Academic tenure, posttenure effort, and contractual damages.
Dnes, Antony ; Garoupa, Nuno
I.INTRODUCTION
In this article we explore the incentive properties of academic
tenure relative to alternatives that might be substitutes for tenure. We
do not present a comprehensive theory of academic tenure, but rather
emphasize the role of tenure in providing an incentive for incumbent
faculty to reveal the characteristics of recruits and to maintain their
own posttenure performance. Academic tenure often implies that its
holder cannot be removed from post except for good cause, usually based
on gross moral turpitude or gross incompetence (McPherson and Schapiro
1999). Such removal is historically characterized by a costly procedure
governed by organizational or state statutes (Tepker 1993). Our results
suggest that tenure is just one of many mechanisms able to achieve
honest revelation and that it has important interactions with other
mechanisms.
There is no question that tenure is a constraint to administrators
and limits the discretion of university managers. The objective of our
article is not to provide a new explanation for academic tenure but to
show how tenure could in principle be replaced by contractual damages
and how it more generally interacts with damages.
We believe it is worth theoretically exploring alternatives to
tenure because universities appear to ignore tenure statutes on
occasions. In particular, it is now common for schools to ignore orders
to reinstate dismissed, apparently tenured faculty and to choose to pay
damages instead (Tepker 1993). Carmichael's (1988) model suggests
that damages can achieve efficient information revelation where the
value of academics' next best occupations are known. A damages
payment equal to the difference between current expected earnings and
next-best earnings, that is, restoring the victim's expectations
(ignoring nonpecuniary benefits for simplicity) will then make an
incumbent indifferent between remaining and being sacked and happy to
reveal the skills of entrants.
Carmichael rules out the payment of "expectation" damages
and concentrates on the use of tenure, which creates a requirement for
specific performance by the university. We contend that the frequent
award of expectation damages by courts faced with cases of refusal to
reinstate suggests that more attention should be given to the damages
option, (1) and indeed to possible interactions between tenure and its
alternatives. Our contention is reinforced by the observation that many
universities are currently softening tenure by introducing devices like
five yearly reviews for tenured faculty. Note also that the role of
tenure looms large once it has been awarded, directing our attention
toward a model of posttenure performance, particularly if it could be
lost possibly subject to the payment of contract damages.
Our model explores the role of contractual damages in replacing
academic tenure (i.e., reinstatement) as well as addressing the problem
of revelation. We depart from previous literature in considering that it
is now common practice for university departments to use rankings and
publication records to evaluate faculty, thus reducing the asymmetry of
information (with respect to research and productivity) detected by
Carmichael (1988, p. 460). We focus on posttenure performance in the
shadow of the threat of dismissal followed by payment of contract
damages.
Dnes and Seaton (1998, 2001) examine the reform of academic tenure
in the United Kingdom by the 1988 Education Reform Act, which allowed
softer tenure to be chosen by universities. (2) The authors tested the
hypothesis that softening tenure encourages incumbent academics to
consolidate their hold on academic life. It seems that after 1988 the
distinction between hard-tenure and soft-tenure universities persisted,
that is, many British universities chose to continue operating a
hard-tenure system. Allowing softer tenure has not hindered the
improvement of academic performance in the context of increased
pressures from a research quality exercise that is periodically carried
out by the Higher Education Funding Council. Li and Ou-Yang (2003) also
confirm that academic tenure does not seem to have a substantial effect
on research productivity (measured by publications) and impact (measured
by citations) when comparing performance before and after tenure
promotion.
Our model also allows risk-neutral academics to be fully
compensated for risk bearing by a salary and expectations-based
contractual damages for dismissal. In such a world the academic is
indifferent between holding a job and being dismissed, and tenure is
important if salaries cannot compensate for risks and contractual
damages are too low. This aspect of our work draws attention to the
interaction between tenure, compensation, and salaries. It is often
asked why we do not simply pay academics more to bear the risk of
dismissal if their effectiveness falls off later. Our model sheds some
light on the role of salaries vis-a-vis tenure and related matters.
II. A MODEL OF ACADEMIC TENURE
The department has I incumbent professors. Each one of them is
ranked according to a research and teaching productivity index: a
[member of] [??].
The index is common knowledge and can be regarded as defined by a
tenure committee of senior faculty within the department. The department
has to decide on giving tenure to a candidate with ability a. The
entrant's ability is judged by the tenure committee and becomes
common knowledge. Under the assumption of risk neutrality, the model
would still follow through if a were an expected value of a
distribution.
The construction of an index of research and teaching solves some
of the problems discussed by McPherson and Winston (1983). In
particular, they argue that an academic job has a high monitoring cost
and a high degree of specificity. By considering an index, we address
these observations in the sense that it becomes quite easy for a
department to assess individuals. It is clear, however, that it excludes
variables that are not strictly research or teaching. (3)
Each tenured faculty member j = 1 ...., I has a research and
teaching productivity index [a.sub.1] when the tenure committee decides
whether to grant tenure. This initial index is exogenous in our model
and should have been set by the department to guarantee efficient
pretenure effort and productivity. (4) After tenure is approved, each
faculty member exerts effort e to provide further research output. The
index [a.sub.2] is given by [a.sub.1] + e - [epsilon], where [epsilon]
is a random variable that measures a mismatch between the
professor's effort and research output after tenure distributed
according to g([epsilon]) with support in [??], and zero expected value.
In our model each faculty member j = 1, ..., I is characterized by two
values for a: one (exogenous) before the tenure review ([a.sub.1]), and
another one (endogenous) after the tenure review ([a.sub.2]). Ours is a
therefore model of posttenure and not pretenure effort and productivity.
(5) Whereas the initial index is used for the tenure decision and
ultimately guarantees efficient pretenure effort, the second might be
used in a posttenured review (in soft-tenure universities), or in
reviewing salaries and promotion, aiming at efficient posttenure effort.
Our model accepts both explicit and implicit incentives for
exerting research effort after tenure is granted. Explicit incentives
include an increase in salary w. Following a first-order approach to
optimal contracting, we opt for the use of the most common solution to
participation contracts with w = [alpha] + [beta][a.sub.2], where
[alpha] [member of] [??] and [beta] [member of] [0, 1], both determined
by the department as employer.
The implicit incentive is based on an external constraint: The
monetary value of academic reputation (thus consultancy revenues or
research grants) is increasing on [a.sub.2] such that an academic has an
extra incentive to research and teach with quality even after a tenure
contract has been signed. (6) This possibility is introduced in our
model by assuming that each faculty member has an extra benefit given by
R([a.sub.2]), with R' > 0 and R" < 0. (7)
There are three stages in our model:
Stage 1: The tenure committee decides whether to give tenure to a
risk-neutral untenured professor j, based on the observable index
[a.sub.1]. A salary w is also negotiated.
Stage 2: The new tenured risk-neutral professor j decides his or
her research effort e, not observable by the department.
Stage 3: The department decides whether to dismiss the tenured
risk-neutral professor j, based on the observable index [a.sub.2] =
[a.sub.1] + e - [epsilon]. If not dismissed, a salary w negotiated in
stage 1 is paid.
We must solve the game backward for sub-game perfection. Let us
start with the last stage. The payoff for the tenured professor, if not
dismissed, is the salary w plus the extra benefit R([a.sub.2]).
Regarding the payoff of the department, much discussion in the
literature has focused on the kind of objective function a university
department has or should have (see McPherson and Winston 1983; McCormick
and Meiners 1988; McKenzie 1996; Brown 1997). We define the
department's payoff as [a.sub.2] - w, where research and teaching
output is mapped into gains for the department.
Now consider the possibility of dismissing tenured faculty. There
will be litigation between the two parties. (8) Let us define the
payoffs of a tenured professor and of the department if the case goes to
court as [S.sub.j] and [S.sub.d] respectively:
[S.sub.j] = qw + (1 - q)(v + d) + R([a.sub.2])
[S.sub.d] = q([a.sub.2] - w) - (1 - q)d,
where d stands for damages awarded by the court, v is the income
from working elsewhere, and q measures the probability of a tenured
professor being reinstated by the court (specific performance). A model
that takes into account litigation costs is presented in the Appendix.
The probability q measures the importance of tenure (in terms of
reinstatement). In hard-tenure universities, we expect q to be high and
close to 1 (specific performance dominates contractual damages). (9) In
soft-tenure universities, we expect q to be low and close to 0
(contractual damages dominate specific performance). Thus, increasing q
can be interpreted as hardening tenure.
A tenured professor is indifferent between hard tenure and
contractual damages if d = w - v. This is the particular case of
expectation damages (that is, damages are awarded so that the professor
will be in the same position as if the tenure contract had been
honored). When d < w - v, the professor is undercompensated (and is
punished if dismissed) and would prefer the tenure contract to be
honored (specific performance). If d > w - v, the professor is
overcompensated and prefers contractual damages to specific performance
(the department is punished by dismissal).
Let us define p = d + v - w, where p [member of] [??]. The
parameter P measures how much actual damages deviate from expectation
damages. When [rho] = 0, we have expectation damages. However, if [rho]
< 0, damages undercompensate the dismissed professor. On the other
hand, if [rho] > 0, damages overcompensate the academic (we could say
that the department has to pay punitive damages for dismissal). Thus, we
can rewrite:
[S.sub.j] = w + R([a.sub.2]) + (1 - q)[rho]
[S.sub.d] = q[a.sub.2] - (1 - q)([rho] - v) - w.
The department decides to dismiss the professor if and only if
[S.sub.d] [greater than or equal to] [a.sub.2] - w. Re-arranging we can
write:
[epsilon] [greater than or equal to] [a.sub.1] + e + [rho] - v =
[[epsilon].sup.*].
Thus, if the random variable is higher than [[epsilon].sup.*], a
dismissal will follow. However, if [epsilon] < [[epsilon].sup.*], the
department will decide not to dismiss a tenured professor. A dismissal
is more likely if contractual damages are low.
Given what happens in the last stage of the game, we should solve
the second stage, that is, incentive compatibility constraint of this
exercise. There is a probability G([[epsilon].sup.*]) that no dismissal
will take place and a probability 1 - G([[epsilon].sup.*]) that a
dismissal will take place, where G(.) is the cumulative distribution.
A tenured professor exerts effort so as to maximize his expected
payoff:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
where C(e) is the effort cost, with C' > 0 and C" >
0, and EIR([a.sub.2])] is the expected value of the extra benefit from
consultancy and research grants (given that at this stage [a.sub.2] is a
random variable because effort is decided before the random variable
[epsilon] being revealed).
The first-order condition is given by:
[differential][U.sub.j]/[differential]e = [beta] + [differential]E
[R([a.sub.2])]/[differential]e - g([[epsilon].sup.*])(1 - q)[rho] -
C' = 0
and the second-order condition is supposed to be satisfied under
the usual concavity assumptions. Consequently the optimal effort is
given by [[epsilon].sup.*](q, [rho], v, [a.sub.1], [beta]). It balances
the marginal benefit from exerting more research effort (marginal
increase in the salary, marginal expected revenues from consultancy and
research grants, marginal reduction in the expected loss from being
dismissed) against the marginal disutility of effort. We should expect
tenured faculty members to exert significant research and teaching
effort as long as (a) salary varies substantially with research output
(when [beta] is near 1), (b) marginal expected gains from consultancy
revenues and research grants are important, or (c) tenure is soft (q is
low) and damages undercompensate the dismissed faculty member ([rho] is
significantly negative). The optimal research and teaching effort after
tenure is likely to be 0 if (a) salary does not vary too much with
research output (if [beta] is negligible), (b) marginal expected gains
from consultancy revenues and research grants are unimportant, and (c)
tenure is hard (q approaches 1) or damages do not undercompensate the
faculty member (p is not too negative). (10) Notice that in the
particular case of expectation damages, the optimal effort is
independent of the nature (soft or hard) of tenure. In other words,
under a rule of expectation damages, tenure is irrelevant to determine
research and teaching effort.
Having solved the second stage, we should look at the first stage.
First, let us solve the participation constraint. A professor who does
not accept the tenure offer receives y, which is the utility given by
the best alternative at that moment (likely to be higher than the best
alternative if dismissed afterward, v). Thus, the reservation wage for a
professor is given by:
[alpha] = y - (1 - G[[[epsilon].sup.*]])(1 - q)p +
C([[epsilon].sup.*]) - E[R([a.sub.2])] - [beta]([a.sub.1] +
[[epsilon].sup.*]).
The department's expected payoff is given by:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The department decides to give tenure as long as [U.sub.d] is
greater than the opportunity cost, which is normalized to 0 after the
appropriate choice of salary. Let us first notice that the optimal
research effort for the department is
[differential][U.sub.d]/[differential]e = 1 - (1 - q)(1 -
G[[[epsilon].sup.*]]) + [differential]E[R([a.sub.2])]/[differential]e -
g([[epsilon].sup.*])(1 - q)[rho] - C' = O,
where the second-order condition is assumed to be satisfied under
the usual concavity assumptions.
The problem for the department is, of course, that the tenured
professor ignores the gain for the department from researching.
Therefore, the department should set [beta] in such a way that the
choice of research and teaching effort will be optimal. Looking at both
first-order conditions we can easily see that
[beta] = 1 - (1 - q)(1 - G[[[epsilon].sup.*]]).
On the left-hand side of the expression we have the residual rights
of the academic over his or her research and teaching gains. On the
right-hand side, we have the marginal benefit to the department from his
or her research and teaching effort. We can see immediately that under a
regime of hard tenure (q is high), the tenured professor should have
more residual rights over the gains produced by research and teaching.
However if we have a regime of soft tenure (q is low), the tenured
professor should have fewer residual rights.
Given that faculty member and department are both risk neutral, we
have the common solution of high-powered incentive contracts. As a
consequence, the fixed component of the salary [alpha] is negative
according to the participation constraint. There might be several
restrictions to the implementation of high-powered incentive contracts
in academia even under the assumption of risk neutrality, including
statutory constraints. (11) Therefore, in the remainder of the article,
we allow for the possibility that a suboptimal contract is implemented.
In this suboptimal contract, the residual rights of the academic (our
[beta]) are less than the marginal gain from his or her research and
teaching effort (our 1 - (1 - q)(1 - G[[[epsilon].sup.*]])), As a
consequence, the choice of effort by the tenured faculty member will be
less than efficient.
After setting the salary (eventually the one that aligns the
interests of the tenured professor with those of the department), we see
how the tenure regime (q) and damages (p) increase the likelihood of
granting tenure to a candidate with an initial index given by [a.sub.1].
Let us start by considering the decision to harden tenure:
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The first term is negative (unless [rho] is substantially negative,
which would mean that the dismissed professor would have to pay damages
to the department, which seems highly unrealistic). The rationale is
that as tenure become harder, it will be more difficult for the
department to dismiss the tenured professor if there is a mismatch in
effort and research output.
As for the second term, it is 0 if the optimal high-powered
incentive contract can be implemented. Otherwise, it depends crucially
on contractual damages. If damages are less than expectation damages (9
< 0), it is negative because the effort exerted by the tenured
professor is less than efficient and decreasing as tenure becomes harder
(due to the fact that there is a lower probability of being
under-compensated and so the marginal loss from being dismissed is
reduced). If damages overcompensate a tenured professor ([rho] > 0),
the second term is positive because the effort exerted by the tenured
professor is less than efficient but increasing as tenure becomes harder
(because there is a lower probability of being overcompensated and so
the marginal loss from not being dismissed is reduced). In the
particular case of expectation damages, the second term is 0 because the
choice of effort is not affected by tenure.
In general, hardening tenure makes the department worse off because
of diminished incentives for research and high-quality teaching (not a
problem if the conflict over optimal effort has been solved by a
high-powered incentive labor contract or if expectation damages are
implemented) and increased departmental costs in cases of a mismatch
between research effort and research output. However, there is a small
caveat (probably not empirically very relevant) to this result: Hard
tenure could increase research and teaching effort if a large
overcompensation for dismissal is in place (with soft tenure, tenured
professors would be looking for the opportunity to be dismissed and
claim damages, thus they would exert less effort to increase their
chances of being overcompensated in the future).
When we have expectation damages (p = 0), a professor is
indifferent between being given tenure or being sacked with
compensation. However, we have just shown that the department prefers
dismissal with compensation over tenure (because the department is worse
off as tenure is hardened unless, of course, dismissed professors are
overcompensated). The department is better off by paying expectation
damages for dismissing faculty than bearing the cost of effort
mismatching.
An immediate consequence of our results is that under a regime of
hard tenure (specific performance), we should expect the department to
impose a higher initial index [a.sub.1] to grant tenure to overcome the
expected costs of a mismatch between research effort and research
output.
The relationship between the payoff of the department and damages
is given by
[differential][U.sub.d]/[differential][rho] =
-g([[epsilon].sup.*])(1 - q)[rho] +
[differential][U.sub.d]/[differential]e x
[differential][e.sup.*]/[differential][rho].
The sign of the first term depends on p. If positive (the
department must overcompensate the dismissed faculty member), the
department is worse off; if negative (the tenured faculty member is
undercompensated), the department is better off. The sign of the second
term is 0 when a high-powered incentive contract is implemented, and it
will be negative otherwise (because the effort exerted by the tenured
professor is less than efficient and decreasing on compensation for
dismissal).
In general, higher contractual damages make the department worse
off, except if the dismissed professor is substantially
undercompensated. In the particular case of expectation damages and a
high-powered incentive contract, the sign of the relationship is 0.
Thus, a marginal increase of damages when a rule of expectation damages
applies does not affect the payoff of the department, but a professor
will prefer being sacked with compensation than tenure. In summary, soft
tenure with a rule of expectation damages (even damages with marginal
undercompensation) comes out as more appropriate than hard tenure.
III. SIGNALING AND REVELATION
As pointed out before, the most compelling argument for tenure is
that those who are responsible for recruitment or tenure decisions
should have an incentive to reveal information about candidates or give
tenure to the best candidate. Consider the situation where the research
and teaching index is only observed by the members of the tenure
committee (for example, the tenure committee can construct an index of
research and teaching productivity as they wish and will only choose the
appropriate index if they have an incentive to do so).
Suppose that if tenure is given to the best candidate K, the
probability of dismissal is 1 - [G.sub.K](.), and if given to the worst
candidate W, the probability of dismissal is 1 - [G.sub.W](.), such that
[G.sub.W](.) > [G.sub.K](.).
Giving tenure to candidate W can also be interpreted as rejecting K
when the decision concerning tenure promotion is taken on an individual
basis. The expected payoffs are, respectively:
[U.sub.jW] = w + [E.sub.W][R([a.sub.2])] + (1 - [G.sub.W][.])(1 -
q)[rho] - C(e)
[U.sub.jK] = w + [E.sub.K][R([a.sub.2])] + (1 - [G.sub.K][.])(1 -
q)[rho] - C(e),
where we allow for the possibility of expected gains from
consultancy revenues and research grants being affected by the tenure
decision, positively (a better department fosters extra gains for the
faculty members) or negatively (better tenured professors make the
market for extra gains more competitive, thus reducing the expected
payoff for the incumbents).
As long as the department implements a policy such that [U.sub.jK]
[greater than or equal to] [U.sub.jW] , the decision maker has no
incentive to hide information or not hire the best candidate. Given the
same choice of research and teaching effort, we can see that such policy
must satisfy
([G.sub.W][.] - [G.sub.K][.])(1 - q)[rho] +
([E.sub.K][R([a.sub.2])] - ([E.sub.W][R([a.sub.2])] [greater than or
equal to] 0.
For the moment, disregard the extra gains from consultancy revenues
and research grants. The sign of the left-hand side of the expression
will depend crucially on [rho]: It is positive if [rho] > 0, negative
if [rho] < 0, and 0 if [rho] = 0. In the particular case of
expectation damages, an incumbent is indifferent between dismissal and
staying at the department, thus there is no need for tenure. However, if
an incumbent is undercompensated if dismissed, then the department
should implement hard tenure for the committee members.
This result must be readjusted once we include the extra gains from
consultancy revenues and research grants. If giving tenure to a better
candidate reduces expected extra gains for incumbents, then even
expectation damages or hard tenure would not solve the revelation
problem, damages overcompensating tenured incumbents would be necessary.
However, if giving tenure to a better candidate improves the standing of
incumbents in the market for consultancy and research grants, soft
tenure with undercompensating contractual damages could solve the
problem.
A different kind of problem also addressed by this set-up is when
tenure decisions are subject to voting by all tenured professors. It is
not a question of information revelation (the quality of the candidate
is common knowledge) but due to the fact that a tenure promotion is
decided by secret ballot, a majority of the incumbents might vote
against tenure if they lose by granting the deserved promotion. Using
previous notation, the department might avoid this problem by simply
compensating incumbents in at least [U.sub.jW] - [U.sub.jK]. Once more
specific performance and appropriate contractual damages are perfect
substitutes in solving this problem. One consequence of the model is
that by only allowing the best tenured incumbents (those less affected
by a new tenure) to vote for a tenure promotion, the department would
save on compensation costs.
IV. DISCUSSION
Our model of faculty hiring focuses on decision-making incumbents,
contract damages, academic wages, and tenure. There is, in principle, a
trade-off between damages and tenure, the wage being endogenous in our
model. In addition, we find that it is important to focus on the faculty
personnel committees that actually make hiring recommendations. This
last point corresponds well with academics' perceptions of
departmental life.
One implication of the model is that universities could focus to
their advantage on the hiring decision makers in a department. Their
wages could be raised to a level that compensates them for the risks of
honestly revealing the skills of entrants. Equally, it would be possible
to create tenure just for this group. In practice, universities use
uniform tenure policies that do not narrowly target decision makers.
They may use higher wages for decision makers, although this may be a
corollary of using the recognizably more able to judge the attributes of
entrants.
Using only the most able departmental members to judge
entrant's skills may be the lowest-cost approach that a university
could take to encouraging honest revelation. In terms of our model, if
the group taking decisions could always be reshaped to keep it a long
way from the hiring margin ([G.sub.W] = [G.sub.K] in the model), there
need be no protection in terms of tenure, higher wages, or contract
damages. The process could be managed by judgment to avoid the problems
flowing from fear of displacement. Also, the information flow might well
be highest using such committees. This process in action is the
impression gained from observing a typical U.S. hiring committee over
time. Being on the committee is a signal that faculty are highly
regarded in the rank order. Our model shows why this might be important.
Tenure may very well be a failsafe for academics. It cannot be
known in advance which individuals will drop in and out of departmental
hiring committees over time. Therefore, tenure may be the way in which
an incentive for revelation is maintained over the long run. When an
incumbent is in favor, he or she need not worry about vulnerability over
time (when dropping out of favor). This observation based on creating
long-run incentives may explain the uniformity of tenure, when,
apparently, short-run considerations would not necessarily indicate a
need for it. Also, it gives an explanation, related to the revelation
problem, for why academics would want tenure. (12)
However, the unqualified supply of tenure might be a problem for
universities. Tenure creates property rights in jobs, and this could
give rise to hold-up possibilities. Whenever a university wished to
restructure, it might find itself paying academics almost all of the
resulting cost saving, rather than just their losses. (13) Bargaining
costs in the face of hold-up would probably deter useful restructuring.
The university would require some safeguard of its other interests, that
is, would wish to avoid supporting information revelation at the cost of
creating huge restructuring costs.
The safeguard appears to be present in the United States. As Tepker
(1993) observes, it is relatively common for courts to require the
reinstatement of dismissed tenured faculty but for schools to refuse.
The courts then award expectation damages, the standard award for breach
of contract that aims to put the victim in the position he or she would
have been in had the contract been honored. (14) This broadly requires
payment of the difference between academic earnings and those in the
next best occupation. Presumably, redundant academics who try to hold
out for more than their expectation induce universities to dismiss them,
knowing that courts impose expectation damages for breach. Courts may
also be useful devices for assessing expectation damages and its
components, like the value of alternative employment.
Our model shows considerable possible interaction between wages,
tenure, and damages. In relation to the discussion, there is always an
upper limit on damages that protects universities from hold up. However,
damages may be the true force behind tenure, which defines property
rights so that expectation damages can be awarded in the event of
dismissal. That protection will encourage participation in hiring
committees and honest revelation of entrants' skills. We are
broadly in agreement with Carmichael's (1988) approach but do not
think it is correct to separate tenure from contractual damages. Tenure
reform may not be the panacea it is often thought to be and, according
to our discussion, may remove an important basis for defining damages
for breach of contract that in turn supports information revelation.
Indeed, in the case of the United Kingdom, it is becoming clear that
statutory reform of tenure yielded little change because the
universities have chosen not to change their existing practices,
presumptively because these were efficient.
Finally in this section, we speculate about the failure to pursue
the logic of performance wages, contractual damages, and tenure
standards differentially across the academy. We do not see vast
differences in salaries and other differentiable rewards, comparing
departments or levels of efficiency attainable for a department. There
is some separation of the kind consistent with the analysis of this
article, for example, rewards in humanities tend to be significantly
less than in business, medicine, or law schools. The impression is that
the differentiation does not go far, and it is unusual for a university
administration to offer efficiency bonuses to departments. Our view on
this is that it is costly to differentiate performance and may invite
costly rivalries within the organization, particularly if errors were
made in allocating bonuses.
V. CONCLUSION
Our results suggest that tenure is just one of many mechanisms able
to achieve honest revelation in university hiring procedures.
Interactions between alternative mechanisms based on wages, damages,
tenure, or restricted hiring committees are of significance. It appears
possible to link damages to tenure in a manner that supports revelation
without creating incentives for hold up. We point to a delicate balance
within the academic labor contract.
APPENDIX: MODEL WITH LITIGATION COSTS
Let [L.sub.j] be litigation costs borne by the academic if
dismissed, and let [L.sub.d] be litigation costs borne by the department
if dismissal takes place. The payoffs should be rearranged:
[S.sub.j] = w + (1 - q)[rho] - [L.sub.j]
[S.sub.d] = q[a.sub.2] + (1 - q)(v - [rho]) - [L.sub.d] - w.
We should notice that [L.sub.j] plays an important role in
determining the credibility of the dismissed professor's threat to
sue. If [L.sub.j] is reasonably low, the lawsuit by the dismissed
professor is credible, and the qualitative results are not very
different from the main text. The department decides to dismiss the
professor if
[epsilon] [greater than or equal to] [a.sub.l] + e + [rho] - v +
[L.sub.d]/(1 - q) = [[epsilon].sup.*],
where higher litigation costs for the department reduce the
likelihood of dismissal.
After the appropriate choice of a labor contract, the expected
payoff of the department is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The first-order conditions with respect to q and [rho] are
(assuming a high-powered incentive labor contract is implemented)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
Litigation costs are a loss for both parties. As a result, avoiding
litigation becomes more important. Thus, specific performance (hard
tenure) becomes more attractive because it saves on litigation costs.
The importance of this effect is overestimated in the model due to the
fact that settlements are not allowed.
Consider now the situation where [L.sub.j] is large enough to deter
a lawsuit filed by the dismissed professor. The department decides to
dismiss the professor if [a.sub.2] < w or
[epsilon] [greater than or equal to] [a.sub.1] + e - [alpha]/(1 -
[beta] = [[epsilon].sup.*].
After the appropriate choice of a labor contract, the expected
payoff of the department is
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII.]
The parameters q and [rho] are irrelevant in this case because
there will be no litigation.
REFERENCES
Brown, W. O. "University Governance and Academic Tenure: A
Property Rights Explanation." Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics, 153(3), 1997, 441-61.
Carmichael, H. L. "Incentives in Academics: Why Is There
Tenure?" Journal of Political Economy, 96(2), 1988, 453-72.
Chatterjee, J., and R. C. Marshall. "A Model of Academic
Tenure." Working Paper. Pennsylvania State University, 2001.
Dnes, A. W., and J. S. Seaton. "The Reform of Academic Tenure
in the United Kingdom." International Review of Law and Eeonomics,
18(4), 1998, 491-510.
"The Research Assessment Exercise and the Reform of Academic
Tenure in the United Kingdom." Contemporary Economic Policy, 19(1),
2001, 39-48.
Li, S., and H. Ou-Yang. "Incentives, Performance, and Academic
Tenure." Working Paper. Duke University, 2003.
McCormick, R., and R. Meiners. "University Governance: A
Property Rights Approach." Journal of Law and Economics, 31(2),
1988, 423-42.
McKenzie, R. B. "In Defence of Academic Tenure." Journal
of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 152(2), 1996, 325-41.
McPherson, M., and M. O. Schapiro. "Tenure Issues in Higher
Education." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 13(1), 1999, 85-98.
McPherson, M., and G. Winston. "The Economics of Academic
Tenure: A Relational Perspective." Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 4(1), 1983, 163-84.
Siow, A. "Tenure and Other Unusual Personnel Practices in
Academia." Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 14(1), 1998,
152-73.
Tepker, H. F. "Good Cause and Just Expectations: Academic
Tenure in Oklahoma's Public Colleges and Universities."
Oklahoma Law Review, 46, 1993, 205-17.
(1.) See, for example, Bruno v. Detroit Institute of Technology,
215 N.W. 2d. 745 (Mich. Ct. App. 1974) (expectation damages should be
awarded for loss of tenure, if reinstatement is resisted by the
college). More recent cases buttressing the argument in the text include
Gray v. Mundelein College (Loyola University), 695 N.E.2d. 1379 (Ill.
App. 1 Dist., 1998) (confirming the right to bring an action for breach
of contract after a merger removed tenure); and Johnson v. Colorado
State Board of Agrieuhure, 15 P. 3d. 309 (Colo. App., 2000) (concerning
the retroactive introduction of posttenure review). In Mundelein, the
court was very clear that custom and practice did not undermine the
contract, and that expectation damages equal lost net earnings absent
the breach. The duty to mitigate losses, for example, by taking an
available job, was also confirmed.
(2.) Tenure in Britain was easier to receive and harder to lose
compared with the United States prior to 1988. The act allowed dismissal
for financial reasons, such as closing a department, subject to
protections on academic freedom. British cases also show a history of
paying damages in lieu of reinstatement, as per Bruno in the United
States.
(3.) For example, Brown (1997) addresses tenure from a property
rights perspective where the ownership of ideas and the freedom of
speech are the driving forces. Both variables are usually excluded from
an index of research and teaching.
(4.) For a model of pretenure effort, see Chatterjee and Marshall
(2001).
(5.) See Li and Ou-Yang (2003) for an investigation of 249
economists before and after their tenure promotion.
(6.) Note that Slow (1998) conversely argues that tenure is used to
induce older academics, whose research productivity has fallen, to do
less research. A tenure contract alleviates the misallocation of effort.
(7.) An empirical validation of this setup can be found in Li and
Ou-Yang (2003).
(8.) We ignore the possibility of settlements and golden parachutes
to avoid litigation. The qualitative results we present are not affected
by this assumption.
(9.) There is of course always the possibility that the whole
department is closed, therefore even with hard tenure q is strictly less
than 1.
(10.) These results are consistent with the empirical analysis
provided by Li and Ou-Yang (2003).
(11.) For example, in most continental European countries,
academics are essentially public servants, salaries are fixed by the
government or the legislator, and high-powered incentive labor contracts
are strictly forbidden.
(12.) Our explanation is a demand-side one. A complementary
supply-side explanation is that uniform tenure is the result of
competition between universities to attract top scholars. Uniform tenure
is the equilibrium of such game because there is a cost to be borne by
those defecting from the equilibrium (a reputation effect).
(13.) That is, compensation would exceed expectation damages, which
are explained shortly.
(14.) The compensating variation for a price fall.
ANTONY DNES and NUNO GAROUPA *
* We are grateful to one anonymous referee, the editor, and Benito
Arrunada, Antonio Cabrales, Andreu Mas-Colell, Luis Corchon, Eduardo
Rodes, Wolfgang Weigel, seminar participants at the Central European
University (where Dnes is a regular visitor) and participants at the
annual conference of the European Association of Law and Economics,
Vienna, in September 2001 for helpful suggestions.
Dnes: Professor, Business School, University of Hull,
Kingston-upon-Hull, HU6 7RX, England. Phone 44-1482-465875, Fax
44-1482-466216, E-mail a.dnes@ hull.ac.uk
Garoupa: Research Affiliate, CEPR, London; and Professor, Faculdade
de Economia, Universidade Nova de Lisboa, Campus de Campolide,
P-1099-032 Lisboa, Portugal. Phone 351-21-3801600, Fax 351-21-387033,
E-mail
[email protected]