DOES A HELPING HAND PUT OTHERS AT RISK?: AFFIRMATIVE ACTION, POLICE DEPARTMENTS, AND CRIME.
LOTT, JOHN R., Jr.
Will increasing the number of minority and women police officers
make law enforcement more effective by drawing on abilities that have
gone untapped and creating better contact with communities and victims?
Or will standards have to be lowered too far before large numbers of
minorities and women can be hired? Using cross-sectional time-series
data for U.S. cities for 1987, 1990, and 1993, I find that hiring more
black and minority police officers increases crime rates, but this
apparently arises because lower hiring standards involved in recruiting
more minority officers reduces the quality of both new minority and new
nonminority officers. The most adverse effects of these hiring policies
have occurred in the areas most heavily populated by blacks. There is no
consistent evidence that crime rates rise when more women are hired, and
this raises questions about whether norming tests or altering their
content to create equal pass rates is preferable. The article examines
how the changing composition of police departments affects such measures
as the murder of and assaults against police officers. (JEL J72, K14,
H42)
I. INTRODUCTION
Using preferential standards to aid minority groups is frequently
justified as rectifying past wrongs. Yet, since Richmond v. Croson Co.
[1989], [1] the U.S. Supreme Court has held that these preferences must
pass the difficult "strict scrutiny test" and will be
invalidated unless they promote a "compelling" governmental
interest. Correcting "societal discrimination" was not viewed
as a compelling interest. Remedial efforts to rectify past
discrimination will only be approved if narrowly tailored to correct
specific instances of discrimination. The question of what goals
constitute a sufficiently "compelling" interest has never been
clearly specified by the Supreme Court, though in a very closely decided
case it reversed its own past decision that Federal Communication
Commission (FCC) allocation of licenses by race is acceptable to promote
diversity in entertainment and news programming and applied these high
standards of strict scrutiny and "compelling" interest to
federal building projects. [2]
The standards set by the Supreme Court in Richmond and Adarand were
motivated by the desire that "The [strict scrutiny] test also
ensures that the means chosen 'fit' this compelling goal so
closely that there is little or no possibility that the motive for the
classification was illegitimate racial prejudice or stereotype."
[3] One can hypothesize what compelling goals would meet these standards
where there is "little or no possibility" that an ulterior
race-based motive might be the true motivation behind an affirmative
action rule, but the most obvious case would be when the racial
preferences actually help to further the central purpose of the
governmental agency. [4] In the case of police, this means that minority
police officers are being employed not because diversity is
intrinsically valued but because it is believed to help lower the crime
rate.
The potential law enforcement advantages from multiracial or female
officers seem obvious. Minority police officers may be more effective in
minority areas simply because residents could be more forthcoming about
information that will lead to arrests and convictions or because of the
officers' ability to serve as undercover agents. Trust is also
important for other reasons, as reports of riots erupting after white
police officers have shot a black man may attest. [5] Officers from a
community may also be better at understanding the behavior of criminals
in those areas or even something as basic as understanding the language
of immigrants. [6] In any event, police efforts to reduce crime are
surely dependent on the help that they receive from the community
(Wilson [1983]).
Rape victims or women abused by their spouses plausibly find it
easier to discuss the traumatic events with women officers. Without
female officers, many attacks against women may go undetected--thus
lowering the expected penalty from attacking women and resulting in even
more attacks. Policing is a rare case where the government output is
likely to be advanced by race- or sex-based preferences. Indeed,
reducing reliance on cognitive tests for police entrance examinations
has been justified with the motivation that "police departments
cannot function effectively in minority neighborhoods when virtually all
police officers are white males" (Dunnette et. al. [1996]).
Another case might be education, where a frequently made claim is
that a diverse student body better prepares students for a "diverse
world." [7] These goals have also been used to justify weighting
applicants by race or sex along with their test scores. By contrast, how
people use roads or machines seems likely to be unrelated to the race of
those who built them. Even the case of fire departments, obtaining
racial diversity seems tangential to the ultimate goal of extinguishing
a fire.
Although the foregoing benefits are clear, there are countervailing
factors that must be taken into account. Most important is whether
explicit race or sex preferences result in less-capable individuals
being hired. For women, this might result because of less-stringent
physical requirements. [8] Slower running speed might make it more
difficult for women to catch criminals. [9] Weaker physical strength
might cause police departments to substitute away from single officer
patrol units (either foot or car) and into units with two officers. If
criminals believe that they have a greater chance of resisting arrest
when officers are weaker, more assaults may be committed by criminals
against women officers. In compensating for their weaker strength, women
may substitute into other ways of controlling criminals--the most
obvious method being guns. Although guns are a "great
equalizer," they may not completely offset differences in strength.
[10] Being less able to fall back on their physical strength to protect
th emselves when faced with a possible attack, women may have to
determine whether they will fire their gun before the possible attacker
gets into physical contact with them. If true, shorter reaction times
risk resulting in more accidental shootings.
Although the U.S. Department of Justice states that the appropriate
testing procedures nearly eliminate disparate impact while improving
merit hiring (Gottfredson [1997]), [11] critics of affirmative action in
policing argue that these tests lower reliance on important cognitive
skills. According to a 1993 survey of 23 large police and sheriff
departments (conducted for the Department of Justice and Nassau County,
New York), the cognitive portion of police tests have been completely
removed in three cases, in an attempt to increase minority recruitment.
Even the remaining 20 had reduced their emphasis on cognitive skills,
with all the respondents indicating "that adverse impact was
considered when determining the selection process" (Dunnette et.
al. [1993, 18]). Using this survey to help justify its decision, Nassau
County removed all cognitive tests except for a reading comprehension
test, which is graded pass-fail and requires that "applicants had
to score only as well as the bottom 1% of current police of
ficers." The Louisiana State Police replaced a cognitive exam with
a test that initially contained six parts: three personality, one
biographical, and two cognitive, but later threw out one of the
cognitive sections to further reduce the impact on minorities (Price
[1997]). [12] After spending "$5.1 million to have consultants
develop unbiased exams, only to have minorities fare poorly again,"
Chicago moved to a heavily weighted seniority system for promoting
police officers and a lottery system for hiring firefighters (Spielman
[1996, 16]). [13] The Department of Justice has used legal action (or
so-called consent decrees) to force police departments to adopt these
rules.
Some academics have charged that the new tests are consciously
designed "to work little better than simply picking applicants at
random" so that the pass rate is the same across different racial
groups (Gottfredson [1997, 1996]). If minority applicants with low
cognitive skills are hired and if these skills predict how good a police
officer a candidate would be, preferential treatment adversely affects
the effectiveness of police departments. Indeed, some shocking reports
have been made about the importance of cognitive skills. Expressing
concerns about the poor English skills of new police recruits, a
Washington Post editorial [1993] claimed that "between 1986 and
1990, 311 of the 938 murder cases the D.C. police brought to the U.S.
attorney's office--roughly a third--were dismissed. [ldots] One
local prosecutor says many D.C cases were thrown out because prosecutors
couldn't read or understand the arrest reports [written by the
police]." [14] Still, some designers of the new tests defend the
changes: "the v alidity of the cognitive ability test was not
high" (Dunnette et. al. [1996]).
The basic economics of these affirmative action regulations is
fairly straightforward. Voters value many objectives but face limited
resources. The question is whether voters were previously discriminating
against certain politically unfavored groups of potential police
officers at the cost of higher crime rates or whether affirmative action
laws are forcing departments to accept higher crime rates as the cost of
changing hiring policies.
This article examines the relationship between the changing racial
and gender composition of police departments and the crime rate. As
mentioned above, there are possibly opposing forces, and the net effect
is not obvious and it may not be the same for all crime categories. For
example, women police officers may deter rapists better than they deter
armed robbers.
Affirmative action can also affect crime rates in many different
ways, for example, through changing the marginal quality of new officers
or affecting which officers are promoted and thus altering the
incentives of the existing police force. If the critics of the new rules
are correct that the replacements for cognitive tests simply introduce
randomness into the hiring process, all new officers, and not simply the
officers the new tests were designed to encourage, could be of lower
quality. After first examining how court orders altering the hiring and
promotion process affect the crime rate, this article seeks to provide a
comprehensive picture for how the changing demographic characteristics
of police departments affect crime rates. The evidence will try to sort
out the differential impact of affirmative action on new hires and the
existing police force as well as try to test whether the changes in
effectiveness are due to the minority officers that are hired or the
changing quality of all officers.
Alternative explanations for the results are examined, such as
whether any observed higher crime rates merely reflect higher reporting
rates and whether police experience levels are affected by the altered
hiring policies. I also examine how changing gender and racial
compositions alter how police departments operate and other measures of
effectiveness such as arrest rates.
II. THE CHANGING COMPOSITION OF POLICE DEPARTMENTS
During 1987, 1990, and 1993, the U.S. Department of Justice
conducted a comprehensive national survey of state and local law
enforcement agencies with 100 or more officers, known as the "Law
Enforcement Management and Administrative Statistics" (LEMAS). My
study focuses on city police department data because they allow a more
precise study of the relationship between how police departments were
organized and the crime rate. By contrast, state and county departments
are more difficult to investigate, because they have jurisdiction over
larger but overlapping areas.
I separated the data into two sets: (1) the entire Justice
Department Survey and (2) a subset in which demographic data are also
available. The results that I report are considerably more significant
statistically and important empirically when using the entire Department
of Justice survey, yet I will focus on the subset with the demographic
data, because changing demographics are related to both the changing
hiring patterns by police departments and crime.
Two characteristics stand out from the survey: city police
departments vary greatly in their racial and gender makeup, and there
have been large increases in the proportion of black and women officers.
Tables I and II illustrate these two points, with Table I illustrating
the distribution of the racial and gender composition of police
departments and Table II examining the distribution of the change in the
composition. The first table shows that although most departments have
no blacks, Hispanics, or Asians, the range is large with the tenth and
ninetieth percentile departments, respectively, employing 0% and 18%
blacks. The diversity for women officers is not quite as large, ranging
from 0% at the tenth percentile to 14% at the ninetieth.
It is possible to subdivide these categories even further, but some
of the racial and sex categories have very small changes in the total
number of officers. In my restricted sample, 189 cities had detailed
employment data within each race category by sex for both 1987 and 1990.
These cities employed 155,071 (or 40%) of the 387,534 sworn full-time
officers employed by local governments in 1990. As examples of the small
number of officers in some of these subgroups, the number of male
American Indian officers between 1987 and 1990 grew from 280 to 378
officers; for female American Indians, the change was from 47 to 91; and
for female Asian Americans, 83 to 203. Even Hispanic females, the
next-largest category, saw an increase of only 378 officers. The number
of male white officers, the only category to decline, fell by 6,912.
The second table illustrates the different rates of changes over
time as well as the impact of the consent decrees which the Department
of Justice entered into with city police departments regarding a
city's hiring and promotion practices. [15] Past work has studied
the effect of these decrees on hiring of black men and found that indeed
they do have an impact (Lewis [1989]). The Department of Justice's
Civil Rights Division provided information on both racial and/or
gender-based consent decrees over the period from 1972 to 1994: 19 of
these 189 cities were covered by consent decrees during the 1987-93
period, though only three of these cities had consent decrees that were
imposed as late as the end of 1987. The 19 cities were Birmingham, Ala.;
Montgomery, Ala.; Los Angles, Calif.; San Francisco, Calif.; Ft.
Lauderdale, Fla.; Pompano Beach, Fla.; Miami, Fla.; Tallahassee, Fla.;
Macon, Ga.; Chicago, Ill.; Indianapolis, md.; Jackson, Miss.; Omaha,
Neb.; Las Vegas, N.V.; Syracuse, N. Y. Cincinnati, Ohio.; Phila delphia,
Penn.; Memphis, Tenn.; and Milwaukee, Wisc.
Many cities are adopting affirmative action rules on their own
either because of their own support for such rules or because of the
threat of Justice Department actions. Any examination of consent decrees
is thus likely to underestimate the impact of such policies. Yet,
consent decrees appear to have clear impacts for both blacks and women.
The median change in the percent of black police officers was 2.5
percentage points more in cities with consent decrees than those without
them, and for women the median increase was 1.7 percentage points. These
may seem like small changes in the share of police employment going to
these groups, but compared to the median percent of black and women
officers over this seven-year period, these changes represent at least a
57% increase over past employment practices.
Finally, despite the large difference in sample sizes between the
entire sample and the restricted one, both sets experienced remarkably
similar changes in types of officers employed during this seven-year
period. This similarity occurs despite the cities in the smaller sample
averaging about 40% more people.
III. EXPLAINING CHANGING CRIME RATES AS A FUNCTION OF THE RACIAL
AND GENDER COMPOSITION OF POLICE DEPARTMENTS
The Direct Impact of Consent Decrees
The FBI's Uniform Crime Report allows us to study violent and
property crimes, with seven primary crime categories (murder, rape,
robbery, aggravated assault, burglary, larceny, and motor vehicle
theft), and ten other subcategories (manslaughter, forcible rape,
attempted rape, gun robbery, knife robbery, other robbery, strong-arm
robbery, assault with a gun, assault with a knife, and other assault).
The results from most of these subcategories will not be reported,
because they differ little from the results shown for the primary
categories. Data on arrest rates for these broader categories as well as
the city populations were obtained directly from the FBI.
The Current Population Survey was used to determine the changing
demographic makeup of cities over the 1987-93 period. The percent of the
population in different demographic categories was broken down by age
(less than 30 years of age, 30-54 years of age, and 55 and older), race
(black, white, and other), and sex (male and female), thus yielding 18
demographic categories. This survey also provided information on the
average weekly wage and the unemployment rate. The National Conference
of Black Mayors provided me with copies of their entire national roster
by year so that the race of a city's mayor could be identified.
Finally, the LEMAS survey provides information on the racial and gender
composition of police departments, as well as on the per capita number
of sworn police officers, and other departmental characteristics. The
means and standard deviations for these variables are shown in the
appendix.
Table III shows simple preliminary regressions that use a simple
time trend for the number of years after a consent decree has been
imposed and a similar time trend for the years before the decree to pick
up changes in before and after trends in crime rates. To do this, I used
yearly violent and property crime data for 1985-94 for 495 cities, a
longer period than is available for the LEMAS survey. Data prior to 1985
was not included because of severe problems with the consistency between
1984 and 1985 in the city-level crime data. Two sets of fixed effects
were used for these simple regressions: city and year fixed effects and
city fixed effects along with separate year fixed effects for each state
to control for any individual state trends. These regressions use
ordinary least squares weighted by city population. The results for both
violent and property crime rates imply that crime rates were declining
in cities before consent decrees were imposed and were rising
thereafter. Violent crimes were rising afte r the consent decrees by at
least 3.3% per year, and for property crimes it was at least 2.1% per
year. The differences in trends are all statistically significant at the
.01 level.
Given the significant declines in preconsent decree crime rates,
the results for three of the four regressions raise the question about
whether the decrees just happen to be imposed when the crime rates were
at their low ebb and the post-decree increase is simply a result of mean
reversion. At least for the cities with new consent decrees imposed
during 1987, the increases in violent crime during the period studied
are 2.4 to 3.7 times larger than preceeding declines and thus exceed any
increase that could simply be attributed to mean reversion. [16] The
evidence is not clear cut for property crimes, where the declines and
increases are of approximately equal size.
Using the smaller sample that matches the LEMAS survey and just the
time trend for years after the imposition of the consent decree produces
similar, though smaller and less statistically significant increases in
crime. Controlling for changing city-level demographics as well as the
average weekly wage, unemployment, per capita number of police officers,
city population, and population squared, and city and year fixed effects
implies: violent crime rises by 1.9% (t-statistic = 2.16) and property
crime by 2.1% (t-statistic = 2.99) for each additional year the consent
decree is in effect.
Figure 1 reports this same data slightly differently by including
separate dummy variables for the years before and after the imposition
of the consent decree. The years included range from three years before
the decree to year 4 afterward, with another dummy variable that equals
one for years 5 or more after the decree. The estimates use the full
sample and correspond to those shown in Table III that account for city
fixed effects as well as separate year fixed effects for each state. The
pattern is similar to that implied by the table with crime rates falling
immediately before the consent decree is imposed and rising after that.
(Recently, extending this data set back to 1977 and expanding the number
of years studied by seven produced similar results [Lott (2000, chapter
9)].)
An Initial Assessment of How Consent Decrees Affect Crime through
the Type of Officers Hired
Consent decrees change hiring policies, and changing hiring
policies may affect the crime rate. The consent decrees favor some
groups more than others, but the link between these group-specific
changes and the crime rate are unclear. Even if the new hiring
procedures introduce randomness, the distribution of skills is not
necessarily the same across potential applicants in all groups. To make
matters more complicated, the types of officers hired may depend on the
crime rate. For example, if departments hired minorities because of
growing crime problems in minority areas or hired women because of
greater crimes against women, simple ordinary least squares estimates
risk improperly blaming some of the higher crime rates on the new police
who were hired to help solve the problem. [17] To explain this problem
differently, crime rates may have risen even though a city hired black
officers, and if they had hired white officers who were less capable of
policing minority areas, the crime rate could have risen by eve n more.
Unfortunately, an alternative explanation exists: higher crime rates may
signal less concern by city governments about crime and thus a greater
willingness to indulge other objectives when hiring police officers.
[18]
The opposite relationship between crime rates and hiring practices
is also possible. Additional law enforcement efforts have a greater
effect on crime in high-crime areas (Lott and Mustard [1997, 28, 291).
If affirmative action actually increases crime, highcrime areas would
find it more costly to engage in affirmative action, and thus,
everything else equal, one suspects that they would engage in less such
hiring. Failure to control for why the particular composition of police
officers was chosen would underestimate the negative impact from this
policy.
To guard against this problem, I initially employ two-stage least
squares where the first equation attempts to explain the proportion of
black, minority (black, Hispanic, and American Indian), or male officers
employed by a city. As discussed in Section II, I expect that the
imposition of a consent decree and, particularly, the length of time
that the decree has been in effect to serve as the instruments and help
explain the levels of minority or female employment, depending on what
type of employment the consent decree deals with. The number of years
that a consent decree has been in effect is an excellent instrument
since it is extremely unlikely that the causation runs from future crime
rates to the number of years since a consent decree has been entered. I
also account for the demographic composition of the city's
population; the average weekly wage and unemployment rate; whether its
mayor was black; the city's population and population squared; and
the per capita number of sworn police officers. The sec ond equation
that explains each one of the individual crime rates included all the
variables except for whether there was the consent decree and the
mayor's race. Weighted least squares, where the estimates were
weighted by city population, was used to deal with heteroaskedasticity.
[19]
The coefficients on the percent of the police force that is black,
minority, or male in the second regression are thus adding the impact on
the crime rate of the consent decree together with that particular group
being studied. I will disaggregate these two effects later when I report
the reduced form regressions in Table VIII and Appendix 2. Because the
instruments that I have for racial or gender hiring consent decrees are
very heavily correlated, the impacts of the racial and gender
compositions of police departments are initially estimated separately
for these two-stage least squares regressions.
Admittedly, there are many location specific and year-specific
differences in crime rates that are not captured by the variables
controlling for demographic, income, and population differences. One
simple way of dealing with this is the use of location and time fixed
effects, where a separate dummy variable is used for each city and year.
However, this approach also has its drawbacks: although it may correctly
measure left-out variables, it may also cause us to falsely attribute
some of the impact of changes in our in our other variables (for
example, the impact of changing racial or gender composition of police
departments) to these fixed effects. Nevertheless, all the regressions
report either city and year fixed effects or county fixed effects with
separate year fixed effects for each state. [20]
As an example, the two-stage least squares estimates examining the
percentage of the police force that is black with city and year fixed
effects take the following form:
(1) % Police Force That Is Black = g(Consent Decree in Effect,
Number of Years Decree in Effect, Dummy for Whether Mayor Is Black, Per
Capita Number of Sworn Officers, City's Demographic Composition,
Population and Population Squared, Average Weekly Wage, Unemployment
Rate, Fixed Year and City Effects)
(2) IN(Crime Rate) = f(% Police Force That Is Black, Per Capita
Number of Sworn Officers, City's Demographic Composition,
Population and Population Squared, Average Weekly Wage, Unemployment
Rate, Fixed Year and City Effects)
The results from the second equation are reported in Table IV
separated Out by the type of fixed effects employed. All crime rates are
in natural logs, where .1 is added to zero values before the natural log
is taken. With the exception of manslaughter, aggravated assault, and
motor vehicle theft, an increase in the percentage of a police force
that is black is consistently associated with significant increases in
crime. The effect is so large that 18 of the specifications imply that a
one standard deviation change in the percent of the police force that is
black increases the corresponding crime rates by at least 5% of its mean
value (see the percentages listed next to the coefficients). The effects
are dramatic no matter how one examines these estimates. For example,
increasing black officers' share by one percentage point increases
property crimes by 4%, and the same increase raises the murder rate by
1.9% and overall violent crime by 4.8%. As the relative median increase
in black officer's share of polic e departments over this
seven-year period because of consent decrees was 2.5 pge points, I
conclude that if nothing else had changed, the average city's
murder rate would have risen by 4.7%. [21]
One point should be made very clear at this point. We are talking
about the impact on crime of hiring "additional" blacks, many
of whom would not have been hired without the consent decree. As
mentioned in the introduction, changes in testing that are used to
encourage hiring more minorities can explain why these blacks are not of
the same quality as previously hired blacks. It can still be true that
qualified black officers are more effective but that the new
less-qualified officers are associated with more crime. The large impact
suggests that more than just the quality of new minority recruits or new
minority promotions is affected. Changing tests to employ a greater
percentage of blacks can make it more difficult to screen out
lower-quality candidates generally, including whites and other racial
groups. Independent of the consent decree, the size of the change in
black employment may thus proxy for changes in the level of standards
used to hire employees in general. Similarly, changing promotion rules
th at favor seniority over achievement can affect morale and incentives
across all categories of police officers.
For the next set of regressions, blacks, Hispanics, and American
Indians were combined to represent the share of minorities in a
department. The groups included in the minority classification was
decided by using a series of reduced-form equations where I tested to
see whether the predicted impact of the different racial groups were
statistically different from each other. Generally, the coefficients for
blacks, Hispanics, and American Indians were not statistically different
from each other, and the whites and Asians usually fit together in a
separate group. [22] More precisely, whites and Asians had different
effects on crime in only three of the 19 crime categories (when the
broadest set of categories was used), whereas blacks and Hispanics were
statistically different in five cases. In the three cases where whites
and Asians differed in their impact on crime (attempted rape, knife
robbery, and other robbery), Asians had a greater deterrent impact on
crime. Hiring additional Hispanics and American Indians did not tend to
increase crime by the magnitude shown by hiring additional black
officers.
The two-stage least square estimates continue to confirm this
pattern. Putting together blacks, Hispanics, and American Indians
continued to produce very similar, though smaller, results compared to
what I found for blacks alone. The minority portion of a police force in
column 3 explains about 75%-80% as much of the percent of the mean
violent and property crimes as did the regressions in column 1 for the
percent of the police force that is black. Nineteen of the 20 crime
regressions imply that increasing the percentage share of minorities in
a department increase crime, and the relationship is statistically
significant for three-quarters of the estimates.
The last two columns in Table IV imply that increasing the share of
males in the police force decreases crime in 19 of the 20 specifications
shown, though the aggregate property crime category implies a
statistically significant relationship only for the time varying state
fixed effects that include the county fixed effects. The specifications
for murder, manslaughter, and rape provide no significant evidence that
increasing women's share of the police force increases these
crimes. Using either simple county or state and year fixed effects
produces a much more consistent negative relationship between higher
males shares of the police force and crime. [23]
Table V reports some of the first equation results from the
two-stage least squares estimation of the percent of the police force
that is black, minority, or male used in the regressions analyzing
violent crime with city fixed effects. The results imply that for the
racial components, the number of years that a consent decree has been in
effect dramatically increases the percentage of minorities in police
forces. Every 10 years after the consent decree goes into effect
increases the number of blacks by another 4.1 percentage points and
minorities by 4.8 percentage points. These results are comparable in
magnitude with those shown in Table II. I also tried these estimates
with a squared term for the number of years that the consent decree had
been in effect, but including this did not noticeably alter the results.
One city in the sample had consent decrees as long as 21 years (with
both the sample median and the mean being about 10 years), and the
estimates indicate the percentage of the police force that is black is
still rising at that time.
Interestingly, the election of a black mayor does not appear to
significantly change the number of minority police officers, with the
corresponding coefficient even being negative is the minorities
specification. There is also surprisingly little relationship between
past crime rates and the composition of the police force, and the
t-statistics are quite small. Only past violent crimes imply more blacks
on a police force with a t-statistic even greater than 1. The Hausman
endogeneity test indicates that the number of years a consent decree is
in effect is a valid instrument for the black and minority regressions.
A possible concern with these results is that the consent decree
not only directly affects the number of minorities or women who are
hired but may also implicitly signal concerns about future crime rates.
If one expects that higher crime rates can be best combated with more
minority police officers, there is also the concern that this motivated
the adoption of the consent decree. While this is possible, it is not
clear why the Department of Justice has better information on a
particular city's future crime rate than the city itself. In any
case, as a check, I reestimated the regressions in Table IV by including
the consent decree dummy variable directly into the second equation that
estimates the crime rate. This change has virtually no effect on the
results reported previously. As a further test of the sensitivity of the
results, I also tried reestimating the results in Table IV by removing
the crime rate variables from the first equation and the pattern of
results remained similar to those already reported. [24]
The question of whether more black police officers had a
differential impact in more heavily black areas can be examined by
interacting the percent of the police force that is black with the
percent of the population that is black. The violent and property crime
estimates corresponding to the regressions in Table IV, and the
estimates that did not include the crime rates in the first regression
all imply that the increase in crime from hiring black officers is
greatest in communities with the most blacks. For example, the violent
and property crime estimates that correspond to city fixed effects
estimates in Table IV are positive and have t-statistics of 4.8 and 4.2,
respectively.
Finally, data on whether a police department was unionized and the
gross salary paid per sworn officer were available, though for only 1987
and 1990. Using these two variables and the smaller data set, I
reestimated the results reported in Table IV and found very little
change in results. For the most part neither of these variables was
significant in explaining changes in the crime rate.
IV. ARE HIGHER CRIME RATES A RESULT OF LESS-EFFECTIVE POLICE OR
GREATER REPORTING RATES?
Unfortunately, the FBI's Uniform Crime Report Data relies on
reported, not actual, crimes. The problem is potentially critical for
this study, because the racial or gender characteristics of the police
officers could either be altering the behavior of criminals and/or the
rate at which victims report crimes. The problem is made even worse by
the fact that both sides of the debate can provide explanations for the
preceding results. Those favoring affirmative action can argue that the
higher reported crime rates when more minorities are hired implies that
the community feels more comfortable about reporting crimes. In
contrast, those who believe that lower standards mainly result in
less-qualified officers can say that the results confirm the poor
performance of the less-qualified officers.
There are several ways of investigating whether the results are
being driven by higher reporting rates. The simplest approach is to look
at murder and manslaughter, where underreporting is essentially
nonexistent. Thus, the race or sex of the police officer does not
produce additional reporting. For both murder and manslaughter, the
results are very consistent. More minority, black, or female officers
are associated with higher murder and manslaughter rates, while more
white and male officers imply fewer deaths. These two crimes are also
the most accurately reported for another reason: if multiple offenses
are perpetrated at the same time, only the most serious offense is
reported. Thus, if an armed robbery resulted in murder, only the murder
and not the robbery is recorded.
Further, the importance of the reporting problem should vary
systematically across crime categories as the loss from the crime
varies. For example, suppose that a black person is making a decision on
whether to report a theft to a predominantly white police department.
His decision to report the crime depends on the value of the item
stolen, the probability that the item will be recovered, and the cost
involved in going to the police station, including whatever difficulties
might arise in how the black man might be treated by white police
officers. The victim would only report crimes where either the value of
the item stolen or the probability of recovery is relatively high.
Lowering the cost of the black person reporting the crime by introducing
more black officers would result in more reporting of relatively
low-value, low-probability-of-detection crimes. Since the cost of making
the complaint constitutes a much bigger percentage of the return to
acting on relatively small harms, actions that reduce those costs have a
much bigger effect on reporting minor crimes.
For at least broad categories of property crimes it is possible to
make this comparison. Miller, Cohen, and Wiersema (1996) claimed that in
1992 the average larceny involved property loss of $270, burglary $970,
and auto theft $3,300. By comparison, the differences in the arrest
rates are small: larceny 30%, burglary 21%, and auto theft 25%. These
figures would imply that the biggest increase in reporting from changing
the racial mix of police should occur for larceny, next for burglary,
and least for auto theft. (Auto theft and burglary should also tend to
have relatively high reporting rates compared to larceny simply because
these crimes must be reported as a condition of obtaining reimbursement
from insurance companies.) Yet, all of the two-stage least squares
estimates in Table IV indicate that the racial or gender compositions of
the police department have always smaller impacts on larceny than on
burglary, and half the time the impact on larceny is smaller than on
auto theft. None of the estimates are consistent with the earlier
results arising from increased reporting rates.
V. DISAGGREGATING FURTHER BY RACE AND SEX
For 1987 and 1990, the Department of Justice survey determined the
percent of each racial group that was male or female. The two-stage
least squares regressions reported earlier were therefore reestimated
with two changes: the previous racial or sex breakdowns were replaced
one at a time with the eight new race and sex categories and the first
equation in the two-stage least squares included a dummy variable that
equals 1 when the consent decree dealt with either race or sex.
Table VI reports the county fixed effects with separate year fixed
effects for each state. Despite the sample size being about onethird
smaller, the results are similar to those already reported. Gender plays
an even smaller role than it did in the earlier results. The
effectiveness of different types of police officers lies more along
racial than gender lines, though there are notable exceptions for
Asians, where males are associated with fewer crimes and females more.
Murder divides along racial lines, with more whites (both males and
females) coinciding with lower death rates but the reverse being true
for blacks and Hispanics. In all but a few of cases, more blacks and
Hispanics are associated with higher crime rates.
The variables explaining rape provide very little evidence that the
gender of the police officer affects this crime differently. For whites
and blacks, the different gender racial groups have the same coefficient
signs and are statistically indistinguishable. Although differences do
exist for Hispanics and Asians, even here the effects do not suggest a
consistent pattern with the relative impacts of male and female officers
having the opposite impacts in the two cases. The strength of these
results make it very difficult to believe that male and female officers
have much of a differential impact on deterring rapes. Although it is
still quite likely that male and female officers have different skills
in dealing with rape (e.g., female officers may be better able at
getting rape victims to reveal details), the tests do not allow us to
differentiate what the skill differences are for each gender. Victims or
potential victims may also value more than simply deterrence. For
example, they may value how they feel g oing through the process, and
that is another dimension that we are unable to measure. However, even
if these other attributes are significantly valued, the results
presented here allow us to discuss the trade-off between the number of
rapes and these other possible dimensions.
As another attempt to control for differences in law enforcement
across states, I also reestimated the regressions shown in Table VI with
city and year fixed effects and including variables for both the per
capita state employment in corrections and the judicial system. [25]
Including these variables had no discernible impact on the results
reported. While the impact of hiring more people in corrections and the
judicial system usually reduced crime, the effect was never
statistically significant. Variables to account for concealed handgun
laws, waiting periods and the length of those waiting periods in buying
a gun, penalties for using guns in commissions of crimes, and cocaine
prices were also included, [26] but only the variable for the presence
of concealed handgun laws reduced crime and none of these variables
appreciably altered the other findings. Passage of concealed handgun
laws reduced murder rates by about 10.5%. [27] Controlling for the use
of Lojack automobile anti-theft devices tended to make the results for
black and minority officers more positive and statistically significant
though the coefficient for Lojack was not significant. [28]
VI. FELONIOUS KILLING OF POLICE, ACCIDENTAL POLICE DEATHS, ASSAULTS
ON POLICE, AND SHOOTING CIVILIANS
Many studies have focused on whether blacks and other minorities
civilians have been shot by police at disproportionately higher rates
(Matulia [1985, 7]). The standard view is that the higher rates at which
blacks are shot by police can easily be explained by blacks being
involved in crimes at higher rates and the observation that black and
Hispanic officers are more likely to engage in shootings can result from
minority officers patrolling minority areas where the crime rate is
highest (Fyfe [1989, 478]). [29] Indeed, if one believes that police
officers are more likely to shoot civilians accidentally when their own
lives are at greater risk, the issues of whether police shoot citizens
and whether the police are likely to be shot or assaulted are closely
related. Previous work has not examined the differences between male and
female officers, and there has been an absence of evidence of the risks
that officers face from being shot or assaulted. [30]
To examine the issue of risks facing different police officers, I
use the same two-stage least squares specifications that were used
earlier to explain the rate at which police officers are assaulted,
killed by attackers, or die in accidents while on the job. As seen in
Table IV, increasing the number of women officers is consistently and
significantly related to more assaults on police officers. Increasing
the number of female officers by one percentage point appears to
increase the number of assaults on police by 15%-19%. The breakdown in
Table VI is similar, with the number of assaults on police officers
being statistically significantly different between men and women for
all races. Clearly, if a physical attack takes place, it is much more
likely to be directed against a female officer. When weapons are
involved, as is much more typically the case with felonious killings,
criminals do not appear to be making as much of a distinction over
whether the officer is male or female. [31] The evidence from Tabl e IV
weakly also suggests that black and minority are more likely to be
assaulted. It is difficult to see any consistent pattern for the killing
of police officers or accidental deaths, though this might arise because
these deaths are so infrequent. [32]
Although the regressions that explain attacks on police officers
have controlled for the same variables used to explain all the different
crime rates, the use of protective body armor could make a significant
difference in the number of felonious killings of police. Unfortunately,
data on body armor are not available for 1987, and thus there is only
one year overlap between these data and the data that break down police
personnel by sex for each racial group. Rerunning the felonious killing
regressions shown in Table IV with this smaller data set produces very
similar results for the racial and sex groupings, and, surprisingly, in
all the cases the body armor variable is very statistically
insignificant, with a t-statistic that is never greater than .4. One
possible explanation for these results is that police officers are
offsetting the greater security offered them by these protective devices
through taking greater risks (Peltzman [1975]).
Finally, it is possible to match evidence on police shootings of
civilians with our data on the racial and sex composition of police
departments. Geller and Scott :[1992] compiled data police shooting of
civilians for 12 cities: Atlanta, Chicago, Dallas, Houston,
Indianapolis, Kansas City, (Mo.), Los Angeles, New York, Philadelphia,
Santa Ana (Calif.), St. Louis, and San Diego. Although they provide as
many as 20 years of data for Chicago and New York, our tests here are
limited by the LEMAS to 1987 and 1990, thus leaving us with only 24
observations, so any results must be viewed as very preliminary. The
central concern is well summarized by Los Angeles Police Commissioner
Bert Boeckmann during a debate before the city's decision to remove
the 5-foot height requirement: "Commissioner Bert Boeckmann
expressed concern that small-statured officers might rely too much on
their guns or partners to compensate for a lack of size and strength in
dealing with uncooperative suspects. 'Would there be more of a
tendenc y to reach for a gun as opposed to using some other form for
quieting a person she may be having an altercation with?' he
asked" (McGreevy [1997, N4]). This argument not only applies to
height requirements but also raises the broader question of whether
women are more likely to resort to substitute methods, such as guns, to
control criminals. To test this, I regressed the per capita number of
police shootings of civilians on the percentage of the police force that
were black or white males as well as on the per capita number of
felonious killings of police and assaults on police, the per capita
number of sworn full-time police, officers, the city population, and
city and year fixed effects. Felonious killings and assaults on police
are used to measure the risks facing officers, with more killings and
assaults implying that officers face higher costs to delaying a decision
on the appropriate response to possible threats. A similar regression
was run using the percentage of the police forces that were black and
white females. [33]
The results reported in Table VII imply that more black or white
male officers lower the number of civilians shot, whereas increasing the
number of white females (but not black females) implies an increase. The
effects are also quite large with a one standard deviation increase in
the black male share of the police force reduces civilian shootings by
1.4 per 100,000 citizens and for white males the reduction is .58 per
100,000 citizens. By contrast, a one standard deviation increase in
white females increases shootings by .87. Both regressions also imply
that increasing the number of felonious police killings increases the
number of accidental shootings of civilians. The other results are more
mixed. In the specification that includes the male share of the police
force, only the coefficients for assaults and population are
statistically significant.
In conclusion, the results for assaults on officers are consistent
with women being physically weaker than men. Criminals are more likely
to attack if they believe that an attack will successfully allow them to
escape. Consistent with the hypothesis, mentioned in the introduction,
that female officers have a shorter time to react to perceived threats
because they must make a decision before they come into physical contact
with the criminal, there is some preliminary evidence that male officers
are more likely to avoid shooting civilians. Interestingly, the
reduction appears to be greatest for black male police officers. More
information is required to draw definitive conclusions for the deaths by
police, but, compared to other officers, blacks are the more likely to
die from accidents than from a criminal's attack. Additional
information on police violence might have provided some important
insights. We may be willing to put up with a less-effective police
departments if they deal with suspects in less-viole nt ways.
VII. MIGHT THE HIGHER CRIME RATES BE DUE TO CHANGING RULES LOWERING
THE QUALITY OF ALL NEW EMPLOYEES? DOES AFFIRMATIVE ACTION AFFECT THE
BEHAVIOR OF EXISTING OFFICERS?
The changing crime rates may be due to additional minorities being
hired, but it is also possible that increasing the minority share of
police forces may be correlated with a lowering of standards for all new
police officers. Thus, it might not be a greater share of police
officers who are minorities that are related to higher crime, but the
causation may run from lowering standards for all officers to more
crime. Thus, an increasing minority share is merely correlated with
higher crime. Rules that base promotion less on merit may also reduce
the efforts by all existing officers. This seems most plausible, if only
because of the very large impacts that hiring minorities appear to have
on crime.
If indeed it is the lowering of overall quality that explains the
higher crime rate, the simplest way of detecting it is by examining the
relationship between each group's absolute effect on a crime rate
and the change in its share of the police force. If the change in a
group's share of the police force was merely proxying for the
overall change in the entire police force's quality, the largest
coefficients would be observed for those groups with the smallest number
of new police officers, while those with the largest changes would have
the smallest coefficients. However, the Pearson correlation coefficient
between each group's effect on murder and the change in their share
of the police force is only -- .17 and is not statistically significant.
The corresponding correlations for the other violent crime categories
are similar: rape is -- .19; robbery, --24; and aggravated assault, --
.22. Although this evidence does not reject the spillover hypothesis, it
also does not provide much support. Spillovers may e xplain a portion,
but not all, of the differences in coefficients.
Another test examines quasi-reduced forms corresponding to the
regressions shown in Table IV. The difference here is that in addition
to the instruments (the consent decree dummy, the number of years that
the consent decree has been in effect, the mayor's race) the racial
composition of the police department is also included. Given that the
percent share of blacks and whites in a police force is highly
correlated with the presence of consent degrees and the length of time
that they have been in effect, this represents a very conservative test
for distinguishing whether rules might have an impact over and above the
changing racial composition of police departments. When only the consent
decrees are included, they produce consistent significant positive
impacts on crime (analogous to the results using the smaller sample
discussed near Table III). [34] This test is also imperfect because
cities with consent decrees were not the only ones changing their hiring
and promotion rules. Other cities that have changed their rules either
voluntarily or under the threat of being faced with a consent decree
will also be changing their hiring practices. Thus, even evidence that
only the racial composition variables matter and that consent degrees
have no effect does not allow us to reject the hypothesis that higher
crime rates are due to both.
The two different consent decree variables may also help us
distinguish whether affirmative action changes the marginal quality of
new officers or effects which officers are promoted, thereby altering
the incentives of the existing police force. If the variable for the
number of years that the decree has been in effect proxies for the
percentage of the department that has been hired under the new hiring
standards, a positive impact from the number of years provides evidence
that general hiring practices are important. The consent decree dummy
variable is less clear in either the county or state fixed effects
specifications because it could be picking either the type of city on
which consent decrees are imposed and/or the immediate impact of the new
rules. If the consent decree dummy variable is measuring the immediate
effect, any large changes in crime would presumably be attributed to
changing the behavior of the existing police force and not simply new
hires.
Table VIII reports the results for violent and property crime rates
using city or county fixed effects. [35] A more detailed breakdown of
the county fixed effects when the gender and racial groups are
simultaneously included with the consent decree information are reported
in Appendix B. Despite the collinearity between the composition of the
police forces and the number of years that the consent decrees have been
in effect, certain patterns are evident in Table VIII. Overall, the
results imply that consent decrees raise crime rates independently of
the changing racial or gender composition of the police force. For both
violent and property crimes, there is evidence that consent decrees
matter because they alter the behavior of the existing police force. For
property crimes, the quality of the new hires produced by consent
decrees also appears to matter with each additional year that the decree
is in effect raising property crimes by another 1.7%-1.9%. Increasing
the number of black officers on a police forc e independently of the
length of time that the consent decree has been in effect is associated
with increased violent crimes, though the inclusion of Hispanics and
American Indians together with blacks to examine minorities as group
produces a much smaller and not statistically significant effect. [36]
These specifications were also used to examine whether more black
police officers had a differential impact in more heavily black areas by
interacting the percentage of the police force that is black with the
percentage of the population that is black. The specification
corresponding to the first row in Table VIII implied that hiring more
black officers produces more violent crime in more heavily black areas
(the coefficient is 1.864; t-statistic = 1.922). Including the
interaction has little effect on the other coefficients. These
interactions imply that black officers are particularly ineffective at
dealing with crime in black communities.
An important question is whether the size of the police force
alters the impact of the hiring programs. For example, a large
department might be able to reallocate new affirmative action hires to
specific jobs where their impact on the functioning of the police force
might be relatively small. This effect would presumably be most
noticeable if the regressions measured the number rather than the
percentage share of minority officers. However, it is not clear why
increasing the share of minority officers should be easier for large
departments to accommodate, and the reverse could even be true if
decisions in large departments are driven more by fixed rules and
race-based decisions are harder to hide. To test this, I added a new
variable that interacted the percentage of the police force that is
black with the number of full-time sworn police officers and included
this variable in a version of the regressions shown in Table VIII that
only included the percent of the police force that is black. I also
tried simi lar specifications for white, Hispanic, and Asian. In none of
these cases was the new interaction statistically significant. [37]
We are thus left with a mixed conclusion. The weight of the
evidence indicates that at least a portion of the crime-increasing
effects of hiring minorities is picking up more general changes in the
way all hiring and promotions are conducted, but the evidence for this
is not overwhelming and cannot explain most of the impact that hiring
minorities has on crime.
VIII. MEASURING THE COST TO VICTIMS FROM THE CHANGING RACIAL AND
GENDER COMPOSITIONS OF POLICE DEPARTMENTS
A recent National Institute of Justice study estimates the victim
costs of different types of crime based on lost productivity,
out-of-pocket expenses such as medical bills and property losses, and
losses for fear, pain, suffering, and lost quality of life (Miller,
Cohen, and Wiersema [1996]). Although there are questions about using
jury awards to measure losses such as fear, pain, suffering, and lost
quality of life, the estimates provide us one method of comparing the
changes in different types of violent and property crimes that arise
from the changing composition of police departments and allow us to
estimate the total cost of these changes.
To provide a conservative estimate of these changes and provide a
simple way of separating out the differential effects of the consent
decree from the changing racial composition, I reestimated the
regressions shown in Appendix 2 using county fixed effects by replacing
the racial and gender breakdowns with the data available for 1987 and
1990 that provided information on the percentage of officers for each
race by sex (see also Table VI). Despite the reduced sample size, the
results used to produce Table IX were consistent with those shown in the
appendix.
Because some of the categories involve such a small number of
police officers, Table IX examines the changes for only those race and
sex groupings that accounted for at least 1% of all police officers in
1990. The top portion of the table lists out the predicted change in
crimes from an additional police officer and compares these changes with
the average number of crimes per officer for the sample. Holding
constant such variables as the size of the police force and the presence
of a consent decree, reducing the number of white male police officers
by 6,912 people appears to have increased the number of murders by 1,145
and rapes by over 100. This, however, assumes that the white officers
would have been replaced by the average new minority officer. In fact,
the actual smaller increase in white female officers more than offset
the pernicious effect of losing these white male officers. The actual
changes among white officers implies that the number of rapes should
have declined by more than 280.
The bottom portion of the table multiplies these estimated changes
in crime by the Miller, Cohen, and Wiersema estimates of victim costs
from crime in 1996 dollars. The increase in violent crimes represents a
loss of $5 billion ($4.4 billion loss from murder, $176 million from
robbery, $453 million from aggravated assault, but a gain of $51 million
from fewer rapes), whereas the increase in property crimes represents a
loss of $442 million ($333 from motor vehicle theft, $87 million from
burglary, and $22 million from larceny). However, although $5.4 billion
is substantial, to put it in perspective, it equals only about 1.1% of
the total aggregate losses from these crime categories. These estimates
are probably most sensitive to the value of life used (in the Miller et
al. study this was set at about $3.2 million in 1996 dollars). Higher
estimated values of life will increase the net costs from changing the
racial and gender composition of police departments, whereas lower
values will reduce the gains. To th e extent that people are engaging in
additional private actions to prevent this increased crime (Philipson
and Posner [19961), these numbers will underestimate the total savings
from these changing compositions.
IX. THE IMPACT ON ARREST RATES
The effectiveness of police officers can take several different
forms, but surely one of the most measurable is the arrest rate. If
certain types of police officers are more productive than others, it may
reveal itself in terms of higher arrest rates, though all arrests might
not be equally valuable. However, a couple of issues about the arrest
rate data should be addressed first. Frequently, because of the low
crime rates in some of the smaller cities, it is quite common to find
huge variations in the arrest rate both across cities and over years. In
this sample, the arrest rate for murder ranges from a low of 5% to a
high of 14 times the offense rate. The arrest rates for violent crimes
range from 10% to 3.6 times the offense rate. This seeming anomaly
arises for a couple of reasons. First, the year in which the offense
occurs frequently differs from the year in which the arrest occurs.
Second, an offense may involve more than one offender. Unfortunately,
the FBI data set allows us neither to link the year s in which offenses
and arrests occurred nor to link offenders with a particular crime.
These problems create significantly more variation in the arrest rate
than in the crime rate.
Tables X and XI rerun the regressions shown in Tables IV and VI
after replacing the natural logs of the crime rates with their
corresponding arrest rates. While the coefficients for the percentage of
the police force that is either black or minority are consistently
negative, Table X indicates that only the arrest rate for robbery is
significantly reduced by black and minority police officers. A similar
pattern holds for Table XI. More white officers are generally associated
with higher arrest rates. whereas more black, Hispanic, and Asian female
officers are associated with lower arrest rates, but coefficients are
usually not statistically significant at the 10% level for a two-tailed
t-test. As the share of black male officers increases, there are
statistically significant drops in arrest rates for violent crime, rape,
robbery, and assault. More white male officers produce a statistically
significant increase in arrests for murder, and more white females
significantly increase arrests for robbery. Increasi ngthe share of
Hispanic male officers consistently lowers arrest rates, but the one
case where the impact of more Hispanic males approaches statistical
significance is for rapesualso the one instance in Table VI where they
significantly lowered the crime rate. Overall, however, just eight of
the 72 specifications in Table XI are statistically significant at the
10% level for a two-tailed t-test, and another 14 coefficients are
significant at the 15% level.
Under the assumption that each dependent variable represents an
independent test of the hypothesis (which would be appropriate for
subcategories that are mutually exclusive), there is a test for
significance over all regressions. The inverse chi-square test, known
also as the Fisher test, can be used to assess overall significance
(e.g., Maddala [1977, 47u48] and Hedges and 01km [1985]). For the seven
subcrime categories shown in Table XI, this test implies that increasing
the share of black male police officers significantly reduces arrest
rates at the .5% level. For Asian-Pacific male officers, that is true at
the 10% level. Black female officers are associated with fewer arrests
for violent crime at the 1% level. The results for white male and female
officers show that as their shares rise, so do arrest rates (these
results are statistically significant at the 10% level).
A different approach is to ask whether the different racial and
gender groupings are statistically different from each other. By this
weaker standard, most of the violent crime arrest rates for blacks and
whites in Tables X and XI are significantly different from each other,
and Table X shows that for murder white male officers' arrest rates
are significantly higher than those for all other racial groups.
These results are certainly not as strong as those for the crime
rates, but they do indicate significant differences in arrest rates
between racial and gender groups. They also provide additional evidence
to rule out the possibility that the higher reported crime rates shown
earlier are a result of victims responding to higher expected payoffs
due to higher arrest rates. Further work still needs to be done in
evaluating the relative quality of different arrests.
X. HOW DOES THE CHANGING RACIAL AND GENDER COMPOSITION OF POLICE
DEPARTMENTS ALTER HOW POLICE DEPARTMENTS ARE ORGANIZED?
The Department of Justice's LEMAS survey provides a wealth of
other information about police departments that can give us some insight
into how changing the demographic composition of police officers alters
how police departments operate. Among the information available is the
percentage of police patrol units (both car and walking patrols) with
only one officer, the percentage of police walking patrol units with
only one officer, and the number of motorcycles and cars per officer.
The most obvious predictions stem from the differences in physical
strength of female and male officers. If there are significant
differences in strength, it effectively raises the cost of having
single-officer patrol units. As long as the percentage of women officers
is small relative compared to the number of preexisting two officer
patrol units, it is possible that women may be substituted into one of
the "men's slots" in an existing two officer unit. Yet,
even here substitutability might not be perfect because the two-officer
unit may have been set up precisely because the physical strength of two
male officers was desired. Even though data on the race and sex
composition of each single and two-officer patrol unit is not available,
it is still possible to examine how the use of these different patrols
differs over time in a city as the composition of the racial and sex
composition of the police department changes.
Although not a systematic analysis, the data confirm certain
regularities. For example, the police departments with the most
two-officer patrols tend to be those in the largest cities. For the
cities for which data were available, the top ten cities with the most
two-officer patrol units include Detroit, Los Angeles, Chicago, and
Buffalo. Only two-city police departments had no women who were
full-time sworn officers (Schenectady, N.Y., and Reno, Nev.), and those
departments averaged 58% fewer two-officer units (only 5%, compared to
the average for the rest of the departments of 12%). Those departments
with more than the median percent of male officers were also less likely
to have two-officer patrols (10%) than departments with fewer than the
median number of male officers (14%).
Table XII uses the same regression specifications employed in
Appendix 2 to explain the organization of departments. Because the data
for the percentage of police patrols and the percentage of walking
patrols with only one officer are only available for one year, it is not
possible to run these regressions using fixed city or county effects,
though there are enough observations here to use state fixed effects. In
addition, since the data are only available for 1993, we cannot break
down the race categories by sex.
The first two regressions reported in Table XII imply that
increasing the female officers' share of the police force
dramatically increases the number of two-officer patrol units. The
average police department has 88% of all police patrols as one-officer
units, but the coefficient on the first regression implies that a one
percentage point increase in the share of officers who are female
increases the number of two-officer patrol units by 1.1 to 1.3
percentage points. The effect is quite important in explaining the
behavior of police departments, with about 46%-55% of a one standard
deviation change in the percentage of patrols with one officer being
explained by a one standard deviation change in the percentage of a
department that is female. I also tried reestimating these results using
two-stage least squares along the lines shown in Table IV (but with the
crime rate variable in the second regression in the two-stage least
squares replaced with a variable measuring single officer patrols).
These estimates are similar to those already shown: a greater share of
black and minority officers reduce the number of single-officer units,
while a higher share of male officers increases the proportion of
single-officer units. [38]
Another concern about the changing composition of police
departments involves foot patrols. Possibly because women are relatively
less well suited for foot patrols and because it is difficult to exclude
women officers from this task once they are on the police force, the
presence of women police officers has an even greater upward effect on
the number of walking patrols with two officers. The second regression
in Table XII indicates that each one percentage point increase in the
percent of police who are women increases the share of two officer foot
patrols by two percentage points.
The third regression examines the percentage of all patrols that
are foot patrols. If women officers are relatively less desirable as
foot patrol officers, more women officers might result in police
departments not only increasing the number of police officers assigned
to each patrol but also switching from foot patrols to car patrols. The
evidence, however, does not support this hypothesis, with changes in the
number of officers per patrol apparently offsetting the weaknesses
produced by increasing the number of women officers. Although the male
share coefficient is indeed positive, it is very small (a one percentage
point increase in the female share reduces the foot patrols by only
eight hundredths of a percent) and is statistically insignificant.
The LEMAS survey also provided information on the number of cars,
motorcycles, bicycles, boats, helicopters, and airplanes used by police
departments. As a rough second check on the results supporting the
hypothesis that more women officers will reduce the number of single
officer patrol units, the number of police cars per officer provides an
independent measure of whether officers patrol together. Presumably the
more cars per officer, the less likely that multiple officers will be
patrolling together in the same car. Consistent with the already
reported results, more female officers do reduce the number of cars per
officer.
While not related to testing whether female officers are more
likely to be paired up with other officers in patrols, the other methods
of transportation at least provide a measure of whether the changing
demographic composition of police departments alter how they operate.
However, with the sole exception of motorcycles, none of the other modes
of transportation appear related to any of the race or gender measures.
The estimates for motorcycles imply that the increased presence of women
officers reduces police departments' reliance on motor-cycles and
that the size of the effect is about two-thirds to three-quarters the
size of women's impact on the number of cars. Undoubtedly,
automobiles are the most important portion of police department
expenditures on transportation, though except for the number of cars and
motorcycles there is no real evidence that altering the race or gender
composition of police departments changes how police departments
allocate their money for transportation.
Before finishing this discussion of the size of patrol units and
modes of transportation, a couple of comments should be made about the
other coefficients. The racial composition of police departments only
seems to help explain the percentage of police patrols with one unit and
the percentage of walking patrols. More black and Hispanic officers
increase the number of two-officer patrols, while more whites reduces
them. This finding is consistent with minority officers operating in
more dangerous areas, but it is also consistent with the desire to pair
the officers together to compensate for other deficiencies. In an
attempt to separate out these two explanations, I tried including
violent and property crime rates as well as the per capita number of
felonious police killings and police assaults in all these regressions
as measures of greater risks, but these variables had very little effect
on the results. Combined with the earlier results on police killings and
assaults, it does not appear that the increased reliance on two officer
units when more minorities are present can be explained by reference to
minority officers operating in more dangerous areas.
Given that we have state-level fixed effects for these regressions,
the consent decree variables imply that these decrees are imposed on
cities with relatively high reliance on single-officer and walking
patrols but that the longer these decrees are in effect, the more these
cities switch away from these types of patrols. The estimates further
support the hypothesis that changing the racial and gender composition
of police departments subject to these consent decrees resulted in lower
quality officers, which was compensated for by doubling up officers.
We next examine variables for whether police officers or special
operations officers are required to wear body armor. However, these
variables have the potential to provide additional information on
whether certain officers face more dangerous tasks, though it also runs
into possible difficulties in separating out the question of dangerous
risks from issues involving discrimination. The results imply that black
officers (both for patrol and special operations) are less likely to be
in police departments that require body armor, whereas the reverse is
true for white patrol officers. In an attempt to separate out the
discrimination story from the lower-risk explanation, I added a variable
to the regression that interacted the percentage of the police force
that is black with the dummy variable for whether the mayor is black. If
the lack of a requirement for body armor arises because of
discrimination, one would expect such an effect to disappear when a
black mayor is elected; thus, the interaction term would h ave to be
positive. In the specification for patrol officers this new interaction
is negative and statistically significant, while for special operations
officers, the effect is positive but quite insignificant (the
t-statistic is .257). The probability that a police department will
require police officers to wear protective body armor also increases as
there are more women officers on the police force, though the
coefficients are only statistically significant at the 10% level for a
one-tailed t-test. This result provides some evidence that police
departments are relatively more concerned in protecting female officers
from attacks.
Another important issue involves the changes in police department
size and thus changes in police experience that accompany the adoption
of consent decrees. Appendix 1 examines this issue but finds no evidence
that this can explain the results reported here.
XI. CONCLUSION
A massive experiment has been conducted with law enforcement during
the last couple of decades, with more minority and women officers being
hired. But does increasing the number of minority and women police
officers raise effectiveness by drawing on new untapped abilities, or
are standards lowered too far in order to hire large numbers of
minorities and women? I have argued here that the effect depends on the
type of crime. The evidence for rape is mixed, with most results
implying essentially no difference between male and female officers,
though some estimates indicate that the actual changes in the
composition of police departments helped reduce the number of rapes.
However, for all other crimes, more black officers are associated with
more crime, not less. But it would be a serious mistake not to realize
that this simple relationship is masking that the new rules reduce the
quality of new hires from other groups. This does not say that there are
not large potential benefits from minority police officers, but only
that the new rules under which new officers have been hired have costs
that outweigh the benefits.
So why do we observe different findings for minority and female
officers? At least part of the difference appears to arise from how the
hiring rules have been altered for the two groups. Physical strength
tests involve norming, whereas written tests have been altered so as to
produce equal pass rates across different groups. Norming may allow
lower-quality applicants in the protected category, but it at least does
not lower the quality of all new recruits. The results suggest that if
affirmative action is to be practiced, norming is the less costly way to
go. This raises a question that economist have thus far ignored: why are
different types of affirmative action used in different settings? Why
does academia use norming for admissions but police forces choose to
alter the testing? [39]
Changes in the composition of police departments have been
accompanied by changes in the organization of police departments. Some
of these changes--such as an increasing movement away from
single-officer patrol units--is likely due to the presence of more
female officers with less physical strength. Women officers are more
likely to be assaulted than men, though their overall probability of
death on the job is the same. Some preliminary evidence indicates that
white women officers are more likely to shoot civilians and that black
male officers are the least likely. The evidence is not consistent with
the hypothesis that black officers are more effective at dealing with
crime in predominately black areas. Instead, surprisingly, the results
suggest that it is the most heavily black communities that are the most
at risk from the increased crime produced by affirmative action
policies.
Other recent research confirms the basic finding in this paper.
While Donohue and Levitt [1998] examine the issue of how nonwhite and
white officers impact crime by members of their own group and by the
other group, taking their sensitivity estimates of "crime rates to
racial composition of the police force" and instead asking what
happens to the total crime rate when a white officer is replaced by a
nonwhite officer implies a large increase in violent crime in eight of
their ten specifications. [40] While they claim that nonwhite officers
relatively reduce white crime and white officers relatively reduce
nonwhite crime, the perverse effect that they find of nonwhite officers
on nonwhite crime dominates in eight of their ten violent crime
specifications.
As a warning for anyone doing future research: the evidence
suggests that a great deal of caution needs to be exercised in
aggregating different racial and/or gender groups. Not all nonwhite
racial groups are the same, and not all men and women in a particular
group are the same. Blacks, Hispanics, and Asians do not have the same
impact on crime. Many differences between men and women on crime also
disappear once different racial groups are subdivided by sex. The
different results obtained from aggregated and disaggregated
classifications strongly suggest that the most disaggregated
classifications should be used whenever possible.
This article was initially motivated by the Supreme Court's
recent rulings on affirmative action. Prior to consent decrees, the
"best" police officers might not always have been hired, but
the imposition of consent decrees appears to have increased crime, and
the longer the decree was in effect the greater was the increase in
crime. The hiring of minority officers thus does not appear to meet the
difficult strict scrutiny standard set forth by the Supreme Court. There
may be strong moral arguments for affirmative action, but crime
reduction is not one of them. The results do suggest that if
preferential hiring is to be practiced, changing testing standards is
much more costly than norming.
(*.) I would like to thank Stephen Bronars, Tom Collingwood,
Richard Epstein, Gertrud Fremling, Ed Glaescr, Linda Gottfrcdson, Robert
Hansen, Dan Kahan, Larry Kenny, Dan Klcrman, Bill Landes, Stan
Liebowitz, Scott Masten, Sam Peltzman, two very helpful referces from
this journal, and the participants in seminars at UCLA, the University
of Chicago, Cornell University, George Mason University, Heritage
Foundation, the NBER Law and Economics Summer Institute, University of
Michigan, Michigan State University, SUNY Binghamton, University of
Southern California, University of Washington, the American Law and
Economics Association, the Western Economic Association Meetings, the
Southern Economic Association meetings, and my students at the
University of Chicago for their helpful comments. Stephen Bronars also
deserves more than normal thanks for the tremendous amount of work that
he has put in helping me put this data set together. John Whitley also
provided valuable research assistance.
Lott: Senior Research Scholar, Yale University School of Law. New
Haven. Conn.,
(1.) See also Epstein [1992, 429-33]. Coate and Loury [1993]
provide an important discussion on the costs and benefits of affirmative
action policies. They rigorously list out conditions under which these
policies will break down negative stereotypes and those cases where they
will make them even worse.
(2.) Adarand overturned the decision in Metro Broadcasting, Inc. v.
Federal Communications commission.
(3.) Adarand.
(4.) A distinction must be drawn between two different types of
affirmative action programs: quotas and preferential treatment. While
preferential treatment already must meet a very high threshold to be
approved, the requirements are if anything even more difficult for
quotas. "it is doubtful that even a federal law establishing an
affirmative action racial classification would be upheld if the law used
a racial quota system" (Nowak and Rotunda [1995, 695].
(5.) For example, in 1996 riots errupted in St. Petersburg Florida,
after a white police officer shot and killed an 18-year-old black man
driving a stolen car and in Leland, Mississippi, after a white police
officer fatally shot a black businessman named Aaron White
("Kissimmee chief wants riot gear for police: The city should learn
from St. Petersburg's riots, John Sutphin said," Orlando
Sentinel, Saturday, April 26, 1997, p. 1, and Bartholomew Sullivan,
"Shooting death prior to Leland riot ruled accidental,"
Commercial Appeal (Memphis, Tenn), Friday, April 18, 1997, p. A15).
Further back "In 1980, one of the worst recent U.S. race riots
erupted in Liberty City and spread through Miami after an all-white jury
acquitted white police officers accused of killing a black man"
(Angus MacSwan, "Drug gangs rule, children suffer in Miami's
Liberty City," Reuters World Service, Friday, February 14, 1997).
Of course, probably the worst recent riots occurred in 1992 after white
police officers were found not guilty in the Rodney King beating. On the
other hand, having a racially diverse police department does not
guarantee that these riots will be prevented. The Los Angeles Police
Department's share of blacks very closely matched the city's.
(6.) Community leaders frequently claim that "We want police
who know the community. We want them to spend time and become part of
the community." (Quote from Dennis L. Chinn, founder of the Asian
Plaza Youth Foundation, as reported by Phat X. Chiem [1995, B1]. The
same article reports on the importance of having bilingual officers.
(7.) For example, see Katyal (1995] and Keohane [1995].
(8.) Testing of the physical strengths of men and women public
safety employees consistently finds large differences. These studies
indicate that "women's strength rang[es] from 44 to 68% of
men's in the upper body and 55 to 82% in the Lower body"
(Landy [1992, 4-56]). The norming adopted by most police departments for
physical fitness tests creates equal probabilities for passing by men
and women (Flannery, [1995, 2]). The same types of rules are adopted by
the military where "women recruits must run two miles in 18
minutes, 54 seconds, which is three minutes slower than the required
time for men. [Women] must do 18 push-ups in two minutes and 50 sit-ups
in two minutes, while men must do 42 push-ups and 52 sit-ups in the same
time." Tom Collingwood, a consultant on physical testing standards
in Dallas, estimates that between 70% and 80% of police departments
explicitly use norming of physical standards in their hiring practices.
However, he believes that most of the departments that use objective
standards do not enforce these rules. Women who fail to meet the
absolute standards during academy training are unlikely to be failed out
of the program. This belief was confirmed by conversations with other
experts in this area (e.g., Mike Bahrke at Fitforce in Champaign,
Illinois). This creates a difficult problem for testing the impact of
norming physical standards because it implies that all cities really
have the same standards whether they explicitly claim so or not (See
also Bahrke and Hoffman [1997]). Courts have also disallowed other types
of tests that produce differential pass rates between men and women. For
example, in a 1980 case involving the Philadelphia Police Department,
the district court ruled that it was unlawful to discharge women who
"failed to achieve a passing score on the firearms qualifying
test" (499 F. Supp. 1196).
(9.) The New York City Police Department is said to illustrate this
point. "The department abandoned all physical screening of
applicants in the '80's out fear of lawsuits by minority
applicants and women. Some officers hired under relaxed testing lack the
strength to pull the trigger on a gun,' said Michael Julian, former
NYPD chief of personnel. 'There are hundreds, if not thousands, of
police officers on the streets today who, when a suspect runs from them,
have no other option than to call another cop, because they do not have
the physical ability to pursue them,' Julian said" (Marzulli
and Lewis, [1997, 7]).
(10.) A gun might not be as much of an equalizer for female
officers as it is for women who use a gun defensively. Officers are
frequently called on to have physical contact with the criminals that
they are pursuing, whereas women who use a gun defensively merely use
the gun to keep a threatening person at bay.
(11.) Some testing consultants back up the Department of
Justice's position, and note the different ways that questions can
be worded which will hurt minority applicants. In particular, the use of
double-negatives, homonyms, questions reflecting middle-class
experiences, or "complex sentence structures toward the end of an
exam" all work to lower minority scores (Wilson, [1996, A]).
President Clinton's recent nominee as assistant attorney general
for civil rights (Bill Lann Lee) argues that "admission standards
for schooling "may not disproportionately exclude members of any
race, ethnicity, or gender" unless "justified by an
educational necessity and no less discriminatory but equally effective
alternatives to the practice exist." Lee argued that
"[University of California) cannot demonstrate any educational
necessity" for standardized tests. (Clint Bolick, "A Vote for
Lee Is a Vote for Preferences," Wall Street Journal October 27,
1997, p. A23).
(12.) The Louisiana case provides a good example of how these cases
work. As part of an agreement with the Department of Justice, the
Louisiana State Police agreed "to set aside $1 million to pay
African Americans who failed the test and hire new troopers from among
qualified African Americans who failed the test" (Shinkle, 1996,
B1-B2). The test that was developed by the Cooperative Personnel
Services, Inc., had been used in other jurisdictions where it had been
upheld as not discriminating against minority applicants by a federal
judge in a Torrance, California case. The Louisiana State Police
"denied the allegations of discrimination, but agreed to settle the
case with the federal government 'to avoid the burdens of contested
litigation." The Department of Justice pointed to the
"disparate impact" that the test was having on blacks and that
the test was not job-related, From August 1991 to May 1996, "of the
2,721 white applicants who took the test, 66 percent passed; of the
1,293 African Americans who took the test, just 25 percent passed."
(13.) The number of people participating in the lottery is to be
adjusted so as to ensure that enough minorities are found in the pool
from which the new hires will be chosen (Kass and O'Connor, [1995,
Al]). Other stories on the affirmative action process and its
consequences in Chicago are provided by Martin (1997, A4) and Oclander
(1995, 22).
(14.) The Washington Post editorial went on to claim that: "Of
the murder suspects who are indicted, many end up being acquitted
because of weak cases prepared by police. Washington's Pretrial
Services Agency reports that only 44 percent of the murder cases filed
in 1990 and closed by the first part of 1992 resulted in
convictions."
(15.) These decrees are contracts that the Department of Justice
and cities have signed that have been approved by a court, which
obligate the city to act in certain ways in the future.
(16.) I tried a regression that predicted which cities would have
consent decrees imposed on them. The most important factors were city
size, whether the city was the largest in a state, and the type of
administration. Republican presidential administrations tended to impose
consent decrees on relatively Democratic states, whereas Democrat
presidential administrations tended to impose consent decrees on
relatively Republican states.
(17.) While the hiring of minority officers is motivated by the
desire to assign these new officers to minority neighborhoods, the legal
prohibition against giving officers assignments based on their race
require that any new minority officers be evenly distributed across
districts. It is very easy for minority officers to bring discrimination
suits if they feel that they are being disproportionately assigned to
more dangerous neighborhoods. Black officers have no more desire than
white officers to be assigned to dangerous high crime areas. (For
another perspective with respect to New York City, see Fyfe [1981].)
(18.) There are also questions about whether some officers have
stronger preferences for policing certain types of communities based on
their level of crime.
(19.) Similar estimates are produced if unweighted estimates are
employed, but these data exhibit definite heteroskedasticity, with the
smaller cities reporting a much greater variation in crime rates over
time.
(20.) I tried three different types of location fixed effects:
city, county, and state. Generally, using the broader measures of
location produced estimates that agreed in sign with the city fixed
effects, but the estimates were larger and more statistically
significant. To deal with possible state-level trends in laws, I also
tried allowing a separate fixed effect for each state for each year,
though when combined with county or city fixed effects this dramatically
reduces the degrees of freedom in each regression. Only the time-varying
state fixed effects are reported with the county fixed effects because
none of the estimates on any of the focus or control coefficients was
statistically significant with city fixed effects.
(21.) One concern raised to me by Ed Glaeser is whether the results
are being driven solely by time-series changes in the data and whether
these results are consistent across the years being studied. To test
this, I reran the regressions shown in Table IV with fixed state effects
separately on the data for each of the three different years. For blacks
the coefficient signs are similar to those already reported, though the
results for these smaller subsets of data are not always statistically
significant. The results for 1987 are as follows: for violent crimes the
coefficient is 4.3 (t-stat = 1.822); property crimes, 3.34 (t-stat =
1.811); and murder 5.52 (t-stat = 1.254). The results for 1990 are as
follows: for violent crimes the coefficient is 3.08 (t-stat = 1.071);
property crimes, 5.46 (t-stat = 2.358); and murder, 3.45 (t-stat =
0.872). The results for 1993 are as follows: for violent crimes the
coefficient is 3.025 (t-stat = 1.900); property crimes, 2.509 (t-stat =
2.847); and murder, 1.711 (t-stat = 0 .815). Similar results are also
produced for the percentage male and the percentage minority
specifications.
(22.) More precisely, when the omitted group in the reduced form
regression (represented by the intercept) is Hispanics, the probability
that the coefficients for whites and Asians are statistically
significantly different from each other at the following levels as: for
violent crimes is 34%; property crimes, 73%; murder, 39%; manslaughter,
41%; rape, 78%; forcible rape, 79%; attempted rape, 5.6%; robbery, 31%;
gun robbery, 15%; knife robbery, 4.9%; other robbery, 0%; strong-arm
robbery, 79%; assault, 66%; burglary, 77%; larceny, 68%; and motor
vehicle theft, 98%. The probability that the coefficients for blacks and
Hispanics are statistically significantly different from each other is:
for violent crimes it is 36%; property crimes, 51%; murder, 14%;
manslaughter, 37%; rape, 77%; forcible rape, 56%; attempted rape, 73%;
robbery, 1.6%; gun robbery, 1.5%; knife robbery, 46%; other robbery,
56%; strong-arm robbery, 74%; assault, 99%; burglary, 3%; larceny, 60%;
and motor vehicle theft, 22%. The probability that the coefficients for
blacks and whites are statistically significantly different from each
ocher is: for violent crimes it is 5%; property crimes, 4.5%; murder,
.12%; manslaughter, .01%; rape, 43%; forcible rape, 39%; attempted rape,
57%; robbery, .16%; gun robbery, .37%; knife robbery, 58%; other
robbery, 8%; strong-arm robbery, 62%; assault, 3%; burglary, 6%;
larceny, 34%; and motor vehicle theft, .17%. State fixed effects were
used for these estimates. A related set of regressions is reported in
Section VII, though these regressions do not have alt these categories
included at the same time.
(23.) Limits on the number of variables that could be handled using
two-stage least-squares with STATA restricted the regressions on the
larger data set to the state fixed effects specifications. (This is the
data set that was not restricted to those cities for which demographic
data was available.) Estimates using these data remain similar to those
already reported in Table IV. The sample size for this larger data set
is 1,015 observations for the regressions explaining the percentage of
the police force that is black or minority and 1,026 for the percentage
of the police force that is male.
(24.) For example, after excluding the crime rates from the
first-stage regression, the city fixed effects regressions produced
estimates for the percentage of the police force that is black of 2.43
(t-statistic 1.741) for violent crimes and 2.25 (t-statistic = 1.864)
for property crimes. For the percentage of the police force that is
minority, the city fixed effect results were: 1.98 (t-statistic 1.810)
for violent crimes and 1,86 (t-statistic = 2.055) for property crimes.
For the percentage of the police force that is male, the city fixed
effect results were: -7.73 (t-statistic = 1.012) for violent crimes and
-7.9 (t-statistic = 1.042) for property crimes. As was true in Table IV,
the level of significance tended to be higher for county fixed effect
regressions. The first-stage regression results also remain similar to
those already reported. For the regression estimating the percentage of
the police force that is black, the consent decree coefficient is .017
(t-statistics .899) and the number of years tha t it is in effect is
.0042 (t-statistic = 3.376). For the regression for minorities, the
consent decree coefficient is .059 (t-statistics = 2.274) and the number
of years that it is in effect is .0049 (t-statistic = 2.962). For the
regression for males, the coefficients are again statistically
insignificant.
(25.) See Lott and Mustard [1997], for a discssion of these data.
(26.) See Lott and Mustard [1997], for a discussion of these data.
(27.) Given the possible relationship between drug prices and
crime, I reran the regressions in Table IV by including an additional
variable for cocaine prices. One argument linking drug prices and crime
is that if the demand for drugs is inelastic and if people commit crimes
in order to finance their habits, higher drug prices might lead to
increased levels of crime. Using the Drug Enforcement
Administration's STRIDE data set from 1977 to 1992 (with the
exceptions of 1988 and 1989), Michael Grossman, Frank J. Chaloupka, and
Charles C. Brown [1996] estimate the price of cocaine as a function of
its purity, weight, year dummies, year dummies interacted with eight
regional dummies, and individual city dummies. However, these data are
not perfect. Because of the lack of observations for 1993, I used the
drug prices for 1992. While the drug price variable was positive it was
not statistically significant and its inclusion had very little impact
on the relationship between the type of police officer and the crime
rate. I would like to thank Michael Grossman for providing us with the
original regressions on drug prices from his paper.
(28.) I followed Ayres and Levitt's [1997] paper, which
identifies when Lojack was adopted so that I could control for both a
dummy variable for the presence of the law and a time trend for the
number of years that the law was in effect. Although both variables
implied that auto theft fell when Lojack was adopted, neither
coefficient was statistically significant. Unfortunately, neither Ayres
and Levitt nor Lojack were willing to share data on the number of Lojack
devices sold.
(29.) It is important to note that there are legal difficulties in
assigning minority officers to specifically patrol minority areas. Such
a policy would generate charges of discrimination (e.g., 411 F. Supp.
218, which writes that police department can not "segregate its
personnel along black neighborhood lines any more than the City's
housing authority can foster racially segregated public housing").
(30.) The 174 cities that were in the sample every year averaged a
felonious killing of an on-duty police officer at the rate of one every
ten years, while accidental deaths (from all sources such as traffic
accidents and accidental shootings) averaged about one every 27 years.
Three cities New York City in 1987 and Chicago and Philadelphia in 1990
had three felonious killings of police officers in a year. Between 1987
and 1993, the number of felonious police killings per full-time sworn
officer rose from .010% to .018%, and the number of accidental deaths
per officer increased even faster, from .0005% to .0028%. While these
are large percentage increases, the amount of variation from one year to
another does not imply an overall trend. With 12 observations having
more than a thousand assaults in a year, a much more frequent occurrence
is an officer being assaulted--though the probability fell from 26% to
22%. The cities with more than a thousand assaults against police in a
year are Baltimore (all three year s), Chicago (one year), Houston (one
year), Los Angeles (three years), Phoenix (one year), Philadelphia (two
years), and New York (one year).
(31.) An alternative explanation for the high assault rates on
women officers is that the changes in assaults arc being driven by a
lack of respect for women that just happens to be correlated with the
changes in the number of female officers. It is difficult to measure
this changing respect for women, but I attempted to do this by including
the rape rate in the regressions that use the percent of the police that
is male to explain the assault rate. In none of the regressions was the
rape rate statistically significant, and its inclusion did not alter the
coefficient on the percentage male. I would like to thank Bill Landes
for raising this possibility to me.
(32.) The comparable estimates for Table VI and Appendix Tables Bi
and B2 are available on request from the author.
(33.) While the existing evidence by Fyfe [1989] and others on
which types of police officers are more likely to engage in shootings is
very interesting, there are several unresolved questions. The primary
issues are that the work is purely cross-sectional, uses even smaller
samples than I use here from just the largest cities, and only attempts
to control for other variables through the use of conditional means.
Tests comparing the percentage of police officers by race in different
specialties that have engaged in a shooting find statistically
significant differences between the races by assignment, but the claim
is that the differences are likely to be explained away by such factors
such as the different tasks being performed within each type of category
(Fyfe, [198]).
(34.) These additional results are available on request from the
author.
(35.) By comparison, the violent crime estimates using county as
well as different state fixed effects for each year result in a
coefficient for the percentage of the police force that is black of
1.721 (t-statistic 3.172) and for the consent decree of .3592
(f-statistic = 2.230). Similarly for the percentage of the police force
that is a minority the coefficient is 1.495 (t-statistic = 3.658) and
the coefficient for the consent decree is .3092 (t-statistic = 1.921).
(36.) Evidence from quasi-reduced form regressions when all the
additional different racial and gender measures are simultaneously
controlled for is mixed (see Appendix B).
(37.) I also used the reduced-form regressions to answer whether
the impact of the consent decrees differred by either the percentage of
the police force that was black or the gap between the percent that was
black and the percentage of the over-16-year-old population that was
black. To do this, I ran the reduced-form regressions with the
percentage of the police force that is black as well as with one of two
new sets of variables: either the percentage of the police force that is
black interacted with the presence of the consent decree and the length
of time that the decree has been in effect or the gap between the
percentage of the population and the police force that are black
interacted with these two variables. The results for the percent black
that were previously statistically significant remain so, but the other
variables for the consent decree and the various interactions are
usually insignificant.
(38.) A seminal article by Wilson and Boland [1978] pointed out
that it is not simply the total number of police or the size of their
budget that matters but also how the police are allocated that
determines their effectiveness. They argued that a more "aggressive
patrol strategy," one that was associated with more single-officer
patrol units, was effective in reducing crime rates. If they are correct
and consent decrees make it more difficult for police departments to
deploy police officers in single-officer patrol units, this might help
identify one of the mechanisms for the increase in crime. However,
including the variable measuring the percentage of patrols that are done
by single officers in the regressions shown in Table III does not appear
to be statistically significant, and it does not alter the significance
of the racial or gender composition variables.
(39.) Of course, in recent years, SAT tests have also moved to
altering the tests and how the different parts of the tests are weighted
so as to equalize the scores of women and men.
(40.) The two-stage least squares estimates for both violent crimes
and property crimes imply the largest increases in crime when a white
officer is substituted with a nonwhite officer. There are many issues
that the authors do not address in their paper. The impact of cross race
assignment of officers is puzzling given the prohibitions against
assigning patrol officers based on their race (see note 17). It is not
clear how two-officer patrol units will favor particular racial groups
when the officers are from different racial backgrounds. For example,
given the relatively small number of minority officers (see Tables I and
II), the rate at which minority officers will be assigned together
should be extremely small in the vast majority of police departments.
Given the desire to team inexperienced officers with more experienced
ones, the probability of that both officers in a patrol unit will be
minority officers will lag any changes in the racial composition of the
department. The research in this paper sugg ests that there is some
danger in aggregating all nonwhite groups together and in not
disaggregating by sex. The current article also goes further in using
the amount of time a consent decree is in effect and also in using this
instrument to try to differentiate whether the changes in crime rates
are do to the nonwhite officers or the affect that the changing rules
have on the quality of all new hires.
(41.) On average, there are about 2.2 police officers per 1,000
residents in a city.
(42.) This pattern of growth is consistent with what is mandated by
consent decrees which required an usually large number of officers to be
hired immediately (e.g., 411 F. Supp. 218).
(43.) The percentage change is defined as the change in the number
of sworn police officers between two years divided by the average of
those two year's number of police officers.
(44.) I also tried replacing the variables for the percent of the
police force that is black with that variable interacted with the
percent change in a police force's size. The results were again
implied that increasing the percent of a police force that is black
increases the crime rate. The t-statistics for this new variable in the
violent and property crime regressions with city fixed effects are 3.092
and 2.919.
(45.) Landy [1992] argues that the increased productivity police
officers acquire from experience are essentially produced during their
first three years of service. Another method of testing the impact of
lack of experience is rerun the regressions in Table IV with a dummy
variable equalling one for the first three or four years after a consent
decree has gone into effect. While this variable is sometimes positive
and significant, the coefficients for the percent of the police force
that is black, minority, or male remain essentially unaltered. Finally,
in an attempt to measure the actual change in the number of new
officers, I contacted the largest 60 police departments and obtained the
number of police officers leaving employment by year for Chicago,
Cincinnati, Colorado Springs, Columbus, Dallas, Denver, El Paso,
Honolulu, Houston, Indianapolis, Memphis, Nashville, New York, Oklahoma
City, Philadelphia, Sacramento, San Antonio, San Jose, and Syracuse. For
most cities, the data imply a fairly consistent r etirement rate for
departments across years. For example, New York experienced 506
retirements in 1987, 568 in 1990, and 528 in 1993. Adjusting my
estimates of the number of new police officers using these retirement
rates leaves those already reported results essentially unchanged.
REFERENCES
Ayres, Ian, and Steven Levitt. "Measuring Positive
Externalities from Unobservable Victim Precaution: An Empirical Analysis
of Lojack." Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 1998, 43-77.
Bahrke, Mike, and Bob Hoffman. "Identifying the Fitness Needs
of Law Enforcement Officers." Working Paper, Fit Force, 1997.
Coate, Stephen, and Glenn Loury. "Will Affirmative-Action
Policies Eliminate Negative Stereotypes?" American Economic Review,
December 1993, 1220-40.
Chiem, Phat X. "The Ethnic Gap: City Short on Asian
Cops." Seattle Times, 18 August, 1995, sec. B, p. 1.
"D.C.'s Finest, at Their Worst; It's All Uphill for
the New Chief, But Here's Where His Climb Should Start."
Washington Post, 17 January 1993, sec. C, p.8.
Donohue, John J, and Steven D. Levitt. "The Impact of Race on
Policing, Arrest Patterns, and Crime." Working Paper, Stanford
University Law School, August 1998.
Dunnette, Marvin, Joan G. Haworth, Leaetta Hough, James L. Outtz,
Erich P. Prien, Neal Schmitt, Bernard Siskin, and Sheldon Zedeck.
"Police Selection and Promotion Practices Survey Results."
HRStrategies, April 1993.
Dunnette, Marvin, Joan G. Haworth, Leaetta Hough, James L. Outtz,
Erich P. Prien, Neal Schmitt, Bernard Siskin, and Sheldon Zedeck.
"Response to Criticisms of Nassau County Test Construction and
Validation Project." Working Paper, University of Minnesota, 1996.
Epstein, Richard, Forbidden Grounds. Cambridge, Mass: Harvard
University Press, 1992.
Flannery, Mary, "Fitness Standards Set Up Through 'Gender
Norming."' Houston Chronicle. 11 September 1995, p. 2.
Fyfe, James J. "Who Shoots? A Look at Officer Race and Police
Shooting." Journal of Police Science and Administration, 9(4),
1981, 367-382.
_____."The Split-Second Syndrome and Other Determinants of
Police Violence." in Critical Issues in Policing: Contemporary
Readings, ed. Roger G. Dunham and Geoffrey P. Alpert, Prospect Heights,
Ill.: Waveland Press, 1989.
Gottfredson, Linda S. "Racially Gerrymandered Police
Tests." Wall Street Journal, 24 October 1996, sec. A, p. 16.
_____."The Department of Justice's Involvement with the
1994 Nassau County Police Entrance Examination." Testimony before
U.S. House Judiciary Committee, Constitution Subcommittee, 20 May 1997.
Grossman, Michael, Frank 3. Chaloupka, and Charles C. Brown.
"The Demand for Cocaine by Young Adults: A Rational Addiction
Approach." Working Paper No. W5713, National Bureau of Economic
Research, 1996.
Hedges, Larry V., and Ingram Olkin. Statistical Methods for Meta
-Analysis. Orlando: Academic Press, 1985.
Kass, John, and Matt O'Connor. "U.S. Judge OKs Exam for
Firefighting Hiring; Ruling Ends 2 Decades of Federal Oversight."
Chicago Tribune, 25 July 1995, sec. A, p.1.
Katyal, Neal Kumar. "Why Affirmative Action in Higher
Education is Safe in the Courts." Journal of Blacks in Higher
Education, Autumn 1995, 83-89.
Keohane, Nan, "Return to the Good Ol' Days?" Journal
of Blacks in Higher Education, Winter 1994/1995, 90.
Landy, Frank J., Principal Investigator. Alternatives to
Chronological Age in Determining Standards of Suitability for Public
Safety Jobs, Volume 1:Technical Report, Boulder, Colo,: Saville and
Holdsworth, 31 January 1992.
Lewis, William G. "Toward Representative Bureaucracy: Blacks
in City Police Organizations, 1975-1985." Public Administration
Review, May/June 1989, 257-67.
Lott, John R., Jr. "Who is Really Hurt By Affirmative
Action?" Police Executive Research Forum, 12(5), May 1998,1,3.
Lott, John R., Jr., More Guns, Less Crime: Understanding Crime and
Gun Control Laws, 2nd ed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2000.
Lott, John R., Jr., and David B. Mustard. "Crime Deterrence,
and Right-to-Carry Concealed Handguns." Journal of Legal Studies,
January 1997, 1-69.
Maddala, G. S., Econometrics. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1977.
Martin, Andrew. "Bias Alleged in Probes of Black Cops."
Chicago Tribune. 20 June 1997, p. 4.
Matulia, Kenneth 3. A Balance of Forces: Model Deadly Force Policy
and Procedure, 2nd ed. Gaithersburg, MD. International Association of
Chiefs of Police, 1985.
Marzulli, John, and David L. Lewis. "Cop Hopefuls Face Chase
Test to Mimic Run After Suspect." New York Daily News, 12 March
1997, p. 7.
McGreevy, Patrick. "Police Height Plan Advances: Commission
OKs Ending LAPD Requirement." Daily News (Los Angeles), 19 February
1997, sec. N, p.4.
Miller, Ted R., Mark A. Cohen, and Brian Wiersema. Victim costs and
consequences: A New Look. Washington, D.C.: National Institute of
Justice, 1996.
Nowack, John E., and Ronald D. Rotunda. Constitutional Law, 2nd ed.
St. Paul, Minn.: West Publishing Company, 1995.
Oclander, Jorge. "Tactics Put Police Brass to the Test."
Chicago Sun-Times. Sunday, 22 October 1995, p. 22.
Peltzman, Sam, "The Effects of Automobile Safety
Regulation." Journal of Political Economy, August 1975, 677-725.
Philipson, Tomas J., and Richard A. Posner. "The Economic
Epidemiology of Crime." Journal of Law and Economics, October 1996,
405-34.
Price, David A. "Dumbing Down the Police Force."
Investor's Business Daily, 13 June 1997, sec. A, p.1.
Shinkle, Peter. "Test Officials Question State's
Move." (Baton Rouge, La.) Advocate, 31 August 1996, sec. B, pp.
1-2.
Spielman, Fran. "Mayor Defends Hiring Promotion Decisions on
Police and Firefighters." Chicago Sun Times, 31 January 1996, p.
16.
Wilson, James Q. Thinking about Crime. New York: Basic Books, 1983.
Wilson, James Q., and Barbara Boland. "The Effect of the
Police on Crime." Law & Society Review, Spring 1978, 367-90.
Wilson, Terry. "Atlanta Fire, Police Exams Win Plaudits;
City's Test Process Viewed As Unbiased." Chicago Tribune, 4
March 1996, sec. A, p.1.
CASE REFERENCES
Adarand Constructors, Inc., petitioner V. Federico Pena, Secretary
of Transportation, et al. 515 U.S. 200; 115 S. Ct. 2097; 1995 U.S. Lexis
4037; 132 L. Ed. 2d 158; 63 U.S.L.W. 4523; 67 Fair Empl. Prac. Case.
(BNA).
411 F. Supp. 218; 1976 U.S. Dist.
499 F. Supp. 1196; 1980 U.S. Dist. Lexis 16108.
Metro Broadcasting, Inc. v. Federal Communications Commission 497
U.S. 547, 110 S. Ct 2997, 111 L. Ed. 2d 445 (1990).
Richmond v. J. A. Croson Co., 488 U.S. 469, 109 S. Ct. 706, 102 L.
Ed. 2d 854 (1989).
The Race and Gender Composition of Police Departments
Distribution of Race and
Gender Characteristics for
Police Departments
10th Percentile Median
Sample for
Which Yearly
Demographic
Entire Estimates are Entire
Sample available Sample
% of the police 0% 0% 0%
force that is
Asian Pacific
% of the police 0% 1.3% 0%
force that is black
% of the police 0% 0% 0%
force that is
Hispanic
% of the police 72% 65% 98.5%
force that is white
% of the police 86% 86% 97%
force that is male
90th Percentile
Sample for Sample for
which Yearly which Yearly
Demographic Demographic
Estimates are Entire Estimates are
available Sample available
% of the police 0% .63% 1.5%
force that is
Asian Pacific
% of the police 7.8% 18.3% 26%
force that is black
% of the police 2.1% 8% 14.5%
force that is
Hispanic
% of the police 85.5% 100% 96.5%
force that is white
% of the police 91.7% 100% 96.6%
force that is male
Notes: The entire sample has 4,158 city/year observations for 1987,
1990 and 1993. The sample for which yearly demographic estimates are
available from the Current Population Survey Contains 664 city/year
observations: 204 Police Departments in 1987, 220 in 1993.
The Changing Racial Composition of Police Departments
Change at the
10th Percentile
No Consent Consent
Decree Decree
A. Changes in the Racial Composition of
Police Departments With and Without Consent
Decrees That Occurred from 1987 to 1993.
Percentage Point -.6 -.23
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Asian Pacific
Percentage Point -6.8 -.2
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Black
Percentage Point -.14 -.12
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Hispanic
Percentage Point -11.5 -21
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
White
B. Changes in the Sex Composition of
Police Departments With and Without
Consent Decrees From 1987 to 1993
Percentage Point -5.3 -6.3
Change in the % of the
Police Force that is
Male
Change at the Median
No Consent Consent
Decree Decree
A. Changes in the Racial Composition of
Police Departments With and Without Consent
Decrees That Occurred from 1987 to 1993.
Percentage Point 0 .2
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Asian Pacific
Percentage Point .73 3.2
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Black
Percentage Point .7 1.1
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Hispanic
Percentage Point -2.3 -5.9
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
White
B. Changes in the Sex Composition of
Police Departments With and Without
Consent Decrees From 1987 to 1993
Percentage Point -1.1 -2.8
Change in the % of the
Police Force that is
Male
Change at the
90th Percentile
No Consent Consent
Decree Decree
A. Changes in the Racial Composition of
Police Departments With and Without Consent
Decrees That Occurred from 1987 to 1993.
Percentage Point 1.0 1.8
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Asian Pacific
Percentage Point 6.0 18.2
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Black
Percentage Point 5.4 7.0
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
Hispanic
Percentage Point .98 -.7
Change in the % of
the Police Force that is
White
B. Changes in the Sex Composition of
Police Departments With and Without
Consent Decrees From 1987 to 1993
Percentage Point 6.4 0
Change in the % of the
Police Force that is
Male
Notes: Panel A again breaks down the sample on the basis of the
complete LEMAS Survey and those cities for which information on changing
city demographics are available. The table shows thc change in the
racial and gender compositions of police departments. The entire sample
contains 333 cities without consent decrees for which information is
available for the same city for all three years. Twenty one cities with
consent decrees meet this criteria. By contrast, the restricted sample
that is used for the regressions contains 163 and 19 cities in these two
categories, though it provides very similar results.
Panel B again breaks down the sample on the basis of the complete
LEMAS Survey and those cities for which information on changing city
demographics are available. The entire sample contains 343 cities
without consent decrees for which information is available for the same
city for all three years. Fourteen cities with consent decrees meet this
criteria. By contrast, the restricted sample that is used for the
regressions contains 163 and 19 cities in these two categories, though
it produces very similar results.
Changes in Crime Rates for Cities with and without Consent
Decrees for the Period 1985--94; Using Only Fixed Effects
Crime Rates Per 100,000 People
Time Trend for
Years before Consent
Decree Went Into
Effect (negative values
imply that crime
was falling until
the decree went
into effect)
Controlling for City and Year
Fixed Effects
Violent Crime Rate -138.6
-5.3%
(4.204)
Property Crime Rate -593.4
-9.4%
(6.257)
Controlling for City Fixed
Effects and Separate Year Fixed
Effects for Each State
Violent Crime Rate -60.85
-2.3%
(1.195)
Property Crime Rate -464.0
-7.4%
(5.998)
Time Trend for
Years after Consent
Decree Went Into
Effect (positive values
imply that crime
was rising after
the decree went
into effect)
Controlling for City and Year
Fixed Effects
Violent Crime Rate 126.1
4.8%
(11.433)
Property Crime Rate 172.2
2.7%
(9.346)
Controlling for City Fixed
Effects and Separate Year Fixed
Effects for Each State
Violent Crime Rate 86.05
3.3%
(7.901)
Property Crime Rate 133.76
2.1%
(8.085)
F-test
(Prob [greater than] F)
that before
and after
time trends Adjacent
are different [R.sup.2]
Controlling for City and Year
Fixed Effects
Violent Crime Rate 36.35 .7939
(.0000)
Property Crime Rate 57.37 .7719
(.0000)
Controlling for City Fixed
Effects and Separate Year Fixed
Effects for Each State
Violent Crime Rate 7.10 .8738
(.0078)
Property Crime Rate 50.94 .8845
(.0000)
No. of
Observations
Controlling for City and Year
Fixed Effects
Violent Crime Rate 4,947
Property Crime Rate 4,947
Controlling for City Fixed
Effects and Separate Year Fixed
Effects for Each State
Violent Crime Rate 4,947
Property Crime Rate 4,947
Notes: The first number is the annual change in crimes per 100,000
people, while the second number is the change as a percent of the
mean crime rate. Absolute t-statistics are shown in parentheses.
The regressions use weighted least squares.
Using Two-Stage Least Squares to Take Into Account the Impact
That Consent Decrees and the Presence of a Black Mayor Have on the
Composition of Police Departments
% of the Police Force
that is Black
County Fixed Effects
City and Year and Separate Year Fixed
Fixed Effects Effects for each State
(1) (2)
coefficient % of coefficient % of
Crime and t- mean and t- mean
Rates Statistic explained Statistic explained
Violent 4.79 8% 7.14 12%
crime (2.38) (3.57)
Property 4.27 5% 3.96 5%
crime (2.51) (3.08)
Murder 1.87 11% 9.43 56%
(1.64) (2.88)
Man 6.39 40% 6.33 39%
slaughter (0.78) (1.11)
Rape 13.27 41% 4.07 12%
(1.78) (1.98)
Total 7.86 16% 9.55 20%
robbery (3.07) (4.08)
Total 2.10 4% 6.06 11%
assault (0.90) (2.71)
Burglary 7.05 11% 6.19 9%
(3.12) (3.88)
Larceny 4.83 6% 3.53 5%
(2.76) (2.77)
Motor -0.81 1% 6.30 11%
vehicle (0.34) (2.69)
theft
Felonious -4.26 20% 5.82 28%
killings of (1.22) (2.23)
police
officers
% of the Police Force
that is Minority (Black,
Hispanic, and American
Indian)
County Fixed Effects
City and Year and Separate Year Fixed
Fixed Effects Effects for each State
(3) (4)
coefficient % of coefficient
Crime and t- mean and t-
Rates Statistic explained Statistic
Violent 3.01 6% 6.068
crime (2.52) (3.85)
Property 2.58 4% 3.20
crime (2.59) (3.18)
Murder 1.46 11% 8.03
(1.82) (3.20)
Man 2.50 20% 5.84
slaughter (0.51) (1.31)
Rape 5.97 23% 3.14
(1.42) (1.96)
Total 4.57 12% 7.67
robbery (3.18) (4.25)
Total 1.83 4% 5.55
assault (1.30) (3.13)
Burglary 3.99 8% 4.999
(3.23) (3.95)
Larceny 3.24 5% 3.05
(3.10) (3.01)
Motor -1.11 2% 4.66
vehicle (0.76) (2.57)
theft
Felonious -4.39 27% 3.846
killings of (1.99) (2.14)
police
officers
% of the Police Force
that is Male
County Fixed Effects
City and Year and Separate Year Fixed
Fixed Effects Effects for each State
(5) (6)
% of Coefficient % of Coefficient
Crime mean and t- mean and t-
Rates explained Statistic explained Statistic
Violent 13% -8.19 9% -10.28
crime (1.97) (1.67)
Property 5% -6.42 5% -6.57
crime (1.18) (1.69)
Murder 61% -6.41 26% -8.26
(0.96) (1.18)
Man 46% -13.06 55% -3.69
slaughter (0.86) (0.35)
Rape 12% -8.98 19% -6.67
(0.73) (1.37)
Total 20% -11.06 15% -13.53
robbery (1.22) (1.78)
Total 13% -6.64 8% -8.54
assault (1.07) (1.44)
Burglary 10% -9.23 9% -10.45
(1.22) (1.79)
Larceny 5% -8.68 8% -6.38
(1.24) (1.69)
Motor 10% 3.79 4% -7.08
vehicle (0.81) (1.34)
theft
Felonious 22% 11.96 29% -10.31
killings of (1.31) (1.58)
police
officers
% of
Crime mean
Rates explained
Violent 12%
crime
Property 6%
crime
Murder 33%
Man 15%
slaughter
Rape 14%
Total 19%
robbery
Total 10%
assault
Burglary 11%
Larceny 6%
Motor 8%
vehicle
theft
Felonious 35%
killings of
police
officers
Using Two-Stage Least Squares to Take Into Account the Impact
That Consent Decrees and the Presence of a Black Mayor
Have on the Composition of Police Departments
% of the Police Force
that is Black
County Fixed
Effects and
Separate Year
City and Year Fixed Effects
Fixed Effects for each State
(1) (2)
coefficient % of coefficient % of
Crime and t- mean and t- mean
Rates Statistic explained Statistic explained
Assaults on 78.14 128% .823 1%
police (3.49) (.095)
officers
Accidental -.543 3% .315 1%
deaths of (0.29) (.242)
police
officers
% of the Police Force
that is Minority (Black,
Hispanic, and American
Indian)
County Fixed
Effects and
Separate Year
City and Year Fixed Effects
Fixed Effects for each State
(3) (4)
coefficient % of coefficient % of
Crime and t- mean and t- mean
Rates Statistic explained Statistic explained
Assaults on 61.84 131% 6.35 13%
police (4.47) (1.00)
officers
Accidental -.097 1% -.179 1%
deaths of (.083) (.190)
police
officers
% of the Police Force
that is Male
County Fixed
Effects and
Separate Year
City and Year Fixed Effects
Fixed Effects for each State
(5) (6)
Coefficient % of Coefficient % of
Crime and t- mean and t- mean
Rates Statistic explained Statistic explained
Assaults on -18.7 16% -15.31 18%
police (1.89) (1.69)
officers
Accidental -2.00 5% -4.80 16%
deaths of (.742) (1.60)
police
officers
Notes: The regression estimates for equation (2) for the two-stage
least squares that are reported above account for the same variables
controlled for in the first-stage regression except for the consent
decree, the number of years since the consent decree went into effect,
and whether the city's Mayor is black, which were instead included
in the first-stage regression. The other variables controlled for were
the percentage of the population in different demographic categories
that were broken down by age (less than 30 years of age, 30-54 years of
age, and 55 and older), race (black, white, and other), and sex (male
and female) so that this information was available for 18 categories,
the average weekly wage, the unemployment rate, and city population and
population squared. The absolute t-statistics are shown in the
parentheses below the coefficient estimate, with the percent of the
endogenous variable's mean that can be explained by a
one-standard-deviation change in the exogenous variable shown in the adj
acent column. All regressions use weighted least squares where the
variables are weighted by the city population. For the percentage of
officers that are black or minority, the sample sizes is 641 and covers
the years 1987, 1990, and 1993. For the percent of officers that are
male over that period, the sample size is 648.
Explaining the Percentage of the Police
Force that is Black, Minority, or Male:
The Regressions for Equation (2) for the City
and Year Fixed Effects Regression in Table IV.
Consent Decree Dummy
(a different dummy Number of Years that
is used for whether Consent Decree Is in Effect
the consent decree involves (consent decrees involving race
sex or race cases and sex are separated out
and is matched with and are matched with the
the appropriate regression appropriate regression listed
listed below) below)
% of the police .014 .0041
force that is (1.003) (3.289)
black
% of the police .0556 .0048
force that is (2.150) (2.899)
minority (black,
hispanic, and/or
american indian
% of the police -.031 -.0015
force that is (0.708) (0.445)
male
City Has In (Violent Crime
a Black Rate per
Mayor 100,000 people) F-Statistic Adjacent [R.sup.2]
% of the police -.00028 -.0100 53.46 .9581
force that is (.049) (1.731)
black
% of the police -.0018 -.0089 40.26 .9446
force that is (0.237) (1.145)
minority (black,
hispanic, and/or
american indian
% of the police -.0026 -.0061 2.15 .3307
force that is (0.192) (0.222)
male
Notes: The regressions listed above represent just three of the
different first-stage regressions. In addition to the lagged violent and
property crime rates, the regressions from equation (2) also included
all the the other variables listed for the weighted least squares
estimates. The fixed effects used in the different first-stage
regressions corresponded with those used in the second stage. The
estimates reported above use city and year fixed effects.
Using Two-stage Least Squares to Further Examine the Differences
by Race and Sex: Controlling for County Fixed Effects
and State Fixed Effects that Vary by Year
Category
of Crime % of Police % of Police Force
Being % of Police Force Black Hispanic
Explained Force Black Male Female Male
Violent 10.43 14% 38.62 14% 13.98 18%
crime (2.672) (2.657) (2.065)
Property 3.95 4% 15.02 4% 5.366 5%
crime (1.723) (1.827) (1.444)
Murder 19.72 60% 66.91 55% 18.46 56%
(2.74) (2.719) (1.758)
Man- 26.074 60% 101.57 63% 27.21 63%
slaughter (2.317) (2.571) (1.976)
Rape 4.269 10% 15.50 10% 6.182 15%
(1.345) (1.354) (1.101)
Total 11.40 18% 41.74 18% 13.90 22%
robbery (2.583) (2.578) (1.951)
Total 9.802 14% 37.28 14% 15.49 22%
assault (2.387) (2.445) (2.024)
Burglary 7.101 8% 27.87 9% 9.553 11%
(2.444) (2.534) (1.879)
Larceny 2.319 2% 11.75 3% 6.490 7%
(1.101) (1.534) (1.694)
Motor 13.30 18% 39.46 15% 3.090 4%
vehicle (2.558) (2.170) (0.457)
theft
Assault -24.16 36% 24.21 7% -38.05 27%
on police (1.292) (0.418) (1.28)
officers
Category % of Police
of Crime % of Police % of Police % of Police Force Asian
Being Force Hispanic Force White Force White Pacific
Explained Female Male Female Male
Violent 234.02 27% -6.28 13% 4.545 2% -56.12 31%
crime (0.890) (2.858) (0.290) (0.735)
Property 93.94 8% -2.43 4% 3.804 1% -28.03 12%
crime (0.849) (1.883) (0.389) (0.621)
Murder 79.28 74% -10.37 78% -2.455 4% -54.34 68%
(0.911) (2.738) (0.095) (0.982)
Man- 148.73 30% -16.47 61% 33.60 28% -95.46 64%
slaughter (0.874) (2.649) (0.670) (0.839)
Rape 90.44 19% -2.588 10% -1.221 1% -6.333 6%
(0.732) (1.404) (0.088) (0.103)
Total 252.82 36% -6.665 17% 6.35 4% -82.098 56%
robbery (0.887) (2.728) (0.360) (0.910)
Total 227.57 29% -6.26 14% 3.015 2% -21.071 13%
assault (0.881) (2.642) (0.174) (0.277)
Burglary 181.06 19% -4.446 8% 12.066 5% -70.765 35%
(0.896) (2.703) (0.868) (1.051)
Larceny 86.85 8% -2.096 4% 9.061 3% -3.773 2%
(0.843) (1.695) (0.839) (0.096)
Motor 201.95 25% -5.3795 12% -6.265 3% -193.24 54%
vehicle (0.853) (2.018) (0.338) (1.289)
theft
Assault 133.06 8% -3.05 12% 16.68 14% -35.32 3%
on police (0.905) (2.295) (.280) (1.671)
officers
Category
of Crime % of Police Force
Being Asian Pacific
Explained Female
Violent 241.91 10%
crime (2.160)
Property 97.25 3%
crime (1.554)
Murder 340.94 50%
(1.904)
Man- 682.163 49%
slaughter (2.101)
Rape 97.025 7%
(1.090)
Total 251.97 13%
robbery (2.104)
Total 251.05 11%
assault (2.047)
Burglary 185.99 7%
(2.284)
Larceny 110.96 4%
(1.803)
Motor 112.87 5%
vehicle (0.932)
theft
Assault 334.5 2%
on police (0.905)
officers
Notes: The second-stage regression estimates that are reported
above account for the same variables controlled for in the first-stage
regression except for the consent decree, the number of years since the
consent decree went into effect, and whether the city's mayor is
black. County fixed effects are used, with additional separate fixed
effects for each state by year to pick up any changes at the state level
that might explain changes in crime rates over time. All regressions use
weighted least squares where the variables are weighted by the city
population. The absolute t-statistics are shown in the parentheses below
the coefficient estimate, with the percent of the endogenous
variable's mean that can be explained by a one-standard-deviation
change in the exogenous variable shown in the adjacent column. Sample
size is 439 and covers the years 1987 and 1990.
Explaining the Rate at Which
Police Shoot Civilians
Exogenous Variables
% of Police % of Police % of Police % of Police
Endogenous Force Black Force White Force White Force White
Variable Male Female Male Female
Per capita -.000135 ... -.0000543 ...
number of (3.671) (2.164)
civilian 1.4% 8.3%
shootings
Per capita ... -.00005 ... .000085
number of (.988) (2.072)
civilian 36.9% 9.3%
shootings
Per Capita
Number of Per Capita
Felonious Number of
Killings of Assaults on Sworn
Endogenous Police Police City Officers Per
Variable Officers Officers Population Capita Adjusted [R.sup.2]
Per capita .000142 2.31 e-7 7.30 e-11 .0175 .9379
number of (2.843) (3.093) (2.331) (1.788)
civilian 3.6% 2.7% 6.7% 13.4%
shootings
Per capita .0000704 -2.64 e-8 -2.57 e-11 -.00362 .8420
number of (2.109) (.285) (.697) (.428)
civilian 8.7% 78.7% 51.7% 68.6%
shootings
Endogenous
Variable F-Statistic
Per capita 20.29
number of
civilian
shootings
Per capita 7.81
number of
civilian
shootings
Notes: Using fixed year and city effects. Absolute t-statistics
are shown in parentheses and the level of statistical
significant for a two-tailed t-test are shown below that.
Regressions are run using ordinary least squares.
Attempting to Disentagle Whether Higher Crime Rates
are Due to Lower Quality of All New Employees:
Using City or County and Year Fixed Effects
Exogenous Variables
Percentage Percentage of Percentage of
the Police the Police the Police
Endogenous Force That Is Force That Is Force That Is
Variable Black a Minority Male
City fixed effects:
Violent crime .7873 ... ...
rate (1.647)
Violent crime ... .3816 ...
rate (1.071)
Violent crime ... ... -.038
rate (.195)
Property .195 ... ...
crime rate (.513)
Property ... .356 ...
crime rate (1.275)
Property ... ... .0712
crime rate (.466)
County fixed effects:
Violent crime 1.425 ... ...
rate (3.196)
Violent crime ... 1.253 ...
rate (3.518)
Violent crime ... ... -.003
rate (.014)
Property .132 ... ...
crime rate (.393)
Property ... .1286 ...
crime rate (.504)
Property ... ... .0504
crime rate (.316)
Number of Years
Endogenous Consent Decree That Consent City Has a
Variable Dummy Decree Is in Effect Black Mayor
City fixed effects:
Violent crime .3286 .0077 .0737
rate (1.996) (0.685) (1.407)
Violent crime .3148 .010 .077
rate (1.896) (.912) (1.455)
Violent crime .3412 .011 .078
rate (2.091) (1.096) (1.498)
Property .1961 .018 .054
crime rate (1.514) (2.054) (1.321)
Property .214 .019 .055
crime rate (1.644) (2.214) (1.334)
Property .191 .0175 .0534
crime rate (1.491) (2.098) (1.307)
County fixed effects:
Violent crime .4631 .009 .1532
rate (3.517) (0.732) (3.079)
Violent crime .4038 .0104 .1545
rate (3.044) (.862) (3.116)
Violent crime .4775 .0173 .166
rate (3.607) (1.467) (3.336)
Property .1279 .0293 .082
crime rate (1.34) (3.406) (2.352)
Property .1325 .0293 .082
crime rate (1.430) (3.462) (2.359)
Property .1260 .029 .081
crime rate (1.385) (3.617) (2.373)
Endogenous
Variable Adjusted-[R.sup.2] F-Statistic
City fixed effects:
Violent crime .8945 20.51
rate
Violent crime .8940 20.42
rate
Violent crime .8951 20.86
rate
Property .6832 5.96
crime rate
Property .6844 5.99
crime rate
Property .6884 6.14
crime rate
County fixed effects:
Violent crime .8510 15.68
rate
Violent crime .8518 15.77
rate
Violent crime .8486 15.57
rate
Property .6489 5.75
crime rate
Property .6490 5.75
crime rate
Property .6550 5.93
crime rate
Notes: Although not all the coefficients are reported, these
regressions are based on the reduced forms of the regressions
used in Table IV. Absolute t-statistics are shown in parentheses.
Calculating the Total Victim Costs That Arose
from the Changing Composition of Police Departments
Change in Number of
Officers Between 1987
Categories of Police and 1990 for the 189 Total Change in the
Officers that cities for which Number of Crimes Due to
Constituted at population numbers are the Changing Composition
least 1 percent of the available for both years of Police Departments
Police Force in 1990 (% change from 1987) Murder
Black males 950 97
(5%)
Black females 1,135 483
(23%)
White males -6,912 1,145
(-6%)
White females 1,067 -176
(12%)
Hispanic males 1,283 180
(13%)
Asian Pacific males 1,542 -366
(171%)
Total 1,363
Crimes Per Police Officer
for All Police Officers 0.067
Total Cost of the
Changing Composition of
Police Forces from 1987
to 1990, in Millions of
1996 Dollars
Black Males 343.8
Black Females 1,540.8
White Males 3,654.8
White Females -561.4
Hispanic Males 576.6
Asian Pacific Males -1,169.4
Totals 4,385.2
Categories of Police
Officers that
Constituted at Motor
least 1 percent of the Aggravated Vehicle
Police Force in 1990 Rape Robbery Assault Theft Burglary Larceny
Black males 300 548 4,699 1,711 -729 - 6,571
Black females 96 6,868 13,149 -8,131 34,618 64,160
White males 111 15,579 37,256 -10,857 28,184 -4,034
White females -496 -8,588 -11,639 -1,759 -15,315 -23,024
Hispanic males -365 8,705 6,119 98 8,130 7,670
Asian Pacific males -220 -2,877 -5,672 3,474 2,767 18,164
Total -575 20,235 43,912 -15,464 57,655 56,364
Crimes Per Police Officer
for All Police Officers 0.34 2.03 3.23 4.82 9.6 24.7
Black Males 31.3 5.2 52.9 7.6 -1.1 -2.9
Black Females 9.0 59.6 134.2 -32.6 52.1 25.7
White Males 10.4 135.3 380.3 -43.4 42.9 -1.6
White Females -46.8 -74.6 -118.8 -7.1 -23.2 -9.2
Hispanic Males -34.4 75.6 62.4 394.2 12.4 3.0
Asian Pacific Males -20.7 -25.0 -57.9 14.0 4.2 7.3
Totals -51.3 176.1 453.1 332.7 87.3 22.3
Categories of Police
Officers that
Constituted at
least 1 percent of the
Police Force in 1990
Black males
Black females
White males
White females
Hispanic males
Asian Pacific males
Total
Crimes Per Police Officer
for All Police Officers
Total Cost of Change by
Type of Officer
Black Males $436.7
Black Females $1,788.9
White Males $4,178.6
White Females -$841.1
Hispanic Males $1,089.7
Asian Pacific Males -$1,247.5
Totals $5,405.4
Notes: Using the estimates that analogous to the county fixed
effect regressions in the appendix, though these use breakdown the each
racial category by gender and sex with the control variables that we
have used through out the article. The National Institute of Justice
Estimated Victim Costs by type of crime are used to calculate these
estimates. All values are in millions of 1993 dollars. The regressions
were only able to use data for 1987 and 1990 because the breakdown by
sex within each racial group was only available for those years.
[Miller, Cohen and Wiorsema (1996)]
Explaining Changes in the Arrest Rate, Using the Specifications
From Table IV: Using Two-Stage Least Squares to Take Into Account
the Impact That Consent Decrees and the Presence of a Black Mayor
Have on the Composition of Police Departments
% of the Police Force
That Is Black
Type of Fixed Effects
Arrest
Rates City County State
Violent -2.48 -2.72 -4.15
crime (.729) (1.168) (2.04)
Property -7.68 -12.33 .899
crime (.584) (.981) (.094)
Murder -4.21 -4.58 -4.33
(1.028) (1.355) (1.875)
Rape -5.074 -3.00 -3.82
(1.196) (.941) (1.64)
Total -3.98 -3.796 -5.578
robbery (1.651) (1.901) (3.287)
Total -3.176 -5.622 -7.66
assault (.896) (1.724) (3.22)
Burglary -.735 -1.54 -.6945
(.520) (1.151) (.598)
Larceny 2.22 .0299 -2.024
(1.146) (.017) (1.341)
Motor 6.26 2.57 0.400
vehicle (2.132) (1.153) (.189)
theft
% of the Police Force That Is
Minority (Black, Hispanic, and
American Indian)
Type of Fixed Effects
Arrest
Rates City County State
Violent -1.71 -1.94 -1.56
crime (.777) (1.137) (1.472)
Property -9.268 -7.186 3.547
crime (1.053) (.847) (.769)
Murder -5.355 -3.801 -1.21
(1.943) (1.597) (.922)
Rape -1.328 -1.46 -1.76
(.468) (.681) (1.635)
Total -4.382 -3.985 -1.5875
robbery (2.654) (2.897) (2.019)
Total -2.31 -.419 -2.077
assault (.995) (.225) (1.874)
Burglary -.3095 -.1716 .478
(.325) (1.305) (1.070)
Larceny 1.231 .03115 -.6659
(.955) (.026) (.921)
Motor 4.01 1.93 1.37
vehicle (1.945) (1.176) (1.201)
theft
% of the Police Force
That Is Male
Type of Fixed Effects
Arrest
Rates City County State
Violent 6.37 7.30 1.09
crime (.942) (.995) (.409)
Property 33.54 31.42 6.77
crime (1.084) (.962) (.510)
Murder 9.489 11.07 -1.037
(1.116) (1.135) (.301)
Rape 9.085 7.0265 5.679
(1.170) (1.199) (1.781)
Total 3.077 8.681 8.3185
robbery (.713) (1.406) (2.710)
Total .77 9.568 1.399
assault (.125) (1.152) (.440)
Burglary .562 4.015 5.252
(.225) (1.104) (2.564)
Larceny -2.435 .9277 9.709
(.642) (.228) (3.141)
Motor 11.38 6.69 .73
vehicle (1.288) (.901) (.255)
theft
Notes: The second-stage regression estimates that are reported
below account for the same variables controlled for in the preceding
tables except for the consent decree, the number of years since the
consent decree went into effect, and whether the city's mayor is
black, which were instead included in the first-stage regression. The
absolute t-statistics are shown in the parentheses below, with the
percentage of a one-standard-deviation change in the endogenous variable
that can be explained by a one-standard-deviation change in the
exogenous variable. All regressions use weighted least squares where the
variables are weighted by the city population. Sample size is 634 and
covers the years 1987, 1990, 1993.)
Explaining Changes in the Arrest Rate, Using the Specification from
Table VI to Further Examine the Differences by Race and Sex: Using
Two-Stage Least Squares to Take Into Account the Impact that Consent
Decrees and the Presence of a Black Mayor Have on the Composition of
Police Departments
% of %
Category of Police of Police
Arrest Rate % of Police % of Police Force Force % of Police
Being Force Black Force Black Hispanic Hispanic Force White
Explained Male Female Male Female Male
Violent -8.28 -17.5 -7.10 58.7 4.04
crime (1.919) (1.01) (.529) (1.466) (1.38)
Property -4.04 -10.3 -14.61 32.9 15.22
crime (0.849) (0.54) (.890) (.074) (1.02)
Murder -10.78 -40.5 -26.44 -51.7 9.10
(1.524) (1.534) (1.091) (.777) (1.89)
Rape -16.14 -46.0 25.01 106.8 6.26
(2.301) (1.597) (1.546) (1.471) (1.311)
Total -5.42 -24.6 -22.5 26.27 3.35
robbery (1.732) (1.53) (1.552) (0.795) (1.395)
Total -8.54 -21.28 -8.05 -69.44 4.11
assault (1.98) (1.16) (0.598) (1.78) (1.45)
Burglary -3.32 -10.65 -10.60 5.74 2.09
(1.45) (1.09) (1.16) (0.26) (1.36)
Larceny -.201 .77 -6.77 99.55 .57
(0.064) (0.06) (0.64) (0.35) (.261)
Motor 2.54 19.4 8.87 33.69 -2.86
vehicle (0.804) (1.54) (0.847) (1.19) (.394)
theft
% of Police % of Police
Category of Force Force
Arrest Rate % of Police Asian Asian
Being Force White Pacific Pacific
Explained Female Male Female
Violent 32.6 -348.7 197.3
crime (1.244) (1.295) (1.10)
Property 89.7 -335.3 -3648.6
crime (.851) (1.284) (1.08)
Murder -5.94 -144.3 -539.6
(0.244) (.699) (1.781)
Rape 22.82 -616.2 205.1
(0.704) (1.610) (0.695)
Total 22.07 -34.1 62.64
robbery (1.681) (0.603) (.447)
Total 12.00 -137.5 195.63
assault (.871) (1.567) (1.156)
Burglary 12.88 -186.3 -.190
(1.17) (1.269) (0.002)
Larceny 7.19 -147.4 35.4
(0.479) (1.497) (0.271)
Motor 22.46 56.85 204.1
vehicle (0.099) (0.863) (1.690)
theft
Notes: The Second-stage regression estimates that are reported
above account for the same variables controlled for in the first stage
regression except for the consent decree, the number of years since the
consent decree went into effect, and whether the city's mayor is
black. Current rather than lagged crime rates are used in the
first-stage regression. County fixed effects are used, with additional
separate fixed effects for each state by year to pick up any changes at
the state level that might explain changes in crime rates over time. All
regressions use weighted least squares where the variables are weighted
by the city population. Sample size is 439 and covers the years 1987 and
1990.
How Does the Changing Racial and Gender Composition of Police
Departments Alter How Police Departments Fight Crime?
Number
% of of Years
% of % of % of Police that
Police Police Police Force Consent Consent
Force Force Force American Decree Decree Is
Male Black Hispanic Indian Dummy in effect
% of police patrol 1.09 -.80 -.377 -5.07 -.357 .014
units with only (2.08) (2.09) (2.11) (1.481) (2.95) (1.471)
one officer
% of police 2.19 1.734 .169 -11.98 .44 -.077
walking patrol (1.93) (1.04) (.368) (1.623) (2.49) (3.386)
units with only
one officer
Ratio of walking .082 -.214 .065 -.637 -.052 .0036
patrols to all (0.52) (2.13) (1.230) (.554) (2.72) (1.570)
patrols
Number of cars .105 -.1833 -.078 -1.347 -.040 -.005
per officer (1.64) (1.12) (.877) (.750) (.915) (1.205)
Number of .076 .036 .0061 .0296 .00026 -.00043
motorcycles per (1.89) (1.40) (.444) (.106) (.037) (.672)
officer
Special operations -1.97 -2.44 .236 -16.55 -.187 -.0068
officers required to (1.50) (2.70) (.518) (1.931) (.595) (.285)
wear body armor
(yes = 3,
sometimes = 2,
no = 1)
Patrol officers -1.87 -1.52 -.5399 -3.025 -.0002 -.0374
required to wear (1.44) (1.70) (1.196) (.357) (.001) (1.587)
body armor
(Yes = 3,
sometimes = 2,
no = 1)
Number of sworn .0002 .0012 -.0011 .0023 .00072 -.00003
officers per capita (.224) (.236) (2.005) (.607) (2.251) (3.142)
Adjusted
[R.sup.2] % of % of % of
City Has and Police Police Police
a Black No. of Force Force Force
Mayor Observations Male White Asian
% of police patrol .037 .55 1.36 .482 4.24
units with only (.619) (2.65) (3.06) (1.90)
one officer 202
% of police -.033 .77 1.95 -.327 1.49
walking patrol (.311) (1.92) (.935) (.537)
units with only 103
one officer
Ratio of walking .004 .63 .006 .003 .471
patrols to all (.224) (.039) (.066) (.903)
patrols 203
Number of cars -.0185 .72 .144 .111 .025
per officer (.844) (1.83) (1.44) (.158)
639
Number of -.003 .51 .064 -.0149 .0093
motorcycles per (.883) (1.68) (1.25) (.382)
officer 439
Special operations .0897 .46 -1.07 .311 -7.88
officers required to (.654) (.847) (.787) (1.69)
wear body armor
(yes = 3, 438
sometimes = 2,
no = 1)
Patrol officers -.1375 .53 -1.62 .7245 -7.073
required to wear (1.013) (1.31) (1.88) (1.55)
body armor
(Yes = 3, 438
sometimes = 2,
no = 1)
Number of sworn -3.1e - 6 .95 -1.2e - 5 -.0002 -8e - 5
officers per capita (.071) (.014) (.515) (.195)
641
Number
of Years Adjusted
That City [R.sup.2]
Consent Consent Has a and
Decree Decree Is Black No. of
Dummy in effect Mayor Observations
% of police patrol -.305 .001 .03 .56
units with only (2.54) (1.04) (.525)
one officer 202
% of police .383 -.07 .002 .77
walking patrol (2.319) (3.171) (.024)
units with only 103
one officer
Ratio of walking -.039 .0023 -.007 .62
patrols to all (2.05) (1.008) (.458)
patrols 203
Number of cars -.035 -.0056 -.021 .72
per officer (.806) (1.669) (.964)
439
Number of -.0008 -.00031 -.002 .51
motorcycles per (.121) (.495) (.703)
officer 439
Special operations -.0203 -.0206 .0002 .45
officers required to (.065) (.875) (.001)
wear body armor
(yes = 3, 438
sometimes = 2,
no = 1)
Patrol officers .042 -.041 -.1718 .5356
required to wear (.139) (1.779) (1.32)
body armor
(Yes = 3, 438
sometimes = 2,
no = 1)
Number of sworn .00079 -.00003 6e - 6 .95
officers per capita (2.465) (2.853) (.143)
641
Notes: Controlling for a City's changing Demographic
Characteristics, the Per Capita Number of Police Officers, the
Unemployment Rate, the Average Weekly Wage, Year Fixed Effects, and City
Population and Population Squared. State fixed effects are used in the
first three specifications, while county fixed effects are used for the
other specifications. The absolute t-statistics are shown in the
parentheses below, with the percentage of a one-standard-deviation
change in the endogenous variable that can be explained by a
one-standard-deviation change in the exogenous variable. All regressions
use weighted least squares where the variables arc weighted by the city
population. Data for the first three regressions are only available for
1987, the data for the number of motorcycles and cars per officer as
well as information on body armor requirements are available for 1987
and 1993, and the data for the number of sworn officers are for 1987,
1990, and 1993.
ABBREVIATIONS
FBI: Federal Bureau of Investigation
FCC: Federal Communication Commission
LEMAS: Law Enforcement Management and Administration Statistics
APPENDIX A ACCOUNTING FOR CHANGES IN POLICE DEPARTMENT SIZE AND
CHANGES IN LEVELS OF POLICE EXPERIENCE
An important question involves what these consent decrees did to
the size of the police departments and what effect that this may have
had on police experience. [41] The last set of regressions in Table XII
use fixed city effects and imply that the imposition of a consent decree
is associated with a large increase in the number of officers of about a
third, and it takes about 20-25 years before the city's police
force returns to its predecree levels. [42] Including a squared term for
the years after the imposition of the consent decree did not appreciably
alter this basic relationship. Since I controlled for the prsenccof the
consent decree and the length of time that it had been in effect in both
the two-stage least square and the quasi-reduced form estimates, this
finding does not alter any of the earlier regressions, though it does
make us ask whether the significant effects of the consent decrees are
due to changes that result from testing and/or whether they arise from
the lower quality associated with a rapid increase in the size of the
police force. A rapidly growing police force with new recruits might
face an increase in crime simply because of having police officers with
less experience.
Unfortunately, I do not have a measure of police officer
experience. One substitute method of measuring this change is to
reestimate the regressions shown in Tables IV and VI by including a
variable for the percentage change in the size of a police force. [43]
While this reduces our sample size to 386 observations for blacks and
minorities and 393 for males, the percentage measures of the composition
of police departments remain similar to those already reported and the
percentage change in a police force's size is almost always
negative, though it is statistically significant about a third of the
time. Thus, if anything, there is weak evidence that large percentage
increases in the size of police departments appear to reduce crime even
after the per capita number of police officers is already controlled
for. [44]
Another way to differentiate between these two theories is to
examine the changing impact that the consent decree has on crime over
time. If the lower initial quality were due to the large sudden increase
in the number of officers, the quality of new officers hired after that
initial binge should he relatively high. Just as the initial hiring
binge would have brought in lower quality officers, the long period of
time over which hiring was below normal, as the city tries to return to
its original-sized police force, would result in above-average quality
hires. The coefficient on the variable for the number of years that the
consent decree has been in effect should thus be negative in the
reduced-form regressions. In fact, almost all these coefficients in the
preceding tables are either significantly positive or insignificantly
different from zero. [45]
APPENDIX B QUASI-REDUCED FORM REGRESSIONS, WHICH ALSO INCLUDE THE
INSTRUMENTS
The two tables reporting these quasi-reduced form estimates produce
rather mixed results. In terms of consistent results, the race measures
shown in county fixed effects specifications indicate that a greater
share of the police force that is black, the higher the violent crime,
murder, manslaughter, robbery, or aggravated assault rates. More
Hispanics are associated with higher violent crime rates, though, as
shown in previous tables, the effect is less consistent than for blacks.
Higher shares that are white or Asian are usually associated with lower
violent crime, murder, manslaughter, robbery, or aggravated assault
rates. The racial share coefficients for the state fixed effects
regressions tend to be largest and the most frequently statistically
significant of the three sets of estimates. The estimates of the impact
of more male police officers vary a great deal across the three sets of
estimates, with the fixed county effects and some of the fixed city
effects implying a positive relationship between m ore male police
officers and the various crime rates.
Perhaps these different results are not so surprising when
different highly correlated variables are included together in one
specification, but the consent decree results provide only strong
support for the notion that the new rules are causing crime to rise over
and above the increase that is occuring from changing racial and gender
composition of the police force in the county fixed effects
specifications. Where the number of years that the consent decree has
been in effect is significant in state fixed effect regressions, it is
the opposite sign and statistically significant in four of the 19 crime
categories. Although the racial control variables produce a consistent
effect, they do not allow us to differentiate whether it is really race
or changing hiring rules that are driving the different crime rates.
One other result should be mentioned. Having a black mayor is
associated with more felonious shootings of police officers and fewer
assaults against officers. The impact of having a black mayor on crime
rates is more mixed, with the county fixed effects regressions implying
that the election of a black mayor is associated with more crime for
violent and property crimes generally, murder, manslaughter, most types
of robbery, burglary, and motor vehicle theft. The state fixed effects
regressions indicate that forcible rapes and burglaries rise but that
one category of robberies and manslaughter fall. Why the presence of a
black mayor is correlated with crime is beyond the scope of this
article.
Explaining Crime Rates as a Function of the Racial and Sex
Composition of Police Departments: Using County Fixed Effects
Number
% of of Years
% of % of % of Police that City
Police Police Police Force Consent Consent has a
Force Force Force American Decree Decree is Black Adjusted
Male Black Hispanic Indian Dummy in effect Mayor [R.sup.2]
Violent 2.46 1.65 0.98 -1.04 0.43 0.02 0.15 .85
crime (2.73) (3.64) (1.842) (.256) (3.17) (1.389) (3.00)
21% 21% 12% 1% 25% 5% 5%
Property 0.79 0.01 -0.13 -0.93 0.14 0.03 0.08 .65
crime (1.25) (.027) (.279) (.323) (1.449) (3.586) (2.30)
12% 0% 3% 1% 14% 18% 4%
Murder 0.59 1.39 2.59 3.59 0.54 0.01 0.30 .78
(.403) (1.89) (2.42) (.541) (2.49) (.311) (3.72)
3% 10% 19% 1% 18% 1% 5%
Man- -5.23 3.16 -0.39 3.65 0.09 0.03 0.53 .44
slaughter (1.59) (1.91) (.164) (.245) (.188) (.756) (2.96)
37% 33% 4% 2% 4% 9% 13%
Rape 3.78 0.62 -1.36 3.72 0.09 0.05 0.12 .89
(1.88) (1.61) (.926) (.409) (.295) (1.798) (1.06)
17% 4% 9% 1% 3% 8% 2%
Total 1.77 1.14 1.46 1.12 0.41 0.04 0.24 .89
robbery (1.75) (2.25) (1.98) (.245) (2.76) (2.61) (4.33)
4% 2% 9% 0% 15% 19% 7%
Total 2.73 2.21 1.67 -4.04 0.49 0.01 0.08 .81
assault (2.52) (4.05) (1.98) (.822) (3.06) (.481) (1.32)
10% 3% 9% 2% 20% 12% 1%
Burglary 0.33 0.09 0.48 0.04 0.17 0.04 0.15 .69
(.434) (.228) (.859) (.012) (1.46) (3.79) (3.64)
4% 2% 9% 0% 15% 19% 7%
Larceny 0.71 0.12 0.43 1.83 0.22 0.02 0.01 .72
(1.16) (.391) (.948) (.658) (2.354) (2.73) (.311)
10% 3% 9% 2% 20% 12% 1%
Motor 2.85 0.83 0.68 1.87 0.13 0.04 0.26 .81
vehicle (2.59) (1.50) (.841) (.375) (.80) (2.881) (4.33)
theft 23% 10% 8% 1% 7% 13% 7%
Assaults -4.12 2.49 4.20 -9.75 2.36 -0.05 -2.00 .44
on police (.789) (.950) (1.11) (.413) (3.043) (.642) (7.00)
13% 11% 19% 2% 49% 5% 22%
Number
of Years
% of % of % of that City
Police Police Police Consent Consent has a
Force Force Force Decree Decree is Black Adjusted
Male White Asian Dummy in effect Mayor [R.sup.2]
Violent 2.332 -1.435 -1.358 0.403 0.019 0.151 .85
crime (2.61) (3.77) (3.57) (3.05) (1.64) (3.07)
20% 25% 7% 23% 6% 5%
Property 0.78 0.01 0.09 0.13 0.03 0.08 .64
crime (1.24) (.033) (.324) (1.401) (3.68) (2.33)
12% 0% 1% 14% 18% 4%
Murder 0.80 -1.78 -1.85 0.58 0.004 0.29 .77
(.553) (2.88) (2.99) (2.704) (.187) (3.67)
4% 18% 6% 19% 1% 5%
Man- -5.65 -2.36 -1.62 -0.04 0.04 0.54 .45
slaughter (1.74) (1.70) (1.16) (.092) (.944) (3.03)
40% 33% 7% 2% 11% 14%
Rape 3.48 0.04 -0.03 0.03 0.05 0.12 .89
(1.75) (.052) (.04) (.100) (1.91) (1.102)
16% 0% 0% 1% 9% 2%
Total 1.82 -1.24 -1.25 0.42 0.04 0.24 .89
robbery (1.83) (2.92) (2.94) (2.87) (2.59) (4.33)
13% 17% 5% 20% 9% 6%
Total 2.47 -1.79 -1.53 0.44 0.003 0.09 .81
assault (2.30) (3.90) (3.33) (2.78) (.211) (1.44)
20% 29% 8% 24% 1% 2%
Burglary 0.45 -0.34 -0.09 0.17 0.04 0.15 .70
(.596) (1.06) (.286) (1.52) (3.83) (3.64)
6% 9% 1% 15% 19% 7%
Larceny 0.65 0.22 0.26 0.21 0.02 0.01 .72
(1.07) (.867) (.994) (2.28) (2.85) (.361)
9% 6% 2% 19% 12% 1%
Motor 2.56 -0.28 -0.32 0.09 0.05 0.27 .81
vehicle (2.35) (.606) (.689) (.538) (3.07) (4.42)
theft 21% 5% 2% 5% 14% 8%
Assaults 3.54 -3.96 -1.88 2.34 0.04 -1.99 .63
on police (.687) (1.80) (.858) (3.08) (.58) (7.02)
11% 24% 4% 49% 5% 22%
Notes: Each crime category listed in the first column represents a
separate regression. The regressions also controlled for a City's
Changing Demographic Characteristics, the Per Capita Number of Police
Officers, the Unemployment Rate, the Average Weekly Wage, Year and
County Fixed Effects, and City Population and Population Squared. The
absolute t-statistics are shown in the parentheses, and below these are
the percentages of a one-standard-deviation change in the endogenous
variable that can he explained by a one-standard-deviation change in the
exogenous variable. All regressions use weighted least squares where the
variables are weighted by the city population.
Explaining Crime Rates as a Function of the Racial
and Sex Composition of Police Departments:
Using State Fixed Effects
Number
% of of years
% of % of % of Police that City
Police Police Police Force Consent Consent has a
Force Force Force American Decree Decree is Black
Male Black Hispanic Indian Dummy in effect Mayor
Violent -1.07 .869 .315 4.566 .256 -.03 -.033
crime (1.79) (2.25) (1.48) (1.13) (2.400) (2.262) (.666)
9% 11% 4% 3% 7% 11% 1%
Property -1.43 .496 .2585 -.4895 -.095 .0002 .02
crime (4.15) (2.22) (2.104) (.210) (1.542) (.038) (.651)
22% 12% 6% 1% 5% 0% 1%
Murder 1.173 1.845 .2271 7.814 .037 -.006 -.008
(1.38) (3.37) (.753) (1.367) (.244) (.435) (.112)
6% 14% 2% 3% 1% 1% 0%
Man- 3.548 3.939 .7574 3.374 -.029 .005 -.27
slaughter (.033) (3.67) (1.279) (.301) (.098) (.200) (1.956)
25% 42% 8% 2% 1% 2% 6%
Rape -1.63 -.488 -.3659 5.613 .092 -.014 .122
(1.38) (.641) (.872) (.706) (.437) (.761) (1.251)
8% 3% 2% 2% 1% 3% 2%
Total -1.32 1.408 .16154 7.8199 .053 -.013 -.051
robbery (2.02) (3.34) (.695) (1.776) (.456) (1.347) (.947)
9% 14% 2% 4% 1% 4% 1%
Total -1.09 .6513 .47418 1.6106 .484 -.052 -.048
assault (1.45) (1.35) (1.782) (.319) (3.63) (4.54) (.770)
9% 8% 6% 1% 12% 18% 1%
Burglary -1.37 .5810 -.18606 -1.14433 -.05 -.002 .062
(3.17) (2.09) (1.213) (.394) (.664) (.337) (1.739)
18% 11% 4% 1% 2% 1% 3%
Larceny -1.30 .320 .331 -1.92 -.014 -.002 -.011
(3.6) (1.38) (2.587) (.79) (.221) (.296) (.383)
18% 7% 7% 2% 1% 1% 0%
Motor -1.90 1.297 .827 9.306 -.378 .004 -.05
vehicle (2.75) (2.91) (3.368) (1.999) (3.078) (0.404) (.794)
theft 16% 16% 10% 6% 9% 1% 1%
Assaults on -5.55 .911 .5227 -29.29 .64 -.06 -1.58
police (2.06) (.524) (.546) (1.613) (1.335) (1.436) (7.08)
17% 4% 2% 7% 6% 8% 15%
Number
of Years
% of % of % of that City
Police Police Police Consent Consent has a
Adjusted Force Force Force Decree Decree is Black
[R.sup.2] Male White Asian Dummy in effect Mayor
Violent .70 -1.27 -.428 -.796 .23 -.03 -.25
crime (2.21) (2.35) (2.17) (2.18) (2.079) (.520)
11% 7% 4% 6% 11% 7%
Property .51 -1.53 -.322 -.259 -.103 .0009 .024
crime (4.64) (3.07) (1.23) (1.71) (.183) (.85)
24% 10% 2% 5% 1% 1%
Murder .65 .57 -.588 -1.19 -.04 .0003 .034
(.706) (2.27) (2.27) (.247) (.023) (.495)
3% 6% 4% 1% 0% 1%
Man- .33 2.30 -1.57 -1.19 -.16 .016 -.21
slaughter (1.44) (3.09) (1.16) (.547) (.656) (1.518)
16% 22% 5% 3% 5% 5%
Rape .83 -1.56 .409 .24 .0899 -.013 .12
(1.38) (1.14) (.333) (.431) (.757) (1.208)
7% 4% 1% 1% 3% 2%
Total .78 -1.77 -.436 -.951 -.006 -.009 -.032
robbery (2.83) (2.19) (2.36) (.055) (.876) (.598)
12% 6% 4% 0% 3% 1%
Total .58 -1.15 -.507 -.679 .48 -.05 -.05
assault (1.61) (2.23) (1.48) (3.63) (4.57) (.744)
9% 8% 3% 12% 17% 1%
Burglary .55 -1.67 -.006 .011 -.08 .0002 .078
(4.05) (.044) (.040) (1.06) (.033) (2.22)
22% 0% 0% 3% 0% 3%
Larceny .56 -1.30 -.337 -.213 -.01 -.002 -.01
(3.79) (3.08) (.967) (.172) (.35) (.34)
18% 9% 2% 0% 1% 0%
Motor .65 -2.05 -.936 -1.03 -.41 .007 -.04
vehicle (3.11) (4.45) (2.43) (3.37) (.67) (.73)
theft 17% 15% 5% 10% 2% 1%
Assaults on .54 -5.82 -.713 .632 .66 -.06 -1.55
police (2.26) (.871) (.383) (1.40) (1.50) (7.05)
18% 4% 1% 6% 8% 15%
Adjusted
[R.sup.2]
Violent .70
crime
Property .51
crime
Murder .65
Man- .33
slaughter
Rape .83
Total .78
robbery
Total .58
assault
Burglary .54
Larceny .56
Motor .65
vehicle
theft
Assaults on .54
police
Notes: Each crime category listed in the first column represents a
separate regression. The regressions also controlled for a City's
Changing Demographic Characteristics, the Per Capita Number of Police
Officers, the Unemployment Rate, the Average Weekly Wage, Year and
County Fixed Effects, and City Population and Population Squared. The
absolute t-statistics are shown in the parentheses, and below these are
the percentages of a one-standard-deviation change in the endogenous
variable that can be explained by a one-standard-deviation change in the
exogenous variable. All regressions use weighted least squares where the
variables are weighted by the city population. Sample size is 641 and
covers the years 1987, 1990, and 1993.