Labor market search and optimal retirement policy.
Bhattacharya, Joydeep ; Mulligan, Casey B. ; Reed, Robert R., III 等
A popular and long-standing view is that social security is a means
for young, unemployed people to "purchase" jobs from older
workers. Can social security, by encouraging retirement and hence
creating job vacancies for the young, improve the allocation of workers
to jobs? Maybe, according to a standard model of labor market search,
but public retirement programs currently pay the elderly substantially
more than their jobs are worth. An important effect is that retirement
reduces the value of other vacant jobs. Our results imply that recent
reforms aimed at reducing retirement incentives are likely to improve
labor market efficiency.
I. INTRODUCTION
The objective of this article is to formalize a popular argument
about the economic rationale for social security and public pension
programs in the United States and other countries. We construct a model
in which there can be significant frictions slowing the process of
matching workers with firms, and social security is a labor market
policy designed to remove old workers from the labor market. In this
sense, it can be said that social security is a means for young,
unemployed individuals to "purchase" jobs from older, employed
workers. President Franklin D. Roosevelt, in particular, in one of his
fireside chats suggested that this would be an important goal for social
security:
The program for Social Security now pending
before the Congress is a necessary part of the
future unemployment policy of the Government.
... It proposes, by means of old-age pensions, to
help those who have reached the age of retirement
to give up their jobs and thus give to the younger
generation greater opportunities for work and to
give all a feeling of security as they look toward
their old age. (Roosevelt 1938, 134-35)
This position on social security continues to receive some support,
at least enough to receive serious consideration in recent social
security debates. In recent discussion about the retirement earnings
test in Congress, many agreed with the following perspective:
"Social Security, when it was created in 1935, sought to achieve
two goals--moving older workers out of the workforce to make way for
younger workers, and to partially replace lost income due to
retirement" (Testimony of Honorable John J. Rhodes III in Social
Security Retirement Test 1991). These debates are not unique to the
United States. As is well known, European countries have recently
devoted much attention to youth unemployment. As a result, public
pension programs have become more generous and increasingly used to
encourage labor force withdrawal among older workers.
Although public pension programs have been used in many countries
as age-targeted employment policies, there has been little work aimed at
understanding their implications for the market at the aggregate level.
In this article we begin to address whether policies aimed at
discouraging work among the elderly, and thereby creating job vacancies
for the young, can improve the allocation of workers to jobs in the
labor market. In particular, the idea that continued employment by the
old contributes to increased youth unemployment implies that the life
cycle contributes to congestion problems in the labor market.
Accordingly, an important aspect of a modeling approach aimed at
addressing these issues should be a setting in which unemployment is an
equilibrium phenomenon, and the labor market participation decisions of
workers impose a negative externality on the pool of the unemployed.
We introduce a simple model of labor market search along the lines
of Mortensen (1982) and Pissarides (2000) extended to include retirement
decisions and show how the optimality of induced retirement depends on
the model's parameter values, some of which imply that the social
value of retirement exceeds the private value while other parameter
values imply that the private value exceeds the social value. We then
consider the parameter values implying the largest wedge between private
and social retirement values and show that even in this extreme case,
optimal retirement policy does much less to encourage retirement than do
the policies used by governments around the world. To put it simply,
labor market search theory provides at best only a partial justification
for publicly induced retirement; public retirement programs pay the
elderly substantially more than labor market search theory implies that
their jobs are worth. An important effect, ignored in arguments for
policy-induced retirement, is that the creation of a vacant job by a
retirement reduces the value of other vacant jobs. In this regard, our
results might be interpreted as either a critique of public retirement
policy or as a puzzle to be explained by positive theories of the public
sector.
Section II begins with an overview of retirement-inducing policies
used around the world. Section III presents a standard model of search,
simplified, amended, and reinterpreted to allow for a retirement
decision. Section IV considers an extreme parameterization of the model
to show that even if it is the case that the social value of retirement
exceeds the private value, an optimal retirement program does much less
to induce retirement than do observed programs. Section V provides some
concluding comments and discusses the possible welfare effects of recent
reforms and policy proposals aimed at reducing retirement incentives and
thereby promoting labor market participation among older workers.
II. AN OVERVIEW OF RETIREMENT-INDUCING POLICIES AROUND THE WORLD
There is a growing body of literature comparing public pension
systems and their retirement incentives across countries and over time.
We report some of the main results from that work. The purpose of our
article here is not to conduct a detailed statistical analysis but
merely to highlight the empirical regularities relevant to a theoretical
study of publicly induced retirement. The most conspicuous (and
theoretically most relevant) regularity is that implicit earnings tax
rates are highest for the elderly.
Public Policies Encourage Retirement
As of 1995, over 100 countries had public pension programs. (1)
Among the 88 of those countries reporting to the U.S. Social Security
Administration sufficient detail of their public pension benefit
formulas, 75% pay pension benefits in such a way as to discourage work
by its elderly citizens. The most typical means by which benefit
formulas induce retirement is remarkably transparent: Retirement is a
necessary condition for receiving public pension benefits, and no credit
is given to those who decide to retire later and collect benefits for
fewer years. Other countries had more complicated benefit formulas
extending some less-than-actuarially fair credits to those who delay
retirement, or allowing employed elderly to collect partial benefits, or
both (the case, until the year 2000, for U.S. Social Security for
elderly aged 65-69). But the more complicated formulas have much the
same effect as the simple one: Elderly labor income is implicitly taxed.
At least in higher-income countries, the rates of implicit taxation
are enormous. Although an exact calculation of marginal tax rates is
complicated due to nonlinearities and other details of benefit formulas,
the reason for the high rates is simple: The elderly must retire to
obtain full benefits, and full benefits are typically a very large
fraction of the earnings enjoyed if one does not retire. Gruber and Wise
(1999, table 1, based on even more detailed computations of their
coauthors) attempt to quantify the rates of implicit taxation for 11
countries. According to their calculations for the early 1990s, the
"typical" implicit tax rate for "someone of retirement
age" ranges from roughly 20% for Japan, United States, and Canada,
to more than 80% for Belgium and the Netherlands. (2)
Another way to appreciate the quantitative significance of the
implicit taxation of elderly labor income by public pension programs is
to notice the prevalence of 100% (!) marginal tax rates. Mulligan (1998)
discusses in some detail a number of examples, including U.S. Social
Security benefit formulas between 1939 and 1971, under which retirees
lost all of their Social Security benefits if their earnings exceeded a
rather low earnings limit by even $1. Other American examples of 100%
marginal tax rates can be found prior to the Social Security Act in U.S.
state-administered old age assistance programs, which typically
implicitly taxed earnings at a 100% rate (US Congress, Joint Economic
Committee 1966, 26-27). Spain is one of several international examples
where their elderly are not allowed to collect a government pension if
they earn any labor income at all (Boldrin et al. 1999, 322; Social
Security Administration 1995, 330), and those benefits are typically
close to or more than what the pensioner would have earned after taxes
if working (Boldrin et al. 1999).
Perhaps these implicit taxes are not distortionary because they are
not enforced or because other government regulations prohibit people
from changing their behavior in response to them? There are two reasons
to be skeptical of such a claim. First, Gruber and Wise (1999) show that
retirement behavior is highly correlated across countries and across age
groups with the measured incentives. (3) Second, the stated purpose of
the implicit tax provision is often to encourage retirement
(Sala-i-Martin 1996; Gruber and Wise 1999, 31).
Pensions are not the only public programs encouraging retirement.
"Disability insurance" and "unemployment insurance"
programs "essentially provide early retirement benefits before the
official Social Security early retirement age" (Gruber and Wise
1999, 9) in many countries. Tax-favored company pensions, mandatory
defined benefit company pensions, and public health insurance are some
other government policies that may substantially induce retirement.
Marginal (Implicit + Explicit) Tax Rates Are Highest for the Old
Perhaps it is unsurprising that public policies discourage work,
because governments need to raise revenue or may want to assist the
poor. But another feature of public pension programs, and government
policy in general, is that elderly work is discouraged more than young
work. Hence, although payroll tax rates are paid by young and old
workers and can be large in many countries more than 10% in the United
States and nearly 50% in Egypt, Italy, and the Netherlands--public
pension benefit formulas in many countries substantially reduce the
incentive to work beyond its reduction due to payroll and income
taxation.
Income taxes, payroll taxes, and public pension benefits are not
the only public policies discouraging work. Minimum wages, unemployment
compensation, welfare payments, work week restrictions, and other
policies have the effect of discouraging work, and a full analysis of
public policy and work incentives would include detailed calculations of
the effects of these programs. However, two observations strongly
suggest that, taken together, the various public policies tax elderly
labor income at much higher marginal rates. First of all, a number of
these programs--such as unemployment and welfare--affect work incentives
for both elderly and young people. Often unemployment and welfare
payments are most generous for the elderly and implicitly tax elderly
labor earnings at higher rates. Indeed, the unemployment insurance
programs in Belgium, Finland, and other countries are hard to
distinguish from public pension programs in terms of their
intergenerational incidence and their age profile of marginal tax rates.
(4) Second, it seems that because of public pension programs, the
prevalence of 100% and near-100% marginal tax rates is much higher among
the elderly than among the young (as a consequence of tax and other
policies), and as a result work is so much more prevalent among the
young.
Pensions Designed This Way Have Existed for Many Decades
For decades, social security benefit formulas have implicitly taxed
labor income of the elderly. To prove this, Mulligan (2000) constructs
an international data set for the years 1958, 1975, and 1995 based on
Social Security Administration reports (various issues). It was somewhat
more common in 1958 and 1975 for benefit formulas to induce retirement
with the simpler formula making retirement a necessary condition for
receiving public pension benefits (e.g., the United States did so in
1958 but not in 1995). Delayed retirement credits and gradual phase-out
of benefits with earnings were more common in 1995, so it might be said
that retirement was induced more dramatically in 1958 and 1975. However,
the size of the benefit forgone by the elderly worker has grown over
time relative to what a retiree would have earned, so in this sense
benefit formulas induce retirement more in recent years. More research
is required to determine exactly how the incentive to retire has changed
over the years in various countries, but it is clear that for decades
public pension benefits have provided an important incentive to retire.
In April 2000, the earnings test was lifted for workers age 65 and
over in the United States. Workers in this age bracket now have a
greater incentive to continue working, but the social security program
still discourages their work. Namely, even without penalties in the form
of reduced benefits, older workers are still liable for the payroll tax,
and the payment of this tax (more precisely, the accrual of
payroll-taxable earnings) does not enhance their ultimate social
security benefit to the degree that it would for younger workers. We
also point out that the very recent lack of social security benefit
penalties for elderly work in the United States is unusual in the
context of the international history of social security.
III. THE BASIC MODEL
Tastes and Technology
With these observations of public policies in mind, we ask whether
publicly induced retirement can alleviate congestion problems in the
labor market induced by the life cycle. We consider a simple one-period
extension of the standard Mortensen (1982) and Pissarides (2000) model.
As in the standard search model of the labor market, there are two
groups of agents: workers and firms. Both types of agents derive utility
from income and are risk-neutral.
Workers are heterogeneous in exactly two dimensions. First, some
workers are matched with an employer, and some are unmatched. We refer
to workers that begin the period matched with employers as
"old" workers and the initially unemployed as
"young" workers, and their population shares as [lambda] and
(1-[lambda]), respectively. (5) Second, workers also differ in their
nonpecuniary costs of working. To be specific, we let [[gamma].sub.i]
represent the cost of working for worker i. One may interpret this cost
as the opportunity cost of working in terms of lost leisure time. These
costs of working may vary across cohorts. The cost of working for old
workers is described by the cumulative distribution function,
[F.sub.1]([gamma]), whereas the cost for young workers is described by
[F.sub.0]([gamma]). One interesting case has old workers having a higher
value of leisure time than young workers, so that [F.sub.1]([gamma])
first-order stochastically dominates [F.sub.0]([gamma])or
[F.sub.1]([gamma])<[F.sub.0]([gamma]). (6) As in the standard search
model of the labor market, firms take the output from the match and sell
it on the market at price p. (7) Given that both the firm and the worker
have linear preferences over income, the total surplus created on
filling a vacancy with a worker i is p - [[gamma].sub.i]. (8)
Technically, this is a departure from the standard
Mortensen-Pissarides model (whose workers have homogeneous preferences
for leisure) because one group of workers, those who are initially
employed, will on average have a higher value of leisure time than those
who are not endowed with jobs. The higher value of leisure time among
the employed provides an economic motivation for a process like
retirement in which older workers are replaced by younger workers. It
also permits a straightforward calculation of a "retirement
rate" in the interval (0,1). Furthermore, some studies have found
that the value of leisure time (interpreted literally) is an important
determinant of who and how many retire. (9)
Worker-firm matches are made in one of two ways. First, matches are
part of the initial conditions for so-called old workers. Second, a
young worker can be matched with a firm, or an unmatched firm with a
young worker, by "search." Job search costs s for each worker,
and for simplicity, worker search costs nothing for firms. Job searchers
and firms with vacancies are brought together according to a matching
technology M. The matching technology, M(U,V), denotes the aggregate
number of matches as a function of the aggregate number of searchers U
and aggregate number of vacancies V. The matching technology is
stochastic and undiscriminating--namely, all searchers enjoy the same ex
ante probability of a match m = M/U and all employers posting a vacancy
enjoy the same ex ante probability of a match M/V. Because the matching
technology exhibits constant returns to scale, we let m = m([theta]) =
M(1,V/U) where [theta] = V/U is the number of vacancies per worker and
therefore may be viewed as the degree of labor market tightness.
Initial worker firm matches can be dissolved, in which case there
is no surplus associated with the initial worker. We interpret this
situation as retirement, with the retiree consuming leisure and his or
her former employer participating in the aforementioned matching process
by posting the vacancy. (10) There are two possibilities in which young
workers may consume leisure. The first, which might be called
unemployment, occurs when a worker searches for a job but does not find
one. The second, which might be called out of the labor force, occurs
when a worker does not search at all.
Note that there is a direct link between the amount of retirement
and the number of job vacancies in our model. We focus on a setting
where there is a fixed potential stock of vacancies that is dictated by
the number of old workers. As has been widely noted (see, for example,
the discussion in Layard et al. 1991), the idea of removing old workers
from the labor market to enhance the employment possibilities for the
young is based in large part on the partial equilibrium idea of a fixed
stock of vacancies. (11) More general equilibrium work needs to be done,
but we expect that general equilibrium models would still allow for the
important possibility that retirement makes search more difficult for
other employers searching for employees.
Efficient Allocations
An efficient allocation is the aggregate surplus-maximizing list of
retirees, job searchers, and firms posting vacancies, given the
economy's matching technology and the costs of searching. An
efficient allocation involves: (a) all unmatched employers posting their
vacancies, (b) retirement for the initially matched workers with high
nonpecuniary costs of work (relative to the others initially matched),
and (c) job search among the initially unmatched workers with low
nonpecuniary costs of work (relative to the others initially unmatched).
Let [[gamma]*.sub.1] and [[gamma]*.sub.0] represent the
planner's choices for the critical values of the costs of working
for the initially matched and unmatched respectively. Let [[PHI]*.sub.1]
= [F.sub.1]([[gamma]*.sub.1]) and [PHI]*.sub.0] =
[F.sub.0]([[gamma]*.sub.0]) represent the planner's choices for the
fractions of the initially matched who do not retire and the unmatched
who choose to search, respectively. The social surplus W in the economy
is, as functions of the number of old workers [[PHI].sub.1] and young
searchers [[PHI].sub.0],
given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The first term is the aggregate surplus resulting from matches
initially filled with old workers, calculated by adding p - [gamma] for
each old person who works (i.e., who has [gamma] < [F.sup.-1.sub.1]
[[[PHI].sub.1]]). The second term is the average surplus of matches with
successful young searchers, whose quantity is M and whose average
surplus is in square brackets. The final term is the total lost surplus
incurred by all young workers who incur the costs of search.
From the description of aggregate surplus, we can derive conditions
for the efficient amount of retirement and job search. Efficient
retirement is described by
(2) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The left-hand side represents the marginal social surplus of less
retirement, and the right-hand side is the social marginal cost of less
retirement. Of particular importance for our analysis is the last term,
which is the effect of retirement by the marginal worker on the surplus
of inframarginal workers because, as we will show, it will be ignored by
a person choosing retirement solely to maximize the joint surplus of
himself and his employer.
The efficient amount of labor market participation by the young is
given by
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The efficient choice of job search recognizes that the marginal
searcher has probability m of finding a job and hence probability
m([theta]) of enhancing surplus by p minus [[gamma]*.sub.0]. But there
are two social costs of search: the search cost s and the marginal
searcher's effect on the surplus of others. This second cost is the
product of the inframarginal searchers' potential surplus (p -
[E.sub.0][gamma]) and the effect [theta]m'([theta]) of additional
search on job finding by the inframarginal searchers.
Equilibrium Retirement, with Public Policy
In this section, we seek to determine the equilibrium allocations
of workers to jobs and the unemployment rate and model some simple
public policies that might affect these decisions. We suppose that the
government can observe whether a worker is matched and producing, and
levies a tax [T.sub.1] on (or, if [T.sub.1] < 0, pays a subsidy to)
each old person, regardless of his or her retirement status, and a tax
To on each young person. The government pays [B.sub.1] to (or, if
[B.sub.1] < 0, taxes) old nonworkers (aka, retirees) and [B.sub.0] to
young nonworkers.
We follow those in the literature and suppose that the net postfisc
surplus, (p - [gamma]), derived from work is split between workers and
firms with shares [beta] and (1 - [beta]), respectively. For simplicity,
we assume that workers' outside options do not affect the
bargaining between workers and firms. That is, we assume that workers
have zero threat points and that the outside options of retirement or
unemployment benefits do not affect the determination of wages. This is
equivalent to assuming that workers cannot actively engage in on-the-job
search and is adopted so that there are no wage distortions resulting
from either the public pension or unemployment programs. As we will
describe, the only margin in which public policy affects labor market
activity is through the labor market participation decision of each
group of workers.
Each initially matched old worker is assumed to decide jointly with
his or her employer whether or not to retire. Each young agent,
initially unemployed, is assumed to decide on her own whether or not to
search, based only on her expected costs and benefits. In other words,
the search decision is not made jointly by the young, old, and the
young's ultimate employer, because the essence of the search
friction is that searchers and employers do not know who are their
ultimate match partners. As we shall show, distortionary public policy
can in principle help coordinate some of these decisions.
Given matching probabilities, the cost of searching, distributions
of working costs, government policy ([B.sub.1], [T.sub.1], [B.sub.0],
[T.sub.0]), and a sharing parameter [beta], an equilibrium allocation is
a list of retirees, job searchers, and firms posting vacancies, so that
(i) the government budget balances; (ii) a job searcher's match
probability is M (U,V)/U and an employee searcher's match
probability is M(U, V)/V, where U and V are the population measures of
job searchers and employee searchers, respectively; (iii) a young person
cannot improve his or her expected surplus by changing the decision to
search or not; and (iv) an old person and his or her employer cannot
improve their joint expected surplus by changing the person's
retirement status.
An equilibrium can be characterized algebraically as a pair of
scalars [[PHI].sub.1] and [[PHI].sub.0] satisfying:
(i) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
(ii) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
(iii) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
(iv) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where [E.sub.0][gamma] is the average cost of work among those
young people searching for a job.
Condition (i) is the government budget constraint, where taxes are
collected from all persons and benefits are paid to retirees and young
nonworkers. Second, condition (ii) accounts for U and V, the number of
job searchers and job vacancies. Third, condition (iii) defines the
marginal retiree. The left-hand side represents the total surplus from
maintaining the match between the firm and the marginal retiree. In
contrast, the right-hand side provides the total surplus to the firm and
the worker if the individual retires. The first term, [B.sub.1], is the
retirement benefit received by the retiree, whereas the second term is
the expected net surplus for the firm from searching for a young worker
in the labor market. In equilibrium, the firm and the worker jointly
determine the retirement decision so that the worker, together with the
original employer, is indifferent between remaining employed and
retiring (in which case benefit [B.sub.1] is collected and a vacancy is
created).
Notice that [T.sub.0] and [T.sub.1] do not enter (iii) because
those particular taxes are collected (subsidies paid) regardless of
labor market status, whereas [B.sub.1] is viewed as benefit of
retirement from the point of view of a potential retiree and his or her
employer because it is an outside source of income that unlike [T.sub.1]
is paid only conditional on retirement. Potential retiree and employer
are maximizing joint surplus, so [beta] enters (iii) only to the extent
that it determines the employer's surplus after retirement.
Finally, condition (iv) defines the marginal job searcher, who is
indifferent between the employment benefit and the expected proceeds
from search. The left-hand side represents the surplus received by
choosing not to search for a job because the worker will definitely
receive unemployment benefits. In contrast, the right-hand side is the
total net surplus from choosing to search for a job in the labor market.
The first term is the expected surplus obtained from working, and the
second term is the surplus obtained if the worker cannot find
employment. Finally, regardless of the labor market outcome resulting
from participating in the labor market, the worker bears the costs of
job search.
This algebraic characterization (i) (iv) of an equilibrium permits
easy proofs of our two main propositions.
PROPOSITION 1. For any [beta], [gamma], s [greater than or equal
to] 0, any distribution functions [F.sub.0](*) and [F.sub.1](*), and any
homogeneous function M(*) defined on [[0,1].sub.2], there exists a
government policy ([T.sub.0], [T.sub.1], [B.sub.0], [B.sub.1])
consistent with an efficient equilibrium.
Proof We prove Proposition 1 by constructing a government policy
that makes the efficient [[PHI]*.sub.1] and [[PHI]*.sub.0] consistent
with equilibrium. First, pick [B.sub.1] = [m'([theta]) - (1 -
[beta])m([theta])(U/V)] (p - [E.sub.0][gamma]), calculating U, V, and
[E.sub.0][gamma] from an efficient allocation. Plugging this into
equilibrium condition (iii), we have that the equilibrium retirement
margin is efficient. Second, pick [B.sub.0] -
[beta]([[theta]m'([theta])]/m[[theta]])(p - [E.sub.0][gamma] - (1 -
[beta])(s/m[[theta]]). Plugging this into equilibrium condition (iv), we
have that the equilibrium search margin is efficient. Third, pick any
([T.sub.0], [T.sub.1] satisfying the government budget constraint for
the ([B.sub.0], [B.sub.1]) calculated above.
PROPOSITION 2. If the elasticity of m ([theta]) is constant and
equal to 1 - [beta], then a government policy consistent with an
efficient equilibrium has [B.sub.1] = O, and [B.sub.0] [greater than or
equal to] 0.
Proof Use Proposition 1's formula for efficient [B.sub.1] to
show that it is zero when the elasticity of m([theta]) is constant and
equal to 1 - [beta]. Use Proposition 1's formula for efficient
[B.sub.0], and the equilibrium condition (iv), to show it is > ( = )
zero as the work cost of the marginal searcher is > ( = ) the work
cost of the average searcher.
Proposition 1 says that efficient allocations are consistent with
equilibrium with the right government policy. Proposition 2 considers a
special case explored by Hosios (1990), where the sharing parameter
[beta] is related to the elasticity of the matching function. Hosios
(1990) finds that if the elasticity of the matching technology is the
same as the worker's degree of bargaining power, the supply of job
vacancies is efficient without any taxes or government transfers. In
contrast to his results, we find that only the retirement decision will
be efficient if the elasticity of the matching technology is the same as
the firm's degree of bargaining power. However, due to the
differing degrees of leisure costs and access to jobs, the efficient
labor market participation decision among the young still requires an
unemployment subsidy. In summary, Proposition 2 provides conditions
where governments do not need a retirement policy to generate labor
market efficiency, but an optimal unemployment policy is still required.
In Hosios (1990), all workers have the same access to the labor market
and disutility of work so that labor market efficiency is guaranteed
under a particular matching function.
Propositions 1 and 2 are important for understanding the
quantitative relationships between search and retirement, so we explore
them further. Notice that from the social point of view, there are three
distortions of the equilibrium retirement decision. The first is the
retirement subsidy (or tax, if [B.sub.1] < 0) seen on the right-hand
side of (iii). Second, the potential retiree and his or her employer put
some value on creating a vacancy according to the average match rate
M/V. When M is homogeneous, and the number of matches are at least
somewhat elastic to the number unemployed, the average match rate
exceeds the marginal match rate [delta]M/[delta]V that is relevant from
the social point of view. This second distortion tends to cause
employers (in agreement with their potential retirees) to excessively
encourage retirement. Third, equilibrium retirement decisions do not
consider the creation of surplus for the unemployed group, which is the
product of the marginal match rate and the average surplus [beta](P -
[E.sub.0][gamma]) for those matched. By itself, this third distortion
means that an equilibrium has too little retirement. The second
distortion can overwhelm the third, as is the case when [beta] is small
and/or the gap between marginal and average match rates is large, or
vice versa. The optimal retirement subsidy is positive when the third
distortion dominates, and negative when the second dominates.
To isolate and quantitatively evaluate the third distortion,
consider the limiting case of a linear matching function M(U,V) = V.
Search is very efficient in this limiting case, because all vacancies
costlessly find a match with probability one, although inefficient in an
important sense which we will demonstrate. (12) Now equilibrium
condition (iii) becomes (iii)':
(iii)' p - [F.sup.-1.sub.1]([[PHI].sub,1]) = [B.sub.1] + (1 -
[beta])(p - [E.sub.o][gamma]).
Condition (iii)' allows us to compute the efficient retirement
subsidy (namely, that for which equilibrium and planned retirement
coincide), in this case [B.sub.1] = [beta] (p - [E.sub.0][gamma]). In
words, the efficient retirement subsidy is that surplus received by the
employee who takes over the job of the retiree because that future
employee is not at the table when employer and potential retiree make
the retirement decision. Or, using the optimal retirement condition for
the planner facing a linear matching function, we see that the optimal
retirement subsidy equates the disutility of work of the marginal
retiree ([F.sup.-1.sub.1] [[[PHI]*.sub.1]]) with the average disutility
of work among the unemployed ([E.sub.0][gamma]).
Furthermore, in this special case, it is quite clear that the
optimal labor market policy should be age-targeted. That is, the optimal
retirement policy definitely affects labor market participation among
both the young and the old so that the unemployment and pension policies
are interdependent. To see this, suppose that [E.sub.0][gamma] = 0. On
substituting the optimal pension subsidy [B.sub.1] into the retirement
condition (iii), we find that all workers who incur any loss of utility
from working will choose to retire. That is, in this case,
[[gamma]*.sub.1] = 0. If old workers experience any additional desire
for leisure relative to their youth, the optimal retirement policy
encourages all of the old workers to retire.
We can also examine how the optimal pension and unemployment
policies affect labor market participation among young workers. In the
case of the linear matching technology, [B.sub.0] = [beta]p - (1 -
[beta])s(U/V). On substitution into the labor market participation
condition for the young, we find that [[gamma]*.sub.0] =
-(s/m[[theta]]). Because all workers must incur the costs of search,
each worker imposes a congestion externality on all other young
individuals who choose to look for jobs. Therefore, in an effort to
conserve on search costs in the labor market, the optimal unemployment
policy would encourage some of the young (even though they derive
utility from working) to withdraw from the labor market. Thus, despite
our use of a static model for tractability, our results demonstrate that
the optimal labor market policy requires that public pension programs
and unemployment policies are dynamically connected. (13)
The special linear matching function permits an intuitive
calculation of the magnitude of the optimal retirement subsidy, although
we point out that the optimal subsidy is especially big in the linear
case because there is no gap between average and marginal match rates
(see our previous discussion of the second distortion). A precise
calculation requires precise estimates of the sharing parameter [beta]
and the average disutility of work among the unemployed (LOT), but
notice how [B.sub.1] = [beta](p - [E.sub.0][gamma]) implies that an
average young worker with a job who suffered a reduction in his or her
after-tax earnings in the amount [B.sub.1] would still have a
nonnegative surplus from working. (14) We believe that in reality,
50-80% reductions in earnings would eliminate the surplus and then
some--from working for a great many young workers (e.g., practically all
women workers, if it is indeed the case that their labor supply is wage
elastic), so the formula [B.sub.1] = [beta] (p - [E.sub.0][gamma])
implies that optimal elderly earnings tax rates would be no greater than
25-50% in the linear case. Given that the optimal elderly earnings tax
rates are even smaller in the nonlinear cases, the retirement subsidies
of 50% and higher seen in several European countries are excessive.
IV. LIMITS ON THE OPTIMAL RETIREMENT INCENTIVE
As long as the matching function is nonlinear, the formula
[B.sub.1] = [beta](p - [F.sub.0][gamma]) overstates the optimal
retirement subsidy. This effect occurs because it ignores the
possibility that the creation of a job vacancy by a retirement lowers
the probability that other job vacancies get filled. The optimal
retirement subsidy for nonlinear matching functions is shown in the
proof of Proposition 1, which we rewrite below:
(4) [ILLUSTRATION OMITTED]
The first two terms show exactly how the optimal retirement subsidy
is less in the nonlinear case. First, subtracted from [beta] in
parentheses is the elasticity of M with respect to V, which is
proportional to the gap between the average and marginal match rates
(M/V and [delta]M/[delta]V). This first reduction can be substantial,
because [alpha] has been estimated in the range of 0.4 to 0.7. (15) In
other words, the worker's share [beta] has to exceed 0.4 if the
optimal retirement subsidy were even to be positive! With [beta] = 0.5,
and the lower estimate of [alpha] = 0.4, the ([beta] - [alpha]) alone is
80% smaller than [beta] ([0.5-0.4]/ 0.5 = 0.2). In other words, even if
M/V were arbitrarily close to one, and [E.sub.0][gamma] were zero (so
that [beta][p - [E.sub.0][gamma]] were as large as employee earnings),
the optimal implicit tax on elderly earnings is only 20%. Most of the
countries studied by Gruber and Wise have implicit taxes in excess of
this amount.
The second term is M/V, which of course is less than one with the
nonlinear matching function and reflects the fact that some retirements
will create vacancies that go unmatched. To quantify this term, we need
to further parameterize our model and carefully distinguish stocks from
flows. In particular, "additional" matches in our
single-period model are more realistically interpreted as matches that
occur more rapidly in the presence of an additional vacancy than they
would otherwise. In other words, all vacancies find a worker with very
high probability if they wait long enough. M/V< 1 is a way to
capture, in our static model, the fact that a new vacancy can expect to
go unused for some period of time. If we let r denote the interest rate,
t time, and [delta] the instantaneous hazard at which a vacancy finds a
match, a continuous-time expression for M/V is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
For a vacancy with productive capacity one, the numerator is the
expected present value of production, accounting for the fact that a
match may take some time to occur. The denominator is the present value
of production if the match were instantaneous. Because the expected
duration of a vacancy (1/[delta]) is measured in months, [delta] is much
larger than r and, for quantitative purposes, we can treat M/V as one.
(16)
Table 1 presents calculations of the optimal retirement subsidy
using formula (4) and various values for the parameters [alpha], [beta],
and [E.sub.0][gamma]. To facilitate comparisons with quantitative
studies of taxes and labor supply, we express the optimal subsidy and
work disutility as fractions of worker earnings. Worker earnings are
computed in our model by subtracting the employer surplus from worker
productivity (i.e., earnings are p - [1 - [beta]][p -
[E.sub.0][gamma]]).
The upper left cell reports the calculation discussed: The optimal
implicit tax rate is 20% when [alpha] = 0.4, [beta] = 0.5, and
[E.sub.0][gamma] = 0. The top half of the table shows how the optimal
rate falls with [alpha] and [E.sub.0][gamma]. The bottom half fixes
[alpha] = 0.5 and varies the employee's share [beta]. Optimal tax
rates are small unless we use [beta] well in excess of 0.5. Even [beta]
= 1 cannot justify elderly implicit tax rates in excess of 50%, as
observed in a number of European countries.
V. CONCLUSIONS
Many countries around the world use public policy, especially
Social Security programs, to induce their elder citizens to retire. An
important motive behind such policy is to create job vacancies that can
be occupied by the young. In this article we seek to evaluate the
strength of the foundations underlying this rhetoric. To that end, we
produce a relatively standard search model with young and old workers
and firms. That model allows for the possibility of significant
frictions in the process of matching workers with firms. We ask whether
policy-induced retirement can be part of an efficient labor market
search and matching equilibrium. In other words, is there really any
reason for governments to intervene in elderly labor markets on behalf
of the young and the unemployed?
Even when the model exhibits significant frictions, and inefficient
labor market allocations without government intervention, it may be the
case that there is too much retirement, in which case the optimal policy
discourages retirement rather than encouraging it. Other cases imply
that an efficient equilibrium can be supported with a positive subsidy
to the old, but that its size is much smaller than what real-world
governments routinely provide. This is primarily because the planner
takes into account the negative effect on aggregate matching
possibilities of an additional vacancy, an effect the empirical
literature suggests to be strong. The Social Security rhetoric, on the
other hand, ignores this effect, overemphasizing the beneficial effects
of an additional vacancy on those searching for jobs. In addition, we
find that when the Hosios (1990) condition is applied to our model, the
amount of retirement is optimal without any government intervention, but
the amount of labor market participation by the young is inefficient. In
short, many societies excessively induce retirement by the elderly, at
least from the standpoint of efficiency as understood in standard search
models. Thus, our results imply that recent public pension and other
policy reforms aimed at reducing retirement incentives (such as the
elimination of the earnings test) are likely to improve labor market
welfare.
There are a number of possible extensions of our framework to
consider. The present analysis studies the impact of public pension
programs on labor market activity assuming that the value of each match
with an old worker is known and the worker and the firm jointly
determine the retirement decision. Another important aspect of public
pension reform involves the impact of Social Security on labor market
contracts and aggregate labor market activity. Notably, old workers may
experience health shocks that are privately known and adversely affect
the firm's surplus more than for a given worker. In this regard,
publicly induced retirement policies may be important because they help
avoid adverse selection problems from retaining older workers. However,
such an explanation for Social Security must also involve a rationale
for why such contracts must be publicly rather than privately provided.
This remains a challenging but important area for future research on the
labor market implications of public pension programs. (17)
TABLE A-1
Summary Statistics
Mean SD
Reliance on EIG 0.014 0.010
taxation
Reliance on general 0.311 0.135
sales taxation
Reliance on personal 0.248 0.156
income taxation
Percent of population 0.011 0.004
85 years or older
Percent of population 0.116 0.021
65 years or older
State per capita income 13231 7673
State per capita federal 408.6 284
transfers
State per capita debt 974 1167
State unemployment rate 1.8 18
Same party-Democrat 0.322 0.467
(Yes = 1)
Same party-Republican 0.152 0.359
(Yes = 1)
Election year dummy 0.277 0.448
(Yes = 1)
Note: N = 1536, annual data (1968-99) for all 48
contiguous states.
TABLE 1
The Optimal Tax Rate on Elderly Earnings
(B1/[p - (1 - [beta])(p-[E.sub.0][gamma])], Assuming (M/V
[approximately equal to] 1)
Young Work Disutility as a
Fraction of Earnings,
[E.sub.0][gamma]/p -
(1 - [beta])(p - [E.sub.0]
[gamma])]
Alpha Beta 0 0.2 0.4 0.6
0.4 0.5 0.20 0.16 0.12 0.08
0.5 0.5 0 0 0 0
0.6 0.5 -0.20 -0.16 -0.12 -0.08
0.7 0.5 -0.40 -0.32 -0.24 -0.16
0.5 0.6 0.17 0.13 0.10 0.07
0.5 0.7 0.29 0.23 0.17 0.11
0.5 0.8 0.38 0.30 0.22 0.15
0.5 0.9 0.44 0.36 0.27 0.18
0.5 1.0 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20
(1.) Data in this paragraph are reported and described in more
detail by Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin (1999, 2004) and Sala-i-Martin
(1996).
(2.) Gruber and Wise (1999) point out that in any one country,
marginal implicit rates vary with earnings, age, calendar year, and
other variables. For a person of age t in the early 1990s, where t is
between the early retirement age (age 60 in 9 of the 11 countries they
study) and 69, they compute for a worker of median earnings the present
value of public pension benefits forgone by delaying retirement one year
and express it as a fraction of earnings (after income and payroll
taxes) for that year, a fraction [[tau].sub.t] that can be interpreted
as an implicit tax rate. They sum [[tau].sub.t], between the early
retirement age and t = 69, then divide their sum by the number of years
in the sum (10 years are in the sum for 9 of the 11 countries they
study) to arrive at the "typical" implicit tax rate for
"someone of retirement age" reported in the text.
(3.) For a discussion on the implications of the earnings test for
the labor supply behavior of older workers, see Baker and Benjamin
(1999), Burtless and Moffit (1984), Disney and Tanner (2000), Friedberg
(2000), and Gruber and Orszag (2003).
(4.) For international examples, see Social Security Administration
(1995) and Gruber and Wise (1999). Leimer (1998, 16-17) reports results
for the American disability insurance program.
(5.) In Shimer (2001), all workers are infinitely lived, but in
each period a new generation of workers are born. "Young"
workers are those who were born in the recent past. Because young
workers have had less time to participate in the labor market, they are
more likely to be unemployed than "older" workers.
(6.) See Hadar and Russell (1969) and Tesfatsion (1976) for
definitions and discussion.
(7.) Because the price of output is exogenous, the model is a
partial equilibrium setting in which workers and consumers are viewed as
separate groups of agents.
(8.) An alternative interpretation is that [[gamma].sub.i]
represents the adverse health consequences of aging, thereby lowering a
worker's level of productivity.
(9.) See Costa (1998), Robinson et al. (1982), Parnes and Nestel
(1981), and Schulz (2001) for discussion.
(10.) An alternative (but more complicated) model would have
employer and potential retiree jointly making a contingency plan for
search and retirement. Namely, the firm would (at some cost) begin
searching for a young worker, and retirement could be conditional on the
firm's success in the search. This would be a form of
"on-the-job search" on the part of employers.
(11.) Although retirement programs in many countries have been
introduced to alleviate problems with unemployment, Layard et al. (1991)
argue that instead these policies have in fact contributed to more
unemployment.
(12.) For the sake of simplicity, we do not consider the case V
> U, in which case the more reasonable linear matching function would
be M(U, V) = U.
(13.) Our modeling choice of a static model implies that we are do
not capture some dynamic aspects of labor market behavior, such as the
accumulation of firm-specific human capital. The use of a static model
provides additional tractability to allow for closed-form solutions of
the optimal retirement and unemployment subsidies. Bhattacharya and Reed
(2001, 2002) study some of these issues in dynamic, general equilibrium
frameworks, but they do not solve for the optimal labor market policies
analytically.
(14.) Remember that a worker's surplus is less than his or her
earnings; earnings are computed in our model by subtracting the employer
surplus from worker productivity (i.e., p - [1 - [beta]][p -
[E.sub.0][gamma]]).
(15.) Blanchard and Diamond (1989) find a to be 0.4 for the U.S.
and Layard et al. (1991) find it to be 0.7 for the United Kingdom.
(16.) Van Ours and Ridder's (1992) calibration implies an
average vacancy duration of about 45 days, whereas Blanchard and
Diamond's (1989) implies 1 month.
(17.) We thank an anonymous referee for this suggestion.
REFERENCES
Baker, M., and D. Benjamin. "How Do Retirement Tests Affect
the Labor Supply of Older Men?" Journal of Public Economies, 72,
1999, 27-51.
Bhattacharya, J., and R. R. Reed III. "Aging, Unemployment,
and Welfare." Mimeo, Iowa State University, 2001.
--. "A General Equilibrium Model of Age-Specific Employment
Policies." Mimeo, University of Kentucky, 2002.
Blanchard, O.J., and P. Diamond. "The Beveridge Curve."
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1989, 1-60.
Boldrin, M., S. Jimenez-Martini, and F. Peracchi. "Social
Security and Retirement in Spain." In J. Gruber and D. Wise, eds.
Social Security Programs and Retirement around the World. Chicago:
University of Chicago Press for NBER, 1999, 305-53.
Burtless, G., and R. Moffit. "The Effect of Social Security
Benefits on the Labor Supply of the Aged," in Retirement and
Economic Behavior, edited by Henry J. Aaron and Gary Burtless.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1984, 135-74.
Costa, D. L. The Evolution of Retirement: An American Economic
History, 1880-1990. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for NBER, 1998.
Disney, R., and S. Tanner. "The Abolition of the Earnings Rule
for U.K. Pensions." Mimeo, University of Nottingham, 2000.
Friedberg, L. "The Labor Supply Effects of the Social Security
Earnings Test." Review of Economics and Statistics, 82(1), February
2000, 48-63.
Gruber, J., and D. Wise, eds. Social Security Programs and
Retirement around the World. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for
NBER, 1999.
Gruber, J., and P. Orszag. "Does the Social Security Earnings
Test Affect Labor Supply and Benefits Receipt?" National Tax
Journal, 56(4), December 2003, 755-73.
Hadar, J., and W.R. Russell. "Rules for Ordering Uncertain
Prospects." American Economic Review, 59(1), 1969, 25-34.
Hosios, A. J. "On the Efficiency of Matching and Related
Models of Search and Unemployment." Review of Economic Studies,
57(2), 1990, 279-98.
Layard, R., S. Nickell, and R. Jackman. Unemployment."
Macroeconomic Performance and the Labour Market. Oxford: Oxford
University Press, 1991.
Leimer, D. R. "Historical Redistribution under the Social
Security Disability Insurance Program." SSA ORES Working Paper
Series no. 77, July 1998.
Mortensen, D. T. "Property Rights and Efficiency in Mating,
Racing, and Related Games." American Economic Review, 72, 1982,
968-79.
Mulligan, C. B. "The 100% Tax in Theory and Practice."
Working Paper, University of Chicago, November 1998.
--. "Can Monopoly Unionism Explain Publicly Induced
Retirement?" NBER Working Paper no. 7680, Cambridge, MA, April
2000.
Mulligan, C. B., and X. Sala-i-Martin. "Gerontocracy,
Retirement, and Social Security." NBER Working Paper no. 7117,
Cambridge, MA, May 1999a.
--. "Internationally Common Features of Old-age Pensions, and
Their Implications for Models of the Public Sector." Advances in
Economic Analysis and Policy, 4(1), 2004.
Parnes, H. S., and G. Nestel. "The Retirement
Experience," in Work and Retirement, edited by H. S. Parnes.
Cambridge: MIT Press, 1981.
Pissarides, C. A. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. 2nd ed.
Cambridge: MIT Press, 2000.
Robinson, P. K., S. Coberly, and C. E. Paul. "Work and
Retirement," in Handbook of Aging and the Social Sciences, 2nd ed.,
edited by R.H. Binstock and E. Shanas. New York: Van Nostrand Reinhold,
1982.
Roosevelt, F. D. The Public Papers and Addresses of Franklin
Roosevelt, Vol. 4 (1935). New York: Random House Press, 1938.
Sala-i-Martin, X. "A Positive Theory of Social Security."
Journal of Economic Growth, (1)2, 1996, 277-304.
Schulz, J. H. The Economics of Aging. Westport: Auburn House, 2001.
Shimer, R. "The Impact of Young Workers on the Aggregate Labor
Market." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 2001, 969-1007.
Social Security Retirement Test, Hearing before the Subcommittee on
Social Security of the Committee on Ways and Means of the House of
Representatives. Serial 102-28. 23 May 1991. Government Printing Office,
1991.
Tesfatsion, L. "Stochastic Dominance and the Maximization of
Expected Utility." Review of Economic Studies, 43(2), 1976, 301-15.
U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, Subcommittee on Fiscal
Policy. Old Age Income Assurance." An Outline of Issues and
Alternatives. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1966.
Social Security Administration. Social Security Programs throughout
the World. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1995.
Van Ours, J., and G. Ridder. "Vacancies and the Recruitment of
New Employees." Journal of Labor Economies, 10(2), 1992, 138-55.
JOYDEEP BHATTACHARYA, CASEY B. MULLIGAN, and ROBERT R. REED III *
* We thank participants of the Macro Lunch Group at Chicago, an
anonymous referee for helpful comments, and Kevin Tsui for research
assistance.
Bhattacharya: Associate Professor of Economics, Department of
Economics, Iowa State University, Ames, IA 50011. Phone 1-515-294-5886,
Fax 1-515-294-0221, E-mail
[email protected]
Mulligan: Professor of Economics and Research Associate, University
of Chicago and National Bureau of Economic Research, Department of
Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL
60637. Phone 1-773-702-9017, Fax 1-773-702-8490, E-mail
[email protected]
Reed: Assistant Professor of Economics, Department of Economics,
Gatton College of Business and Economics, University of Kentucky,
Lexington, KY 40506. Phone 1-859-257-5975, Fax 1-859-323-1920, E-mail
[email protected]