Women and tariffs: testing the gender gap hypothesis in a Downs-Mayer political-economy model.
Hall, H. Keith ; Kao, Chihwa ; Nelson, Douglas 等
"I am convinced that at least two out of every three women have
a grudge against the tariff, and a grudge which is all too frequently
increased to an indignation by the subtle suggestion, on the part of
importers and retailers, that the tariff adds to the prices of the
things they buy. It is the women of the household who spend the
husband's earnings-she has to make them go around, and anything
which she is told adds to the prices of the things she buys naturally
finds little excuse in her mind. Her attitude, regardless of logic, is a
natural one. She doesn't stop to consider the part the tariff may
have played in making her husband's earnings what they are, or in
fact in making them possible at all, nor does she stop to consider the
relatively minor part the tariff plays in the retail prices of the
things she buys. She has never seen the tariff law, and so she cannot
know that with such commodities as coal, coffee, tea, cocoa, furs and
shoes on the free list, some explanation other than the tariff must
account for the increased price of these things." (Barbour,
1928)(1)
The notion that women and men hold systematically differing political
preferences, that there is a "gender gap," is an old one in
American politics. Even before the national enfranchisement of women in
1920, analysts and commentators attempted to identify issues on which
such a gender gap would affect policy outcomes. One such issue was the
tariff, with which we are concerned in this paper. The above passage
from the January 1928 issue of the Tariff Review serves as an excellent
text for our sermon. The logic of the argument is interesting: American
women prefer a low tariff because a high tariff raises the prices of the
things they purchase. Our paper represents this hypothesis as an
extension of the Downs [1957]-Mayer [1984] political-economy model and
then presents a simple empirical test of the hypothesis.
We present our analysis in four major parts. First, we set the stage
with a brief discussion of the political-economy of the tariff during
the period relevant to our analysis [18901934]. This discussion provides
motivation for the details of the more formal analysis in the following
section. Next we develop the logic of the classic tariff system in the
context of the Downs-Mayer model. The third section presents the
testable proposition that the enfranchisement of women results in a
lower equilibrium tariff as an implication of this model. In the final
section we present our methodology and results.
I. THE POLITICAL-ECONOMY OF THE CLASSIC TARIFF SYSTEM
It is not unreasonable to think of the period from the end of the
Civil War until 1934 as the era of classic tariff politics in the United
States. During this period the tariff was a significant, partisan,
electoral issue. Republicans were the party of the protective tariff,
Democrats were opposed to the "tariff system." While there was
regional variation with respect to details at the level of specific
products, this characterization is quite accurate over the entire period
with respect to overall commitment to the tariff system. Whether one
studies political platforms or campaign speeches, this split between
Republicans and Democrats remains clear.(2) Furthermore, there seems to
be a fairly direct relationship between sectional economic interests and
strength of partisan support: the industrial northeast was the
historical center of Republicanism, while the rural south and mid-west
was the center of Democrat support.
Another important aspect of the electoral politics during the era of
classic tariff politics (from the perspective of this paper) was the
essential one-dimensionality of "the tariff" as an issue.(3)
That is, partisan conflict revolved primarily around support for, and
opposition to, the tariff system - not the details of the tariff
structure. It is important to recall that, during this period, the
tariff was one of the few instruments of industrial policy available to
the national government and, at least since the end of the Civil War,
the tariff as an electoral issue was explicitly presented by both
Democrats and Republicans as a system of support for American industry.4
The details of the tariff schedule were determined by Congress, with the
House Committee on Ways and Means taking the lead, in response to the
lobbying pressure of organized economic interests, but the electoral
competition between the Republicans and Democrats determined the context
within which the lobbying took place. Thus, elections can be thought of
as setting the average level of protection while lobbying determined the
dispersion around that level. The one-dimensionality of the tariff as a
political issue and the centrality of that issue to the political
contest between Democrats and Republicans in the era of classic tariff
politics is an essential element of the link between the theoretical
development of this paper and the empirical work.
Given the centrality of the characterization of classic tariff
politics to the research reported here, it is useful to briefly discuss
the role of the tariff in the election of 1896. Political scientists and
historians are in broad agreement that the McKinley-Bryan election was
of particular political significance.(5) This was certainly true with
respect to the tariff system, which faced its most sustained and
explicit challenge in the 1896 election. Populists and Democrats under
the general leadership of William Jennings Bryan offered a progressive
income tax as a direct attack on the tariff system. Specifically, the
income tax was to replace the tariff, which was seen not only as a
symbol of the power of eastern industrial interests, but as a
fundamental defender of those interests. At the same time, the populists
sought to go beyond simply removing the tariff by proposing a
progressive income tax that would fall most heavily on the holders of
"money power."(6) Republicans, and conservatives generally
(including important elements of the Democrat party), opposed the income
tax. As Baack and Ray [1985a,b] point out, during the Civil War (the
only U.S. experience with an income tax prior to the 20th century) the
income tax fell particularly heavily on New York, Massachusetts and
Pennsylvania - the centers of Republican power. The tariff, on the other
hand, provided substantial benefits for those same states. Perhaps of
equal importance, the tariff had for some time been an important symbol
of government commitment to U.S. industry, while Bryan made the income
tax a symbol of sectional and class struggle.
The rout of Bryan and the populists defended the classic tariff
system from its most serious challenge and resulted in stable tariff
politics until the emergence of the New Deal political system. A
fundamental rethinking of the tariff system had to wait until the
Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act of 1934. The reestablishment of control
of the Democrat party by establishment Democrats permitted a return to
classic tariff politics. Furthermore, this ultimately permitted the
institutionalization of the income tax as a revenue raising device
subordinate to the tariff.(7) Thus, even when the Democrats gained
control of the White House and the Congress: there was no attempt to
replace the tariff system (although there was some tariff reduction);
the income tax was not used for redistributive purposes; and, as Baack
and Ray [1985] point out, the structure of increased federal
expenditures involved substantial benefits for the centers of
Republicanism.
The purpose of this section has been to argue that the tariff
constituted a significant issue, possibly the most significant
continuing issue, in American electoral politics during the last part of
the 19th century and the first part of the 20th century. Furthermore, we
have argued that the electoral politics of the tariff can reasonably be
characterized as one-dimensional. Finally, we have argued that both the
politics of the tariff and the relationship of the tariff to the
electoral/political system as a whole was relatively constant over this
period. These aspects of the political-economy of the tariff undergird
the theoretical and empirical analysis which is developed in the
remainder of the paper. In the next section, we sketch a simple formal
model of the political-economy of the classic tariff system in which the
gender gap hypothesis plays a significant role.
II. THE POLITICS OF THE CLASSIC TARIFF SYSTEM IN THE DOWNS-MAYER
MODEL
The spatial analysis of partisan competition that constitutes one
essential element of Downs' [1957] economic theory of democracy
rests on two fundamental results: Black's [1948] theorem that if
agents preferences over a one-dimensional political issue are
single-peaked, then the most preferred point of the median voter cannot
be beaten in a majority rule contest; and Hotelling's [1929]
theorem that the most preferred point of the median voter is the Nash
equilibrium of two-party competition over that dimension.(8) An
important paper by Mayer [1984] applies the spatial model to the case of
trade policy determination by deriving voter preferences over the tariff
from a standard (Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson) trade theoretic model. In
the Mayer model, every household is characterized by an endowment of
productive factors and tastes (i.e., preferences over the consumption of
goods and services). These endowments then determine household
preferences over policy choices as these policies affect equilibrium
factor and commodity prices. A full political-economic equilibrium is
then determined through a majority-rule referendum on the tariff.
Specifically, assuming that indirect utility functions are concave in
the tariff, Mayer uses Black's theorem to analyze the effect of
restricted franchise on the equilibrium tariff determined by a simple
referendum.
Downs, however, is less interested in single-issue referenda than in
the functioning of representative democracy in a complex and
informationally rich political environment. The key contribution of
Downs here is the notion of rational ignorance. The basic idea is that,
since each agent has only a minuscule effect on the final outcome of the
electoral contest, it is in no agent's interest to invest large
resources in collecting or processing political information. This
process of economizing on political information costs involves:
conditioning voting behavior on low cost information; and using a simple
evaluative scheme for processing that information. Both of these
elements will be important to our analysis, but at this point we focus
on the role of simple evaluative schemes. There are three key elements
of such a scheme: it must be in common use throughout the electorate;
must differentiate the parties; and it must be stable across time. The
first point is obvious, if the evaluative scheme is not public and
commonly understood, it cannot serve as a basis for partisan
competition. The second is also straightforward, if parties engage in
Hotelling-like clustering on the dimension it will not serve to reduce
decision-making costs. The third element, intertemporal stability, is a
bit less obvious, but very important: without such stability information
costs would not really be reduced since voters would have to identify a
new evaluative dimension in every election.
Downs discusses these issues in the context of a general left-right
evaluative dimension.(9) Modern voters will normally conceive of this in
terms of big government versus small government, or level of commitment
to macroeconomic policy activism. That particular form of evaluative
dimension is of fairly recent vintage. In fact, it is a property of what
political scientists usually refer to as "the New Deal
system." The main point of the first section of this paper,
however, was to argue that from the end of the Civil War until some time
in the early part of this century, The Tariff served as precisely such a
Downsian issue. The purpose of the next section is to argue that female
franchise marks the end of the tariff as such an issue.
III. THE GENDER GAP, FEMALE FRANCHISE AND THE EQUILIBRIUM TARIFF
We can capture the gender gap on the tariff issue with a simple
extension of the Downs-Mayer model. We assume that every household
consists of two individuals (with identical tastes) that specialize in
their economic activities: one undertakes all factor-market transactions
while the other undertakes all product market transactions. If,
following Downs, we assume that individual agents economize on
information costs in making their political choices by weighing more
heavily the information they observe directly, then individuals within a
single household have different political preferences.(10) For
simplicity we use the assumptions that factor-market specialists (men)
are only concerned with the effect of policy on returns to their
household's factor endowment, while product market specialists
(women) are only concerned with the effect of policy on the prices of
consumption goods. In the language developed below, each household is
seen as having a wealth effect voter and a consumption effect voter. We
have therefore modeled exactly the "political gender gap" that
concerned political activists at the time.
How reasonable are the special assumptions of our model for the
classic tariff era in the United States? With respect to the
specialization of household economic decisions, we are convinced that
this assumption is completely unproblematic. Data on women's labor
force participation in the period with which we are concerned
[1890-1934] show a very clear pattern of exclusion of women from the
formal workforce [Goldin, 1990].(11) With respect to the additional
assumption that this specialization results in a political gender gap,
we offer two lines of defense. First, contemporary political
discussions, like the one cited at the beginning of this paper, suggest
that political activists during this time period believed that such a
gender gap existed. Assuming that policy is driven by the desire for
reelection, a general belief in such a gender gap may be enough to cause
a shift in trade policy whether such a gender gap actually existed or
not. Second, given the specialization of decision-making within the
household and the observation that information is generally costly to
obtain, is seems perfectly rational that a household member would weigh
more heavily that part of economic reality with which they are most
directly concerned (i.e., the effects of policy on either factor or
consumer prices). For simplicity we adopt the strong assumption that
each is exclusively concerned with that part of economic reality with
which they are most directly concerned.
The logic of the model should now be clear.(12) Prior to female
franchise, the distribution of factor-ownership among households was
such that the tariff could function as the Downsian issue dimension
along which parties could differentiate themselves. Female franchise
introduces a substantial population of people into the electorate that
have preferences skewed toward lower tariffs. This has two empirical
implications: the median voter now has a lower optimal tariff, and thus
the equilibrium tariff must be lower; and the system of partisan
competition based on the tariff must collapse. Before we turn to the
econometric analysis of the first empirical implication in the next
section, we can briefly consider the second.
In his discussion of "The Origin of New Parties" (pp.
127-32), Downs argues that new parties emerge when the distribution of
voters shifts in such a way as to make the initial equilibrium unstable.
Downs' example is the effect of the extension of franchise to
working class voters in the late-nineteenth century with the demise of
the Liberal party, the birth of the Labor party and the realignment of
British electoral politics. While Downs' analysis implies that
events like franchise extension have no effect on the underlying
dimension defining political competition, it should be clear that this
is not necessarily implied by the analysis. In fact, research on party
systems proceeding from the foundational work of V. O. Key [1955] and
Walter Dean Burnham [1970] makes it clear that political realignments
are essentially about the content of political contests (see footnote
5). Thus, although the institutional parties may (or may not) exist
after a realignment, the membership and the terms on which the parties
compete will be fundamentally changed - they will in effect be new
parties. In the case which concerns us, the adoption of female franchise
undermined the system of partisan competition based on the tariff in a
particularly strong way: it created an expected majority of voters
opposed to the platform of the previously dominant party.(13) That is,
the "system of 1896" was dominated by the high tariff
Republicans and the new voters would be expected to enter the electorate
on the low tariff side of the low tariff party, thus undermining the
commitment of the Republicans to the system. The result was not the
elimination of either party, but the disappearance of the tariff as an
electoral issue and the concomitant collapse of the "system of
1896."(14) It is in fact the case that the tariff played no role in
partisan competition in the system that replaced the "system of
1896," generally referred to as the "New Deal
system."(15)
Interestingly, while political scientists have been very clear on the
political alignments that define the New Deal system, and their
differences from the "system of 1896," there has always been a
certain uneasiness in the dating of the system. The problem is that the
alignments that define the system seem to have emerged from the politics
of the depression, but the voting behavior that signals the realignment
seems to precede the depression, or more precisely to phase in over a
period of several years. Specifically, as Lichtman [1982] argues, it is
difficult to find the kind of decisive changes in voting behavior over
the period 1916-1940 that one would normally associate with a
realignment. But this is exactly the kind of behavior predicted by the
analysis developed in this paper: with the collapse of the tariff, both
parties would seek to find a new issue around which to organize partisan
competition; the search process would generate some period characterized
by uncertainty; with a catastrophic event like the depression, however,
a new system could form around alternative visions of the relationship
between government and the economy. Thus, the macrohistorical evidence
is consistent with our analysis. We now turn to an econometric
evaluation of the microhistorical evidence.
IV. A SIMPLE TEST OF THE GENDER GAP HYPOTHESIS
The Downs-Mayer model is based on the notion of an equilibrium
relationship between citizen preferences (derived from their
factor-ownership positions and their consumption preferences) and policy
outcomes. Previous time series research on the political economy of the
tariff suggests that the tariff is a function of business cycle effects
(proxied by either level of GNP or unemployment), international
competition (trade balance or import penetration), party (the
equilibrium tariff is lower with Democrats).(16) Our extension of the
Downs-Mayer logic to the extension of voting rights to women suggests a
straight-forward empirical test of that logic. Thus, the research
reported in this section differs in two fundamental ways from the
previous research by Magee and Young [1987] and Bohara and Kaempfer
[1991a,b]. First, we focus only on the period of classic tariff
politics. As we argue in section I, this period is characterized by a
stable relationship between the tariff and the political system.
Following the New Deal realignment, of which the Reciprocal Trade
Agreements Act of 1934 was a fundamental part, virtually every aspect of
the politics of trade policy underwent fundamental change. Second, and
of more direct relevance to the major argument of this paper, we
explicitly test for the impact of female franchise on the political
economic equilibrium. This section presents the results of our analysis
using annual data for the period 1866-1934 and 1896-1934.(17)
Table I contains several interesting results consistent with our
hypothesis.(18) As previous research has already shown, we find that the
domestic business cycle, the trade balance, and Democrat presidents all
have the predicted effects. With respect to the gender gap hypothesis,
assuming that the dummy variable accurately reflects the effect of
female franchise, we find a strong effect, and we find this effect using
a variety of domestic business cycle indicators, and we find this effect
both from 1866-1934 and 1896-1934. Also of considerable interest is the
lack of a significant effect for the income tax (as measured by the
share of income tax revenue in total government revenue). This latter
result seems to be consistent with our argument that the existence of
the income tax (or some alternative source of revenue) was a necessary
but not sufficient condition to the collapse of the classic tariff
system. It has been the main argument of this paper that the politically
necessary allowed the tariff to function as a key issue in partisan
competition.
Before considering the significance of female franchise result in
more detail, we first discuss several possible objections to the result.
A first objection is methodological and relates to our use of a dummy
variable to capture the effect of female franchise. The fundamental
difficulty here relates to the possibility that the dummy variable is
actually picking up some other politically significant phenomenon.
Although our search for obviously compounding events has not turned up
anything, it remains the case that a dummy variable is far from
ideal.(19)
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED]
A second objection to our interpretation of the results flows from
the fact that women did not vote in significant numbers even after they
were enfranchised. First, it follows from the work of Fenno [1978] and
Cain, Ferejohn and Fiorina [1989] that people need not vote to be
considered in the political calculus of reelection maximizing
politicians, they only need to be able to vote. Furthermore, some women
did vote. Both of these facts are sufficient to change the location of
the median voter if women's preferences are as characterized in
section II.
A third objection is that women already had the franchise before 1920
in several states. The first line of response to this is that, as with
the previous point, all that is necessary with respect to the model
developed in section II is that a large group of women entered the
electorate in 1920. The fact that some states had already experienced
this phenomenon would weaken the effect and make it harder to establish
the result. More importantly, virtually all the early franchise states
were Western states and, thus, generally supporters of trade
liberalization in any event. Thus the identity of the median legislator would not be affected by these early franchise states. The gender gap
should be strongest in the Northeast.(20)
Finally, there were women in the labor force, and working women (by
the logic of this paper) should have the same preferences as men with
respect to the tariff. We have already noted that female labor force
participation was considerably lower than male labor force participation
and that this was even more striking for what we can think of as
"voting women"--i.e. middle class women. These facts suggest
that the median preferences of women with respect to the tariff are for
lower tariffs. Furthermore, contemporary accounts suggest that
politicians believed women to have a preference for lower tariffs.
Thus, we believe that the results reported here provide strong,
preliminary evidence for the effect of female franchise on the level of
the average tariff. That is, there was a gender gap on the tariff. If
this result stands up to further scrutiny, it is important for several
reasons. First, it has been an open question in political science for
some time whether or not female franchise had any politically
significant impact at the time it occurred. It has been argued that, as
new voters, women were not well socialized and, therefore, did not vote
or voted in ways that reduced their impact as a group with common
interests. Most of this research proceeds by studies of their voting
behavior (e.g. Kleppner [1982] on turnout) and/or the activities of
women's political organizations [Andersen, 1990]. The research
reported here, by focussing directly on an issue over which men and
women were presumed to disagree, provides some direct evidence of an
immediate political impact of female franchise. Furthermore, not only is
the effect of female franchise positive but, from the macrohistorical
perspective, it is of substantial historical interest. Specifically, we
argued at the end of section III that female franchise caused the
collapse of the system of 1896 and created the conditions in which the
New Deal system could be born.
A similar logic provides a more compelling account for Congress'
adoption and continued support for the Reciprocal Trade Agreements Act
of 1934. This act institutionalized an alternative approach to
Congressional management of U.S. trade policy. The standard account of
support for the RTAA asserts that Congress collectively learned a lesson
from the Smoot-Hawley tariff. Unfortunately, there are two serious
problems with this account. First, there is virtually no contemporary
evidence of such a change. That is, there are no significant instances
of individual members of Congress making this connection. Second, the
changes in voting behavior that would be assumed to go along with such
learning do not occur until well into the 1950s [Nelson, 1989]. There is
a good reason why we should not observe changed political behavior:
there is no systematic evidence of a strong economic connection between
the Smoot-Hawley tariff and the severity of the depression [Eichengreen,
1989]. This has led to an alternative account, based in part on
Schattschneider's [1935] classic account of the making of the
Smoot-Hawley tariff: Congress delegated the making of the trade policy
to the President because the writing of tariffs had become too time
consuming and too politically difficult. The problem with these accounts
is timing. The logic is straightforward and compelling, but why after
Smoot-Hawley? The argument of this paper suggests a simple answer: with
the collapse of the tariff as an organizing structure in partisan
competition, there was no longer any reason to continue.
V. BY WAY OF A CONCLUSION: IMPLICATIONS FOR FUTURE RESEARCH
One interesting implication of this result for future research is
that, once the labor market status of women becomes more like that of
men, we would expect their political preferences with regard to trade
policy to become more similar.(21) Using labor market participation
data, we should, in principle, be able to study this effect directly. We
say "in principle" not because there are fundamental problems
with measuring women's labor force participation, but because
measuring the average level of protection during the GATT era is
difficult. Not only is there no longer direct legislation of protection,
but there has been steady substitution of non-tariff for tariff barriers
over the entire period; and trade economists have still not found
satisfactory ways of measuring the economic effects of such barriers.
Nonetheless, we find it at least suggestive that trade policy activism
has made a substantial recovery as a public political issue in the 1990s
- a period of substantially increased female labor force participation.
The second contribution of this paper relates to the direct link
between endogenous tariff theory and empirical tariff politics. Much of
the casual empiricism which is attached to the theoretical work on
endogenous tariff theory implies a fairly direct relationship between
those models and the political-economy of current trade policy. This is
clearly inappropriate. As we have just commented, and as is well known
in policy discussions: modern trade policy is not about tariffs; and
modern trade politics has not been about elections. Most endogenous
tariff theory is of direct application only to the period of classic
tariff politics. Pincus [1975], Baack and Ray [1983], Eichengreen
[1989], and Conybeare [1991] demonstrate the usefulness of lobbying
models for the explanation of tariff dispersion, while the research
reported here illustrates the value of voting models for the explanation
of the average tariff.
This suggests two important directions for future research. First, we
need to move toward models that integrate the electoral process (to set
the average propensity to protect) with lobbying models (to determine
dispersion). Preliminary steps are taken in this direction by Hall and
Nelson [1992] via their introduction into a standard lobbying model of
an explicit parameter for tariff resistance. Perhaps more importantly,
we need to develop better models of the political-economy of protection
in the GATT era. This is difficult primarily because trade policy has
become inherently multidimensional. Instead of "the tariff" as
an electoral issue there is market access, unfair competition, and trade
liberalization to name only a few. This makes the formal
characterization of trade policy as either an electoral or a lobbying
issue difficult.
Third, and finally, the research reported here is significant because
it links political exclusion to an economically relevant social
category: gender. Mayer's [1984] important work showed the
potentially significant impact of political exclusion on equilibria of
endogenous policy models. However, Mayer's analysis is difficult to
test because the relevant patterns of political exclusion (i.e.
factor-based exclusion) have not generally been observed in modern
American politics. By focussing on gender-based exclusion we have moved
toward a more testable version of the Downs-Mayer model.
[TABULAR DATA FOR APPENDIX OMITTED]
The authors would like to thank: Elias Dinopoulos, Kevin Grier, Doug
Holtz-Eakin, Bill Kaempfer, Carsten Kowalczyk, Steve Marks, Jay Wilson,
several referees for Economic Inquiry and seminar participants at the
Claremont Graduate School, University of Alabama, University of
Nottingham, and the Fall 1991 Midwest International Economics Meetings.
None of these should be implicated in any errors in fact, logic or good
taste. This paper is solely meant to represent the opinions of the
authors, and is not meant to represent in any way the views of the
International Trade Commission or its members.
1. W. Warren Barbour, in addition to being the President of the Linen
Thread Company, was the President of the American Tariff League when the
lecture from which this article was derived was given.
2. Thus, it should not be surprising that, over this entire period,
final votes on tariff legislation consistently showed high levels of
party-line voting. In fact, the tariff was usually one of the two or
three most divisive issues.
3. In fact, this assertion does not meet with universal approval
among historians of this period. While many assume that the close link
between centers of partisan strength and aggregate economic interest
signifies that the politics of the protective system reflected classic
inter-regional redistributive politics (e.g. Taussig [1931]; Rogowski
[1989]), a substantial school of research based on careful study of
local political conditions suggests that this is too simple.
Specifically, a number of prominent ethnocultural historians, have
emphasized that "the tariff" had different meanings in
different locations precisely because it was more important as a symbol
than as a commitment to any particular policy. See especially: Jensen
[1971]; Kleppner [1970]; and McSeveney [1972]. McCormick [1974] presents
a convenient survey of this research. Thus, if "the tariff"
was a sort of ideological portmanteau, our assumption that it is
essentially one-dimensional is clearly problematic.
4. It is also important to recall that, unlike the modern trade
policy system, it was the tariff (as legislated by Congress) that was
the dominant instrument of industrial protection. For a detailed
development of the argument that the classic tariff system was
essentially one-dimensional while modern system is irreducibly
multi-dimensional, see Nelson [1989].
5. In the language of modern research on political history, the 1896
election was one of a small number of "critical elections." In
fact, the electoral system defined by that election is generally
referred to as the "system of 1896." On the general concept of
critical elections and the periodization of American politics in those
terms, see Burnham [1970], Sundquist [1973], and Clubb, Flanigan and
Zingale [1980]. For more critical perspectives on critical elections,
see: McCormick [1982] and Lichtman [1982]. With particular reference to
the election of 1896 and the "system of 1896," see: Burnham
[1981; 1986] and McCormick [1986].
6. Stewart [1980] and Hansen [1980] for excellent presentations of
the politics of the income tax and its relationship to critical election
theory. Also of interest is Hansen [1990].
7. This is an important point to which we shall return. While it is
true, as a number of scholars have noted (e.g. Riezman and Slemrod
[1987]), that there is a general relationship between the development of
an income tax and the elimination of the tariff as a revenue raising
device, the above discussion should make clear that this connection is
far from direct in any particular case. In the U.S. case, it was
precisely the agreement that the income tax would not constitute a
threat to the tariff system that made adopting one politically feasible
in the context of the "System of 1896." It was only with the
collapse of the "System of 1896" and the emergence of the
"New Deal System" that the classic tariff system could be
dismantled and replaced with something else. Thus, while the existence
of an alternative source of government revenue is a necessary condition
to elimination of a protective system, it is not sufficient.
8. See Enelow and Hinich [1984] for an excellent textbook treatment
of the spatial model.
9. See Hinich and Munger [1994] for a current development of Downs
theory of the role of ideology in electoral competition.
10. We see this as directly related to Downs' [1957] notion of
rationally ignorant voters. That is, politically relevant information is
costly to obtain. As a result, voters will economize on information
gathering. Furthermore, some information is relatively cheap, while
other information is more costly. In our model we are assuming that
factor-price information is observed freely by men and not at all by
women, while commodity price information is observed freely by women and
not at all by men. Neither is particularly concerned with the overall
state of the economy as a whole. Each conditions both economic and
political behavior on the information that is freely observed. While
information may be exchanged between household members, each considers
the information directly observed to be the most accurate information
and essentially ignores other information. Some readers of this paper
have found this assumption ad hoc. We would argue that it is no more ad
hoc than the assumption of perfectly reliable information transfer.
Others have argued that the existence of a gender gap may flow from
sources other than differential information. Most of the alternative
accounts that have been suggested vary from the unlikely (e.g. perhaps
female employment was concentrated in export-oriented sectors) to the
genuinely silly (e.g. perhaps women were free traders because
liberalization would cause relative price shifts that would change the
balance of household bargaining power in their favor). However, our
purpose in this paper is not to explain the gender gap, but to
incorporate it in the corpus of endogenous tariff theory in a relatively
straightforward way. We would argue that our differential information
story does this effectively. The fact that this is consistent with
contemporary accounts is simply an additional bonus.
11. According to Goldin [1990, Table 2.1] female labor force
participation in 1890 was 18.9%, 20.6% in 1900 and 23.7% in 1920. This
pattern is even clearer if we focus on women who were likely to be
voters - i.e. middle class, white women, We do not have data by economic
status, but the percentages for white, married women were 2.5%, 3.2%,
and 6.5%. This can be compared to the labor force participation of males
in these census years of 84.3%, 85.7%, and 54.3% (Historical Statistics
of the United States, series D30).
12. In fact, while the general logic is straightforward, formally
proving that the claims follow from the assumptions is far from easy.
Hall and Nelson [1995] provides a detailed development and formal
analysis of the gender gap model.
13. It is interesting to note that Downs explicitly rules out female
franchise in this context: "A change in the number of voters per se
is irrelevant; it is the distribution which counts. Hence, women's
suffrage does not create any new parties, although it raises the total
vote enormously." The main point of this paper is that, while Downs
got the mechanism exactly right, female franchise did shift the
distribution on the one issue that mattered to the stability of the
system.
14. Note that the disappearance of the tariff as a political issue is
not in any way the same thing as the disappearance of the tariff. In
fact, once the tariff ceased to be an instrument of public partisan
competition it was freed to become first an example of pure pork barrel politics and, with the recognition that the costs exceeded the benefits
of treating trade policy as distributive politics, the Reciprocal Trade
Agreements Act of 1934 redefined those politics in an essential way. See
Nelson [1989] for a detailed development of this argument.
15. Note the implication for the equilibrium tariff. With the tariff
no longer a Downsian valence issue both parties will converge on the
optimal tariff of the median voter in Hotelling-Black fashion. Since
under Republican domination the political equilibrium involved a tariff
that was higher than the optimal tariff of the median voter even without
female franchise, this implies that the equilibrium tariff would be even
lower with female franchise.
16. The majority of empirical research on the political economy of
the tariff emphasizes sectoral dispersion of the tariff. Baldwin [1984],
Anderson and Baldwin [1987], and McCarthur and Marks [1989] are
convenient surveys of the research on tariff dispersion. Of particular
note for the research presented here are the papers explaining tariff
dispersion in the era of classic tariff politics: Pincus [1975]; Baack
and Ray [1983], Eichengreen [1989] and Conybeare [1991].
17. The dependent variable in the analysis is the average tariff (in
logarithms: tariff revenue/total dutiable imports). Our measures of
domestic macroeconomic conditions are the unemployment rate, the real
wage, and GNP, and our measure of international competitive conditions
is the trade balance (= export value - import value). The source for
these data is the Historical Statistics of the United States: total
imports (Series U194); total exports (series U191); total dutiable
imports (series U209); total duties (series U210). The income tax
revenue and total government revenue series are from the same source.
Unemployment rate, nominal and real GNP, and inflation are from the
series in the appendix to Gordon's Macroeconomics, and the real
wage series is reported in Williamson [1995]. All variables are in logs
except trade balance (which takes negative values) and income tax/total
government revenue (which takes zero values in many years).
To examine the effect of female franchise, we used a dummy variable
which takes a value of 0 for the period 1890-1919 and 1 from 1920-1934.
As we suggest in the text, the parties had very clearly defined
preferences on trade policy. We attempt to control for partisan effects
with a dummy variable for party of the president (Democrat = 1;
Republican = 0).
18. At the suggestion of a reviewer, we ran all six versions of the
model in first differences as a simple specification test. In all cases,
both the signs and the significance levels of the parameters are
unchanged. These results are reported in the Appendix.
19. It is, however, the case that we have explicitly considered the
effect of the most commonly mentioned alternative (the income tax) as
well as trade balance, business cycle, and partisan competition. Since
we have discussed this in detail elsewhere we simply note that the other
events that have been suggested bear no essential relationship to the
politics of the tariff, whereas the burden of the argument in this paper
is that there is a good theoretical reason for believing that female
franchise does bear such a relationship.
20. There may even be a certain degree of endogeneity here. That is,
given the centrality of the tariff to political contestation, women were
more easily enfranchised where they least threatened the political
equilibrium.
21. Recent research by Claudia Goldin [1991] suggests that World War
II was not the major turning point in women's labor market status
that it has sometimes been taken to be. However, this argument relates
as much to the social context of increased employment as to the
economic. With respect to the issue raised in this paragraph, while the
actual social turning point with respect to women's labor force
participation may have been later than the 1940s, it seems
uncontroversial to suggest that it did come at some point in the
post-War era.
REFERENCES
Andersen, Kristi. "Women and Citizenship in the
1920's," in Women, Politics and Change, edited by Louise Tilly
and Patricia Gurin. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1990, 177-98.
Anderson, Kym, and Robert Baldwin. "The Political Market for
Protection in Industrial Countries," in Protection, Cooperation,
Integration and Development, edited by A.M. El-Agraa. London: Macmillan,
1987, 20-36.
Baack, Ben, and Edward Ray. "The Political Economy of Tariff
Policy: A Case Study of the United States." Explorations in
Economic History, January 1983, 7393.
-----. "Special Interests and the Adoption of the Income Tax in
the U.S." Journal of Economic History, September 1985a, 607-25.
----- "The Political Economy of the Origin and Development of
the Federal Income Tax," in Emergence of the Modern Political
Economy, edited by R. Higgs. Greenwich: JAI Press, 1985b, 121-38.
Baldwin, Robert. "Trade Policies in Developed Countries,"
in Handbook of International Economics, edited by R. Jones and P. Kenen.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1984, 571-619.
Barbour, W. Warren. "The Protective Tariff - On the
Defensive." The Tariff Review, January 1928, 3-6, and 29.
Black, Duncan. "On the Rationale of Group Decision-Making."
Journal of Political Economy, February 1948, 23-34.
Bohara, Alok, and William Kaempfer. "A Test of Tariff
Endogeneity in the United States." American Economic Review,
September 1991 a, 952-60.
-----. "Testing the Endogeneity of Tariff Policy in the U.S.:
Further Evidence." Economics Letters, March 1991b, 311-15.
Burnham, Walter Dean. Critical Elections and the Mainsprings of
American Politics. New York: Norton, 1970.
-----. "The System of 1896: An Analysis," in The Evolution
of American Electoral Systems, edited by P. Kleppner, et al. Westport:
Greenwood Press, 1981, 147-202.
-----. "Periodization Schemes and 'Party Systems': The
System of 1896 as a Case in Point." Social Science History, Fall
1986, 263-314.
Cain, Bruce, John Ferejohn, and Morris Fiorina. The Personal Vote.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1989.
Campbell, Bruce, and Richard Trilling. Realignment in American
Politics: Toward a Theory. Austin, Tex.: University of Texas Press,
1980.
Clubb, Jerome, William Flanigan, and Nancy Zingale. Partisan
Realignment: Voters, Parties, and Government in American History.
Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage, 1980.
Conybeare, John A. C. "Voting for Protection: An Electoral Model
of Tariff Policy." International Organization, Winter 1991, 57-81.
Downs, Anthony. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York:
Harper-Collins, 1957.
Eichengreen, Barry. "The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley
Tariff." Research in Economic History, 12, 1989, 1-43.
Enelow, James, and Melvin Hinich. The Spatial Theory of Voting: An
Introduction. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1984.
Epstein, David, and Sharyn O'Halloran. "The Partisan
Paradox and the U.S. Tariff, 1877-1934." International
Organization, Spring 1996, 301-24.
Fenno, Richard. Home Style. Boston: Little-Brown, 1978.
Gardner, Grant, and Kent Kimbrough. "The Behavior of U.S. Tariff
Rates." American Economic Review, March 1989, 211-18.
Goldin, Claudia. Understanding the Gender Gap: An Economic History of
American Women New York: Oxford University Press, 1990.
-----. "The Role of World War II in the Rise of Women's
Employment." American Economic Review, September 1981, 741-56.
Hall, H. Keith, and Douglas Nelson. "Institutional Structure and
the Political-Economy of Protection: Administered versus Legislated
Protection." Economics and Politics, March 1992, 61-77.
-----. "Women and Tariffs, If: A Formal Analysis of the Gender
Gap Extension of the Downs-Mayer Model." Massachusetts: Tulane
University, 1992.
Hansen, John Mark. "Taxation and the Political Economy of the
Tariff." International Organization, Autumn 1990, 526-49.
Hansen, Susan B. "Partisan Realignment and Tax Policy:
1789-1976." Campbell and Trilling, 1980, 288-323.
Hinich, Melvin, and Michael Munger. Ideology and the Theory of
Political Choice. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994.
Hotelling, Harold. "Stability in Competition." Economic
Journal, March 1929, 41-57.
Jensen, Richard. The Winning of the Midwest: Social and Political
Conflict, 1888-1896. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1971.
Key, V. O. "A Theory of Critical Elections." Journal of
Politics, February 1955, 3-18.
Kleppner, Paul. The Cross of Culture: A Social Analysis of Midwestern
Politics, 1850-1900. New York: Free Press, 1970.
-----. "Were Women to Blame? Female Suffrage and Voter
Turnout." Journal of Interdisciplinary History, Spring 1982,
621-43.
Lichtman, Allan. "The End of Realignment Theory? Toward a New
Research Program for American Political History." Historical
Methods, 15(4), 1982, 170-88.
Magee, Stephen P, and Leslie Young. "Endogenous Protection in
the United States, 1900-1984," in U.S. Trade Policies in a Changing
World Economy, edited by R. Stem. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT, 1987, 145-95.
Mayer, Wolfgang. "Endogenous Tariff Formation." American
Economic Review, December 1984, 970-85.
McCarthur J., and S. Marks. "Empirical Analyses of the
Determinants of Protection: A Survey and Some New Results," in
International Trade Policies: Gains from Exchange Between Economics and
Political Science, edited by J. Odell and T. Willett. Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press, 1989, 105-39.
McCormick, Richard L. "Ethno-Cultural Interpretations of
Nineteenth-Century American Voting Behavior." Political Science
Quarterly, June 1974, 351-77.
-----. "The Realignment Synthesis in American History."
Journal of Interdisciplinary History, Summer 1982, 85-105.
----- "Walter Dean Burnham and the 'System of
1896'?' Social Science History, Fall 1986, 245-62.
McSeveney, Samuel T. The Politics of Depression: Political Behavior
in the Northeast, 1893-1896. New York: Oxford University Press, 1972.
Nelson, Douglas R. "The Domestic Political Preconditions of U.S.
Trade Policy: Liberal Structure and Protectionist Dynamics."
Journal of Public Policy, 9(1), 1989, 83-108.
Pincus, J. J. "Pressure Groups and the Pattern of Tariffs."
Journal of Political Economy, August 1975, 757-78.
Riezman, Raymond, and Joel Slemrod. "Tariffs and Collection
Costs." Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 123(3), 1987, 545-49.
Rogowski, Ronald. Commerce and Coalitions: How Trade Affects Domestic
Political Alignments. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989.
Schattschneider, E. E. Politics, Pressure and the Tariff. New York:
Prentice Hall, 1935.
Stewart, Charles "The Federal Income Tax and the Realignment of
the 1890s." Campbell and Trilling, 1980, 263-87.
Sundquist, James L. Dynamics of the Party System. Washington, D.C.:
Brookings, 1973.
Taussig, F. W. The Tariff History of the United States. New York: G.
P. Putnams, 1931.
Williamson, Jeffry. "The Evolution of Global Labor Markets Since
1850: Background Evidence and Hypotheses." Explorations in Economic
History, April 1995, 1-54.
Hall: Economist, U.S. International Trade Commission Washington,
D.C., Phone 1-202-205-3245 Fax 1-202-205-2340, E-mail
[email protected]
Kao: Associate Professor, Department of Economics Syracuse
University, New York, Phone 1-315-443-3233 Fax 1-315-443-1081, E-mail
[email protected]
Nelson: Associate Professor, Murphy Institute of Political Economy,
Tulane University, New Orleans, La. Phone 1-504-865-5317, Fax
1-504-862-8755 E-mail
[email protected]