The Effect of State and Local Taxes on Economic
Growth: A Time Series Cross Section Approach." Review of Economics
and Statistics, February 1985, 574-82.
Hsiao, Cheng. Analysis of Panel Data. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press, 1986.
Judge, George G., W. E. Griffiths, R. Carter Hill, Helmut Lutkepohl,
and Tsoung Chao Lee. The Theory and Practice of Econometrics, 2nd. ed.
New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1985.
Koester, Reinhard B., and Roger C. Kormendi. "Taxation,
Aggregate Activity and Economic Growth: Cross-Country Evidence on Some
Supply-Side Hypotheses." Economic Inquiry, July 1989, 367-86.
Kormendi, Roger, and Philip Meguire. "Macroeconomic Determinants
of Growth: Cross-Country Evidence." Journal of Monetary Economics,
September 1985, 141-63.
Landau, Daniel. "Government Expenditure and Economic Growth: A
Cross-Country Study." Southern Economic Journal, January 1983,
783-92.
-----. "Government Expenditures and Economic Growth in the
Developed Countries, 1952-1976." Public Choice, 47(3), 1985,
459-77.
-----. "Government and Economic Growth in the Less Developed
Countries: An Empirical Study for 19601980." Economic Development
and Cultural Change, 35(1), 1986, 35-75.
Levine, Ross. "Stock Markets, Growth, and Tax Policy."
Journal of Finance, September 1991, 1445-65.
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. "A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-Country Growth Regressions." American Economic Review,
September 1992, 942-63.
Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil. "A
Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth." Quarterly Journal
of Economics, May 1992, 407-37.
Miller, Stephen M., and Frank S. Russek. "Fiscal Structures and
Economic Growth at the State and Local Level." Public Finance
Review, March 1997, 213-37.
Mofidi, Alaeddin, and Joe A. Stone. "Do State and Local Taxes
Affect Economic Growth?" Review of Economics and Statistics,
November 1990, 686-91.
Ram, Rati. "Government Size and Economic Growth: A New Framework
and Some Evidence from Cross-Section and Time-Series Data."
American Economic Review, March 1986, 191-203.
Romer, Paul M. "Human Capital and Growth: Theory and
Evidence." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No.
3173, 1989.
-----. "Capital, Labor, and Productivity." Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity, special issue, 1990, 337-420.
Stephen M. Miller: Professor and Head of Economics, University of
Connecticut, Storrs, Phone 1-860-486-3853 Fax 1-860-486-4486 E-mail
[email protected]
Frank S. Russek: Principal Analyst, Congressional Budget Office
Washington, D.C., Phone 1-202-226-2766 Fax 1-202-226-2601, E-mail
[email protected]