Growing by leaps and inches: creative destruction, real cost reduction, and inching up.
Darby, Michael R. ; Zucker, Lynne G.
Drunk: Can you help me find my keys?
Passerby: Sure, where exactly did you drop them?
Drunk: Way over there by the trash can.
Passerby: Then why are you searching over here?
Drunk: The light's much better under the lamppost.
Milton Friedman (Economics 331, 1967)
The class laughed after hearing this joke, not yet realizing how
well it described the profession for which they were preparing. Even
those present who cannot carry memory of a joke home from the barbershop
still remember the day they first heard that little joke. The thesis of
this article is that the economics profession has spent years looking
for technological progress under the familiar lamppost of research and
development (R&D) by incumbent firms aimed at improvement in
existing commodities or productive methods. Such perfective progress (as
we call it) is amenable to hedonic measurement and analysis of firm
behavior and market equilibrium in terms of return on investment, public
goods, and positive externalities. We show here that metamorphic
progress, associated with creation of new industries or technological
transformation of existing industries, is of the same or higher order of
magnitude as a source of technological progress.
We believe that our approach complements Arnold C. Harberger's
recent emphasis on the concentration of growth in a few companies in a
few industries that are achieving dramatic real cost reductions. He
began to formulate his own schema in his 1990 Western Economic
Association presidential address and by his 1998 American Economic
Association presidential address could report considerable empirical
evidence in support of this concentration (Harberger, 1998). Harberger
distinguishes between yeast, which makes bread rise evenly, and
mushrooms, which pop up unexpectedly in the back yard. In titling this
article, we had in mind the Japanese picture of progress by inching
up--or Frank Knight's (1944) Crusonia plant, which grows
proportionately except as parts are cut off and eaten. (1) In contrast,
we emphasize the process of this or that industry leaping forward at any
given time--a process that may have prompted Schumpeter's (1934)
model of creative destruction.
Breakthrough discoveries in science and engineering--particularly
invention of a new way of inventing, such as corn hybridization,
integrated circuits, and recombinant DNA--typically drive metamorphic
progress. These discoveries are rarely well understood in the early
years following them. As a result, natural excludability is
characteristic of these radical technologies due to the extensive tacit
knowledge required to practice them and the lengthy period of
learning-by-doing-with at the lab bench required to transfer them. Thus,
metamorphic progress cannot be analyzed following Arrow's
information as a public good paradigm.
The importance of metamorphic progress based on naturally
excludable technologies motivates a challenging and exciting research
agenda to remove the black box covering the linkages among scientific
breakthroughs, high technologies, entry and success in nascent
industries, and the movement toward industrial maturity where government
statistics and economic research are most likely (coincidentally) to
begin. There are real data problems in studying hundreds of private
start-up companies in industries still lumped into one or another
classification ending in "n.e.c." (not elsewhere classified).
They are manageable, however, if economists are willing to exploit
unconventional sources and methods more familiar to organizational
theorists, such as industry directories, financial practitioners'
online services, the ISI and other scientific literature databases, and
sophisticated matching methods for linking firms and individuals across
databases.
Before addressing these central issues, we make a necessary
digression in the next section to clarify the relationship between
metamorphic progress and the supposed acceleration of secular
productivity growth post-1995 labeled the new economy by Federal Reserve
Chairman Alan Greenspan (2000a, 2000b, 2001) and others. (2) In section
II, we review a large and important sociology of organizations and
management literature that has identified recurrent patterns of industry
formation. These patterns clearly indicate that the formation process
involves decades of change in numbers and average size of firms
inconsistent with standard microeconomic analyses of entry and exit for
industries in and around equilibrium. We also review equilibrium models
of industrial organization, highlighting key points of difference and
congruence. In the third section we report in some detail on research on
biotechnology by us and others, emphasizing theoretically and
empirically interesting results that appear to be generalizable to other
industries during their formative and transformative phases. The fourth
section focuses on natural excludability, which is central to
understanding the slow diffusion of very profitable innovations. We then
point out the implications of these results for important issues in
policy analysis and welfare economics. In the concluding section we
attempt to draft a collective research agenda that suggests some next
steps for economics and its sister disciplines in understanding growth
and the wealth of nations.
I. METAMORPHIC PROGRESS AND THE NEW ECONOMY
Experience suggests that our arguments on the importance of
metamorphic progress can be misread--and perhaps dismissed--as
supporting or even implying the new economy ideas discussed most
significantly by Greenspan (2000a, 2000b, 2001). We have no reason to
believe that the processes driving metamorphic progress have either
accelerated or decelerated in the last half of the 1990s and thus have
no expectation of change in either direction of overall technical
progress.
Little support for any extraordinary productivity growth in
1996-2000 is found in the 1950-2001 record of U.S. nonfarmbusiness labor
productivity growth reported in Figure 1. (3) We believe that the years
1996-2000 are better characterized as years of average productivity
growth with one year moderately above average. Despite his best efforts,
Rudebusch (2000) was unable to find any statistically significant
increase in potential output (corrected for cyclical movements using the
demographics-adjusted unemployment rate). (4) This sort of new economy
looks very much like the same old economy. Indeed, 1995-2000
productivity growth was considerably below that experienced in the
period 1960-68 just preceding the great inflation. We believe that the
evidence is fully consistent with normal procyclical patterns.
In summary, although changes in the rate of metamorphic progress
might explain a new economy increase in potential-output growth, we do
not believe that has occurred in recent years. Landefeld and Fraumeni
(2001) provide a nice review of the debate and measurement issues in
regard to the new economy hypothesis.
II. PATTERNS OF INDUSTRIAL FORMATION
The typical pattern of formation of new industries involves a few
firms initially entering, growing to many, and ultimately consolidating,
producing the curve shown in Figure 2 for number of firms. When the
number of firms stabilizes or begins to decline, that does not
necessarily imply that the overall industry size also declines. What
typically happens instead is that the remaining successful entrants grow
fast enough that the overall size of the industry continues to increase
(as does the average size of the remaining firms), as shown in the
industry gross domestic product share curve in Figure 2. Costs of
adjustment in size are generally nonlinear, with fixed costs of
adjustment rather than the standard assumption of convex adjustment
costs, as the review of evidence in Haltiwanger (1997) shows. (5) Thus
the peak number of firms is reached at a time when industry output is
still growing. The general form of the industry life cycle shown in
Figure 2 has been strongly supported in empirical research.
We first review the findings relevant to our main line of argument
in the population or organizational ecology approach in the
sociology/management literature. We then do the same for the more
familiar (to economists) industrial organization literature concerned
with learning by firms under competition. We aim to place our own
approach in a broader context, not to attempt a global review.
Organizational Ecology
Populations of organizations emerge sharing the same organizational
form, meaning central or core design. Reviews by Baum (1996) and Singh
and Lumsden (1990) identify a wide range of organizational forms,
including savings and loan associations, hotels, life insurance
companies, day care centers, semiconductor firms, and California
wineries. The mixture of private and public organizations is typical of
ecological research and represents exploitation of available data
resources rather than systematic comparison across these two sectors.
Most ecological research gathers data on the initial or at least
early growth of each organizational form and sometimes captures the full
life cycle of a population as shown in Figure 2. Organizational ecology
focuses attention on the founding/birth of firms and on the population
dynamics that support moving from the initial founding of a single firm
to emergence of a new industry. Clearly, a population is generally a
significantly narrower group of firms than an industry and has the
advantage of studying proto-industries during the process of their
development.
The hypothesized shape of the number of firms curve shown in Figure
2 has been broadly supported across strikingly different empirical
settings, as shown for trade associations by Aldrich and Staber (1988,
Figures 7-2 to 7-5), local units of Mothers Against Drunk Driving by
McCarthy et al. (1988, Figures 5-1 and 5-2), labor unions by Carroll and
Hannan (1989, Figure 1), telephone companies by Barnett and Amburgey
(1990, Figures 4.1 and 4.3), and Finnish newspapers by Miner et al.
(1990, Figures 1, 2, 3). But theory development has not kept pace with
empirical work, and the framework within which results can or should be
interpreted is often unclear, contradictory, or disconfirmed. Variables
proliferate with few validity tests and tenuous relationships to
theoretical dimensions of central interest; central theoretical
constructs often have no clear empirical referents. (6)
Probably the most robust thread in ecological theory is
organizational form, introduced explicitly and developed in McKelvey
(1982), McKelvey and Aldrich (1983), and Romanelli (1991). Processes by
which new forms are developed include imprinting at the period of
emergence in Stinchcombe (1965), and the source and emergence of
varieties of forms in Brittain and Freeman (1986), Marrett (1980), and
Aldrich and Waldinger (1990).
What underlies the initial emergence and early growth of a new
organizational population? Ecological research has only recently gone
beyond measuring the effects of the number of prior births on the number
of births in the next period, called population dynamics, and the number
of organizations in a population in the prior period, called population
density. Zucker et al. (1998c) show that fundamentals of resource
reallocation and mobilization, coupled with resource quality, provide
significantly stronger predictive power, especially in predicting
location of growth than population dynamics or density. We report
repeated dynamic simulations demonstrating that population ecology model
predictions are essentially uncorrelated with the panel data on
biotechnology entry by year and region, whereas our alternative model
has correlation coefficients averaging above 0.8.
Industrial Organization
Most theory and research in industrial organization (hereafter,
I/O) begins where organizational ecology leaves off. Ecology-based
research focuses on the history of development of an organizational
population--the process of industry emergence. I/O research has been
primarily concerned with firms in mature industries and processes
central to mature industries life cycles, including growth and turnover,
as Caves's (1998) recent review indicates. In mature industries,
observed differences in profitability, productivity, industry output
shares, investment, and similar variables provide the basis for entry by
the firm as well as the basis for later changes in firm strategy,
predicting growth and turnover in industries.
Studies in industrial organization broadly support the pattern of
change shown in Figure 2 but only for a subset of companies operating in
mature industries, as Caves summarizes (1998, 1958-59): "Hazard
rates for incumbents are lower than for entrants through all stages of
the cycle in 'non-technical' products (where experience
advantages might be great)," but "higher for
'technical' products, where entrants bring the continuing flow
of innovations." The latter results come from Audretsch (1991).
Klepper and Miller (1995) and Klepper (1996) show that the number of
firms offering a product reaches a long-run stable equilibrium after
declining from an early peak through a prolonged, steady shakeout phase
that suggests continuing competition among firms to reduce costs rather
than initial entry that overshoots the potential market.
I/O research is based directly on economic theories of competition.
From the I/O perspective (Caves, 1998, 1947, note 2), organizational
ecology "suffers from eschewing simple priors about business
behavior: intended profit-maximization and the need to cover costs to
keep a firm's coalition together."
Hence, the orienting theories underlying population ecology and I/O
are sufficiently different that there has been little
cross-fertilization, despite empirical research on the same or very
similar underlying processes. (7)
Our research program seeks to build a bridge between these two
related approaches by bringing organizational ecology's focus on
industry emergence into a model that includes wealth maximization and
measures of resources (e.g., intellectual human capital of the stars,
venture capital), competencies (e.g., main technology employed), and
external environment (beyond other firms to include top-quality
universities and other local characteristics, as well as quality of the
local labor force and national cost of capital).
In standard I/O studies, two major theoretical approaches have
developed over the past two decades to deal with empirical
inconsistencies with earlier models, such as the law of proportionate
growth. Central to both are the processes of learning by and the
characteristics of the information available to firms in an industry.
Learning about the decisions and success of other firms, as well as your
own firm through its experience, improves the firm's efficiency and
hence growth and survival.
Most models of competition and growth are more suited to
manufacturing and other routinized production contexts where the main
source of uncertainty is arguably how an entering firm will perform
relative to existing firms in that same industry. In Jovanovic (1982)
and Lippman and Rumelt (1982), firms learn about their competitiveness
only after entry through experience relative to that of other firms.
Because costs are random and different between firms, a potential
entering firm does not know its own expectation but knows the
distribution of all firms' costs in that industry. Firms differ in
size because some discover that they are more efficient than others, not
because of fixity of capital. These models have proven themselves in
numerous empirical studies of mature industries as reviewed by Caves
(1998).
Recent large-scale research in I/O has documented the variability
of the performance path of individual firms, as shown especially in
panel studies by Davis and Haltiwanger (1992) and Pakes and Ericson
(1998). A recent model developed by Ericson and Pakes (1995) explicitly
incorporates firm-specific changes in investment in response to changes
in uncertainty and to evolution of competing firms and other industries.
The success of the firm in terms of profitability and value is
determined by the stochastic outcome of its investment, within the
context of success by other firms in the same industry and the context
of competitive pressures from new entry and other industries.
This model endogenizes the processes of selection in industry
evolution and thus both entry and exit. Industry-level dynamics are
predicted to develop over time in an increasingly regular way, spending
more time in natural states, including number of incumbents and entrants
and exits, but failing to reach a limit. The Ericson-Pakes approach
provides a more complete model of firm behavior in industries where
production is not routine but where central tasks are invented and
reinvented as the frontiers of knowledge develop, whether due to
technological breakthrough or other kinds of invention, from quality
circles to new financial instruments.
III. FINDINGS FOR BIOTECHNOLOGY AND OTHER SCIENCE-DRIVEN
TECHNOLOGICAL REVOLUTIONS
The process underlying metamorphic progress is defined by the
introduction of a new breakthrough technology that either eliminates the
ability of firms practicing the old technology to survive or creates an
entirely new industry. (8) If the technological breakthrough relies on
the same scientific and engineering base as the previous technology
incumbent firms are generally strengthened as they readily convert to
the new technology. Focusing on what happens to incumbent firms, Tushman
and Anderson (1986) refer to these changes as competence-enhancing. If
the science and engineering base of the new technology is disjoint from
that of the existing technology, existing firms tend to shrink and exit
and many new entrants arise practicing the new (incumbent's)
competencedestroying technology (Tushman and Anderson, 1986; Henderson,
1993).
We emphasize whether the breakthrough technology is
incumbent-enhancing or entry-generating. Incumbent-enhancing
breakthroughs are the same as Tushman and Anderson's
competence-enhancing breakthroughs. Entry-generating breakthroughs
include both their competence-destroying technologies and breakthroughs
that create whole new industries. The key example of entry-generating
breakthroughs are the entrepreneurial start-up phase in high-technology
industries characterized by a high valuation on ability to practice the
new technology while any incumbent firms' expertise in a previous
technology becomes obsolete and, often, a barrier to adoption of the new
technology.
Much recent research--including ours--has concentrated on
industries being formed or transformed in response to entry-generating
technological breakthroughs. Nonetheless, Tushman and Anderson (1986)
provide an impressive list of incumbentenhancing breakthroughs and the
recent work by Harberger (1998) and his associates suggest that
metamorphic progress of this type is also a relatively frequent feature
of a growing economy. In contrast, we (Darby and Zucker, 2001; Zucker
and Darby, 2001) found in Japan that the technological breakthroughs
that led to a wave of entrepreneurial start-ups in the United States were adopted more or less successfully either by established firms with
congruent scientific bases that took advantage of the opportunity to
enter new industries or by technological transformation of incumbent
firms. The key institutional difference that appears to have led to
different metamorphic processes in the two countries was the (recently
relaxed) Japanese prohibition on public offerings of stock in firms
without an established record of substantial profitability. The
extraordinary length of private financing implied by this prohibition
effectively eliminated the possibility of Japanese startup firms
financed by venture capitalists.
Research on the formation/transformation entrepreneurial phase in
high-technology industries has proceeded far enough that we can begin to
define and (in some cases) tentatively answer key questions about
processes that shape metamorphic change and ultimately the total rate of
technological progress in the economy. We focus here on entry-generating
breakthroughs, but incumbentenhancing metamorphic change also may be
important for technological progress. (9)
Many Are Called, But Few Are Chosen
Entry-generating breakthroughs are characterized by a formation
phase of perhaps 10 to 20 years (see Figure 2) during which many more
firms enter the industry than will survive in the long run. In the
following consolidation or shakeout phase of perhaps 10 to 30 years,
most of these firms are either absorbed by the industry's winners
or leave the industry at their owners' initiative or that of their
creditors. (10) This occurs even as industry output continues to grow
dramatically; average (surviving) firm size grows even more rapidly. The
consolidation phase may be followed by an extended period of stability
corresponding to the standard price-theory model of entry and exit
maintaining zero-economic profits and optimal firm size. A final phase
of decline is not necessary but often observed. Alternatively, the
entire process may be interrupted in any phase by another metamorphic
break-through.
Why are so many more new firms or new operations of existing firms
created than are really needed? Is their creation and destruction a case
of organizational waste and entrepreneurial misjudgment or is
firm-number overshooting valuable and entry ex ante justified?
Uncertainty about which entrants will be most successful in implementing
the new technology is sufficient for the observed pattern to be
efficient, as shown by Jovanovic and MacDonald (1994) and Ericson and
Pakes (1995), and recently elaborated by Bernardo and Chowdhry (2002).
For incumbent-enhancing breakthroughs it is obvious that the most
successful implementers will be among the incumbent firms where much
expertise relative to the technology and cooperative technologies is
present. Indeed, one or more of these firms is likely to be the source
of the breakthrough. Though inventing and early adopting incumbent firms
are likely to improve their standing in the industry (Tushman and
Anderson, 1986), there is no reason for any outsiders to enter in the
expectation that they will outcompete the incumbents. Thus the
overshooting of firm numbers is characteristic of only entry-generating
metamorphic progress.
Although there are many hopeful entrants in the latter case, few of
them typically survive. For example, Table 1 presents some data on new
U.S. biotechnology firms in 1989 drawn from a study we did with Jeff
Armstrong (Zucker et al., 2002). The first of these firms was founded in
1976 to exploit the string of technological breakthroughs in the life
sciences, most of which followed directly or indirectly from the
invention of genetic engineering as reported by Cohen et al. (1973).
Firm formation accelerated after the 1980 U.S. Supreme Court decision
that upheld the patenting of engineered cells and cell parts and the
underlying recombinant-DNA technology covered by the Cohen-Boyer patent
(1980). By 1990 over half of the employees in the industry were
concentrated in the top 10% of the firms, and over two-thirds of the
industry were in the top 20% of the firms. Figure 3 illustrates these
data and shows that the same top 21 firms (out of 211) also accounted
for 54% of the growth in employment from 1989 to 1994. (11) More
generally, Lamoreaux and Sokoloff (2002, Table 6) show that U.S. patents
have been concentrated in a relatively few career inventors since the
1870s.
Academic Science Matters a Lot
Entry-generating metamorphic progress almost always arises from
outside the industry(ies) to which it will be applied. Many observers
have pointed to anecdotal evidence of the importance of research
universities as a source of breakthroughs that have created such regions
as the Silicon Valley around Stanford; Route 128 around MIT and Harvard;
and the Research Triangle Park around Duke, the University of North
Carolina--Chapel Hill, and North Carolina State University. (12)
Mansfield (1995) documents the important role played by academic
research in even incremental industrial R&D, that is, in perfective
progress.
A stream of recent research on innovation in the United States has
found evidence of "geographically localized knowledge
spillovers" occurring in areas around major universities: Jaffe
(1986, 1989), Jaffe et al. (1993), Audretsch and Feldman (1996), and
Henderson et al. (1998). The underlying assumption is that proximity to
a major university itself provides technological opportunity; the
localization is assumed to be due to the social ties between university
and firm employees or to firm employees' access to seminars at the
university. The importance of distance is strengthened by Adams and
Jaffe's (1996) finding that geographic distance is an important
impediment to flow of technology even within the firm.
Zucker et al. (1998b) and Darby and Zucker (2001) find that firms
are more likely to begin using biotechnology near where and when
"star" bioscientists are actively publishing in the United
States and Japan, respectively. Although these findings have been cited
as evidence of geographically localized knowledge spillovers, we read
our results--and those of the other authors cited--as only demonstrating
geographical localization of knowledge. Zucker et al. (1998a, 2002) and
Zucker and Darby (2001) show for California, the United States, and
Japan, respectively, that university effects on nearby firm R&D
productivity are highly concentrated in the particular firms with
bench-science working relationships with top academic scientists and
practically absent otherwise. We identify these academic-firm links by
the academic scientist publishing a journal article that also has one or
more firm-affiliated authors. (13) Table 2 and Figure 4 indicate the
close connection between links to top research university faculty a nd
success: ranking firms by their linked articles up to 1989 does about as
well as ranking by 1989 employment at predicting the 1989-94 employment
increase. Put another way, an investor who restricted his or her biotech
portfolio at the end of 1989 to only the 22.7% of firms with any linked
firm-research university core biotech publications or the 10.9% with
more than one or two of these would include all of the top 10 firms and
nearly all of the base-hit firms. The message of these simple
correlations holds up in the context of poison regressions which allow
for other determinants. Figure 5 reports the strong estimated effects of
these linked articles on firm research productivity in California and
Japan. (14)
Fieldwork--supported by analysis of the timing of the academic
scientists' first articles with a firm and its founding--indicates
that these academic-firm copublishing relationships most often connote that the academic scientist was a firm founder or at least presently has
a significant financial interest in the firm. (15) Indeed, Herbert
Boyer, of the Cohen-Boyer team who discovered recombinant RNA or genetic
engineering, and entrepreneur Robert Swanson founded the first of the
new biotech firms (Genentech). Similarly, Torero (1998) finds that a few
hundred top scientists and engineers account for a large part of the
patenting in the semiconductor industry, and firm success depends
heavily on the degree of involvement of those stars in a firm. Where and
when these star semiconductor scientists and engineers are working is an
important determinant of where and when new semiconductor firms are
established (Torero et al., 2001).
IV. NATURAL EXCLUDABILITY AND THE DIFFUSION OF METAMORPHIC
BREAKTHROUGHS
The central role of a relatively small number of scientists and
engineers in determining success of high-technology firms forces us to
rethink the nature of technology. Economists have traditionally analyzed
technology as if it were a public good with a marginal cost of
(re)production of zero (Nelson, 1959; Arrow, 1962). Despite the seminal
works of Stigler (1961) and Becker (1964) spawning the vast literatures
on the economics of costly information and human capital, most analyses
of technology including the "new" endogenous growth models
typically conceive of technology as information that can be recorded on
a floppy disk and then be costlessly reproduced and applied. Romer
(1990), for example, acknowledges that this nonrivalrous
characterization is an idealization but argues that it is much more
expensive to create a new technology than learn it and that the
idealization is harmless. We disagree.
When a major scientific breakthrough occurs and creates the
opportunity for a corresponding incumbent-enhancing or entry-generating
technological breakthrough, it may be very difficult for anyone other
than the discovering scientists or their close working associates to
reduce the discovery to technological practice. The ideas are far from
codified and even the discovering scientists are not sure exactly what
it is that they are doing, which is crucial. Published
results--including those in a patent--may not be reproducible unless the
reproducing scientist goes to the discoverer's lab and learns by
doing with him or her. (16) In biotechnology, patent disclosures are
often made by deposit of a cell line with an independent agent so that
they will be publicly available at the expiration of the patent term: it
is simply not possible to write down what a person skilled in the art
would have to do to obtain the same organism.
Breakthrough discoveries leading to metamorphic growth are often of
the same nature as Griliches's (1957, 1960) classic case of corn
hybridization: an invention of a way of invention. Such platform
technologies involving new techniques and instrumentation are typically
hard to work with at first, and their diffusion is based on
learning-by-doing-with at the laboratory bench: that is, by immediate
observation and practice with someone who holds the tacit knowledge of
how to make the technique work.
Not only are breakthrough discoveries often characterized by
extensive tacit knowledge, only a relatively few top scientists near the
frontier of the area are likely to be able to figure out how the
discovery might be used to actually produce something of economic value.
Although everyone might want to pluck the newly available low-lying
fruit, not everyone can see where they are. The late Robert Swanson,
founding CEO of Genentech, liked to tell the story of how the firm
obtained such a favorable royalty deal for Humulin[R] (human insulin produced by genetically modified bacteria) from the usually shrewd
bargainers at Eli Lilly and Co. The scientists there were so sure that
Herbert Boyer and Genentech were attempting the impossible that no
serious bargaining was done until Genentech notified Lilly that they
were holding a press conference announcing success in three days.
We say that this embodied knowledge--transferred slowly only by
learning-by-doing-with--is characterized by natural excludability. Even
if the university is assigned a patent to the discovery, most of the
value accrues to the discoverers because without their cooperation the
patent cannot be used. Our fieldwork for biotechnology and more general
studies by Jensen and Thursby (2001) and Thursby and Thursby (2002)
support the natural excludability hypothesis. For example, in the Jensen
and Thursby (2001, 243) survey of Technology Transfer Office managers,
"For 71 percent of the inventions licensed, respondents claim that
successful commercialization requires cooperation by the inventor and
licensee in further development."
Diffusion with Natural Excludability
If new metamorphic technologies were really like software on a
disk, diffusion of this highly profitable knowledge would be limited
only by the speed with which people realize the value of the new
processes (Mansfield, 1961; Griliches and Schmookler, 1963). In contrast
to this potentially infinite rate of adoption, natural excludability
limits the extent of diffusion to an exponential times the number of
discoverers.
To see this, consider biotechnology in 1973 and suppose that six
people in two laboratories knew how to do genetic engineering
(recombinant DNA). Suppose one knowledgeable person can transfer the
knowledge to at most one person per year. Then the maximum number of
potential practitioners of the art in year t(t = 0 in 1973) is
6*[2.sup.t]. Even if this rapid rate of diffusion were possible, there
would only be 6*[2.sup.10] = 6,144 potential practitioners of genetic
engineering in 1983, each of whom would still be earning a very large
shadow wage. Over time, the value of the knowledge declines as the
number of practitioners increases until new apprentices earn only the
normal human capital return to their investment in learning the
knowledge.
Thus there is a varying period of time during which the discovers
and early learners derive supranormal returns from practicing their
knowledge and also benefit from lower-cost assistants due to the
implicit tuition chain. This period of time can be long enough to
significantly impact the formative period of a new industry, such as
biotechnology or nanotechnology, or transformative periods, such as have
occurred in semiconductors. We have formulated a much more elaborate
model involving multiyear learning in a lab with the number of learners
in the lab and their probability and lag to leading their own lab, all
as a function of the value of the knowledge, but the basic message of at
most exponential growth from a small base remains intact. Zucker et al.
(2002) illustrate both the geometric growth in scientists publishing
their first paper reporting a genetic-sequence discovery and the
continuing tacit nature of the knowledge. (17)
Discovering and other top scientists and engineers play a key role
in metamorphic progress as we have seen so far for biotechnology and
semiconductors, lasers as described by Sleeper (1998), and
nanotechnology (based on our new research). We believe that natural
excludability makes this role a frequent feature of metamorphic
progress. Note that even where university professors follow the rules
and promptly disclose inventions for patenting by the university under
the Bayh-Dole Act, the value of those patents is impacted by the usual
necessity to license the patent to a firm and on terms such that the
discovering professors are willing to cooperate in the commercialization
process.
V. UNSETTLED WELFARE AND POLICY ISSUES
Academic purists often express concerns about faculty involvement
in commercialization of their discoveries. These concerns include: (1)
lost scientific productivity of the scientists, (2) reduction in the
amount of science contributed to the common pool by publishing, (3)
deflection of the development of science toward more commercially
relevant problems, (4) conflict of interest leading to scientists'
distorting their findings, and (5) conflict of commitment to the
university. Our research can shed light on some of these concerns, but
others remain open issues. We do not consider more radical objections to
scientific progress and productivity growth because we believe that
these are well answered in more general debates.
Lost Scientific Productivity of the Scientists
One of the initial motivations of the biotechnology study that
spawned our current larger growth, science, and technology project was
to examine the cost in lost scientific productivity of commercial
involvement of the very best academic bioscientists. Surprisingly, we
found robust evidence that scientific productivity of these scientists
increases during their commercial involvement (as compared to their own
productivity before or after) on the standard measures of publications
and citations to those publications (Zucker and Darby, 1995, 1996). To
give an extreme example, the most commercially involved star scientists
(those ever affiliated with a firm and with patents) have nine times as
many citations as do star scientists who are never affiliated or linked
to a firm and have no patents. About half of that difference reflects
the fact that those who become involved are more energetic to begin
with, and the rest reflects the increase in publications per year and
citations per publication during their years of firm involvement.
In the half-decade since we first published those findings, we have
further tested them on an expanded U.S. data set using improved
methodology and replicated them for Japan. Because publishing increases
robustly for scientists working with firms, we were forced to reconsider
our initial assumptions. First, the delays in publication required for
patenting by firms are typically on the order of three months, and
universities also require delay while they prepare patent applications
with possibly less efficiency. Furthermore, purely academic scientists
also may prefer to delay publication for strategic reasons; one
respondent put it this way: "When I was a pure academic, I
didn't exactly throw away my lead by publishing rich discoveries
until I put together three or four articles following them up." We
may not only have overestimated the increased returns to secrecy but
also missed two factors that seem to swamp any higher value for secrecy.
The first countervailing factor is that commercial involvement
gives the scientists much more resources to do their work. Not only are
venture capitalists and investment bankers easier funding sources (per
dollar) than the National Institutes of Health or the National Science
Foundation, but it permits scientists the luxury of research assistants
who are highly experienced and skilled long-term employees instead of
first-year graduate students performing an assay or protocol for the
first time.
The second countervailing factor is that the best scientists really
love doing science! That is, doing science is a luxury good for which
the income elasticity is greater than 1. When their company goes public,
they consume not only more Ferraris but more experiments. (18)
Reduction in the Amount of Science Contributed to the Common Pool
by Publishing
These concerns in part refer to publishing activities by scientists
who are commercially involved and those have been addressed. There is,
however, a broader concern that the commercialization of science will
reduce the amount of publishing by scientists generally--thus reducing
the positive externalities that enrich the entire enterprise. Put
another way, extensive faculty involvement in the commercial world may
import commercial norms of trade secrecy into the academy. Our evidence
suggests that just the opposite is true and that the new biotech
firms--largely started with active faculty as principals--have exported
academic values of publishing to the industries in which they are
involved. The new biotech firms were a major organizational form/design
innovation that forced the surviving incumbents to permit and reward
journal publication to compete for the best and brightest scientists who
are needed for the firm to survive and prosper. As the top research
executive at one of the largest pharmaceutical fir ms put it:
We see some danger of losing our competitive advantage by
publishing, but a much greater danger if we do anything that deters the
best scientists from coming here. Further, we need for our scientists to
have great reputations in order to bring others like them to [the firm].
We are the beneficiaries of world-wide scientific research, and thus we
also need to contribute to this pool of scientific knowledge, creating a
public good.... Relative to new biotechnology firms, [we] may believe
more strongly in the commonality of research tools because we have a
wider array of methodologies and products. (Zucker and Darby, 1997,
438-39).
Table 3 is an extract of the top and other references (i.e.,
nonpatent references) section from Goeddel and Heyneker's (1982)
U.S. Patent 4,342,832, assigned at issue to Genentech. The patent was
applied for in July 1979 and cites related work by the inventors
(Goeddel et al., 1979). Note the extensive citations to other work
published in leading academic journals, indicating the continuity
between basic science and new intellectual property in the
science-driven industries. Indeed, much research done at firms is openly
published either without a patent or shortly after one is applied for.
In the most successful firms, world-class scientists are more likely to
follow high-stakes, high-return R&D strategies instead of more
predictable incremental strategies, as indicated by the larger jump-size
in their stock price when success or failure is revealed (Darby et al.,
2002).
The evidence is clear that the involvement of university faculty in
commercialization of their discoveries has widened the norms of
publication of research results into the very science-driven industries
where there is the most to be learned from firm research. It is hard to
credit that other university scientists are publishing less while those
directly involved are publishing more; so we conclude that there has
likely been an overall increase in the propensity to publish research
results rather than the hypothesized decrease.
Deflection of the Development of Science toward More Commercially
Relevant Problems
We believe that the trajectory of science is bent to a degree
toward more commercially relevant problems. Just as provision of
government research funding targeted to politically important issues
would seem to have some impact on the trajectory of science, we would
expect that the availability of commercial funding should also have an
impact. However, it is very hard to develop a counterfactual trajectory
for science, so our evidence is indirect: Zucker et al. (2002) find that
bio-scientists working in areas more directly relevant to human disease
are more likely to become linked to firms, and, as noted, scientists who
are linked to firms are both generally more productive of articles and
citations to those articles and are significantly more productive during
their linkage than they were previously. Thus there must be some impact
of commercial relevance on the course of science. However, because more
science is being done in total and progress in one area depends partly
on progress in other areas, we cannot conclude unambiguously that there
is less progress in the less commercially applicable areas than there
would have been in the absence of commercial involvement.
Even if there were less science in the less commercially applicable
areas, it does not follow that this is a cost rather than a benefit. In
the case of biotechnology, it means that more people are being spared
from death and spared from suffering from disease and starvation due to
high food costs. Possibly it is appropriate that scientists weigh these
benefits directly and in terms of their financial implications in
choosing which problems to work on. Even in economics, there are some
distinguished practitioners who argue that their science would be
healthier if empirical relevance played a greater role in allocation of
rewards and hence choice of problems.
Conflict of Interest Leading to Scientists' Distorting Their
Findings
From time to time cases of scientific fraud emerge, and the fear is
that this frequency is inevitably increased where scientists can profit
directly from selling products or shares of stock based on such claims.
This is probably a very small risk for star scientists who are likely at
a robust corner solution due to reputations of immense value and
realistic prospects for the Nobel and other major prizes. Where
reputation value is less, one would expect that fraud increases with the
returns. However, we do not normally argue against wealth creation on
the grounds that it increases the incentives for theft and fraud.
Conflict of Commitment to the University
Finally, there is an argument that the opportunity to commercialize
discoveries distracts faculty from the roles for which they are paid: to
instruct, do research, and attend committee meetings. We can leave out
any threat to research because that unambiguously increases in quantity
and quality during commercial involvement, so the threat is concentrated
in the areas of teaching and collegiality. Even for teaching, the issues
are complicated by the extraordinarily high value of training received
by apprentice researchers in the laboratories of scientists making
valuable discoveries with natural excludability. If the possibility of
working with such scientists increases the applications to the
university in the relevant department(s) or school(s), can we truly say
that their teaching output has decreased?
Moreover, in addressing the question of diversion from commitment
to the university, we must face the issue that the roles or commitments
of a professor are not standardized and are traditionally subject to
individual negotiation as discussed by Stigler (1950) and Stinchcombe
(1990). This immediately raises the issues of incentive packages and
compensating differentials in wages of professors who--if they make a
commercially valuable discovery--will tend to profit from the discovery
as well as do more research and less teaching and collegiality.
Normally, we would suppose that markets handle these contracting issues
rather efficiently, although not perfectly compared to a costless world
(Darby and Karni, 1973; Aghion and Tirole, 1994). Possibly the
complaints about conflict of commitments reflect more the feeling of
some faculty in other departments that they work just as hard and should
be equally rewarded by the market.
VI. CONCLUSIONS: A DRAFT RESEARCH AGENDA
The endogenous growth literature assumes that technology is a
nonrivalrous recipe that is costly to discover but costless to
replicate. We saw in section IV that for many industries undergoing
metamorphic progress, technology instead possesses natural
excludability, resides in particular individuals, and diffuses by
learning-by-doing-with. That is, breakthrough technologies are better
thought of as rivalrous human capital, not a recipe on a disk capable of
free copying. It follows that the focus of the endogenous growth
literature should shift from the theory of the firm toward understanding
the motivations of discovering scientists to report or bootleg
discoveries, to found new firms or cooperate with existing firms in
commercializing their discoveries, and most important to do the initial
research that creates the opportunity for a commercial breakthrough. Key
issues largely ignored in the current growth literature include
compensating wage differentials, incentive pay, rents and quasi-rents,
and moral haza rd along the lines of Aghion and Tirole (1994). Jensen
and Thursby (2001), Thursby and Thursby (2000), and Zucker et al. (2002)
explicitly pursue those issues.
If the most important breakthrough technologies are typically
embodied in individual scientists and transferred or diffused by
learning-by-doing-with, then the incentives to discover are considerably
higher than conventionally analyzed even if the university or firm gets
nominal ownership of the intellectual property rights in the discovery
through a patent. The discoverers and patent owner have an interesting
bargaining problem because the patent is worthless unless the
discoverers cooperate with the licensee(s), often firms in which the
discoverers have founders' interests. On the other hand, the angel
investors and venture capitalists financing discovers' firms want
to be sure that the intellectual property is secure and tied down, so
the discoverers must either negotiate a reasonable agreement with their
employers (the patent owners) or take extraordinary steps to document
that the discoveries were not made with, say, university resources.
Hence, the plethora of firm laboratories very near campuses and th e
attraction of university-adjacent science parks to ensure that follow-up
discoveries clearly belong to the firms and not the universities.
Our approach also suggests that the analysis of spillovers (the
science and technology literature's term for positive
externalities) is basically flawed. The spillovers from the ivory tower that are widely used to explain geographically localized knowledge
(i.e., increased research productivity for firms) in the neighborhood of
great research universities do not hold up to rigorous empirical
analysis. Increased research productivity is very large in firms with
specific identifiable links to discovering university scientists and
engineers and otherwise nil or insignificant. The more important
positive externalities associated with commercialization of university
discoveries have been neglected in the literature. These are the
nonlocalized spillovers associated with increased publishing by the
university scientists working with the firms and by the scientists and
engineers employed by the firms. (19)
We know from a great deal of empirical research in the field of
growth accounting that technological progress together with growth in
the average level of human capital are the ultimate determinants of
growth in output per capita. The endogenous growth literature has
started the important work of understanding the determinants of
technological progress in an aggregate model. The aggregate models to
date are oriented toward explaining what we call perfective
progress--based on incremental R&D performed by incumbent firms. We
argue that metamorphic progress is an equal or greater source of
technological progress and that most often (but not always) metamorphic
progress involves discoveries made by scientists and engineers external
to the existing industry and involves embodied knowledge that is
protected by natural excludability and diffused by
learning-by-doing-with. We believe that building on these ideas will
strengthen both the science and technology and the endogenous growth
literatures with the ultimate r esult that we understand what
institutional arrangements are most conducive to growth in the standard
of living.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
FIGURE 3
Concentration of U.S. New Biotechnology Firms' 1989 Employment and
Employment Change 1989-94
Empolyment Change
1989 Employment 1989-1994
Bottom 80% 31% 37%
Next Decile 15% 9%
Top Decile 54% 54%
Note: Table made from pie chart
FIGURE 4
Concentration of New Biotechnology Firms' Links to Top Research
Universities for 1989 Employment Deciles
Core Links to Top Other Links to Top
Research Universities Research Universities
Bottom 80% 17% 17%
Next Decile 6% 4%
Top Decile 77% 79%
Note: Table made from pie chart
TABLE 1
Concentration of Employment in New Biotech Firms, 1989
Number Employment
of firms in 1989 (%)
Top decile 21 53.8
Next decile 21 15.0
Bottom 80% 169 31.2
Totals 211 100.0
Source: Calculations of the authors for the biotechusing firms that
disclosed employment for 1989 and 1994 and were formed after 1975 in the
Zucker et al. (2002) database.
TABLE 2
Relation of Employment in New Biotech Firms to Links to High Science as
Represented by Articles Coauthored with Scientists in Top 112 Research
Universities
Employment Employment
Number in 1889 change 1989-94
of firms (%) (%)
By 1989 employment
Top decile 21 53.8 53.2
Next decile 21 15.0 9.4
Bottom 80% 169 31.2 37.4
Totals 211 100.0 100.0
By core links
Top decile 21 48.7 53.4
Next decile 21 7.1 4.6
Bottom 80% 169 44.2 42.0
Totals 211 100.0 100.0
Core links to Other links to
top universities top universities
(%) (%)
By 1989 employment
Top decile 76.4 79.4
Next dccilc 6.2 4.0
Bottom 80% 17.4 16.6
Totals 100.0 100.0
By core links
Top decile 94.0 81.5
Next decile 5.1 7.7
Bottom 80% 0.9 10.7
Totals 100.0 100.0
Source: Calculations of the authors for the biotech-using firms that
disclosed employment for 1989 and 1994 and were formed after 1975 in the
Zucker et al. (2002) database.
Notes: Core links are a count of articles published through 1989 in
journals directly related to biotechnology indexed by the Institute of
Scientific Information and with one or more authors affiliated with the
firm and one or more authors affiliated with any of the top 112 U.S.
research universities in terms of receipt of federal research funding.
Other links are a count of articles published through 1989 in journals
not directly related to biotechnology indexed by the Institute of
Scientific Information and with one or more authors affiliated with the
firm and one or more authors affiliated with any of the top 112 U.S.
research universities in terms of receipt of federal research funding.
TABLE 3
Extract from U.S. Patent 4,342,832, Assigned to Genentech Illustrating
Close Ties to Academic Science
United States Patent 4,342,832
Goeddel et al. August 3, 1982
Method of constructing a replicable cloning vehicle having
quasi-synthetic genes
Abstract
Described are methods and means for the construction and microbial
expression of quasi-synthetic genes arising from the combination of
organic synthesis and enzymatic reverse transcription from messenger RNA
sequences incomplete from the standpoint of the desired protein product.
Preferred products of expression lack bioinactivating leader sequences
common in eukaryotic expression products but problematic with regard to
microbial cleavage to yield bioactive material. Illustrative is a
preferred embodiment in which a gene coding for human growth hormone
(useful in, e.g., treatment of hypopituitary dwarfism) is constructed
and expressed.
Inventors: Goeddel; David V. (Burlingame, CA); Heyneker; Herbert L.
(Burlingame, CA)
Assignee: Genentech, Inc. (South San Francisco, CA)
Appl. No.: 055126
Filed: July 5, 1979
Other references
Technology Review, pp. 12 and 13, Dec. 1976.
Martial et al., Science, vol. 205, Aug. 10, 1979.
Shine et al., Nature, vol. 285, Jun. 12, 1980, pp. 456-461.
The Economist, pp. 87 and 88, Jul. 14, 1979.
Time, Jul. 30, 1970, p. 70.
Newmark, Nature, vol. 280, pp. 637 and 638, Aug. 23, 1979.
Villa-Komaroff et al., Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., vol. 75, pp.
3727-3731, Aug. 1978.
Seeburg et al., Nature, vol. 276, pp. 795-798, Dec. 1978.
Itakura et al., Science, vol. 198, pp. 1056-1063, Dec. 1977.
Crea et al., Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., vol. 75, pp. 5765-5769,
Dec. 1978.
Klenow et al., Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., vol. 65, pp. 168-175,
Jan. 1970.
Sutcliffe, Cold Spring Harbor Symposium 43, pp. 70-90 (1978).
Curtis et al., Molecular Cloning of Recombinant DNA, by
Scott et al., pp. 99-111 (1977).
Ullrich et al., Science, vol. 196, pp. 1313-1319, Jun. 1977.
Bolivar et al., Gene 2, pp. 95-113 (1977).
Goedel et al., Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci., vol. 76, pp. 106-110,
Jan. 1979.
Chang et al., Nature, vol. 275, pp. 617-624, Oct. 1978.
Maxam et al., Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci., vol. 74, pp. 560-564
(Feb. 1977).
Kornberg, DNA Synthesis, pp. 87 and 88, pub. by
W. H. Freeman & Co., 1974.
Razin et al., Proc. Natl. Acad., vol. 75, pp.
4268-4270, Sep. 1978.
Wickens et al., The Journal of Biological Chemistry,
vol. 253, No. 7, pp. 2483-2495 (1978).
(1.) Abba Lerner (1953) also propagated the Crusonia plant.
(2.) See, for example, the papers collected in Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City (2001).
(3.) If it were the point of the article, we would do a full
analysis of productivity growth taking account of changes in capital,
labor-quality adjustments for the hours worked, and procyclical
movements in productivity (see Darby 1984a, 1984b). Before undertaking
such an effort, we would want to see evidence of an interesting anomaly
in cruder measures of productivity growth. Central bankers saying that
the economy works differently from before so that they can ignore the
usual signs of monetary overstimulus hardly qualify as an anomaly.
(4.) Rudebusch (2000) clearly walked a tight line between
professional and institutional loyalty: "As noted above, there is,
of course, always a large amount of uncertainty about estimates of the
growth rate of potential output. Indeed, based on a strict statistical
interpretation of Figure 1, there is a one in five chance that there has
been no change in the growth of potential output in the 1990s."
(5.) Growth in overall industry size can be attributed to movement
down an elastic demand curve as more efficient, lower-cost producers
replace higher-cost producers. The question is why it takes so long for
the low-cost producers to emerge and drive Out the others.
(6.) Zucker (1989), Baum and Powell (1995), as well as the review
articles by Baum (1996) and by Singh and Lumsden (1990), raise
significant questions about the directions of theory and research in
organizational ecology, while also stressing the value of particular
empirical studies done under the ecology banner.
(7.) Compare infant mortality in Wedervang (1965) to liability of
smallness, ruling out age effects, in Freeman et al. (1983).
(8.) New industries may eliminate or greatly reduce the size of
other industries previously satisfying the fundamental function--for
example, the advent of the automobile industry all but eliminated both
the buggy and buggy whip industries. In principle, we could view the
present automobile and vestigial buggy industries as a transformed
personal land transportation industry, but it is not apparent what would
be gained from such semantic niceties.
(9.) The range and impact of incumbent-enhancing metamorphic change
is suggested by Harberger's ongoing work on major cost reductions
in existing industries.
(10.) This process may interact with waves of optimism and
pessimism about the future of an emerging industry. For example, despite
a promising and ultimately successful pipeline of drug discoveries,
Cetus faced a cash shortage during a phase of biotech pessimism and
merged into Chiron.
(11.) Note that we maintained the decile sorting by level of 1989
employment in Figure 3. If we had instead sorted by employment change
along the lines of Harberger (1998), the top and second deciles so
defined would account for 75.8% and 17.4% of the net employment change
with only 6.7% left for the other firms. The bottom 80% (169 firms) on
this basis includes 63 firms with negative change, 10 with no change,
and 96 firms with positive employment change.
(12.) See especially Dorfman (1988), Jones and Vedlitz (1988),
Smilor et al. (1988), and Bania et al. (1993). There are, of course,
other important sources of geographic agglomeration (see, for example,
Head et al., 1995).
(13.) Publications involving scientists at two firms are extremely
rare. Furthermore, the scientists practice serial monogamy, usually
writing with only one firm during his or her career and, in the
alternative, writing with only one firm at a time.
(14.) We introduce major methodological innovations in Zucker et
al. (2002), exploiting a substantially broadened database, so that
simple comparisons are not possible although the results are very
supportive of the importance of academic-firm linked articles.
(15.) In Japan, explicit principal status in a firm is forbidden to
professors at the national universities. However, continuing unreported
cash payments on the order of the scientist's salary are common
(and rarely prosecuted, but see Japan Times, 1999, for a counterexample)
as are lucrative corporate directorships promised when the professor
"descends from heaven" at age 55 or 60 (i.e., postretirement).
(16.) Sometimes when an important result is difficult to reproduce
in another location, the entire laboratory is reproduced, including the
placement of equipment down to the coffee urn. If the result can then be
obtained, detective work ensues to figure out what features are crucial.
In a similar vein, during our fieldwork we heard one distinguished
scientist grumble that another "had stolen [his] best cloner."
This is not a remark applicable to something easy to learn from material
written on a floppy disk!
(17.) Tacitness is indicated by the fact that the bulk of new
authors reporting genetic-sequence discoveries for the first time were
writing as coauthors with previously published discovers, and this
continued to the end of the data set (1994), as reported in Zucker et
al. (2002).
(18.) Milton Friedman reminds us that economists are not immune to
this science as (tax.exempt or conspicuous?) consumption phenomenon:
Irving Fisher amassed a fortune inventing a visible file system and
founding one of the constituents of Remington.Rand. He used it to hire a
sizable staff of assistants to compute [(X'X).sup.-1] X'y in
the days before electric calculators. The ability to estimate multiple
regressions was a powerful professional advantage in the 1920s.
(19.) We are indebted to Milton Friedman for this point.
REFERENCES
Adams, J. D., and A. B. Jaffe. "Bounding thc Effects of
R&D: An Investigation Using Matched Establishment-Firm Data."
Rand Journal of Economics, 27(4), 1996, 700-21.
Aghion, P., and J. Tirole. "The Management of
Innovation." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(4), 1994,
1185-209.
Aldrich, H., and U. H. Staber. "Organizing Business Interests:
Patterns of Trade Association Foundings, Transformations, and
Death," in Ecological Models of Organizations, edited by Glenn R.
Carroll. Cambridge: Ballinger, 1988, 111-26.
Aldrich, H. E., and R. Waldinger. "Ethnicity and
Entrepreneurship." Annual Review of Sociology, 16, 1990, 111-35.
Arrow, K. J. "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention," in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity:
Economic and Social Factors, edited by R. R. Nelson. Princeton:
Princeton University Press, 1962.
Audretsch, D. B. "New-Firm Survival and the Technological
Regime." Review of Economics and Statistics, 73(3), 1991, 441-50.
Audretsch, D. B., and M. P. Feldman. "R&D Spillovers and
the Geography of Innovation and Production." American Economic
Review, 86(3), 1996, 630-40.
Bania, N., R. Eberts, and M. Fogarty. "Universities and the
Startup of New Companies: Can We Generalize from Route 128 and Silicon
Valley?" Review of Economics and Statistics, 75(4), 1993, 761-66.
Barnett, W P., and T. L. Amburgey. "Do Larger Organizations
Generate Stronger Competition?," in Organizational Evolution: New
Directions, edited by J. V. Singh. Newbury Park, CA: Sage, 1990, 78-102.
Baum, J. A. C. "Organizational Ecology," in Handbook of
Organization Studies, edited by S. R. Clegg, C. Hardy, and W R. Nord.
London: Sage, 1996, 77-114.
Baum, J. A. C., and W. W. Powell. "Cultivating an
Institutional Ecology of Organizations: Comment on Hannan, Carroll,
Dundon, and Torres." American Sociological Review, 60(4), 1995,
529-38.
Becker, G. S. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis,
with Special Reference to Education. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 1964.
Bernardo, A. E., and B. Chowdhry. "Resources, Real Options,
and Corporate Strategy." Journal of Financial Economics, 2002, in
press.
Brittain, J. W, and J. H. Freeman. "Entrepreneurship in the
Semiconductor Industry." Paper presented at the 46th Annual Meeting
of the Academy of Management, New Orleans, 1986.
Carroll, G. R., and M. T Hannan. "Density Dependence in the
Evolution of Populations of Newspaper Organizations." American
Sociological Review, 54(4), 1989, 524-41.
Caves, R. E. "Industrial Organization and New Findings on the
Turnover and Mobility of Firms." Journal of Economic Literature,
36(4), 1998, 1947-82.
Cohen, S., and H. Boyer. "Process for Producing Biologically
Functional Molecular Chimeras." U.S. Patent number 4,237,224,
granted December 2, 1980.
Cohen, S., A. Chang, H. Boyer, and R. Helling. "Construction
of Biologically Functional Bacterial Plasmids in Vitro."
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 70(11), 1973, 3240-44.
Darby, M. R. Labor Force, Employment, and Productivity in
Historical Perspective. Los Angeles: UCLA Institute of Industrial
Relations, 1984a.
-----. "The U.S. Productivity Slowdown: A Case of Statistical
Myopia." American Economic Review, 74(3), 1984b, 301-22.
Darby, M. R., and E. Karni. "Free Competition and the Optimal
Amount of Fraud." Journal of Law and Economics, 16(2), 1973, 67-88.
Darby, M. R., and L. G. Zucker. "Change or Die: The Adoption
of Biotechnology in the Japanese and U.S. Pharmaceutical
Industries." Comparative Studies of Technological Evolution, 7,
2001, 85-125.
Darby, M. R., Q. Liu, and L. G. Zucker. "High Stakes in High
Technology: High-Tech Market Values as Options." UCLA Working
Paper, April 2002.
Davis, S. J., and J. Haltiwanger. "Gross Job Creation, Gross
Job Destruction, and Employment Reallocation." Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 107(3), 1992, 819-63.
Dorfman, N. S. "Route 128: The Development of a Regional High
Technology Economy," in The Massachusetts Miracle: High Technology
and Economic Revitalization, edited by D. Lampe. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press, 1988, 240-74.
Ericson, R., and A. Pakes. "Markov-Perfect Industry Dynamics:
A Framework for Empirical Work." Review of Economic Studies, 62(1),
1995, 53-82.
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. Economic Policy for the
Information Economy. A Symposium Sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City. Kansas City: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 2001.
Freeman, J., G. R. Carroll, and M. T. Hannan. "The Liability
of Newness: Age Dependence in Organizational Death Rates." American
Sociological Review, 48(5), 1983, 692-710.
Goeddel, D. V., and H. L. Heyneker. "Method of Constructing a
Replicable Cloning Vehicle Having Quasi-Synthetic Genes." U.S.
Patent number 4,342,832, granted August 3, 1982.
Goeddel, D. V, D. G. Kleid, F. Bolivar, H. L. Heyneker, D. G.
Yansura, R. Crea, T Hirose, A. Kraszewski, K. Itakura, and A. D. Riggs.
"Expression in Escherichia coli of Chemically Synthesized Genes for
Human Insulin." Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences,
76(1), 1979, 106-10.
Greenspan, A. "Technology and the Economy." Remarks
before the Economic Club of New York. New York, NY, January 13, 2000a.
_____. "Technological Innovation and the Economy."
Remarks before the White House Conference on the New Economy.
Washington, DC, April 5, 2000b.
_____. "Economic Developments." Remarks before the
Economic Club of New York. New York, NY, May 24, 2001.
Griliches, Z. "Hybrid Corn: An Exploration in the Economics of
Technological Change." Econometrica, 25(4), 1957, 501-22.
_____. "Hybrid Corn and the Economics of Innovation."
Science, 132(3422), 1960, 275-80.
Griliches, Z., and J. Schmookler. "Inventing and
Maximizing." American Economic Review, 53(4), 1963, 725-29.
Haltiwanger, J. C. "Measuring and Analyzing Aggregate
Fluctuations: The Importance of Building from Microeconomic
Evidence." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 79(3), 1997,
55-77.
Harberger, A. C. "A Vision of the Growth Process."
American Economic Review, 88(1), 1998, 1-32.
Head, K., J. Ries, and D. Swenson. "Agglomeration Benefits and
Location Choice: Evidence from Japanese Manufacturing Investments in the
United States." Journal of International Economics, 38(3-4), 1995,
223-47.
Henderson, R. "Underinvestment and Incompetence as Responses
to Radical Innovation: Evidence from the Photolithographic Alignment
Industry." RAND Journal of Economics, 24(2), 1993, 248-70.
Henderson, R., A. B. Jaffe, and M. Trajtenberg. "Universities
as a Source of Commercial Technology: A Detailed Analysis of University
Patenting 1965-1988." Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(1),
1998, 119-27.
Jaffe, A. B. "Technological Opportunity and Spillovers of
R&D; Evidence from Firms' Patents, Profits, and Market
Value." American Economic Review, 76(5), 1986, 984-1001.
_____. "Characterizing the 'Technological Position'
of Firms, with Application to Quantifying Technological Opportunity and
Research Spillovers." Research Policy, 18(1), 1989, 87-97.
Jaffe, A. B., M. Trnjtenberg, and R. Henderson. "Geographic
Localization of Knowledge Spillovers as Evidenced by Patent
Citations." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 63(3), 1993, 577-98.
Japan Times. "Professor Guilty in Drugs Bribes Case."
Japan Times International Edition, April 18, 1999.
Jensen, R., and M. Thursby. "Proofs and Prototypes for Sale:
The Tale of University Licensing." American Economic Review, 91(1),
2001, 240-59.
Jones, B. D., and A. Vedlitz. "Higher Education Policies and
Economic Growth in the American States." Economic Development
Quarterly, 2(1), 1988, 78-87.
Jovanovic, B. "Selection and the Evolution of Industry."
Econometrica, 50(3), 1982, 649-70.
Jovanovic, B., and G. MacDonald. "The Life-Cycle of a
Competitive Industry." Journal of Political Economy, 102(2), 1994,
322-47.
Klepper, S. "Entry, Exit, Growth, and Innovation over the
Product Life Cycle." American Economic Review, 86(3), 1996, 562-83.
Klepper, S., and J. H. Miller. "Entry, Exit, and Shakeouts in
the United States in New Manufactured Products." International
Journal of Industrial Organization, 13(4), 1995, 567-91.
Knight, F. H. "Diminishing Returns from Investment."
Journal of Political Economy, 52(1), 1944, 26-47.
Lamoreaux, N. R., and K. L. Sokoloff. "Inventive Activity and
the Market for Technology in the United States, 1840-1920." Paper
presented at the Second Annual Roundtable for Engineering
Entrepreneur-ship Research, Atlanta, Georgia, March 21-23, 2002.
Landefeld, J. S., and B. M. Fraumeni. "Measuring the New
Economy." Survey of Current Business, 81(3), 2001, 23-40.
Lerner, A. P. "On the Marginal Product of Capital and the
Marginal Efficiency of Investment." Journal of Political Economy,
61(1), 1953, 1-14.
Lippman, S. A., and R. P. Rumelt. "Uncertain Imitability: An
Analysis of Interfirm Differences in Efficiency under Competition."
Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 1982, 418-38.
Mansfield, E. "Technical Change and the Rate of
Imitation." Econometrica, 29(4), 1961, 741-66.
-----. "Acadcmic Research Underlying Industrial Innovations:
Sources, Characteristics, and Financing." Review of Economics and
Statistics, 77(1), 1995, 55-65.
Marrett, C. B. "Influences on the Rise of New Organizations:
The Formation of Women's Medical Societies." Administrative
Science Quarterly, 25(1), 1980, 185-99.
McCarthy, J. D., M. Wolfson, D. P. Baker, and E. Mosakowski.
"The Founding of Social Movement Organizations," in Ecological
Models of Organizations, edited by G. R. Carroll. Cambridge: Ballinger,
1988, 71-82.
McKelvey, B. Organizational Systematics: Taxonomy, Evolution,
Classification. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1982.
McKelvey, B., and H. Aldrich. "Populations, Natural Selection,
and Applied Organizational Science." Administrative Science
Quarterly, 28(1), 1983, 101-28.
Miner, A. S., T. L. Amburgey, and T. M. Stearns.
"Interorganizational Linkages and Population Dynamics: Buffering
and Transformational Shields." Administrative Science Quarterly,
35(4), 1990, 689-713.
Nelson, R. R. "The Economics of Invention: A Survey of the
Literature." Journal of Business, 32(2), 1959, 101-27.
Pakes, A., and R. Ericson. "Empirical Implications of
Alternative Models of Firm Dynamics." Journal of Economic Theory,
79(1), 1998, 1-46.
Romanelli, E. "The Evolution of New Organizational
Forms." Annual Review of Sociology, 17, 1991, 79-103.
Romer, P. M. "Endogenous Technological Change." Journal
of Political Economy, 98(5, part 2, suppl), 1990, S71-S102.
Rudebusch, G. D. "How Fast Can the New Economy Grow?"
FRBSF Economic Letter, number 2000-05, February 25, 2000.
Schumpeter, J. A. The Theory of Economic Development, translated by
R. Opie. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1934.
Singh, J. V., and C. J. Lumsden. "Theory and Research in
Organizational Ecology." Annual Review of Sociology, 16, 1990,
161-95.
Sleeper, S. D. "The Role of Firm Capabilities in the Evolution
of the Laser Industry: The Making of a High-Tech Market." Ph.D.
dissertation, Carnegie Mellon University, 1998.
Smilor, R. W., G. Kozmetsky, and D. V. Gibson. Creating the
Technopolis: Linking Technology, Commercialization, and Economic
Development. Cambridge: Ballinger, 1988.
Stigler, G. J. Employment and Compensation in Education. New York:
National Bureau of Economic Research, 1950.
-----. "The Economics of Information." Journal of
Political Economy, 69(3), 1961, 213-25.
Stinchcombe, A. L. "Organizations and Social Structure,"
in Handbook of Organizations, edited by J. G. March. Chicago: Rand
McNally, 1965, 142-93.
-----. "University Administration of Research Space and
Teaching Loads: Mangers Who Do Not Know What Their Workers Are
Doing," in Information and Organizations, edited by A. L.
Stinchcombe. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1990, 312-40.
Thursby, J. G., and M. Thursby. "Who Is Selling the Ivory
Tower? Sources of Growth in University Licensing." Management
Science, 48(1), 2002, 90-104.
Torero, M. "Analyzing the Spillover Mechanism on the
Semiconductor Industry in the Silicon Valley and Route 128," in
Essays on Diffusion of Technical Change, edited by M. Torero. PhD diss.
UCLA Economics Department, 1998, 6-48.
Torero, M., M. R. Darby, and L. G. Zucker. "The Importance of
Intellectual Human Capital in the Birth of the Semiconductor
Industry." UCLA Working Paper, January 2001.
Tushman, M. L., and P. Anderson. "Technological
Discontinuities and Organizational Environments." Administrative
Science Quarterly, 31(1), 1986, 439-65.
Wedervang, F. Development of a Population of Industrial Firms: The
Structure of Manufacturing Industries in Norway, 1930-1948. Oslo:
Universitetsforlaget, 1965.
Zucker, L. G. "Combining Institutional Theory and Population
Ecology: No Legitimacy, No History." American Sociological Review,
54(4), 1989, 542-45.
Zucker, L. G., and M. R. Darby. "Virtuous Circles of
Productivity: Star Bioscientists and the Institutional Transformation of
Industry." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No.
5342, November 1995.
-----. "Star Scientists and Institutional Transformation:
Patterns of Invention and Innovation in the Formation of the
Biotechnology Industry." Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences, 93(23), 1996, 709-16.
-----. "Present at the Biotechnological Revolution:
Transformation of Technical Identity for a Large Incumbent
Pharmaceutical Firm." Research Policy, 26(4, 5), 1997, 429-46.
-----. "Capturing Technological Opportunity via Japan's
Star Scientists: Evidence from Japanese Firms' Biotech Patents and
Products." Journal of Technology Transfer, 26(1/2), 2001, 37-58.
Zucker, L. G., M. R. Darby, and J. Armstrong. "Geographically
Localized Knowledge: Spillovers or Markets?" Economic Inquiry,
36(1), 1998a, 65-86.
-----. "Commercializing Knowledge: University Science, Venture
Capital, and Firm Performance in Biotechnology." Management
Science, 48(1), 2002, 138-53.
Zucker, L. G., M. R. Darby, and M. B. Brewer. "Intellectual
Human Capital and the Birth of U.S. Biotechnology Enterprises."
American Economic Review, 88(1), 1998b, 290-306.
Zucker, L. G., M. R. Darby, and Y. Peng. "Fundamentals or
Population Dynamics and the Geographic Distribution of U.S.
Biotechnology Enterprises, 1976-1989." National Bureau of Economic
Research Working Paper No. 6414, February 1998c.
Zucker, L. G., M. R. Darby, and M. Torero. "Labor Mobility from Academe to Commerce." Journal of Labor Economics, 2002, in
press.
RELATED ARTICLE: ABBREVIATIONS
I/O: Industrial Organization
R&D: Research and Development
MICHAEL R. DARBY and LYNNE G. ZUCKER *
* An earlier version of this article was delivered as Michael R.
Darby's presidential address at the Western Economic Association
International Meetings, San Francisco, CA, July 6, 2001. The research
has been supported by grants from the University of California's
Industry-University Cooperative Research Program, the University of
California Systemwide Biotechnology Research and Education Program, and
the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation through the NBER. Research Program on
Industrial Technology and Productivity. We are indebted to many
coauthors, postdoctoral fellows, and graduate and undergraduate research
assistants who have contributed to the development of these ideas over
the past decade. This article is part of the NBER's research
program in productivity. Any opinions expressed are those of the authors
and not those of their employers or the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
Darby: Warren C. Cordner Professor of Money and Financial Markets,
Anderson Graduate School of Management, UCLA Box 951481, Los Angeles, CA
90095. Phone 1-310-825-4180, Fax 1-310-454-2748, E-mail
[email protected]
Zucker: Professor of Sociology and Policy Studies, UCLA Box 951551,
Los Angeles, CA 90095. Phone 1-310-825-9155, Fax 1-310-454-2748, E-mail
[email protected]