Economic growth regressions for the American states: a sensitivity analysis.
Crain, W. Mark ; Lee, Katherine J.
I. INTRODUCTION
Researchers motivated by a variety of questions turn to data on the
economic performance of the American states to analyze their ideas
empirically. The appeal of cross-state empirical analysis derives from
the fact that while states differ in relevant dimensions, they are not
so different as to make omitted variables an overwhelming source of
error. For example, the state economies operate under the same monetary
regime (The Federal Reserve), comparable legal institutions (The U.S.
Constitution), and borders open to the flow of productive factors,
knowledge and products. Cross-state analysis avoids the myriad
structural differences that encumber cross-national empirical analysis.
Thus, investigators feel secure in considering a relatively small number
of control variables in attempting to establish a statistical
relationship between state economic performance and a particular
variable of interest. The availability of uniform and accurate
time-series data for the states adds to the appeal of cross-state
regression models.
Despite the advantages associated with evaluating institutionally
similar economies, researchers who rely on state regressions find little
systematic guidance concerning which variables to include and other
basic specification issues. For instance, do demographic and geographic
characteristics vary sufficiently across states to require independent
controls? Do cultural or climatic conditions affect growth, or are these
variables correlated with other factors that may affect growth such as
labor force participation rates or education levels?
A review of the extensive literature reveals that few studies
control for the variables analyzed by other researchers. These
specification differences make it hard to evaluate and compare the
results of existing studies. Bartik [1991] and Phillips and Goss [1995]
illustrate this problem as they attempt to garner the effect of taxes on
state economic development from dozens of studies that employ
alternative specifications and methodologies. They use Meta Regression
Analysis (MRA) to test whether specification changes and alternative
variables significantly affect the estimated elasticity of state growth
with respect to taxes. The MRA technique focuses on the sensitivity of
the estimated coefficients for state tax variables to model variation.
In this paper we employ a technique to assess the sensitivity of
numerous control variables identified in the state growth literature. We
also introduce several new control variables. The approach identifies
which variables are robust to small changes in the conditioning
information set.
Our procedure closely follows that in Levine and Renelt [1992]
which for its part relies on the Extreme-Bounds Analysis (EBA) suggested
by Learner [1983; 1985].(1) The main difference is that we employ annual
panel data on the American states (pooling cross-sectional and
time-series data) whereas Levine and Renelt employ cross-country data
averaged over 20-year or even longer time intervals. The cross-country
studies such as those assessed in Levine and Renelt that average long
time periods generally seek to identify factors associated with
long-run, steady state growth. The U.S. state studies using annual panel
data do not share a comparable unifying purpose. Relationships estimated
from yearly data reveal short-term responses and pick-up business cycle
effects which confounds drawing implications about growth theory. With
this qualification in mind the results presented below indicate which
variables included in past studies are robust and provide a set of core
variables as a starting point for future research that relies on state
growth regressions and annual panel data. Finally, the findings
demonstrate that several important conclusions in the literature depend
on how variables are measured. For example, the relationship between
state growth and government size reverses sign depending on whether we
denominate government size in per capita terms or as a share of state
income.
II. SPECIFICATION ISSUES, SAMPLE, AND SENSITIVITY TECHNIQUE
Adopting the convenient notation in Levine and Renelt [1992], the
EBA uses equations of the general form:
(1) Y = [[Beta].sub.i] I + [[Beta].sub.m] M + [[Beta].sub.z] Z + u,
where
Y = real per capita personal income;
I = a set of core variables always included in the regressions;
M = the variable of interest;
Z = a subset of variables chosen from a pool of variables
identified by past studies as potentially important explanatory
variables of state growth; and
u = a random disturbance term.
Annual observations on the 48 contiguous American states serve as
the basic unit of measurement. The Appendix tables provide complete
definitions of the variables, data sources, and summary statistics.
Equation (1) specifies real per capita personal income, a common
indicator of state economic performance, as the dependent variable.(2)
Two variables constitute I, the set of core variables always included in
the EBA: the share of the state population between the ages of 18 and
64, and the share of the state population with a bachelor's degree
or better.(3) The two core variables target a fundamental element of
growth, the size and skill of the labor force.(4) Using a common core
specification to compare across models makes the analysis tractable,
while leaving most of the variables open to the sensitivity analysis.
The EBA evaluates 29 variables identified by past studies as
potentially relevant to state economic performance, i.e., we examine 29
"M variables" as defined in Equation (1).(5) The procedure
first regresses Y on I and M, producing a "base" regression
result for each M variable. We then regress Y on I, M, and linear
combinations of a set of six Z variables taken two at a time (further
described below). The ten regressions generated for each M variable
using the subsets of Z variables allow us to identify the highest and
lowest values for the coefficient on M (denoted [[Beta].sub.m]), and
thereby define the upper and lower bounds of [[Beta].sub.m]. The extreme
upper bound is the highest value of [[Beta].sub.m] plus two standard
deviations; the extreme lower bound is the lowest value of
[[Beta].sub.m] minus two standard deviations.(6) If [[Beta].sub.m]
remains significant and of the same sign at the extreme bounds, we label
the partial correlation between Y and the M variable "robust."
If [[Beta].sub.m] does not remain significant or if it changes signs at
the extreme bounds, we label the partial correlation
"fragile."
We select the set of Z variables for the EBA from the pool of 29
variables. The selection process involves two steps. First we group the
29 variables into seven general categories. For example, three variables
represent alternative ways to proxy a state's industrial
composition, and seven variables represent alternative ways to proxy
fiscal policy indicators. The Appendix identifies the seven categories,
and the variables associated with each. Second we use univariate
regressions to identify one variable from within each category that best
proxies that particular dimension.(7) To illustrate, among the three
variables that proxy a state's Industrial Composition, the
univariate regression for the "Industry Diversity" variable
exhibits a much higher R-square than the regressions for the other two
variables in that category; we thus use it to represent the Industrial
Composition group in the set of Z variables. We likewise select one
variable from the other categories to obtain a set of six Z
variables.(8) The Appendix identifies the Z variables. Again, the EBA
for each of the 29 M variables varies the subset of Z variables by
running regressions that include all linear combinations of the Z
variables taken two at a time. These Z-variable combinations exclude the
representative variable from the same category as the variable of
interest.(9) This procedure thus yields ten regressions for the EBA of
each M variable.
Samples and Preliminary Diagnostics
The samples consist of panel data for the 48 contiguous states for
a 16-year period, except for the category of variables measuring the
stocks of public and private capital (we explain the exception in more
detail below). The sample period commences with 1977 data, the initial
year for which we could obtain a consistent series on all variables. The
sample period ends with 1992 data, the most recent year for which all
data are available (excepting the capital stock variables as noted in
footnote 8).
Preliminary specifications using the logged-levels of the variables
indicated first-order positive serial correlation, yielding
Durbin-Watson statistics well below the lower limit critical values.
Furthermore, Dickey-Fuller unit root tests failed to reject the
hypothesis that the series follow random walks. As a remedial strategy
we first-difference all of the variables (first-differencing makes the
model stationary). Of course, first-differencing the variables frames
the analysis in terms of growth rates. As it turns out, employing growth
rates as the dependent variable coincides with the majority of past
studies.(10) In summary we use a Generalized Least squares estimation
procedure on logged, first-differenced data to correct for
nonstationarity, serial correlation, and heteroscedasticity. Finally we
include a constant term in the first-differenced model to pick up the
effect of any time trend.(11)
III. RESULTS OF THE EXTREME BOUNDS ANALYSIS
The core model of the EBA yields the following regression results
(t-statistics are in parentheses):
PPY = 0.008 + 1.401 LABOR + 0.210 EDUC, (3.91) (8.36) (2.76)
where PPY is real per capita personal income, LABOR is the share of
the population between the ages of 18 and 64, and EDUC is the share of
the population with a bachelor's degree or better.(12) The signs of
the estimated coefficients are consistent with theory and significant at
the 1% level. The core specification explains 20% of the variation in
the dependent variable. The EBA Uses this core specification as a
starting point to evaluate the effect of small changes in the
conditioning information on the variable of interest.
Table I presents the EBA results for 29 variables. The table
organizes the results into the seven variable categories, and the
discussion proceeds in that order. Table I reports three regression
results for each variable: the base model (which includes only the
variable of interest and the core variables); the extreme upper bound
model; and the extreme lower bound model. The columns list: the
estimated coefficient for [[Beta].sub.m]; its t-statistic; the R-square;
and the Control Variables (i.e., the subset of the Z variables) included
in the upper- and lower-bound models. The far right column reports the
results of the EBA, identifying the variable of interest as either
fragile or robust.
State Industrial Composition
Growth regressions often include a variable controlling for a
state's industrial composition. For instance, Mofidi and Stone
[1990] include the percentage of non-agricultural employment in durable
goods industries, and Romans and Subrahmanyam [1979] include the ratio
of non-agricultural to agricultural income. Glaeser et al. [1992]
explicitly test the effect of industrial composition using data on
American cities, finding that a diversified economy tends to promote
growth more than a homogeneous economic base.
We evaluate three variables that proxy a state's industrial
composition: Industry Diversity; Manufacturing Share of Gross State
Product (GSP); and Service Share of GSP.(13) Two variables, the Service
Share of GSP and Industry Diversity, yield robust results. The growth
rate in per capita income decreases as the Service Share of GSP grows
more rapidly, and increases as the industrial base diversifies [TABULAR
DATA FOR TABLE I OMITTED] more rapidly.(14) These results indicate that
while state growth regressions appropriately include a control for a
state's industrial composition, it would be beneficial to use
Industry Diversity or the Service Share of GSP rather than the
Manufacturing Share of GSP.
Fiscal Policy Indicators
The effects of fiscal policy and public sector growth on state
economic performance have received considerable attention since the
late-1970s.(15) While this relationship had been examined at the
national level, researchers turned to the diverse revenue and
expenditure policies of the states to add a new dimension to empirical
research. State data provide an opportunity to identify the alternative
effects of taxes and expenditures and to test fairly specific hypotheses
concerning fiscal policy. Romans and Subrahmanyam [1979] find that tax
progressivity and expenditure policies affect growth to a larger extent
than the overall level of taxes. Plaut and Pluta [1983] find that states
relying more heavily on the property tax exhibit higher rates of
industrial growth than states relying more heavily on other revenue
sources. Helms [1985] finds that taxes used to finance transfers reduce
state incomes, but the net effect of tax-financed spending in other
areas may be positive.
We include seven broad measures of fiscal policy in the EBA: Total
Revenue Share of Personal Income; Tax Revenue Share of Personal Income;
Total Revenue Per Capita; Tax Revenue Per Capita; Expenditure Share of
Personal Income; Expenditure Per Capita; and the Government Share of
GSP. Although the public finance literature offers evidence that
particular tax and expenditure policies matter, we evaluate broad
measures of fiscal balance for two reasons. First, as a practical matter
this approach offers guidance to researchers primarily interested in
non-fiscal variables, and who simply want a reasonable set of control
variables. Second, introducing narrow fiscal variables such as the state
income tax or state spending on welfare invites an endogeneity problem.
For example, the demographic or economic composition of a state may
influence the tax structure.(16) Finally, the analysis informs the
empirical question of whether alternative measurements of fiscal policy
affect the results. For instance, do the results change if measures of
revenue include all sources of revenue or only tax revenue?(17) Does it
matter if we denominate taxes as a share of personal income, or in per
capita terms?
Six of the seven fiscal policy variables evaluated exhibit robust
results; only Expenditure Per Capita proves fragile.(18) We find that
using total revenue versus tax revenue affects the results. The signs of
the estimated coefficients are consistent, but the magnitudes (even
after accounting for different means) yield different implications for
the marginal effect of revenue changes.
More importantly, we find that the signs of the coefficients on the
robust fiscal policy variables generally depend on whether such
variables (expenditures, total revenue, or tax revenue) are measured in
per capita terms or as a share of the state's economy. The
estimated coefficients exhibit positive signs for Total Revenue Per
Capita and Tax Revenue Per Capita. The estimated coefficients exhibit
negative signs for Total Revenue Share of Personal Income, Tax Revenue
Share of Personal Income, Expenditure Share of Personal Income, and the
Government Share of GSP. Here the opposite signs highlight an underlying
source of difficulty in evaluating the results from different areas of
fiscal policy research. For instance, studies estimating the
relationship between state fiscal policies and economic performance
typically measure the size of government as a share of the economy.(19)
Alternatively, studies of the determinants of public sector growth
typically measure the size of government in per capita terms.(20)
Public and Private Capital
A flurry of studies investigating the impact of public and private
capital on state economic output appeared in the 1990s. The conventional
approach estimates a state-level production function, regressing output
against public capital, private capital, labor, and other conditioning
variables such as the unemployment rate.(21) The extensive efforts by
Munnell [1990] and Holtz-Eakin [1993] to assemble previously unavailable
state-level measures of capital stocks represent a valuable by-product
of this research program.
In their cross-country sensitivity analysis Levine and Renelt find
investment as a share of GDP to be the most important factor in
explaining variations in long-run growth rates. We evaluate this result
at the state level using the variables produced by Munnell and
Holtz-Eakin. As noted above, these data series end in 1987, as opposed
to 1992 for the other variables analyzed in this study.(22)
We evaluate five variables created from the capital stock data,
each lagged one period. Of course, first-differencing the capital stock
measures generates variables that reflect investment rates, comparable
to the investment measure examined by Levine and Renelt. The EBA
identifies these five variables as robust, although the estimated
coefficients are opposite of the expected sign. The confounding state
results suggest that updating the Munnell and Holtz-Eakin data series
would not enhance growth rate regressions employing panel data. Levine
and Renelt conclude investment rates are key components of growth
models, but their analysis focuses on long-term growth rates. This
analysis of short-term responses and business cycles in the state
economies finds nothing comparable.
Cultural/Ethnic Characteristics
In addition to the age and education controls in our core model, we
include three demographic variables in the analysis intended to capture
cultural and ethnic differences across states: Religious Affiliation
Diversity; Church Membership; and the Black Population Share.(23) Of the
subset of econometric studies evaluating the relationship between
economic performance and fiscal policy, Mofidi and Stone [1990] are the
only researchers controlling for a state's demographic
characteristics. Mofidi and Stone find a negative coefficient on the
percent of population that is nonwhite. We find a positive, but
insignificant coefficient on the percent of the population that is
black, and overall this variable is fragile.(24) The other cultural and
ethnic characteristics variables also produce fragile results. These
findings indicate neglecting cultural and ethnic differences does not
appear to bias existing studies.
Public Choice Variables
The variables in this section draw from concepts addressed in
studies of state growth but with foundations in the public choice
literature. They generally proxy factors that affect government
structure and the performance of public policy, forces that in turn
affect individual and firm location decisions. These factors include
agglomeration economies, availability of public services, government
influence, and market access.(25) Studies employing cross-state
regressions commonly control for population density: Plaut and Pluta
[1983], Smith and Smith [1984], Helms [1985] and Garand [1988]. As
Garand [1988] points out, population density may affect government
performance through its relationship to the demand for public services.
We evaluate Population Density in the EBA and four other Public Choice
Variables: Local Share of Government Tax Revenue; Urbanization;
Interstate Commuting; and Owner-Occupied Housing. While Population
Density or Urbanization appear in a number of econometric studies, three
of the five measures included under the Public Choice category are not
widely used in the state growth literature (Local Share of Government
Tax Revenue, Interstate Commuting, and Owner- Occupied Housing),
warranting a brief discussion of their potential impact on growth. These
three measures each relate to factors that may restrain, or at least
influence, state and local government policy and may ultimately affect
the availability or cost of public services. As the empirical public
finance literature suggests, these measures also may affect growth if
they affect the tax structure adopted by a state. For instance, local
governments rely more heavily than state governments on property taxes,
which we control for with the variable Local Share of Government Tax
Revenue.26 The Interstate Commuting variable may be tied to growth
because a state with a high percentage of its workers crossing state
boundaries suggests residents have jurisdictional choices available to
them. The state government may be more constrained in fiscal-policy
decisions and may be more likely to implement policy consistent with
constituent preferences. In many areas, labor market participants must
jointly make residential and labor market mobility decisions. In areas
conducive to interstate commuting, individuals may choose to work in
high wage, high tax areas, but live in low wage, low tax areas.(27)
Finally, as discussed by Bartik [1991] the effect of development
policies on households partially depends on whether they are renters or
owners, which we control for with the Owner-Occupied Housing variable.
The EBA identifies only Local Share of Government Tax Revenue as
robust. The estimated negative relationship indicates that a decline in
local government relative to state government tax revenues facilitates
economic growth. Further research is required to determine whether this
result derives from the resulting tax structure, factors relating to inter-jurisdictional competition, or some other factor.
Pressure Groups
George Stigler's seminal [1971] article that framed economic
regulation in an interest group perspective inspired a large empirical
literature on the effects of political pressure groups on economic
development. Olson [1982] initiated the use of American state data to
test the interest group theory, followed by a host of studies that both
support and refute the thesis that pressure groups significantly affect
growth.(28) Becker's [1983] theoretical elaboration of the pressure
group framework mediates these opposing empirical results. While each
pressure group may seek efficiency-reducing policies, competition among
multiple pressure groups drives the policy process toward outcomes that
minimize excess burden.
We evaluate four measures of pressure group activity: Business
Association Revenue Share of Personal Income; Business Association
Revenue Per Capita; Number of Business Associations; and Union
Membership.(29) The EBA finds the Business Association Revenue Share of
Personal Income and Business Association Revenue Per Capita variables
robust, but the Number of Business Associations and Union Membership
variables fragile. As with the fiscal policy variables, we find that the
signs of the coefficients on the robust measures of interest group
activity depend on the measurement method. The per capita variable
exhibits a positive sign consistent with Becker's hypothesis,
whereas the share of personal income variable exhibits a negative sign
in support of the Stigler-Olson hypothesis.(30) In short, empirical
conclusions concerning the impact of pressure groups on state economic
performance appear quite sensitive to variable measurement.
Energy Prices
Many researchers explore the thesis that sunbelt and frostbelt
states exhibit different growth paths, primarily because of differences
in energy and labor costs; these include Plaut and Pluta [1983] and
Wasylenko and McGuire [1985]. Although the two temperature variables we
considered could not be used because they lacked time-series variation
(see footnote 5), we examine one variable that controls for differences
in energy prices across states. The EBA identified Real Energy Prices as
fragile. The estimated coefficient is insignificantly different from
zero, and it switches signs at the extreme bounds.
IV. ROBUST REGRESSION MODELS RECOMMENDED FOR FUTURE RESEARCH
Table II seeks to consolidate and refine the results from the
sensitivity analysis into a format useful for future empirical research.
Table II includes only the core variables and select "robust"
variables as determined by the extreme bounds analysis. We sift the
robust variables and nominate five model specifications for reasons
described below.
First, for categories yielding more than one robust variable, we
allot these robust variables into separate model specifications; for
example Models 1, 3, and 5 contain Industry Diversity and Models 2 and 4
contain Service Share of GSP. The exception is the Fiscal Policy group
from which we include revenue and expenditure variables within a single
specification (Model 3).(31) Second, from the Fiscal Policy and Pressure
Groups categories Table II extracts only the robust variables
denominated as a share of the state's economy; we pan the robust
variables from these categories denominated in per capita terms. We base
this choice on the principle that the share-denominated variables
reflect the economically relevant allocation of resources more
appropriately than the population-denominated variables.(32) Likewise
Table II extracts from the Pressure Group category one of the variables
measured in relation to a state's economy; Business Association
Revenue Share of Personal Income is included in Models 4 and 5. A
conceptual principle stands behind this choice. Growth implications
derive from the relative allocation of private sector resources within a
state between redistributive versus productive activities. Finally, the
recommended models in Table II adopt the "Total Revenue Share of
Income" variable instead of the related "Tax Revenue Share of
Income" [TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE II OMITTED] variable. The EBA
results in Table I indicate that the marginal effect of total revenue
shares exceed the marginal effect of tax revenue shares; in other words,
changes in non-tax revenue sources as well as changes in taxes affect
economic growth.(33)
The overall explanatory power of the models in Table II ranges from
0.469 to 0.622. By comparison, the core cross-country model of long run
growth identified by Levine and Renelt [1992] yields an R-square of
0.46. In the five recommended models the estimated coefficients of the
variables evaluated in the EBA retain the sign, significance and
magnitude that one would expect from the sensitivity analysis on the
variables individually. Of the core variables, Share of the Population
with a BA or Better retains a positive sign in four of the five models,
but is not significant. The other core variable, Share of the Population
Ages 18-64, remains positive and significant.
Finally, we note that these models rely on a common intercept term
for each cross-section. As discussed by Bartik [1991] this restriction
may attribute to one of the included variables an effect deriving from
an omitted variable. To test for an omitted variable bias, we
re-estimate the models with state fixed effects. We then evaluate the
coefficients in the restricted and unrestricted models to determine
[TABULAR DATA FOR TABLE III OMITTED] whether the change in model
specification changes the explanatory power of the variables found to be
robust in the EBA. As shown in Table III, Wald tests restricting the
coefficients in the fixed effects models to the coefficients in the
common intercept models generally fail to reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients are the same. The common intercept restriction
does not appear to bias the results.34
V. CONCLUSION
The 1992 watershed study by Levine and Renelt inventoried
cross-country growth regressions and provided an important baseline for
subsequent empirical research. This paper emulates their purpose and
approach, drawing on the voluminous literature that estimates growth
equations using panel data for the American states. Like Levine and
Renelt we discover that many commonly used control variables are fragile
to small changes in model specification. We also find that the sign of
the estimated coefficient for critical variables depends on how a
variable is transformed, for example whether state government revenue or
political pressure groups are denominated in per capita terms or as a
share of state income. This helps to explain the array of incongruent results in the literature.
The extreme bounds sensitivity analysis provides a starting point
for future research that relies on panel data and state growth
regressions. We identify robust control variables including proxies for
industrial composition, fiscal policy, the relative cost of state versus
local government services, and pressure group activity. Limitations of
the analysis merit recognition, however. Identifying robust correlations
with growth does not necessarily imply an interpretable or important
economic relationship; issues such as causality and coefficient size
remain. Further, a fragile correlation does not automatically imply an
unimportant economic relationship; rather the variation among two
control variables may simply be too close to identify an independent
link with growth. Extreme bounds analysis furnishes a useful guide for
analysis, but it alone does not define what is a valuable result.
[TABULAR DATA FOR APPENDIX TABLE A1 OMITTED]
[TABULAR DATA FOR APPENDIX TABLE A2 OMITTED]
ABBREVIATIONS
EBA: Extreme-Bonds Analysis
GSP: Gross State Product
MRA: Meta Regression Analysis
We are grateful to Bob Tollison, Tom Saving, Nicole Crain and an
anonymous referee for helpful comments and to the Center for Study of
Public Choice for financial support.
1. Its large number of citations indicates the influence of the
work by Levine and Renelt [1992]. Like Levine and Renelt we do not
estimate a structural model, establish causal links, identify growth
determinants, or conduct other analyses discussed in Leamer [1985] and
McAleer et al. [1985]. Rather we examine whether estimated relationships
are robust or fragile to small changes in model specification.
2. Some studies use Gross State Product (GSP) or state employment
to measure economic performance. The simple correlation coefficient between real per capita personal income and real per capita GSP is 0.80;
the correlation coefficient between real per capita personal income and
employment is 0.63. Note that these correlations reflect logged,
first-differenced transformations of the variables for the period
1977-1992. Although GSP and personal income tend to exhibit similar
trends, these alternative measures of economic performance differ in
important ways. For instance GSP includes allowances for depreciation
and indirect business taxes. The preferred measure to use depends on the
particular question being evaluated.
3. We follow the procedure in Levine and Renelt [1992] and use a
small set of core variables (they also include a country investment
variable, reflecting the long-run growth model underlying their
analysis). Unlike many growth studies we do not include the initial
level of income as an independent variable. The validity of using lagged
values of the level of income has received considerable attention in
models that test the convergence hypothesis (e.g., Friedman [1992], Quah
[1993], Hart [1995], and Barro [1996]). This debate notwithstanding, our
model considers annual observations on performance, and does not address
the convergence hypothesis.
4. We note that a related measure of educational attainment - the
high school graduate share of a state's population - exhibits
little variation across the American states, and in a preliminary
estimation (not reported in the text) it did not perform as well as the
population share with a bachelor's degree. Another sometimes-used
variable, engineering degrees, is not readily available for our entire
sample period. We also do not include a wage variable in the analysis
despite its use by some researchers because of an endogeneity problem:
the influence of growth on wages. The core model includes two variables
that affect labor market conditions and thus wage costs. We also examine
union membership, another commonly-used proxy for labor costs, as an M
variable.
5. Beyond the 29 M variables described in the Appendix we discarded three other M variables prior to the EBA analysis: Miles of Common
Border, Average Temperature, and Average Deviation from the Average
Temperature. These variables do not exhibit time-series variation, and
regression models including these variables as panel data fail to yield
non-singular matrices.
6. We consider only statistically significant equations to identify
the upper and lower bounds of [[Beta].sub.m].
7. The univariate analysis regressed Y against each M variable and
a constant term. We identified one variable from each of the general
categories based on an overall assessment of three criteria: the
regression R-square, the significance of the estimated coefficient, and
the Durbin-Watson statistic.
8. We do not include a representative variable from the Public and
Private Capital group in the set of Z variables because these data only
spanned two-thirds of the sample period available for the other
variables.
9. For example, in the EBA for the variable "Manufacturing
Share of GSP," we exclude the Industry Diversity variable from the
subset of Z variables. Both variables proxy a state's Industrial
composition.
10. A notable exception is the Helms study [1985] that specifies
the level of real personal income as the dependent variable. Many of the
studies examining the productivity of public capital such as Aschauer
[1989a] and Munnell [1990] also use levels (GDP) as the dependent
variable. These studies have been criticized, for example by Tatom
[1991], for failing to correct for nonstationarity.
11. Performing the analysis with state fixed effects generates
similar results. This is not surprising because first-differencing and
fixed effects offer alternative techniques to control for problems
caused by omitted variables. (Bartik [1994] and Phillips and Goss [1995]
reach this same conclusion.) We rely on a common intercept for the EBA
as way to attribute as much explanatory power as possible to the
variable of interest. We then evaluate whether our final model
specifications based on the EBA results suffer from omitted variable
bias. Section 4 describes the method and results of this test. The
non-fixed effects models provide an additional benefit: sometimes
researchers have limited time series data on a particular variable of
interest, which renders fixed effects models infeasible.
12. We reiterate that all variables enter the regression analysis
as logged first-differences.
13. The Industry Diversity variable is calculated as the sum of the
squared share of private, non- farm GSP originating in eight industries:
agricultural services; mining; construction; manufacturing;
transportation and utilities; wholesale and retail trade; finance,
insurance, and real estate; and services.
14. This measure of industrial diversity does not assess the effect
of competition within particular industries. The degree of competition
represents a different dimension as described in Glaeser, et al. [1992].
15. Bartik [1991; 1994], Phillips and Goss [1995], and Wasylenko
[1997] survey most of this literature.
16. The Public Choice Variables group tangentially addresses the
effects of alternative tax and expenditure policies. Several variables
in that group intend to capture factors that may influence government
policy choices.
17. In 1993 tax revenue accounted for 47% of total revenue on
average across states, and ranged from 35% to 59%. Intergovernmental transfers in the form of federal grants account for most of the non-tax
portion of state revenue.
18. We enter the fiscal policy variables contemporaneously,
although lagging these variables made no difference in the signs of the
estimated coefficients. In an effort to keep the number of reported
specifications to a manageable level, we simply report the
contemporaneous models. At first blush, contemporaneous fiscal policy
indicators may seem unreasonable. However, note that the enactment of
fiscal policy legislation typically precedes implementation by six to 12
months. For instance, tax legislation in Virginia that becomes law in,
say, January of 1999 would typically affect the 2000 Fiscal Year,
beginning in July of 1999 and ending in June 2000, and subsequent years
because tax policy changes are often phased-in. The state government
finance statistics produced by the U.S. Bureau of the Census relate to
fiscal years, typically beginning in July.
19. An exception is the state growth study by Dye [1980] that
includes taxes as a percentage of personal income, but expenditures in
per capita terms.
20. For example, Abrams and Dougan [1986] and Shadbegian [1996]
evaluate the effects of constitutional constraints on per capita
expenditures.
21. The seminal, if controversial work by David Aschauer [1989a and
1989b] surely spurred research using state level data. Aschauer
estimates a high marginal product of public capital relative to private
capital using aggregate U.S. data. Morrison and Schwartz [1996] recently
employ a cost function approach. For comprehensive literature surveys
see Munnell [1992] and Gramlich [1994].
22. We are grateful to Alicia Munnell and Douglas Holtz-Eakin for
making their data available. One motivation for evaluating the
robustness of the capital stock data is to assess the usefulness of
updating the Munnell and Holtz-Eakin data series, no small task.
23. The Religious Affiliation Diversity variable is calculated as
the sum of the squared share of total adherents comprising four broad
denominations: Baptists, Catholics, Methodists, and all others.
Barro [1996] investigates the impact of religion on political
freedom and economic growth using cross-country regressions. His
estimated coefficients show weak results, but Barro argues that
religious creeds carry indirect effects (e.g., religious tenets affect
female schooling that in turn affects growth and political freedom).
24. The conflicting signs with Modifi and Stone [1990] may result
from our inclusion of an education variable in the core model.
25. Schmenner, Huber and Cook [1987] broadly characterize similar
factors as relating to the "attractiveness of the state."
26. Local Share of Government Tax Revenue also may proxy the
independence of localities relative to the state or the degree of fiscal
centralization within a state. If factor mobility within a state exceeds
factor mobility between states, a state with less centralized decision-making may offer attractive alternatives to individuals and
firms. A higher Local Share of Government Tax Revenue also may be
correlated with more intergovernmental competition.
27. Additionally, states with a higher value for Interstate
Commuting may rely more heavily on sales taxes as a mechanism to export
the tax burden to non-residents.
28. Conceptually, the Stigler-Olson thesis states that interest
groups move the policy process toward unproductive, redistributional
outcomes at the expense of market-driven activities that promote
efficiency and lower prices. For examples of the empirical studies, see
Mueller and Murrell [1986], Gray and Lowery [1988], and the survey
articles by Tollison [1988] and Mitchell and Munger [1991].
29. A variable controlling for union membership appears in many
state growth regression models, for example, in Dye [1980], Newman
[1983], and Helms [1985]. We use this variable as a measure of pressure
group activity, but some researchers use union membership as a proxy for
labor costs. In this context, we alternatively categorized Union
Membership as an Industrial Composition variable or a Public Choice
variable in results not reported in the text. The results of the EBA did
not change when we re-categorized the Union Membership variable; Union
Membership proves fragile regardless of its categorization.
30. The positive signs on the per capita interest group measures
are consistent with Becker's hypothesis that competition among
pressure groups minimizes inefficient policy outcomes, but do not
validate his hypothesis. These measures reflect only a crude proxy for
the degree of pressure group competition.
31. Helms [1985] pioneered this approach in state growth
regressions using panel data, stressing the relevance of both taxes and
the expenditures financed by these taxes.
32. A simple case illustrates. Government revenue per capita in
Massachusetts exceeds government revenue per capita in Michigan. At the
same time, state government revenues absorb a smaller share of state
income in Massachusetts than in Michigan. The extent to which the public
sector exercises control over a state's resources is thus greater
in Michigan than in Massachusetts, although the per capita revenue
variables would suggest otherwise. Recall that the EBA results in Table
I show opposite signs on the fiscal policy coefficients depending on how
the variables are measured, rendering this choice a non-trivial
decision.
33. This finding supports Vedder's [1982] hypothesis that the
methods of distributing intergovernmental transfers affect states'
policy decisions. For example, federal intergovernmental transfer
programs may encourage states to adopt growth-retarding revenue
policies.
34. The Wald test on the Pressure Groups variable rejects the null
hypothesis that the estimated coefficient suffers from omitted variable
bias, but the results are opposite of what would be expected if the
common coefficient restriction were attributing to pressure groups an
effect deriving from another source. The estimated coefficient in the
unrestricted model retains a negative and significant coefficient, but
the effect of pressure groups in the unrestricted model exceeds the
effect in the restricted model. This finding offers reassurance that the
estimated negative relationship between Pressure Groups and Personal
Income growth is not spurious.
REFERENCES
Abrams, Burton A., and William R. Dougan. "The Effects of
Constitutional Restraints on Government Spending." Public Choice,
49(2), 1986, 101-6.
Aschauer, David A. "Is Public Expenditure Productive?"
Journal of Monetary Economics, March 1989a, 177-200.
-----. "Does Public Capital Crowd Out Private Capital?"
Journal of Monetary Economics, September 1989b, 171-88.
Barro, Robert J. "Determinants of Economic Growth: A
Cross-Country Empirical Study." National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 5698, 1996.
Bartik, Timothy J. Who Benefits from State and Local Economic
Development Policies? Kalamazoo, Michigan: W. E. Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research, 1991.
-----. "Jobs, Productivity, and Local Economic Development:
What Does Economic Research Have for the Role of Government?"
National Tax Journal, December 1994, 847-61.
Becker, Gary S. "A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups
for Political Influence." Quarterly Journal of Economics, August
1983, 371-400.
Dye, Thomas R. "Taxing, Spending, and Economic Growth in the
American States." Journal of Politics, November 1980, 1,085-107.
Friedman, Milton. "Do Old Fallacies Ever Die?" Journal of
Economic Literature, December 1992, 2, 129-32.
Garand, James C. "Explaining Government Growth in the U.S.
States." American Political Science Review, September 1988, 837-49.
Glaeser, Edward L., Hedi D. Kallal, Jose A. Scheinkman, and Andrei
Shleifer. "Growth in Cities." Journal of Political Economy,
December 1992, 1,126-52.
Gramlich, Edward. "Infrastructure Investment: A Review
Essay." Journal of Economic Literature, September 1994, 1,176-96.
Gray, Virginia, and David Lowery. "Interest Group Politics and
Economic Growth in the American States." American Political Science
Review, March 1988, 109-31.
Hart, Peter E. "Galtonian Regression Across Countries and the
Convergence of Productivity." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and
Statistics, August 1995, 287-93.
Helms, L. Jay. "The Effect of State and Local Taxes On
Economic Growth: A Time Series-Cross Section Approach." Review of
Economics and Statistics, November 1985, 574-82.
Holtz-Eakin, Douglas. "State-Specific Estimates of State and
Local Government Capital." Regional Science and Urban Economics,
April 1993, 185-209.
Leamer, Edward E. "Let's Take the Con Out of
Econometrics." American Economic Review, March 1983, 31-43.
-----. "Sensitivity Analyses Would Help." American
Economic Review, June 1985, 308-13.
Levine, Ross, and David Renelt. "A Sensitivity Analysis of
Cross-Country Growth Regressions." American Economic Review,
September 1992, 942-63.
McAleer, Michael, Adrian Pagan, and Paul A. Volker. "What Will
Take the Con Out of Econometrics?" American Economic Review, June
1985, 293-307.
Maitland, Ian. "Interest Groups and Economic Growth
Rates." Journal of Politics, February 1985, 44-58.
Mitchell, William, and Michael Munger. "Economic Models of
Interest Groups: An Introductory Survey." American Journal of
Political Science, May 1991, 512-46.
Mofidi, Alaeddin, and Joe A. Stone. "Do State and Local Taxes
Affect Economic Growth?" Review of Economics and Statistics,
November 1990, 686-91.
Morrison, Catherine J., and Amy Ellen Schwartz. "State
Infrastructure and Productive Performance." American Economic
Review, December 1996, 1,095-111.
Mueller, Dennis C., and Peter Murrell. "Interest Groups and
the Size of Government." Public Choice, 48(2), 1986, 125-45.
Munnell, Alicia H. "How Does Public Infrastructure Affect
Regional Economic Performance?" New England Economic Review,
September/October 1990, 11-32.
-----. "Infrastructure Investment and Economic Growth."
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall 1992, 189-98.
Newman, Robert J. "Industry Migration and Growth in the
South." Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1983, 76-86.
Olson, Mancur. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth,
Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1982.
Phillips, Joseph M., and Ernest P. Goss. "The Effect of State
and Local Taxes on Economic Development: A Meta-Analysis." Southern
Economic Journal, October 1995, 320-33.
Plaut, Thomas R., and Joseph E. Pluta. "Business Climate,
Taxes and Expenditures, and State Industrial Growth in the U.S."
Southern Economic Journal, July 1983, 99-119.
Quah, Danny. "Galton's Fallacy and Tests of the
Convergence Hypothesis." Scandinavian Journal of Economics,
December 1993, 427-43.
Romans, Thomas, and Ganti Subrahmanyam. "State and Local
Taxes, Transfers, and Regional Economic Growth." Southern Economic
Journal, October 1979, 435-44.
Schmenner, Roger W., Joel C. Huber, and Randall L. Cook.
"Geographic Differences and the Location of New Manufacturing
Facilities." Journal of Urban Economics, January 1987, 83-104.
Shadbegian, Ronald J. "Do Tax and Expenditure Limitations
Affect the Size and Growth of State Government?" Contemporary
Economic Policy, January 1996, 22-35.
Smith, Janet K., and Richard L. Smith II. "State and Local
Fiscal Policy: Implications for Property Values and Economic
Growth." Public Finance Quarterly, January 1984, 51-76.
Stigler, George J. "The Theory of Economic Regulation."
Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Spring 1971, 1-21.
Tatom, John A. "Public Capital and Private Sector
Performance." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, May/June
1991, 3-15.
Tollison, Robert D. "Public Choice and Legislation."
Virginia Law Review, March 1988, 339-71.
Vedder, Richard K. "Rich States, Poor States: How High Taxes
Inhibit Growth." Journal of Contemporary Studies, Fall 1982, 19-32.
Wasylenko, Michael. "Taxation and Economic Development: The
State of the Economic Literature." New England Economic Review,
March/April 1997, 37-52.
Wasylenko, Michael, and Therese McGuire. "Jobs and Taxes: The
Effect of Business Climate on States' Employment Growth
Rates." National Tax Journal, December 1985, 497-511.