An empirical analysis of alcohol addiction: results from monitoring the future panels.
Grossman, Michael ; Chaloupka, Frank J. ; Sirtalan, Ismail 等
I. INTRODUCTION
This paper aims to refine and enrich the empirical literature dealing
with the price sensitivity of alcohol consumption by incorporating
insights provided by Becker and Murphy's [1988] theoretical model
of rational addictive behavior. Their model emphasizes the
interdependency of past, current, and future consumption of an addictive
good. In addition, we reexamine the relative potency of excise tax and
drinking age hikes as policy instruments to curtail alcohol abuse by
young adults. Our study is unique in that it addresses these issues in a
panel of individuals. The panel is formed from the nationally
representative cross-sectional surveys of high school seniors conducted
each year since 1975 by the Institute for Social Research of the
University of Michigan. The members of the panel range in age from 17
through 29. Since Grant et al. [1991] report that the prevalence of
alcohol dependence and abuse is highest in this age range, addictive
models of alcohol consumption may be more relevant to this sample than
to a representative sample of the population of all ages. By testing for
rational addiction, we address the issue of whether teenagers and young
adults ignore the internal costs of alcohol use and abuse and whether
these costs should be considered in formulating public policy.
Rachal et al. [1980] demonstrate a positive relationship between
alcohol abuse at early and later stages of the life cycle, indicating
that excessive consumption is an example of an addictive behavior. Yet
the substantial empirical literature on the demand for alcohol does not
incorporate insights from the Becker-Murphy theoretical model of this
behavior.(1) The main element of this and other models of addiction is
that an increase in past consumption of an addictive good raises the
marginal utility of current consumption and therefore raises current
consumption. A key feature of the Becker-Murphy model which
distinguishes it from other models of addictive behavior is that addicts
are rational or farsighted in the sense that they anticipate the
expected future consequences of their current actions. This is in sharp
contrast to myopic models of addiction in which consumers ignore the
effects of current consumption on future utility when they determine the
optimal or utility-maximizing quantity of an addictive good in the
present period.
The Becker-Murphy model predicts intertemporal complementarity of
consumption or negative cross price effects and a long-run own price
elasticity of demand which exceeds the short-run elasticity (the former
allows past consumption to vary while the latter does not). This model
has been successfully applied to the addictive behavior of cigarette
smoking in published research by Chaloupka [1991]; Keeler, Hu, Barnett,
and Manning [1993]; and Becker, Grossman, and Murphy [1994]. These three
studies report negative and significant price effects, positive and
significant past and future consumption effects, and long-run
elasticities which are larger than short-run price elasticities.
We find that alcohol consumption by young adults is addictive in the
sense that increases in past or future consumption cause current
consumption to rise. The positive and significant future consumption
effect is consistent with the hypothesis of rational addiction and
inconsistent with the hypothesis of myopic addiction. The long-run
elasticity of consumption with respect to the price of beer (the
alcoholic beverage of choice by young adults) is approximately 60%
larger than the short-run price elasticity and twice as large as the
elasticity that ignores addiction.
II. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
Following Becker, Grossman, and Murphy [1994], we assume that
consumers maximize a lifetime utility function given by
(1) V = [summation of] [[Beta].sup.t-1] U([Y.sub.t], [C.sub.t],
[C.sub.t-1], [e.sub.t]) where t = 1 to [infinity].
Here [Y.sub.t] is consumption of a non-addictive good at time or age
t, [C.sub.t] is consumption of an addictive good (alcohol in our case)
at age t, [C.sub.t-1] is alcohol consumption at age t-1, [e.sub.t]
reflects the effects of unmeasured life cycle variables on utility, and
[Beta] is the time discount factor [[Beta] = 1/(1 + r), where r is the
rate of time preference for the present]. An increase in lagged alcohol
consumption ([C.sub.t -1]) lowers utility if the addiction is harmful
([Delta]U/[Delta][C.sub.t-1] [less than] 0), while an increase in the
lagged consumption raises utility if the addiction is beneficial
([Delta]U/[Delta][C.sub.t-1] [greater than] 0). Presumably, the partial
derivative just defined is negative, although the model simply assumes
that this term is nonzero. Regardless of the nature of the addiction, an
increase in past consumption must raise the marginal utility of
[C.sub.t] in order for an increase in past consumption of C to increase
current consumption.
When the utility function is quadratic and the rate of time
preference for the present is equal to the market rate of interest,
equation (1) generates a structural demand function for consumption of C
of the form
(2) [C.sub.t] = [Theta][C.sub.t-1] + [Beta][Theta][C.sub.t+1] +
[[Theta].sub.1][P.sub.t] + [[Theta].sub.2][e.sub.t].
Here [P.sub.t] is the price of [C.sub.t], and the intercept is
suppressed. Since [Theta] is positive and [[Theta].sub.t] is negative,
current consumption is positively related to past and future consumption
([C.sub.t-1] and [C.sub.t+1], respectively) and negatively related to
current price. In particular, [Theta] measures the effect of an increase
in past consumption on the marginal utility of current consumption. By
symmetry, it also measures the effect of an increase in future
consumption on the marginal impact of current consumption on next
period's utility. The larger the value of [Theta] the greater is
the degree of reinforcement or addiction.
Equation (2) is the basis of the empirical analysis in this paper.
Note that ordinary least squares estimation of the equation might lead
to biased estimates of the parameters of interest. The unobserved
variables that affect utility in each period are likely to be serially
correlated. Even if these variables are uncorrelated, [C.sub.t-1] and
[C.sub.t+1] depend on [e.sub.t] through the optimizing behavior. These
relationships imply that an ordinary least squares estimation of the
equation might incorrectly imply that past and future consumption affect
current consumption, even when the true value of [Theta] is zero.
Fortunately, the specification in equation (2) suggests a way to solve
the endogeneity problem. The equation implies that current consumption
is independent of past and future prices when past and future
consumption are held constant; any effect of past or future prices on
current consumption must come through their effects on past or future
consumption. Provided that the unobservables are uncorrelated with
prices in these periods, past and future prices are logical instruments
for past and future consumption, since past prices directly affect past
consumption, and future prices directly affect future consumption.
Therefore, the empirical strategy amounts to estimating equation (2) by
two-stage least squares, with past and future prices serving as
instrumental variables for past and future consumption. This strategy
can be modified when measures of some of the life cycle events that
affect utility and therefore partially determine [e.sub.t], such as
marital status and unemployment, are available. Then current marital
status, for example, is a relevant regressor in the structural demand
function given by equation (2), and past and future marital status are
instruments for past and future consumption.
The statistical significance of the coefficient of future consumption
provides a direct test of a rational model of addiction against an
alternative model in which consumers are myopic. In the latter model
they fail to consider the impact of current consumption on future
utility and future consumption. That is, the myopic version of equation
(2) is entirely backward looking. In this version, current consumption
depends only on current price, lagged consumption, the marginal utility
of wealth (which is one of the determinants of the current price
coefficient), and current events. Because of these distinctions, myopic
models and rational models have different implications about responses
to future changes. In particular, rational addicts increase their
current consumption when future prices are expected to fall, but myopic
addicts do not.
Equation (2) implies that there are important differences between
long- and short-run responses to permanent price changes (price changes
in more than one period) in the case of addiction. The short-run price
effect describes the response to a change in price in period t and all
future periods that is not anticipated until period t. The long-run
price effect pertains to a price change in all periods. Since
[C.sub.t-1] remains the same if a price change is not anticipated until
period t, the long-run price effect must exceed the short-run price
effect.(2)
III. DATA AND EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION
Every spring since 1975 the University of Michigan's Institute
for Social Research has conducted a nationally representative random
sample of between 15,000 and 19,000 high school seniors as part of the
Monitoring the Future research program. These surveys, which are
described in detail by Johnston, O'Malley, and Bachman [1993],
focus on the use of illegal drugs, alcohol, and cigarettes. Starting
with the class of 1976, a sample of approximately 2,400 individuals in
each senior class has been chosen for follow-up. Individuals reporting
the use of marijuana on 20 or more occasions in the past 30 days or the
use of any other illegal drug at least once in the past 30 days in their
senior year are selected with a higher probability (by a factor of
three). The 2,400 selected respondents are divided into two groups of
1,200 each; one group is surveyed on even-numbered calendar years, while
the other group is surveyed on odd-numbered calendar years. As a result
of this design, one group is resurveyed for the first time one year
after baseline (the senior year in high school), while the other group
is resurveyed for the first time two years after baseline. Subsequent
follow-ups are conducted at two-year intervals for both groups.
We estimate alcohol demand functions using ten of the 20 panels
formed from the high school senior surveys conducted from 1976 through
1985. We limit the panels to those in which the first follow-up occurred
two years after baseline, so that each follow-up was conducted at two
year intervals. The last follow-up in our data set, which contains
approximately 12,000 persons, took place in 1989. We have between one
and five observations on each person since we require information on
current, past, and future consumption of alcohol. Since an annual
measure of consumption is used in the regressions, past consumption
coincides with the second annual lag and future consumption coincides
with the second annual lead.
Information on county identifiers at baseline and at each follow-up
allowed us to augment the data set with alcoholic beverage prices from
the Inter-City Cost of Living Index, published quarterly by the American
Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association [various years] for between
250 and 300 cities since the first quarter of 1968. This association,
termed the ACCRA from now on, collects information on the prices of a
number of consumer goods including beer, wine, and distilled spirits. In
addition to prices, the ACCRA constructs a city-specific cost of living
index for each of the cities with an average for all cities in a given
quarter and year equal to one.
The baseline survey is conducted between March 15 and April 30 and
takes place in the youth's high school. The follow-up surveys are
mailed to the home addresses of respondents during the weeks of April
1-15. Respondents are requested to return the surveys promptly but do
not always do so. Consequently, we assume that the annual alcohol
consumption measure described below, which pertains to consumption
during the last year, reflects consumption in the first two quarters of
the year in which the survey was conducted (year t) and the last two
quarters of the previous year (year t-1). Thus, the current annual price
of alcohol described below is computed as a simple average of the prices
over these four quarters. The second annual lead and lag, which are
employed extensively in the regressions in Section IV, are given as a
simple average of the price in the first two quarters of year t+2 and
the last two quarters of year t+1 (second annual lead) and as a simple
average of the price in the first two quarters of year t-2 and the last
two quarters of year t-3 (second annual lag). The current, past, and
future prices are annual averages of quarterly prices rather than prices
as of a certain month within the year. Thus, they account fully for
state excise tax changes that take place during the 12-month period for
which consumption is measured.
The price assigned to each person comes from the ACCRA survey city
nearest the person's county of residence. Similar comments apply to
the computation of lags and leads of the price. For persons with
different county residence codes in survey years t and t+2, prices from
the third quarter of year t through the fourth quarter of year t+1 are
computed as simple averages of the prices in each county. Since much of
the cross-sectional variation in alcoholic beverage prices is due to
variations in state excise tax rates on these beverages, persons are
never matched to ACCRA cities outside their state of residence. This
results in the deletion of some observations because not all states are
represented in a given ACCRA survey.
Data on the consumption of specific alcoholic beverages (beer, wine,
and distilled spirits) are not collected for four-fifths of the
Monitoring the Future respondents. Therefore, the price of beer is used
as the measure of the price of alcohol. This price is selected because
beer is the most heavily consumed alcoholic beverage and because beer is
the beverage of choice among teenagers and young adults. The specific
price used is the price of a six-pack (six 12 ounce cans) of Budweiser
or Schlitz. All quarterly nominal beer prices are averaged over the four
relevant quarters to obtain the current annual nominal price of beer and
the second annual lead and lag of the price. These prices are converted
to real prices by dividing them by a year- and city-specific cost of
living index. This index is the ACCRA city-specific cost of living index
multiplied by the quarterly CPI for the U.S. as a whole (1982-84 = 1)
and then averaged over the four relevant quarters.
A sample of 21,420 person-years or person follow-ups is employed in
the empirical analysis. It is obtained by deleting persons who failed to
respond to at least three consecutive questionnaires (including
baseline) and by deleting observations for which the number of drinks of
alcohol in the past year, the current real price of beer, or current
real annual earnings are missing. Given three observations per person on
average, there are approximately 7,140 respondents in the final sample.
The number of drinks of alcohol consumed in the past year is the
dependent variable in all regressions in Section IV. This variable is
given by the product of the number of drinking occasions during the last
12 months and the number of drinks consumed on a typical drinking
occasion. The number of drinking occasions is an ordered categorical
variable with seven outcomes: 0 occasions, 1-2 occasions, 3-5 occasions,
6-9 occasions, 10-19 occasions, 20-39 occasions, and 40 or more
occasions. It is converted into a continuous variable by assigning
midpoints to the closed intervals and a value of 50 to the open-ended
interval.
The number of drinks on a typical drinking occasion is inferred from
the response to the question: "On the occasions that you drink
alcoholic beverages, how often do you drink enough to feel pretty
high?" The response categories are none of the occasions, few of
the occasions, half of the occasions, most of the occasions, and nearly
all of the occasions. We assume that the second response category
corresponds to 25% of all occasions, that the fourth corresponds to 75%
of all occasions, and that the fifth corresponds to 100% of all
occasions. We also assume that four drinks must be consumed to feel
pretty high. Persons in the first response category are assumed to
consume 1.5 drinks on a typical drinking occasion. Persons in the second
category are assumed to consume .75x1.5 + .25x4 = 2.125 drinks on a
typical occasion. Persons in third category are assigned a value of
.5x1.5 + .5x4 = 2.75. Persons in the fourth category are assigned a
value of .25x1.5 + .75x4 = 3.375, and persons in the fifth category are
given a value of four drinks on a typical occasion.
The minimum legal drinking age for the purchase and consumption of
low alcohol beer is a partial determinant of the full price of alcohol,
especially for underage youths. Since no state has ever had a legal
drinking age greater than 21, the drinking age is multiplied by a
dichotomous variable that equals one for persons 21 years of age or
younger. In addition to the own-state minimum legal drinking age, a
dichotomous indicator equal to one if a respondent resides in a county
within 25 miles of any state with a lower legal drinking age is employed
as a regressor. It is interacted with the dichotomous indicator for
persons whose age is less than or equal to 21 for the same reason that
the drinking age is interacted with this indicator. The border age
variable is included in the model to capture potential border crossings
by youths from states with high drinking ages to nearby lower age states
to obtain alcohol. With the own-state legal drinking age held constant,
the coefficient of the border age variable in the demand function should
be positive.
A variety of independent variables were constructed from the
demographic and socioeconomic information collected in the surveys.
These include sex; race (black or other); age (dichotomous indicators
for ages 19, 21, 23, and 25); real annual earnings; years of formal
schooling completed; college student status (full-time, half-time, or
less than half-time); work status (full-time, part-time, or unemployed);
religious participation (infrequent or frequent); marital status
(married, engaged, or separated or divorced); and the respondent's
number of children. Finally, all models include dichotomous variables
for nine of the ten cohorts (the high school senior classes of 1976
through 1984). The time-varying variables serve as proxies for
life-cycle variables that affect the marginal utility of current
consumption.
Given the nature of the panel, we estimate equation (2) with the
second lag of the annual number of drinks of alcohol as the measure of
past consumption and the second lead of the annual number of drinks of
alcohol as the measure of future consumption. Since past consumption and
future consumption are endogenous, the equation is fitted by two-stage
least squares (TSLS). The instruments consist of the exogenous variables
in the model, the second lag of the annual real beer price, the second
lead of the annual real beer price, the second annual lags of the two
measures pertaining to the legal drinking age (legal drinking age x age
[less than or equal to] 21 and lower border drinking age indicator x age
[less than or equal to] 21), and the second leads and the second lags of
all time-varying socioeconomic variables. These include real annual
earnings, years of formal schooling completed, college student status,
work status, religious participation, marital status, and number of
children. The second leads of the two measures pertaining to the legal
drinking age are not used as instruments because the values of these two
variables are zero except at the first follow-up.
A problem with the use of leads and lags of the socioeconomic
variables as instruments is that these variables may not be exogenous.
While plausible arguments can be made for the endogeneity of all of
them, the real issue is which ones are most likely to be caused by
alcohol consumption or correlated with the disturbance term in the
structural alcohol demand function given by equation (2). In our view,
religious participation, marital status, and number of children are more
likely to fall into the latter category. Therefore, demand functions are
obtained with and without these variables.
IV. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Panel A of Table I contains price, legal drinking age, and border age
coefficients from standard alcohol demand functions that ignore
addictive behavior. In particular, past and future consumption are
excluded from these estimates. The regression in column 1 omits
religious participation, marital status, and number of children, while
the regression in column 2 includes these variables.
The most important findings in these regressions are the negative and
significant price and legal drinking age effects and the positive and
significant border age effect. The magnitude, but not the significance,
of the price coefficient is sensitive to the inclusion of religious
participation, marital status, and number of children. In particular,
the price coefficient is cut in half when these variables are added to
the set of regressors. At the weighted (to correct for oversampling of
illegal drug users at baseline) sample means of consumption (60.630
drinks in the past year) and price ($2.789 in 1982-84 dollars for a
six-pack of Budweiser or Schlitz), the price elasticity of demand equals
-0.38 in the first regression and -0.20 in the second regression. The
first estimate may be influenced by omitted variables bias, while the
second may be influenced by simultaneous equations bias. Therefore, we
regard these two figures as bracketing the true estimate. We consider
their average of -0.29 as the benchmark price elasticity that emerges
from a demand function for the number of drinks of alcohol in the past
year that ignores addictive behavior, but we realize that the reader may
want to use the range in comparing the non-addictive and addictive
estimates.
Panel B of Table I tests the rational addiction model directly by
estimating the structural demand function given by equation (2). The
first two columns contain two-stage least squares (TSLS) regression
coefficients of past consumption, future consumption, price, and the two
drinking age variables from models in which past consumption (the second
annual lag of consumption) and future consumption (the second annual
lead of consumption) are endogenous. Religious participation, marital
status, and number of children are excluded from the first regression
and included in the second. The last two columns contain the
corresponding ordinary least squares (OLS) coefficients. Panel B also
contains F-ratios resulting from Wu's (1973) test of the hypothesis
that the regressors are exogenous and thus that the OLS estimates are
consistent.
In the model with religious participation, marital status, and number
of children, the exogeneity of the regressors is rejected. In the
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] model without these variables, the Wu
test is inconclusive. The F-ratio of 3.18 is significant at the 5% level
but not at the 1% level. Given these results and the potential
endogeneity of religious participation, marital status, and number of
children, it is useful to consider the OLS regressions as well as the
TSLS regressions in evaluating the findings.
The estimated effects of past and future consumption on current
consumption are significantly positive in the four regressions in Panel
B, and the estimated price and legal drinking age effects are
significantly negative in all cases. The positive and significant past
consumption coefficient is consistent with the hypothesis that alcohol
consumption is an addictive behavior. The positive and significant
future consumption coefficient is consistent with the hypothesis of
rational addiction and inconsistent with the hypothesis of myopic
addiction.
Clearly, the estimates indicate that alcohol consumption is addictive
in the sense that past and future changes significantly impact current
consumption. This evidence is inconsistent with the hypothesis that
alcohol consumers are myopic. Still, the estimates are not fully
consistent with rational addiction because the estimates of the discount
factor ([Beta]) - given by the ratio of the coefficient of future
consumption to the coefficient of past consumption - are implausibly
high. The implied discount factor is 2.58 in the first regression, 1.26
in the second regression, 1.37 in the third regression, and 1.34 in the
fourth regression. These discount factors correspond to negative
interest rates of -61%, -20%, -27%, and -26%, respectively.
We imposed a discount factor of 0.95 (interest rate of 5%) a priori and reestimated the four regressions in Panel B of Table I. The price
and legal drinking age coefficients in these models are extremely close
to their unconstrained counterparts. These results, combined with the
detailed analysis in Becker, Grossman, and Murphy [1994], suggest that
data on alcohol consumption or cigarette smoking are not rich enough to
pin down the discount factor with precision even if the rational
addiction model is accepted.
At the weighted sample means of consumption and price, the long-run
price elasticity of demand ranges from -0.26 to -1.26 (average equals
-0.65) in Panel B. The short-run elasticity ranges from -0.18 to -0.86
(average equals -0.41). The ratio of the long-run elasticity to the
corresponding short-run elasticity is more stable. It varies from 1.44
to 1.77 (average equals 1.60). This ratio should be compared to a ratio
of approximately 1.91 in the case of rational addiction demand functions
for cigarettes reported by Chaloupka [1991] and by Becker, Grossman, and
Murphy [1994]. Becker, Grossman, and Murphy [1991] show that the ratio
of the long-run price elasticity to the short-run price elasticity rises
as the degree of addiction, measured by the coefficient of past
consumption, rises. Thus, our results suggest that alcohol consumption
is somewhat less addictive than cigarette smoking.
Nevertheless, the long-run elasticity of demand for the number of
drinks of alcohol in the past year is substantially larger than the
short-run elasticity. The average long-run price elasticity of -0.65
also is more than twice as large as the benchmark price elasticity of
-0.29 that emerges from the demand functions in Panel A that ignore
addiction. Indeed, the average short-run elasticity is almost 40% larger
than the benchmark elasticity.
Our results bear on efforts to reduce youth alcohol abuse by raising
the legal drinking age or by raising the Federal excise tax rate on
beer. The former policy was actively pursued by the Federal government
and state governments in the late 1970s and the 1980s. It resulted in a
uniform minimum drinking age of 21 in all states as of July 1988.
Increased taxation of beer - the alcoholic beverage of choice among
youth and young adults - has been virtually ignored in the anti-drinking
campaign. Between November 1951 and January 1991, the Federal excise tax
rate on beer was fixed in nominal terms at 16 cents per six-pack.
Moreover, despite the popularity of beer, the alcohol in distilled
spirits currently is taxed twice as heavily as the alcohol in beer, and
the alcohol in spirits was taxed three times as heavily as the alcohol
in beer prior to October 1985.(3) Due in part to the stability of the
Federal beer tax and the modest increases in state beer taxes, the real
price of beer declined by 20% between 1975 and 1990.
We use the four regression models in Panel B of Table I to simulate
the effects of drinking age changes and Federal beer tax excise tax
hikes on the annual number of drinks of alcohol consumed by 19 year olds
in the mid years of our sample - 1982 and 1983. This age group consumed
62 drinks per year in the period at issue (this is the weighted mean).
The average legal drinking age was 19.6, and 19% of the sample lived
within 25 miles of a state with a lower drinking age.
If the drinking age had been 21 in all states in 1982 and 1983 (which
means that the border age indicator would have been zero for all youth),
19 year olds would have consumed approximately 11 fewer drinks of
alcohol in the long run. This is an average of the four long-run
declines predicted by the regression models in Panel B and amounts to an
18% reduction relative to the mean of 62. If the Federal beer tax had
been indexed to the rate of inflation in the Consumer Price Index since
1951, consumption would have declined by six drinks or by 10%. If the
beer tax were raised to equalize the rates at which the alcohol in beer
and liquor are taxed and if beer and liquor taxes both were indexed to
the inflation rate, consumption would have fallen by 26 drinks per year
or by more than 40%.
The impact of the combined tax policy is more than twice as large as
the impact of the drinking age policy. In part, this is because a number
of states had raised the drinking age to 21 by 1982 or 1983. Therefore,
to put these two policies in perspective, suppose that the drinking age
had been 18 (the historical minimum in any state) in all states in the
years at issue. Then consumption would have risen by eight drinks per
year. Put differently, the effect of going from a minimum legal drinking
age of 18 to one of 21 amounts to a reduction of 19 drinks per year or
slightly more than 30% relative to the mean of 62. Thus, the reduction
in consumption associated with the combined tax policy exceeds that
associated with the maximum increase in the drinking age by
approximately 37%. These computations agree with conclusions reached by
Grossman, Coate, and Arluck [1987]; Coate and Grossman [1988]; Kenkel
[1993]; and Grossman, Chaloupka, Saffer, and Laixuthai [1994] with
regard to the effectiveness of beer tax hikes. The absolute magnitudes
of the effects in these studies differ from those in our study because
the outcomes differ and because our estimates are obtained in the
context of a model of rational addiction.
Our evaluations of policies that would increase the Federal excise
tax on beer in order to curtail teenage and young adult alcohol abuse
extend previous evaluations in two important ways. First, we find that
the long-run price elasticity of consumption with respect to the price
of beer is approximately 60% larger than the short-run elasticity and
twice as large as the elasticity that ignores addiction. Thus, forecasts
of reductions in consumption in this age group would be considerably
understated if they were not based on the long-run elasticity. Put
differently, a tax hike to curtail abuse may have an unfavorable
cost-benefit ratio based on the short-run price elasticity or the price
elasticity that ignores addiction, while the same policy may have a very
favorable cost-benefit ratio based on the long-run price elasticity.
Second, we find evidence that alcohol consumption decisions made by
teenagers and young adults exhibit rational or farsighted behavior in
the sense that current consumption is positively related to future
consumption. This suggests that at least some of the internal effects or
costs of alcohol abuse are not ignored costs that can be used to justify
government intervention. If consumers take into account the future costs
that they impose upon themselves by abusing alcohol, then the case for
higher taxes or other policies to curtail abuse must be based solely on
the harm that abusers do to third parties. This conclusion is tentative
because we have focused on a measure of alcohol use rather than on a
measure of abuse and because certain aspects of moderate current alcohol
consumption may raise future utility by lowering the risk of heart
disease or by improving social interactions at bars, clubs, and parties.
Future research could clarify these issues by directly considering
measures of abuse in the context of rational addiction.
ABBREVIATION
ACCRA: American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association
This is a condensed version of Grossman, Chaloupka, and Sirtalan
[1996]. The longer version, which is available on request, contains a
detailed discussion of the model, data, and empirical results. It also
considers a number of estimation issues and performs a variety of
sensitivity analyses. In particular, we show that the choice between
weighted regressions (to correct for oversampling of illegal drug users
at baseline) and unweighted regressions is moot because the two sets of
estimates are very similar. We also present results with alternative
values for the open-ended alcohol drinking frequency category of 40 or
more occasions in the past year of 45, 55, 60, 65, 70, 80, 90, 100, 200,
and 300 (a value of 50 is used in the paper). The slope coefficient of
the price of beer rises in absolute value as the value assigned to the
open-ended category rises, but tests of significance and long- and
short-run price elasticities are not affected. In addition, results with
alternative assumptions about the number of drinks of alcohol that it
takes to get pretty high are shown to be very similar to those in the
paper. Finally, estimates obtained from a two-stage least squares
fixed-effects model in which all time-varying variables are transformed
into deviations from person-specific means and time-invariant variables
are deleted confirm the estimates presented in the paper. Research for
this paper was supported by grant 5 R01 AA08359 from the National
Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism to the National Bureau of
Economic Research. We are extremely grateful to Patrick M.
O'Malley, Senior Research Scientist at the University of
Michigan's Institute for Social Research, for providing us with the
Monitoring the Future panels and for agreeing to attach county
identifiers to our tapes. We also are extremely grateful to Jerome J.
Hiniker, Senior Research Associate at ISR, for creating the computer
programs that produced these tapes. Part of the paper was written while
Grossman was a visiting scholar at the Catholic University of Louvain in
Belgium, and he wishes to acknowledge the financial support provided by
that institution. We are indebted to Gary S. Becker, Randall K, Filer,
Robert J. Kaestner, Theodore E. Keeler, Donald S. Kenkel, Lee A.
Lillard, John Mullahy, Kevin M. Murphy, William S. Neilson, Jon P.
Nelson, Thomas R. Saving, Frank C. Wykoff, Gary A. Zarkin, and two
anonymous referees for helpful comments and suggestions. Preliminary
versions of the paper were presented at the 1995 meeting of the American
Economic Association and the 1994 meeting of the Western Economic
Association and at seminars at Brigham Young University, the Catholic
University of Louvain, Charles University in Prague, the University of
Chicago, Erasmus University in Rotterdam, the Rand Corporation, the
Stockholm School of Economics, and the United States Military Academy at
West Point. We are indebted to the participants in those meetings and
seminars for comments and suggestions. Finally, we wish to thank
Patricia Kocagil, Hadassah Luwish, Geoffrey Joyce, Sandy Grossman, Esel
Yazici, and Sara Markowitz for research assistance. This paper has not
undergone the review accorded official NBER publications; in particular,
it has not been submitted for approval by the Board of Directors.
1. For a review of this literature, see Leung and Phelps [1993]. For
recent contributions, see Baltagi and Griffin [1995] and Manning,
Blumberg, and Moulton [1995].
2. These results can be seen more formally by solving the
second-order difference equation in (2). The solution, which is
contained in Becker, Grossman, and Murphy [1994], results in an equation
in which consumption in period t depends on prices and life-cycle
variables in periods. Formulas for the long-run and short-run price
effects also are contained in the paper just cited.
3. Prior to October 1, 1985, the Federal excise tax on distilled
spirits amounted to $10.50 per gallon of spirits (50% alcohol by volume)
or $21.00 per gallon of alcohol in spirits. The beer tax of 16 cents per
six-pack is equivalent to a tax of $.29 per gallon. Since one gallon of
beer contains 4.5% alcohol by volume, this amounts to a tax of $6.44 on
one gallon of alcohol in beer. Between October l, 1985 and January 1,
1991, the Federal tax rate on spirits was $12.50 per gallon or $25.00
per gallon of alcohol in spirits. On January 1, 1991, the Federal beer
tax rate doubled to $.58 per gallon, and the spirits tax rose by 8% to
$13.50 per gallon.
REFERENCES
American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association. Inter-City Cost
of Living Index. Louisville, Kentucky, various years.
Baltagi, Badi H., and James M. Griffin. "A Dynamic Model for
Liquor: The Case for Pooling." Review of Economics and Statistics,
August 1995, 545-54.
Becker, Gary S., Michael Grossman, and Kevin M. Murphy.
"Rational Addiction and the Effect of Price on Consumption."
American Economic Review, May 1991, 237-41.
-----. "An Empirical Analysis of Cigarette Addiction."
American Economic Review, June 1994, 396-418.
Becker, Gary S, and Kevin M. Murphy. "A Theory of Rational
Addiction." Journal of Political Economy, August 1988, 675-700.
Chaloupka, Frank J. "Rational Addictive Behavior and Cigarette
Smoking." Journal of Political Economy, August 1991, 722-42.
Coate, Douglas, and Michael Grossman. "Effects of Alcoholic
Beverage Prices and Legal Drinking Ages on Youth Alcohol Use."
Journal of Law and Economics, April 1988, 145-71.
Grant, Bridget F., Thomas C. Hartford, Patricia Chou, Roger
Pickering, Deborah A. Dawson, Frederick S. Stinson, and John Noble.
"Prevalence of DSM-III-R Alcohol Abuse and Dependence."
Alcohol Health & Research World, 15(1), 1991, 91-96.
Grossman, Michael, Frank J. Chaloupka, Henry Suffer, and Adit Laixuthai. "Alcohol Price Policy and Youths: A Summary of Economic
Research." Journal of Research on Adolescence, 4(2), 1994, 347-64.
Grossman, Michael, Frank J. Chaloupka, and Ismail Sirtalan. "An
Empirical Analysis of Alcohol Addiction: Results from the Monitoring the
Future Panels." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper
No. 5200, Revised August 1996.
Grossman, Michael, Douglas Coate, and Gregory M. Arluck. "Price
Sensitivity of Alcoholic Beverages in the United States," in
Control Issues in Alcohol Abuse Prevention: Strategies for States and
Communities, edited by Harold D. Holder. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press,
Inc., 1987, 169-98.
Johnston, Lloyd D., Patrick M. O'Malley, and Jerald G. Bachman.
National Survey Results from the Monitoring the Future Study, 1975-1992.
NIH Publication No. 93-3597/98. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office, 1993.
Keeler, Theodore E., Teh-wei Hu, Paul G. Barnett, and Willard G.
Manning. "Taxation, Regulation, and Addiction: A Demand Function
for Cigarettes based on Time-Series Evidence." Journal of Health
Economics, April 1993, 1-18.
Kenkel, Donald S. "Drinking, Driving, and Deterrence: The Social
Costs of Alternative Policies." Journal of Law and Economics,
October 1993, 877-913.
Leung, Siu Fai, and Charles E. Phelps. "'My Kingdom for a
Drink....?' A Review of the Price Sensitivity of Demand for
Alcoholic Beverages," in Economic and Socioeconomic Issues in the
Prevention of Alcohol-Related Problems, edited by Gregory Bloss and
Michael Hilton. National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism
Research Monograph 25. NIH Publication No. 93-3513. Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Government Printing Office 1993, 1-32.
Manning, Willard G., Linda Blumberg, and Lawrence H. Moulton.
"The Demand for Alcohol: the Differential Response to Price."
Journal of Health Economics, June 1995, 123-48.
Rachal, J. Valley, L. Lynn Guess, Robert L. Hubbard, Stephen A.
Maisto, Elizabeth R. Cavanaugh, Richard Waddell, and Charles H. Benrud.
"The Extent and Nature of Adolescent Alcohol Abuse: The 1974 and
1978 National Sample Surveys." Prepared for the National Institute
on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism. Springfield, Virginia: U.S. National
Technical Information Service, 1980.
Wu, De-Min. "Alternative Tests of Independence between
Stochastic Regressors and Disturbances." Econometrica, July 1973,
733-50.
Grossman: Distinguished Professor of Economics, City University of
New York Graduate School and Research Associate, National Bureau of
Economic Research Phone 1-212-953-0200 x104, Fax 1-212-953-0339 E-mail
[email protected]
Chaloupka: Associate Professor of Economics, University of Illinois
at Chicago and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Phone 1-312-413-2367 Fax 1-312-996-3344, E-mail
[email protected]
Sirtalan: Director, Health Economics, Greater New York Hospital
Association, Phone 1-212-506-5414 Fax 1-212-397-0717, E-mail
[email protected]