Crony capitalism and financial system stability.
Haslag, Joseph H. ; Pecchenino, Rowena
I. INTRODUCTION
Prior to the Asian financial crisis, the cozy relationships between
corporations, governments, and banks were seen as a potent force for
economic growth and development. In the wake of the crisis, these same
links were derogated as crony capitalism and blamed for many of the
economic ills suffered by the now wounded tigers.
In this article, we examine the institution of crony capitalism.
Under conditions in which the Second Welfare Theorem does not hold,
there is a role for government. Some governmental institutions do
encourage more risky, high-payoff entrepreneurial activities. Our aim is
to examine crony capitalism as a potential source of government activity
that enhances economic productivity. In addition, we explore the
conditions under which the government activity can instigate a financial
crisis. (1)
We begin with a characterization of the relationship between banks
and project owners, sans cronies. In this economy, project owners, or
borrowers, have access to both positive and negative expected net
present value (NPV) projects. We consider a perfectly competitive
banking industry. The representative, risk-neutral bank can write
incentive compatible loan contracts that induce risk-neutral borrowers
to undertake the positive expected NPV projects by requiring that the
borrowers take an equity stake in their projects. Under the equilibrium
loan contract, only positive expected NPV projects are funded, the bank
earns zero profits, and, by appealing to the law of large numbers, the
representative bank does not suffer from bankruptcy risk.
We next introduce a crony system under which the government agrees
to guarantee some fraction of its cronies' loan payments in the
case of project failure. Crony status garners a project owner pecuniary and possibly nonpecuniary benefits. The government's guarantees are
promises and as such are not the result of formal legislative or
executive action or formal loan negotiation. (2) Rather, these
guarantees can be seen as a mechanism by which the government makes sub
rosa rewards to its friends and family and also buys their political
loyalty. Crony lending makes up only a small part of a bank's
balance sheet, so the attendant risk cannot be diversified away. To
ensure its solvency, the representative bank must put its own capital at
risk. Given a project owner's crony status and the loan guarantee,
the bank writes a crony-specific loan contract that takes the
crony's incentives into account as well as the bank's need to
remain solvent should a crony's project not pay off.
In this setup, a financial crisis is an ex post event. It is
identified by a simple condition: A bank becomes insolvent. A financial
crisis is triggered when the government fails to honor its guarantees.
One can imagine several factors that could contribute to such a failure.
For instance, perhaps a government faces unforeseen external constraints
(e.g., constraints imposed by the International Monetary Fund and/or the
government's revenues are inadequate). Or, alternatively, it
reneges on its implicit contingent liabilities because there has been a
change in government personnel.
We extend the model economy by introducing crony effort. More
specifically, cronies improve the return distribution of the projects
they undertake by putting forth unobservable effort to garner
nonpecuniary benefits, such as political power and prestige. We also
show that such crony systems may induce project quality improving effort
if the nonpecuniary benefits to crony status are high enough. If this is
the case, a crony system would not necessarily lead to reductions in
output or increases in bank portfolio risk, but the demise of a crony
system would.
Much has been written about the Korean chaebol and the Japanese
zaibatsu, what some consider classic crony institutional forms, but we
use Occam's razor to pare the institutional structure of crony
capitalism to its bare minimum: Crony project owners receive implicit
financial support from the government. We model this as an explicit
off-the-books guarantee on a crony project owner's loan payments in
the event of project failure. The relationship bears a strong
resemblance to the government-public enterprise relationship explored in
Shleifer and Vishny (1994). In Shleifer and Vishny, the government makes
direct transfers to project owners to meet their expenses; we do not.
Thus, their model is silent on the spillover effects from cronyism on
the financial system. Faccio (2002) finds that such spillovers are
pervasive in crony-type systems found in Indonesia and Malaysia, as well
as Italy and France. Even in countries where cronyism/corruption is low,
Faccio (2002) finds that politically connected firms (cronies) tend to
have higher debt to equity ratios and lower profits than their less
well-connected peers. Her empirical results are mirrored in our
analysis. (3)
There is a large body of literature specifically on the Asian
financial crisis. In a closely related article, Corsetti et al. (1999)
examine an open-economy model with productivity shocks. They derive
conditions under which a reduction in foreign loans is supplanted by
government funding. To finance these loans, the government must rely
more heavily on seigniorage. Thus, Corsetti et al. propose an
explanation for the coexistence of a financial crisis and a currency
crisis. Our model shares some key features with Corsetti and
colleagues--specifically, the presence of moral hazard that arises
because there is an implicit government transfer programs. However, the
timing and purpose of government intervention here is different from
their model. The key distinction is that we explicitly model the
contracts--loan and deposits--that comprise the financial system. (4)
The deposit contract guarantees consumers a certain (net of tax) return.
Consumers are not immune to the ill effects of cronyism because of the
tax burden. As such, a financial crisis when the government stops
supporting the crony and the bank's equity is gone reduces the
consumers expected tax payments, which is good but may also obliterate
their deposit accounts, which is bad.
Our model also bears some resemblance to the models of government
loan guarantees. (5) There are at least two important differences
between our work and the existing literature studying loan guarantees.
First, the previous body of literature focuses on the effect that loan
guarantees have with regard to safeguarding jobs or protecting an
essential industry (e.g., agriculture). In addition, previous work
examines cases in which the guarantee is offered only after a firm has
already defaulted on its loan. In other words, the guarantee is not a
precondition for the loan being made. In our work, the loan contract is
written contingent on the borrower having crony status, that is, a loan
guarantee; the guarantee itself is the mechanism by which those in power
redistribute wealth, in expected value terms, away from taxpayers to
their cronies.
Although the model design differs from previous work, our results
are similar to other studies examining the effects of government
transfer programs. For instance, Gale (1991) studied the efficiency
costs associated with federal credit programs that are broadly similar
to the efficiency costs of cronyism. In both cases, the efficiency costs
can be large; that is, the wealth transfers from taxpayers to the owners
of the firm receiving the loan guarantee (Selby et al. 1988) can be
high, as are the wealth transfers to cronies. In addition, a firm with a
government guaranteed loan (Chaney and Thakor 1985), like a crony, will
choose riskier projects and a more highly levered capital structure.
However, none of the previous work on loan guarantees asks how the
financial system and broad economic indicators, such as output, may be
affected, for good or ill. We do. (6)
Our main results are easily summarized in the following points:
1. Higher loan guarantee rates lead to lower bank capital and a
banking industry more susceptible to financial crisis.
2. Aggregate risk is, generally, higher in crony systems.
3. Bank solvency is inversely related to the pervasiveness of
cronyism and to crony borrowers' equity stake in the project.
4. Moral hazard and the exigencies of the government's
on-balance-sheet commitments, Imply that there are realizations that can
destabilize an otherwise healthy banking industry.
The article is organized as follows. In section II, we describe the
model economy, including the representative bank's decision rules.
We analyze the effects produced by changes in the government's
loan-guarantee rate in section III. We discuss the expected impact of
the crony loan guarantee in terms of the redistribution of wealth in
section IV. In section V, we discuss the ramifications associated with
an unexpectedly large number of crony defaults. Specifically, at some
point the loan guarantee will swamp the government's revenue; the
government will have to ration credit, thus precipitating calls on
capital and a potential collapse of the banking system. In section VI,
we modify the economy to consider the effects that nonpecuniary benefits
of crony status could have on financial sector risk and aggregate
output. We offer brief remarks about the key features of a model economy
in which cronyism can destabilize the banking system. These remarks and
generalizations to the real world are presented in section VII.
II. THE MODEL
Risk plays a central role in this model economy. More specifically,
two investment projects are available, one with positive expected net
returns and the other with negative expected net returns. We begin by
examining the features of loan contracts when no loan guarantees exist.
The economy is closed and exists for three dates: t = 0, 1, 2.
There is a single time-dated good that can be invested or consumed.
There are four types of agents: project owners, consumers, banks, and
the government. There are potentially two types of project owners:
cronies and noncronies. Cronies differ from noncronies in that their
loan payments are partially guaranteed by the government in the event of
project failure. There are three types of investment technologies: a
riskless technology, which requires an initial investment of 1 unit; and
two risky technologies A and B, both of which require an initial
investment of 1.
Project Owners
There is a large number, N, of risk-neutral project owners who
derive utility from consuming at date 2. At date 2 project owners
consume the net proceeds of their activities. Each project owner has
initial endowment of w < 1 time-zero goods and has access to the two
risky projects, A and B. If project A is funded at date 0 it yields
[R.sup.A] > 1 units of date - 1 goods at date 1 with probability
[[phi].sup.A], and 0 with probability (1 - [[phi].sup.A]). If project A
is successful at date 1, the project can be continued with an additional
investment of 1 unit of date--1 goods with payoff [R.sup.A] with
probability [[phi].sup.A] and 0 with probability (1 - [[phi].sup.A]). If
project A is unsuccessful, the project terminates. If project B is
funded at date 0 it yields [R.sup.B] > 1 at date 1 with probability
[[phi].sup.B] and 0 with probability (1 - [[phi].sup.B]). If project B
is successful at date 1, the project can be continued with an additional
investment of 1 with payoff R8 with probability [[phi].sup.B] and 0 with
probability (1 - [[phi].sup.B]). If project B is unsuccessful, the
project terminates. (7) Assume [[phi].sup.A][R.sup.A] > 1 >
[[phi].sup.B][R.sup.B], but [R.sup.A] < [R.sup.B] (so [[phi].sup.A]
> [[phi].sup.B]): Thus, project B is riskier than project A in the
sense that project B has negative NPV. Assume goods flows are
observable, but project choice is not. Furthermore, assume that project
returns are iid and that the distribution of payoffs is the same across
dates.
Consumer/Depositors
There is a large number, D, of risk-averse individuals, hereafter labeled consumers. Each consumer is endowed with d < 1 - w units of
time-0 goods. Consumers have time-separable preferences, deriving
utility from consumption at dates 1 and 2. Formally, consumer's
preferences are represented by a utility function: u([x.sub.1]) +
v([x.sub.2]), with u'(*), v'(*)>0, u" (*).
v''(*) [less than or equal to] 0, u'(0) = v'(0) =
[infinity], x denotes the level of consumption by the consumer. Because
of their small initial goods endowments, consumers do not have direct
access to technologies that transform time-t goods into time-t + 1
goods. Thus, consumers will deposit all their available funds in the
banks.
Banks
Banks operate in a perfectly competitive environment in the market
for deposits and the market for loans. We assume the banking system is
comprised of F identical banks, N [much less than] F. Banks are
risk-neutral, do not discount the future, and derive utility from
consumption at date 2. Each bank is initially endowed with [bar.k]
[greater than or equal to] 0 units of date-0 goods. One can think of
this endowment as equity capital. (8)
Banks offer demand deposit contracts to depositors, pool depositor
and own funds, and make one-period loans to project owners or invest in
the riskless storage technology that transforms a unit of date-t good
into a unit of date-t + 1 good. In short, a representative bank's
balance sheet is represented by [bar.k] + d= i + l, where i stands for
the quantity of goods placed in the risk-free technology and I denotes
the volume of goods loaned to project owners. Throughout our analysis,
we will focus on cases in which i = 0.
We assume that dD [much less than] N and [s.sub.1]dD [much less
than] [[phi].sup.A]N, where [S.sub.1] is the date-1 consumer's
savings rate. Thus all projects can be funded initially with
consumers' deposits alone, all successful projects can be
refinanced with consumers' deposits alone, and depositors can
withdraw their funds on demand without affecting system liquidity.
Overall, the banking system can be characterized as follows.
Competition among banks drives each bank's expected profits to
zero. At date 0, banks behave identically, pricing loans and offering a
return to deposits. Ex ante, therefore, we can describe the date-0
decisions from the perspective of a representative bank. The expected
consumption by a representative banker is exactly equal to the size of
their capital endowment. Indeed, loans are priced and deposits offer
returns based on this date-0 expectation.
Government
There is a government that may have a crony relationship with a
positive fraction of the borrowers. If the government does have a crony
relationship with a borrower, it agrees to guarantee some fraction, 0
< [eta] [less than or equal to] 1, of the borrower's loan
payment in the event that the funded project fails. Any loans extended
at date 1 are also guaranteed at the same rate. To fund the expected
value of these guarantees, the government collects nondistortionary
taxes from consumers at dates 1 and 2. Taxes are collected at the
beginning of each period before the realization is made on projects. At
the end of date 2, we assume the government rebates, lump-sum, any
unused taxes collected that are not applied toward a crony loan
guarantee. The expected value of the lump-sum rebate to consumers is
zero because the taxes collected are exactly equal to the expected value
of the loan guarantee.
The Baseline (No Crony) Case
We begin with a case in which cronies do not exist. Banks are only
willing to fund positive NPV projects. Thus the representative bank must
write loan contracts such that project owners find it incentive
compatible to undertake project A. That is, the representative bank
prices a loan
1. assuming that the borrower will choose project A,
2. assuming that it will roll the loan over if A is chosen and is
successful,
3. knowing that if the borrower chooses project B and is successful
the bank will know that it violated the contract (because goods flows
are observable) and will not roll the loan over.
Then, the bank requires the project owner to place its goods
endowment in a risk-free storage technology, which reverts to the bank
should the project fail, and demands repayment [n.sub.l] if the project
is successful. Note that the bank constructs the loan contract so that
project A is incentive compatible and so that the expected date-I gross
return is 1 (all depositors can be repaid in full). Formally, expected
gross real return is satisfied by
(1) [[phi].sub.A][n.sub.1] + (1 - [[phi].sub.A]) w + 1 [??]
[n.sub.1] = [1 - (1 - [[phi].sub.A])w]/[[phi].sub.A].
Equation (1) simply says that the bank is willing to lend if and
only if expected receipts from loan repayment and collateral
confiscation equal the guaranteed return from storage.
If A is undertaken and is successful, the project owner controls
[R.sup.A] w- [n.sub.1] units of date-1 goods, which may exceed unity. If
so, the project owner will self-finance the date-2 project. (9)
Suppose, however, that [R.sup.4] + w- [n.sub.1] < 1. The bank
prices a loan to the project owner (now locked into project A) requiring
the repayment of [n.sub.2] such that
(2) [[phi].sub.A][n.sub.2] + (1 - [[phi].sub.A])[R.sub.A] + w
-[n.sub.1]] =1 [??] [n.sub.2] = [1 - (1 -
[[phi].sub.A])([R.sub.A+w-[n.sub.1]]/[[phi].sub.A].
Together, equations (1) and (2) are interpreted as the pricing
equations for date-0 and date-1 loans. The equations indicate the
repayment value that will satisfy the ex ante expected zero-profit
condition for the representative bank. As such, for every good loaned to
a project owner, the bank receives [n.sub.1] date-1 goods at date 1 and
[n.sub.2] date-2 goods, conditioned on the date-0 information that the
representative bank has.
Next we turn our attention to the borrower. In particular, we
establish conditions under which the borrower is willing to accept the
date-0 loan. Clearly, the borrower must be at least as happy with the
expected date-1 loan outcome, ([R.sup.A] +w-[n.sub.1])[[phi].sub.A],
compared with storing the borrower's endowment. In this case, the
borrower would receive w goods with certainty. In other words, the
participation constraint must be satisfied. At date t= 0 the borrower
also evaluates the value of the initial loan package, subsequent
rollover and repayment. We assume the net proceeds from the successful
date-I project are applied as collateral for the date-1 loan. Thus,
(3) [[phi].sub.A][.sub.2] ([R.sub.A]+[[R.sub.A] + w -[n.sub.2]]
> w [??] [1 + [[phi].sub.A])([[phi].sub.A][R.sub.A - 1) > 0. (10)
Conditioned on the date-0 loan being acceptable, at date 0, the
agent is willing to participate in a rollover loan if the expected
revenues from the rollover loan plus the expected proceeds from the
date-0 loan are greater than the endowment. (11) Remember that the bank
can always store the deposits into a risk-free technology with gross
return equal to one. Under these conditions, the loan package is
acceptable.
Given that the bank has priced the loan as if project A is chosen,
the natural question is whether the borrower will indeed choose project
A over project B. The borrower will accept the loan and choose project A
if the project owner's expected income is higher than if the
project owner were to choose project B. If, instead, the project owner
chooses to undertake project B, the project owner's expected income
will be conditioned on the terms offered by the bank. Assume that the
bank priced the date-0 loan assuming that the project owner would choose
project A. The proceeds to the project owner will be ([R.sub.B] +w -
[n.sub.1])[[phi].sub.B]. Remember that if the borrower chooses B and is
successful the bank will not roll the loan over (because cash [goods]
flows are observable), and the borrower never chooses to self-finance a
negative expected net present value project. Thus the borrower will
choose A if
(C1) [[phi].sub.A][.sub.2] ([R.sub.A]+[[R.sub.A] + w -[n.sub.1]] -
[n.sub.2] > ([R.sub.B] + w - [n.sub.1])[[phi].sub.B] [??] [1 +
[[phi].sub.A])([[phi].sub.A][R.sub.A] - 1) + w
>[[phi].sub.A][R.sub.B] + w - 1)[phi].sub.B]/[phi].sub.A]
We assume that condition (C1) holds (otherwise the bank will not
lend and the date-0 loan market will collapse).
In the no-crony case, there is no aggregate risk. Thus by the law
of large numbers and with iid project returns, the representative bank
earns zero profits with certainty, can repay consumers at the risk-free
rate of return (the return on storage) with certainty, and the
individual borrower earns positive expected profits. Banks' capital
(endowments), either stored or invested, also earns the risk-free rate
of return and is not at risk.
Cronies with (Iron-Clad) Government Guarantees
In this section, we modify the model economy, adding a second type
of project owner, hereafter called a crony. Crony relationships are
captured by loan guarantees provided to a fraction of project owners by
the government.
Suppose the government has crony relationships with [N.sub.2]
borrowers and has no relationship with the other [N.sub.1] borrowers;
note [N.sub.1] +[N.sub.2]=N. If the government has a crony relationship
with a borrower, it guarantees a fraction n of the borrower's loan
payment in the event that the funded project fails. A crony borrower is
costlessly identifiable to each bank. (12)
Note that there is no aggregate risk associated with the noncrony
portion of the representative bank's portfolio decision. With
[N.sub.2]/[N.sub.1] small, the law of large numbers still applies to
noncrony lending. Thus, the baseline (no-crony) result still applies to
the contract for noncronies. Insofar as we have solved the noncrony
portion, we concentrate solely on the portion of the bank's
portfolio devoted to crony loans. Specifically, for cronies the
situation has changed because the government now guarantees some
fraction of their loan payments if their projects do not succeed.
Because the number of cronies is small, the risk associated with crony
loans cannot be diversified away. (13) As a result, for a bank to be
able to meet its contractual obligations to consumers, it may need to
put its capital at risk and/or require that cronies collateralize their
borrowing.
With government guarantees in place, the government's budget
constraint becomes especially important. For simplicity, we assume that
the government does nothing at date t = 0. We assume the government
commits to a pattern of tax collections, imposing a lump sum tax of
[[tau].sub.t] on all consumers at dates t= 1,2. Taxes collected at date
1 can be stored; that is, the government has access to the storage
technology. (14) The government also sets the crony loan guarantee rate,
[eta]. Throughout this analysis, aggregate risk is present if and only
if the crony choose project B. The loan guarantee applies to the risk
that goes with a representative crony who has chosen project B. We drop
the superscript B in this discussion. Note that whatever the government
guarantee does not cover, the bank and/or consumers must absorb.
Table 1 summarizes expenses and revenues at each relevant date. We
adopt the following notation: [[tau].sub.t] is the date-t lump-sum tax,
and [c.sub.t] is the crony's loan repayment at date t. Thus the
government faces two budget constraints. We assume that in each case,
the government collects taxes to meet its expected liability arising
from the crony loan guarantees. Formally,
(5) D[[tau].sub.1] - (1 - [phi])[N.sub.2][eta][c.sub.1] [greater
than or equal to] 0
and for date 2
D[[tau].sub.1] - [N.sub.2](1] - [[gamma].sub.1,1]) [eta][c.sub.1]
+ D[[tau].sub.1] - [N.sub.2](1 - [phi]) [eta][c.sub.1]
if [[gamma].sub.1,1] [greater than or equal to] [phi], or
(6) D[[tau].sub.2] - (1 - [phi])[N.sub.2][eta][c.sub.2] [greater
than or equal to] 0,
otherwise, where [[gamma].sub.1,t] denotes the realized fraction of
crony loans that were successful at date t. Because the law of large
numbers does not hold, [phi]=[[gamma].sub.1,t] does not necessarily
hold. Note that equation (5) says that the government collects taxes to
meet the expected value of crony guarantees. Because the government can
store unused taxes, equation (6) says that resources available to the
government are used to meet its expected crony loan guarantee liability.
Note that if resources are left after date 2, there is a lump-sum rebate
to consumers. Let a be the value of date-2 lumpsum transfers made to
consumers, reflecting the unused portion of taxes by the government. In
other words, we have D[[tau].sub.1]-
[N.sub.2](1-[[gamma].sub.1,1])[eta][c.sub.1] + D[[tau].sub.2]-
[N.sub.2](1 - [[gamma].sub.1,2)][eta][c.sub.2] = a [or D[[tau].sub.2]-(1
- [[gamma].sub.1,2])[N.sub.2][eta][c.sub.2] = a] when equation (6) holds
as a strict inequality. Throughout our analysis, we will consider a
special case in which the government smoothes taxes across dates so that
[[tau].sub.1] = [[tau].sub.1] = [tau] We assume throughout our analysis
that [tau] and [eta] are known and the government can precommit to each
level.
By fixing the government revenues that can be used to meet the
government's implicit liability, we introduce the possibility that
its realized liability will exceed its ability to pay. Clearly, a
government could impose additional taxes or borrow to meet its
liability. However, there are circumstances where such actions would not
be feasible (for example, IMF scrutiny of government spending) or,
perhaps, as a result of a change in government, not politically
expedient.
In a symmetric environment, all banks would face the same number of
crony borrowers. We assume the government matches cronies to banks and
distributes them so that all banks have the same number of crony
borrowers. (15) The representative bank makes take-it-or-leave-it offers
to the cronies, where all contracts are written so that the bank makes
zero expected profits (the assumed sharing rule gives all surplus to the
crony). The crony must either take the contract offered or revert to
noncrony status. Unlike the no-crony case, there are a number of
contracts banks can offer crony project owners, depending on the
presence of bank equity or collateral and on the solution to the Nash
bargaining problem. In this article, we consider three such types of
contracts. Because banks make zero expected profits under all contracts,
they are indifferent among contract types. However, the government could
mandate a specific type of contract be offered to secure the guarantee,
or the bank, being indifferent, could choose that contract most
beneficial to the crony. To maintain the representative bank assumption,
we assume that all banks offer the same contract type to their crony
borrowers.
Under Contract I the bank puts its own capital at risk but does not
require the crony to collateralize the loan. With Contract II the bank
puts its capital at risk and requires the crony to collateralize the
loan. For Contract III the bank does not put its capital at risk but
requires the crony to collateralize the loan. The bank initially prices
the crony loan contracts as follows:
1. assuming that the borrower will choose project A,
2. assuming that it will roll the loan over if A is chosen and is
successful,
3. knowing that if the borrower chooses project B and is successful
the bank will know that it violated the contract (because goods flows
are observable) and will not roll the loan over.
The bank then compares the date-2 expected income of the crony if
it were to undertake project A with the date-2 expected income of the
crony if it undertakes project B. If the crony's expected income is
higher undertaking project B, the bank will either choose not to lend to
cronies, because the equivalent of C1 does not hold, or will price a
loan under the assumption that project B is undertaken. If it is willing
to do the latter it is because project B is now, because of the loan
guarantee, (16) a positive NPV project. (17) Banks will not lend against
negative NPV projects.
We will examine the three contracts in turn. In each case, the bank
takes the ability of the government to meet its crony guarantee as
credible and as given. For notational simplicity we will drop the
project identifying superscripts unless required for clarity.
Loan Contract I: Bank Capital, No Collateral
The representative bank sets contract terms on a loan to a crony:
loan repayment, c; interest rate, r; and its capital holdings per crony
loan, k, such that k [less than or equal to] k, where k=k/[zeta] is bank
capital per crony loan (the bank lends to [zeta] cronies), at date 0 and
date 1 (because, from the perspective of the bank, the loans are
identical). (18) We drop the time subscripts because there is no
difference between the loan contract terms across time.
For the bank to be willing to lend, three conditions must be
satisfied. First, the sum of actual crony payments and bank capital must
meet the deposits backing the crony loans in all states. Thus, the ex
ante balance sheet solvency condition with respect to crony loans,
wherein the aggregate risk lies, is written as
(7) [[eta].sub.c] + k = 1.
Because the bank is putting up its own capital, the expected return to crony loans cannot be less than the return to storage to compensate
the bank for risk taking. That is, with equality
(8) [phi]c + (1 - [phi])[eta]c = 1 + r.
Last, on average, the bank's capital stock is unchanged. In
the "good" state, the bank receives (net) r goods from the
crony loans and in the bad state there is a net loss of tic - 1 goods
such that the following condition holds
(9) [phi]r + (1 - [phi])([eta]c - l) = k.
Together equations (7)- (9) can be used to solve for the repayment
level, the size of bank capital, and the real interest rate.
(10) c = 2/2[eta] + [[phi].sub.2](1 - [eta])
(11) k=[[phi].sub.2](1-[eta])2[eta]+[[phi].sub.2](1-[eta])
(12) r = [phi](2 - [phi])(1 - [eta])/2[eta] + [[phi].sub.2](1 -
[eta])
The expected value of the crony project under this contract is
(13) (l + [phi])[[phi]R - 2/2[eta] + [[phi].sub.2](1 - [eta])].
Loan Contract H: Collateral and Bank Capital
Suppose the bank requires that the project owner put up collateral
and the bank puts up capital as well. We focus on cases in which w <
1 - [eta] so that if the loan fails, repayment is less than what is
required to repay consumers in full. Note that under these contract
conditions, contract terms could change over time precisely because the
goods the crony can pledge as collateral can change over time. Here we
will focus on contract terms at date 1. Accordingly, we keep time
subscripts on the contract terms that hold for date 1.
The bank sets contract terms at date 0, given k [less than or equal
to] k, such that it is solvent in all states
(14) [eta][c.sub.1] + w + [k.sub.l] = 1,
that it compensates its owners for risk taking
(15) [phi][c.sub.1] + (1 - [phi])[eta][c.sub.1] + (1 - ]phi]) w = 1
+ [r.sub.1],
and that the expected value of its capital is unchanged
(16) [phi][r.sub.1] + (1 - [phi])[eta][c.sub.1] + w - 1] =
[k.sub.1],
Together equations (14) (16) can be used to solve for the repayment
level, the size of bank capital, and the real interest rate.
(17) [c.sub.1] = 2 - w(2-[[phi].sub.2])/2[eta] + [[phi].sub.2] (1 -
[eta])
(18) [k.sub.1] + [[phi].sub.2] (1 - [eta] - w)/2[eta] +
[[phi].sub.2](1 - [eta])
(19) [r.sub.1] + (2 - [phi]) [phi] (1 - [eta] - w) /2[eta] +
[[phi].sub.2](1 - [eta])
If R - [c.sub.1] + w > 1 - [eta], then [c.sub.2] = l, [k.sub.2]
= 0, and [r.sub.2] = 0 because the bank does not need to put its capital
at risk to ensure that consumers are paid in full. If this is not the
case. then the crony has R - [c.sub.1] + w = w in goods that can be
pledged to collateralize its borrowing. The bank then sets contract
terms at date 1, given [k.sub.2] [less than or equal to] k, such that it
is solvent in all states
(20) [eta][c.sub.2] + w + [k.sub.2] = 1,
that it compensates its owners for risk taking
(21) [phi][c.sub.2] + (1 -[phi])[eta][c.sub.2] + (1 -[phi]) w = 1 +
[r.sub.2],
and that the expected value of its capital is unchanged
(22) [phi][r.sub.2] + (1 -[phi])[eta][c.sub.2] + w = 1 + [k.sub.2],
Together equations (20) (22) can be used to solve for the repayment
level, the size of bank capital, and the real interest rate.
(23) [c.sub.2] = 2 - w(2-[[phi].sub.2])/2[eta] + [[phi].sub.2] (1 -
[eta])
(24) [k.sub.2] = [[phi].sub.2] (1 - [eta] - w)/2[eta] +
[[phi].sub.2](1 - [eta])
(25) [r.sub.2] = (2 - [phi]) [phi] (1 - [eta] - w) /2[eta] +
[[phi].sub.2](1 - [eta])
Loan Contract III: Collateral No Bank Capital
Note that with w > 1 - [eta] the bank can require that the crony
put up collateral, and that collateral will, along with the government
payments, fully cover the bank's costs. The bank sets contract
terms at date 0 and date 1 to solve
(26) [phi]c + (1 -[phi])[eta]c +(1 - [phi]) (1 - [eta]) c+ 1 [??] c
= 1.
III. COMPARATIVE STATICS: THE EFFECTS OF LOAN GUARANTEES
In this section, we analyze the effects that changes in the loan
guarantee rate, [eta], would have on the features of the optimal loan
contract and on the expected level of bank capital.
PROPOSITION 1. Consider an increase in the crony loan guarantee
rate, [eta]. Under Contracts I and II, one sees (i) a decrease in bank
capital, (k); (ii) a decrease in the real interest rate (r); and (iii)
and a decrease in the loan repayment. (c). A change in the crony
guarantee rate, however, has no effect on the loan repayment schedule
for Contract III.
Proof The proof follows immediately from equations (10) (12) for
Contract I, equations (17) (19) and (23) (25) for Contract II, and
equation (26) for Contract III.
The loan guarantee reduces the risk to the bank of lending. Thus,
the greater the guarantee, the less capital the bank needs to ensure its
solvency, the lower the return required on its capital, and the lower
the repayment required from the borrower. The lower repayment schedule
increases the expected return to the borrower, thus making the crony
better off.
Deadweight Loss of Cronyism
With the government guarantee on some fraction of a crony's
loan payments, the loan contract terms are affected, and so are
crony's decision regarding the project that generates the highest
profits. What is not altered is the number of risky loans financed by
the banking industry (all project owners borrow at date 0 whether they
are cronies or not). We interpret the product generated by the projects
as gross domestic product (GDP). With this interpretation and with the
bank's decision, it is straightforward to compute expected ex ante
GDP generated on risky lending. Formally,
(27) [E.sub.0]GD[P|.sub.nocronies] = N [[phi].sub.A] [(1 +
[[phi].sub.A]) [R.sub.A] - 1]
(28) [E.sub.0]GD[P|.sub.cronies all do A] = N [[phi].sub.A] [(1 +
[[phi].sub.A]) [R.sub.A] - 1]
(29) [E.sub.0]GD[P|.sub.nocronies all do B] = N [[phi].sub.A] [(1 +
[[phi].sub.A]) [R.sub.A] - 1] + N [[phi].sub.B] [(1 + [[phi].sub.B])
[R.sub.B] - 1]
where [E.sub.t] is the mathematical expectation taken as of date t.
Because all cronies are identical and are offered identical contracts,
they all will either undertake project A or all undertake project B.
Following the tradition in the trade literature, we use expected
GDP, or expected national income, as the ex ante measure of deadweight
loss to the economy. (19) Later in the article, we will discuss how the
crony relationship affects welfare of the different agents in the
economy. First, we consider a comparison of GDP under the no-crony
setting and under the setting in which all cronies choose project A. By
inspection of equations (27) and (28), expected GDP is identical for
these two cases. Thus the deadweight loss, measured by expected GDP, is
zero. Next, we consider the case in which all cronies undertake project
B. Compared with the no-crony case, we subtract equation (27) from (29)
indicate that the expected deadweight loss of cronyism is
(30) [E.sub.0]DWL = [N.sub.2][[[phi].sub.A](1 +
[[phi].sup.A])[R.sup.A] - [[phi].sup.B](1 + [[phi].sup.B])[R.sup.B] -
([[phi].sup.A] - [[phi].sup.B])] > 0.
We summarize our findings with respect to the deadweight loss
associated with crony loan guarantees in the following proposition.
PROPOSITION 2. (i) The expected deadweight loss created by crony
loan guarantees is" positively related to the number of cronies
designated; (ii) all else equal, the expected deadweight loss is
positively related to an increase in the variance of returns to Project
B.
Proof. (i) Obvious. (ii) Consider a case in which [[phi].sup.A] and
[R.sup.A] are constant. Now, suppose that the probability that project B
succeeds declines and if the return to project B increases, but the
expected return is unchanged; that is, [[phi].sup.B] declines, [R.sup.B]
increases, but the product [[phi].sup.B][R.sup.B], is constant. By
construction, we are examining the effects of a mean-preserving spread
to the distribution of returns offered to Project B. (20) Although the
means of the distribution are unchanged, the variance has increased for
returns on Project B. In this case, we get
[[partial derivative][E.sub.0](DWL / [partial
derivative][[phi].sup.B])|.sub.MPS] =
[N.sub.2](1-[[phi].sup.B][R.sup.B]) > O.
IV. WEALTH REDISTRIBUTION
Because the government imposes taxes to pay for the contingent
liabilities generated by its crony relationships, cronyism redistributes
goods away from taxpayers to cronies and their bankers. All taxes are
imposed on consumers. We turn our attention to an analysis of the
redistributive impact associated with cronyism. To compute the impact,
we need a benchmark; formally, what would the consumer's, the
representative bank's, and the project owner's wealth be
without cronies, and then we recompute each group's wealth under
cronyism. The difference between the two wealth levels is monotonically
related to the group's welfare. In words, these calculations tell
us which agents gain and which lose as a result of the system. (21)
Throughout this section we will maintain the assumption that the
government's tax revenues are sufficient to cover all its expected
as well as realized liabilities. The derivations are relegated to the
appendix.
In the no-crony case, consumers earn the risk-free rate of return
on their deposits. For the representative bank, capital is not put at
risk (it is stored or replaces consumer funds one to one), and project
owners, choosing project A, are rewarded for their risk taking.
We assume that the government sets the lump-sum tax high enough so
that it can meet all its contingent liabilities, at least in
expectation. Then, under Contracts I and II, wealth is transferred from
consumers to banks and cronies. Banks receive part of the redistributed wealth as a result of their need to put some or all of their capital at
risk to meet their contractual liabilities to consumers under the crony
system. Because banks do not put their capital at risk under Contract
III, the expected transfer payment from consumers goes entirely to crony
project owners.
Clearly, the institution of crony lending funded via taxes on
consumers impoverishes taxpayers, but it need not undermine the
stability of the financial system should tax revenues be sufficient in
all states to cover the government's contingent liability. (22)
Moreover, it may be difficult to distinguish a financial system
characterized by cronyism from one absent cronyism. In both systems,
collateralized lending may be the norm and crony lending can actually
put less "solvency" pressure on the bank.
In the next section, we turn our attention to cases in which
government revenues are too small in certain states of the world and
bank insolvency occurs.
V. GOVERNMENT REVENUE SHORTFALL
Now suppose that the government's tax revenues are inadequate
to meet its realized liability to the banks. Formally, D[[tau].sub.1]
< (1 - [[gamma].sub.1, 1] [N.sub.2][eta][c.sub.1]. The chief
implication is that the government is unable to honor some of its crony
loan guarantees at date 1. (23) We define 0 < [[gamma].sub.2,1] [less
than or equal to] 1 as the fraction of crony loans that fail and the
government's implicit guarantee is not honored. Thus, 1 -
[[gamma].sub.1,1] - [[gamma].sub.2,1] is fraction of failed crony loans
that the government honors by paying the implicit guarantees.
The question is, does the bank have the capital per crony loan
necessary to absorb the losses and remain solvent? We next consider
cases in which the government has undercollected taxes in the sense that
tax revenues are too small relative to the realized quantity of failed
crony loans at date 1. Clearly for Contract III, the representative bank
will fail because the bank does not hold capital. For both Contracts I
and II, there is the possibility of solvency.
Conditions for Solvency under Contract I
PROPOSITION 3. The representative bank remains solvent if and only
if the successful crony loans are large enough relative to the share of
failed crony loans the government does not honor.
Proof Under Contract I, we substitute equation (10) for crony loan
repayment so that the banks' revenues are written as
N2[[gamma]sub.1.1] c + (1 - [[gamma].sub.1,1] -
[[gamma].sub.1.2])[eta]c] = [N.sub.2]2/2[eta] + [[phi].sup.2](1 -
[eta])][[gamma].sub.1,1] + (1 - [[gamma].sub.1,1] -
[[gamma].sub.1.2])[eta]],
and after substituting for k using equation (11), the bank's
costs that must be covered are
[N.sub.2](1 - k) = [N.sub.2][2[eta]/2[eta] + [[phi].sup.2](1 -
[eta])].
Thus, to remain solvent it must be the case that
[[gamma].sub.1.1] 1 - [eta]/[eta] > [[gamma].sub.1.2]
Should the bank remain solvent, its capital is depleted. In other
words, its date-1 capital stock is smaller than k units per successful
crony loan. The bank must give credit to cronies. (24) Should the
government want the bank to continue to lend to all remaining cronies
given the bank's depleted capital position, the government would
have to increase its guarantee rate on the remaining crony loans.
Otherwise, capital levels are insufficient to insure solvency. (25)
Thus, any attempt to dismantle the crony system may put the stability of
the financial system at risk. For instance, if the government reduces
tax revenues dedicated to funding the system, bank solvency is at risk.
Conditions for Solvency under Contract II
PROPOSITION 4. The representative bank remains solvent if and only
if the fraction of successful crony loans is large enough relative to
the share of Jailed crony loans for which the government does not honor
its implicit guarantee. Under Contract II, the size of the project
owner's equity, w, is inversely related to the bank's ability
to remain solvent.
Proof Under Contract II, we substitute for the crony loan repayment
using equation (17). Thus, the bank's revenues are
[N.sub.2][[gamma].sub.1,1][c.sub.1] + (1 - [[gamma].sub.1,1] -
[[gamma].sub.1,2])([eta][C.sub.1] + W)] = [N.sub.2][2 - w(2 -
[[phi].sup.2])/2[eta] + [[phi].sup.2](1 - [eta])] x [[[gamma].sub.1,1] +
(1 - [[gamma].sub.1,1] - [[gamma].sub.1,2])[eta]] + [N.sub.2](1 -
[[gamma].sub.1,1])w,
and the bank's costs under Contract II, after substituting for
k from equation (18), are
[N.sub.2](1 - k) = [N.sub.2][2[eta] - [[phi].sup.2]w/2[eta] +
[[phi].sup.2](1 - [eta])].
The bank remains solvent if
(31) [[gamma].sub.1,1](1-[eta]-w)/[eta][1-w(1-([[phi].sup.2]/2))]
> [[gamma].sub.1,2].
The solvency condition is decreasing in w because
([partial derivative]/[partial
derivative]w)([[gamma].sub.1,1](1-[eta]-w)/[eta][1 - w(1 -
([[phi].sup.2]/2))]) = - [[gamma].sub.1.1]/[eta][[1 - w(1 -
([[phi].sup.2]/2))].sup.2]([eta](1 - [[phi].sup.2]/2) + [[phi].sup.2]/2)
< 0.
The relationship between bank solvency and crony's equity
stake appears at first to be counterintuitive. However, as the project
owner's equity stake increases, for instance, the bank's
capital holdings decrease. Thus, the bank is less able to withstand a
reduction in the government's loan guarantee.
Bank Solvency in a Riskier Environment
COROLLARY TO PROPOSITION 2. All else equal, an increase in the
riskiness of Project B, increases the probability that the government
will be unable to honor its implicit loan guarantees.
Proof By Proposition 2, holding [[phi].sup.A] and [R.sup.A]
constant and subjecting the return distribution of Project B to a
mean-preserving spread, we find that the deadweight loss of the crony
system increases. If taxes are collected as a fraction of GDP, then the
reduction in GDP implies a reduction in tax revenues. It follows that
there is a greater chance that the government's revenues will be
less than its liabilities.
Capital Adequacy Requirements
The contracts analyzed require that the banks remain solvent in all
states conditional on the government meeting its contingent liability.
Clearly, externally (rather than internally) set capital requirements (say, those set by international agreement, such as the Basel Accords)
that do not take the particular institutional structure of the banking
market into account need not be adequate to achieve bank solvency. A
risk-based capital requirement that did not account for the possibility
of the government failing to honor its implicit contract would generally
set capital requirements too low. Capital requirements that ignored the
implicit guarantee altogether (ignored the guarantee and just evaluated
banks' portfolios without taking off-balance-sheet contingent
assets into account) would set capital requirements too high and would
induce the usual effect of making banks' portfolios more risky.
VI. NONPECUNIARY BENEFITS AND PROJECT OWNER EFFORT
In this section, we explore two modifications to the basic crony
setup. First, we offer nonpecuniary benefits to the crony. Our view is
that crony status involves a wide variety of benefits, including
proximity to political power, ability to influence policy decisions, and
so on. Our efforts here are to broaden the sense in which cronyism is
valuable to the crony. More important, our goal is to examine the impact
that such broadening would have on observable economic outcomes. So we
consider a case in which cronies obtain nonpecuniary as well as
pecuniary benefits. (26) Suppose the total quantity of nonpecuniary
benefits is fixed. As such, benefits per crony are decreasing in the
number of other cronies to whom such benefits are offered. We assume
that the quantity of nonpecuniary benefits is positively related to the
expected longevity of the government in power. If the nonpecuniary
benefits are valuable enough, project owners will want to maintain their
crony status. To do so, suppose that crony status is linked to a crony
project owner's project being successful. (27)
Second, we explore the role of unobservable effort in terms of the
effect on economic outcomes. Consider a case in which all project owners
have the ability to improve the return distribution on their projects
(the probability that a project will be successful) by putting forth
unobservable effort. Because this effort is unobservable (it does not
change observable cash flows), loan contracts cannot be written
contingent on it. Thus, loan contracts in this revised scenario will be
written on the underlying distribution, as in the basic model, not the
effort-enhanced distribution.
Define et as the effort expended by a project owner at date t, t =
0, 1 and let [phi](e) be the probability of a project being successful,
[phi]'(e) > 0, [phi]"(e)< 0, and V(e) be the cost of
undertaking that effort, V'(e) > 0, V"(e) > 0. A
noncrony project owner, taking the loan repayment schedule as given,
chooses [e.sub.0][greater than or equal to] 0 and [e.sub.1][greater than
or equal to] 0 to solve
max [phi]([e.sub.0])[R - [n.sub.1] + [phi]([e.sub.1])(R -
[n.sub.2])] - V([e.sub.0]) - [phi]([e.sub.0]) V([e.sub.1]) +
[[mu].sub.0][e.sub.0] + [[mu].sub.1][e.sub.1]
where the [[mu].sub.t], for t- 1, 2 is the Lagrange multiplier for
the constraint date-t effort is nonnegative. If the following condition
is satisfied,
(32) [phi]'(0)[R - [n.sub.1] [phi](0)(R - [n.sub.2])]<
V'(0),
then noncronies will never find it to their benefit to undertake
effort. If the inequality in equation (32) holds, a noncrony project
owner at date 0 will not put forth effort to increase the probability
that the project will succeed at date 1. The intuition is
straightforward; equation (32) represents the condition under which the
marginal cost of effort exceeds the marginal benefit. (28)
Crony status is awarded at date 0 prior to the initial loans being
granted. Cronies, taking the loan repayment schedule as given, choose
[e.sub.0] > 0 and [e.sub.1][greater than or equal to] 0 to solve
max [phi]([e.sub.0])[R - [c.sub.1] + [phi]([e.sub.1])(R -
[c.sub.2])] + [phi]([e.sub.0])[[beta].sub.1 - V ([e.sub.0]) +
[phi]([e.sub.0])[phi]([e.sub.1])[[beta].sub.2] - [phi]([e.sub.0])
V([e.sub.1]) + [[lambda].sub.0][e.sub.0] + [[lambda].sub.1]e
where [[beta].sub.1], t = 1, 2 is the nonpecumary benefit of
maintaining one's crony status at date t, and the [[lambda].sub.t]
= 1, 2 is the Lagrange multiplier associated with the constraint on
date-t crony effort. Note that we model nonpecuniary benefits as
parameter that the representative crony takes as given. It enters into
welfare multiplicatively, increasing the marginal value of goods
available to the crony. The first-order conditions are
[phi]'([e.sub.0])[R - [c.sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] +
[phi]([e.sub.1])(R - [c.sub.2] + [[beta].sub.2])] - V'([e.sub.0]) +
[[lambda].sub.0] = 0, [phi]([e.sub.0])[[phi]'([e.sub.1])(R -
[c.sub.2] + [[beta].sub.2]) - V'([e.sub.1])] + [[lambda].sub.1], =
0.
If at [e.sub.0] = [e.sub.1] = 0 the following conditions hold,
[phi]'(0)[R - [c.sub.1] + [[beta].sub.1] + [phi](R - [c.sub.2]
+ [[beta].sub.2])] > V'(0), [phi]'(0)[R - [c.sub.2] +
[[beta]2]]> V'(0),
then the crony will choose to put forth project-improving effort at
both dates to increase the probability of a high cash flow and thus
maintain crony status. The interpretation is that if projects could be
renewed for more than two dates, the incentives provided by the
nonpecuniary benefits of crony status would potentially induce effort as
long as the nonpecuniary benefits remained high enough.
What this extended model suggests is that as long as crony status
brings with it adequate additional benefits, cronyism can generate
increases in output and imply only small contingent liabilities for the
government (taxpayers). The banking system would be stable and
profitable, and portfolio risk would be low. The knowledge that a bank
had lent to cronies would not undermine confidence in the bank. On the
contrary, banks that were part of the crony system would be more
profitable than their counterparts who eschewed the system.
Suppose, for example, that the government at date t = 0 is removed
from office. Agents formed their state-contingent plans, taking the
government's actions as given. In our setup, cronies would plan on
efforts levels, taking the level of nonpecuniary benefits as given. With
a change in government, the nonpecuniary benefits--insofar as such
benefits are tied to a specific government--could fall. Mexico and
Taiwan provide real-world examples of such changes in government
relationships. With such a change, the incentives to put forth effort
would also fall. In addition, the potential that the government will not
honor its guarantees would rise. Thus a financial crisis may be the
outcome of improvements in democracy (or of a changing of the guard in
which loyalty to the old guard may put one out of favor with the new).
VII. REMARKS
The model developed herein examines the effects of cronyism on
financial system stability and economic output and its distribution. We
find that crony systems are not inherently unstable and need not lead to
reductions in GDP or extortionate taxation, although in practice they
may lead to both. Externally, crony systems may appear much like
noncrony systems. Thus there may be no clear early warning signal of an
impending collapse. Whatever the causes and effects of cronyism, the
system itself has a potentially fatal flaw. It benefits those in power
who are expected to remain in power. Anything that undermines this
power, be it IMF dictate or the death of a long serving ruler with no
clear successor, also undermines the system. (29) We characterize this
by the government being unable to honor its crony loan guarantees and/or
being unable to provide nonpecuniary benefits of enduring value. Either
puts the financial system at risk.
The collapse or weakening of a crony system places great strain on
the financial system. This suggests that policies aimed at reforming
financial systems characterized by pervasive cronyism must take the
institutional features of this system into account in designing the
reform process. Banks as well as project owners must be weaned off the
crony system. Banks must be given the time to build up their capital
reserves so that they can remain solvent when crony payments are no
longer forthcoming. Crony project owners must be given the time to
transfer their resources into positive NPV projects. Consumers and
noncrony borrowers' interests should be protected and maintaining
while reforming the financial system will do this. Shock treatment or a
short timetable for reform may root out the cronies but take down
everyone else as well.
APPENDIX
Wealth Distributions for the No-Crony Case
[E.sub.0] (Depositor Wealth) = dD
[E.sub.0] (Bank Wealth) = [bar.k]F
[E.sub.0](Firm Wealth) = N[(1 +
[[phi].sup.A])([[phi].sup.A][R.sup.A]-1) + w]
In the no-crony case, consumers earn the risk-free rate of return
on their deposits, bank capital is not put at risk (it is stored on
replaces consumer funds one to one), and project owners are rewarded for
their risk taking.
Wealth Distribution/Redistribution.[or Crony Case Contract I
We assume that the government sets the lump-sum tax high enough so
that it can meet all its contingent liabilities, at least in
expectation. The distribution of wealth is as follows:
(A-1) [E.sub.0](DepositorWealth]) = dD - [N.sub.2]
[[2[eta](1-[[phi].sup.2])]/[2[eta] + [[phi].sup.2](1 - [eta])]]
where the second term in equation (A-1) is the expected net tax
liability as a result of all crony lending and where superscripts are
absent both cases (Project A undertaken or Project B undertaken) are
simultaneously represented.
(A-2) [E.sub.0](Bank Wealth) =[bar.k]F + [N.sub.2](1 + [phi])
[[[phi](2 - [phi])(1-[eta])] /[2[eta] + [[phi].sup.2](1 - [eta])]]
(A-3) [E.sbu.0](Noncrony Firm Wealth) = [N.sub.1][1 +
[[phi].sup.A]([[phi].sup.A][R.sup.A] - 1) + w]
(A-4) [E.sub.0](cronyFirmWealth) = [N.sub.2] [(1 + [phi])([phi]R -
(2/[2[eta] + [[phi].sup.2](1-[eta])])) + w]
Because the tax scheme transfers wealth from consumers to banks and
cronies, the second term in equation (A-1) represents the size of the
expected transfer payment. Banks receive part of the redistributed
wealth as a result of their need to put some or all of their capital at
risk to meet their contractual liabilities to their consumers under the
crony system.
Wealth Distribution/Redistribution Crony Case Contract II
(A-5)[E.sub.0] (Depositor Wealth) = dD - [N.sub.2][[(1 -
[PHI])[eta][2 - w(2 - [[PHI].sup.2])]] /[2[eta] + [[PHI].sup.2](1 -
[eta])] + [PHI](1 - [PHI])[eta]]
(A-6)[E.sub.0] (Bank Wealth) = [bar.k] F + [N.sub.2][[[PHI](1 -
[eta] - w)] /[2[eta] + [[PHI].sup.2](1 - [eta])]]
(A-7)[E.sub.0] (Noncrony Firm Wealth) = [N.sub.1][(1 +
[[PHI].sup.A])([[PHI].sup.A][R.sup.A] - 1) + w]
(A-8)[E.sub.0] (crony Firm Wealth) = {N.sub.2][R - [[2 - [??][2 +
[eta](2 - [[PHI].sup.2])]] /[2[eta] + [[PHI].sup.2](1 - [eta])]]]
Again, equation (A-5) indicates that consumers expect a transfer
payment from themselves to banks and cronies in Contract II.
Wealth Distribution/Redistribution Crony Case Contract III
(A-9) [E.sub.0] (Depositor Wealth) = dD - [N.sub.2] (1 -
[[PHI].sup.2])[eta]
(A-10) Bank Wealth = [bar.k] F
(A-11) [E.sub.0] (Noncrony Firm Wealth) = [N.sub.1][(1 +
[[PHI].sup.A])([[PHI].sup.A][R.sup.A] - 1) + w]
(A-12) [E.sub.0] (crony Firm Wealth) = [N.sub.2][[PHI](1 + [PHI])(R
- 1) + w - (1 - {{PHI].sup.2]) (1 - [eta])
Because banks do not put their capital at risk under Contract III,
the expected transfer payment from consumer [see equation (A-9)] goes
entirely to crony project owners.
ABBREVIATIONS
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
NPV: Net Present Value
TABLE 1
Date-by-date Government Activity
Date Expected Expenses (by Date) Revenues
1 (1 - [phi]) [N.sub.2][eta][c.sub.1] D[[tau].sub.1]
2 [phi](1 - [phi] [N.sub.2][eta][c.sub.2] D[[tau].sub.2]
(1.) We forgo an analysis of the optimal institutional arrangement.
Rather, we take the existence of cronyism as given, comparing
macroeconomic outcomes. See Haslag and Pecchenino (2002) for a detailed
analysis of the welfare impacts associated with cronyism.
(2.) As the reader will see. taxes are collected to back the
government guarantees. That these tax revenues are so used is known to
the government, but not to the taxpayers. "'Off the
books" refers to the fact that crony status is absent from the
government's books and the bank's books.
(3.) Faccio (2002) provides an excellent review of the literature
on politically connected (crony) firms.
(4.) As such, we eschew two specific issues addressed in Corsetti
et al. Namely, we specify a closed economy in which fiat money is not
valued. Thus there is no role for foreign borrowing/lending and no
insight with respect to currency crisis, only crisis in the explicit
banking system.
(5.) See, for example, papers by Sosin (1980), Chaney and Thakor
(1985), Innes (1991), Lai (1992), and Li (1998).
(6.) The effects on the financial system of crony relationships are
similar to those associated with deposit insurance. However, bank
portfolio risk is not increased, and risk is fairly priced when the
crony guarantees are introduced. The ultimate impact on the financial
system outcomes are similar if the government fails to honor the
guarantees because it is banks and bank consumers who are hurt ex post.
(7.) The assumption that projects undertaken at date 0 can be
continued at date 1 if successful is equivalent to the assumption that
projects have two period maturities; require goods inputs at date 0 and,
contingent on success, in period 1; and generate cash (goods) flows in
period 1 and, contingent on success and the availability of inputs, in
period 2.
(8.) See Hancock and Wilcox (1998) for an analysis on the
interaction between bank size (as measured by bank capital) and loan
guarantees operated by the Small Business Administration in the United
States.
(9.) Our naming convention is as follows. Projects are dated
according to when the payout is realized. A project initiated at date
t=1 and paying out at dale t=2, is referred to as a date-2 project.
Loans are dated likewise. The loan payout is treated as occurring when
the funds are given to the project owner.
(10.) The derivation is obtained by substituting the loan-repayment
values into the left-hand side on the inequality and rearranging.
(11.) Remember that the bank can always accumulate deposits and
store them in the risk-free technology. This is why equation (3)
specifies the participation constraint this way: the relevant comparison
is between two conditional expected values: one in which the bank makes
a sequence of loans and the other in which the bank stores the goods in
the risk-free technology, both evaluated on information available at
date t=0.
(12.) There are plenty of examples of government loan guarantees
that do not require crony status. See, for example. discussions in
Riding (1997) and Thornton (1997). We assume that noncronies cannot
transfer funds to cronies.
(13.) This assertion is formalized in the assumption that [N.sub.2]
is small enough so that the mass around the expected value is not
captured by a degenerate distribution at a single point.
(14.) We are assuming that aggregate taxes exceed one.
(15.) Because banks are competitive and so make zero profits on all
loan contracts (including those to cronies), this assumption is not
necessary to obtain our results.
(16.) Thus there will be critical values of [eta] for which being a
crony and undertaking project B is preferable to being a crony and
undertaking project A and vice versa. These critical values are
straightforward to compute, are contract type-specific, and depend oil
the parameters of the risky projects but do not affect our conclusions
in a fundamental way. This is because all cronies are identical.
(17.) In short, the crony is the beneficiary of a government
transfer program that Krugman (1998) referred to as "a game of
heads 1 win, tails the taxpayer loses."
(18.) It is assumed that the bank loans out equity endowment except
the quantity applied toward supporting crony loans. By construction,
note that [zeta] = [N.sub.2]/F.
(19.) See, for instance, Ethier (1986). The basic notion is that
the marginal utility of goods is positive, higher expected national
income.
(20.) Formally, the mean preserving spread is an example of
second-order stochastic dominance.
(21.) With heterogenenous agents populating our model economy and
with no "standard" social welfare function available, we
measure the impact of cronyism on expected total income where the
expected value is computed conditioned on information available at date
0. In this section, we compute how cronyism redistributes wealth.
Together, the results in sections III and IV measure two effects: one
effect is on aggregate income and the other on distribution of income.
From section IV, it becomes clear that there is some redistribution from
noncronies to cronies. Hence, the crony system described is pareto
noncomparable to the noncrony system. Because of the expected
rate-of-return dominance, it is straightforward to show that a social
planner would choose the noncrony system, maximizing expected aggregate
income by putting the entire endowment into Project A.
(22.) Here, the stability of the financial system refers to the
breadth of the financial crisis. If a bank is insolvent, the financial
system is less stable and closer to a financial crisis.
(23.) We are not thinking of the government as practicing
time-inconsistent behavior. Remember, the government commits to a path
of tax collections. In these circumstances, the small number of crony
loans means there is uninsurable aggregate risk. Suppose the
tax-commitment technology keeps the government from changing its tax
revenues by enough to support the revenue shortfall. This could be
because the tax rate is set too low given the guarantee rate, the
guarantee rate is set too high given the tax rate, or because an
exceptionally large percentage of crony loans fails. See Cowling (1995)
for an analysis of the United Kingdom's loan guarantee program.
(24.) An alternative would be for the bank to raise more capital.
In this model, the bank's capital is an endowment. We recognize
this alternative, but the current model is not developed in a way to so
that additional bank capital cannot be acquired privately, but must be
received as an additional endowment.
(25.) Recall in Proposition 1 that the bank's capital is
decreasing in the loan-guarantee rate.
(26.) Such benefits would include factors not included in loan
guarantees for investment projects. For instance, cronies may have
special privileges that raise welfare. We leave these specific details
out and simply include as being determined outside the model economy.
(27.) The implicit bargaining in the background could be as
follows. The government promises a crony a loan guarantee that enables
the crony to receive financing at below market rates. For this favor,
the crony promises to provide members of the government with pecuniary
benefits: The tax funds are laundered by the cronies. The members of the
government add the inducement of political power, or proximity to that
power, but only so long as the pecuniary benefits continue to flow to
the members of the government.
(28.) Equation (26) is stated in terms of a local result. With
strict concavity of the benefit function and strict convexity of the
effort's cost function, the result implies a global result.
(29.) This result is very similar to that found by Rajan and
Zingales (2001) in their study of financial development. There, insiders
are adverse to change as it increases competition thus reducing their
oligopoly rents. Here, cronies and their banks will also be adverse to
change and must be given time to change to ensure a smooth transition
and forestall financial collapse.
REFERENCES
Chaney, P. K., and Anjan V. Thakor. "Incentive Effects of
Benevolent Intervention: The Case of Government Loan Guarantees."
Journal of Public Economics, 26, 1985, 169-89.
Corsetti, G., Paolo Pesenti, and Nouriel Roubini. "Paper
Tigers? A Model of the Asian Crisis." European Economic Review, 45,
1999, 1211-36.
Cowling, M. "Initial Tests on the Sensitivity of the
Parameters of the UK Loan Guarantee Scheme." Public Finance, 50,
1995, 356-70.
Ethier, W. J. "Illegal Immigration: The Host-Country
Problem." American Economic Review, 76, 1986, 56-71.
Faccio, M. "Politically-Connected Project Owners: Can They
Squeeze the State?" Working Paper, University of Notre Dame, 2002.
Gale, W. G. "Economic Effects of Federal Credit
Programs." American Economic Review, 81, 1991, 133-52.
Hancock, D., and James A. Wilcox. "The 'Credit
Crunch' and the Availability of Credit to Small Business."
Journal of Banking and Finance, 22, 1998, 983-1014.
Haslag, J., and Rowena Pecchenino. "Crony Capitalism and
Economic Development." Working Paper, University of Missouri, 2002.
Innes, R. "Investment and Government Intervention in Credit
Markets when There Is Asymmetric Information." Journal of Public
Economics, 46, 1991, 347-81.
Krugman, P. "What Happened to Asia?" Unpublished
manuscript, 1998.
Lai, V. S. "An Analysis of Private Loan Guarantees."
Journal of Financial Services Research, 6, 1992, 223-48.
Li, W. "Government Loan, Guarantee, and Grant Programs: An
Evaluation." Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly,
84, 1998, 25-52.
Rajan, R., and Luigi Zingales. "The Great Reversals: The
Politics of Financial Development in the 20th century." Working
Paper, University of Chicago, 2001.
Riding, A. L. "On the Care and Nurture of Loan Guarantee
Programs." in Financing Growth in Canada, edited by P. J. N.
Halpern. Calgary: University of Calgary Press, 1997, 637-72.
Selby, M. J. P., J. R. Franks, and J. P. Karki. "Loan
Guarantees, Wealth Transfers and Incentives to Invest." Journal of
Industrial Economics, 37, 1988, 47-65.
Shleifer, A., and Robert Vishny. "Politicians and Project
Owners." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 1994, 995-1025.
Sosin, H. B. "On the Valuation of Federal Loan Guarantees to
Corporations." Journal of Finance, 35, 1980, 1209-21.
Thornton, D. B. "On the Care and Nurture of Loan Guarantee
Programs," in Financing Growth in Canada. edited by P. J. N.
Halpern. Calgary: University of Calgary Press, 1997, 683-88.
JOSEPH H. HASLAG and ROWENA PECCHENINO, We thank participants of
the 2001 Irish Economics Association Conference, the 2002 Midwest
Macroeconomics Conference, the 2002 Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Conference on Finance and Growth: the seminar participants at the
University of Sydney, the University of Adelaide, Indiana University,
CERGE-EI, and Purdue University: and two anonymous referees for helpful
comments. All remaining errors are ours alone.
Haslag: Associate Professor of Economics, 118 Professional Bldg.,
University of Missouri-Columbia, Columbia, MO, 65211. Phone
1-573-882-3483. Fax 1-573-882-2697, Email
[email protected]
Pecchenino: Professor of Economics, 101 Marshall Hall, Michigan
State University, East Lansing, MI 48824. Phone 1-517-335-7583. Fax
1-517-432-1068, E-mail
[email protected]