首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月12日 星期四
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Group size and social ties in microfinance institutions.
  • 作者:Abbink, Klaus ; Irlenbusch, Bernd ; Renner, Elke
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2006
  • 期号:October
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:In recent years microfinance institutions (MFIs) have become one of the most important instruments in development policy. The idea of microfinance arose in the mid-1970s when Mohammad Yunus started a pilot scheme lending small amounts of money to villagers in Bangladesh who, due to a lack of collateral, had no access to conventional loans. Encouraged by high repayment rates, he founded the Grameen Bank to run such schemes on a larger scale. Today the Grameen Bank lends to more than 2 million people. Since Grameen's early successes, the concept of microcredits has spread throughout the world, and a plethora of organizations providing small loans to the poor have come into being. (1) MFIs are most widespread in less developed countries, although they are by no means confined to them. Microlending programs have also been introduced in transition economies like Bosnia and Russia and even in Western economies like Canada and the United States. (2) There are more than 5 million households served by microcredit schemes in the world today.
  • 关键词:Financial institutions;Personal loans

Group size and social ties in microfinance institutions.


Abbink, Klaus ; Irlenbusch, Bernd ; Renner, Elke 等


I. INTRODUCTION

In recent years microfinance institutions (MFIs) have become one of the most important instruments in development policy. The idea of microfinance arose in the mid-1970s when Mohammad Yunus started a pilot scheme lending small amounts of money to villagers in Bangladesh who, due to a lack of collateral, had no access to conventional loans. Encouraged by high repayment rates, he founded the Grameen Bank to run such schemes on a larger scale. Today the Grameen Bank lends to more than 2 million people. Since Grameen's early successes, the concept of microcredits has spread throughout the world, and a plethora of organizations providing small loans to the poor have come into being. (1) MFIs are most widespread in less developed countries, although they are by no means confined to them. Microlending programs have also been introduced in transition economies like Bosnia and Russia and even in Western economies like Canada and the United States. (2) There are more than 5 million households served by microcredit schemes in the world today.

Prior to the microfinance revolution, poor people's opportunities to take up loans had been severely limited for several reasons. First, poor households cannot offer collateral to back up their loans, because they own too few substantial possessions. Second, the potential addressees of small loans in less developed countries often live in remote rural villages beyond the reach of the traditional banking system. Third, although loans needed for individual projects are small, their myriad nature makes monitoring and enforcement costs prohibitively high. Poor villagers' only access to credit had been through non-commercial development programs that provided subsidized credit. However, because these schemes faced the same monitoring difficulties as traditional banks, they often suffered from poor repayment rates and high costs and were typically doomed to failure for that reason.

MFIs use innovative means to overcome these problems. Though the individual schemes differ vastly in their concrete implementations, most of them share some main characteristics, the most prominent of which is that of group lending. (3) In a typical microfinance scheme, borrowers with individual risky projects form groups that apply for loans together. The whole group is liable if one or more group members default. Thus, joint liability provides an insurance against individual risks. Even if an individual project fails and some of the borrowers are unable to repay, the group as a whole might still be able to do so. In this sense, joint liability serves as a substitute for collateral. Unless the individual risks are perfectly correlated, the overall risk of involuntary nonrepayment can be substantially lower than with individual borrowing.

Compared with traditional credit programs in less developed countries, microcredit schemes have proved to be a great success. Repayment rates leaped to levels previously unseen in less developed regions. Grameen reports repayment rates of more than 90%; other programs replicated such figures. However, the story is not without blemish: Although many were successful, numerous MFI programs have failed to live up to their promise (see, e.g., Conlin 1999). Furthermore, the ultimate goal of establishing sustainable credit schemes for the poor has not been reached, and most programs still rely on subsidies and donations.

To improve the performance of microlending, it is vital to improve the design of these schemes. Among practitioners as well as academic scholars, there is a heated debate on the appropriate design of their key features. Lending to groups involves a fundamental dilemma: It may insure the credit against involuntary defaults, but individual borrowers' reliance on fellow borrowers to repay the loan gives the former an incentive to free ride. Indeed, if the success of an individual project is not sufficiently verifiable by other group members, the dominant strategy for each individual is to shirk and hold others liable for own default. Being aware of this peril, MFI schemes have usually incorporated a number of safeguards, the most prominent of which is that borrower groups be self-selected. This is the case in many programs, the expectation being that close social ties enhance peer pressure and group solidarity. In a theoretical study, Besley and Coate (1995) show that the possibility of inflicting social sanctions on peers helps improve repayment. (4) However, the effectiveness of self-selection is not undisputed; Wydick (1999) empirically investigates MFIs in Guatemala and finds no evidence that groups made up of acquaintances have higher repayment rates than those consisting of strangers. Social ties may even hamper repayment discipline if they lead to more "forgivingness" toward defaulters. (5)

Free-riding incentives may depend crucially on the size of the borrowing groups. In practice, it is unclear how far group size affects repayment rates. FINCA, the organization that pioneered the village banking concept, lends to large borrower groups of between 10 and 50 members and boasts repayment rates of 96%. (6) On the other hand, Grameen prefers smaller groups with typically only five members to keep free riding and in-group coordination problems under control. In the academic literature, both positions have their advocates. Ghatak and Guinnane (1999) argue that despite the insurance effect of larger groups, smaller groups are to be preferred for their better in-group coordination and reduced level of free riding. (7) On the other hand, Buckley (1996) empirically finds that groups with 10 or more members still can work effectively.

Though much of the literature focuses on group size and social ties, the importance of dynamic incentives is acknowledged to a much lesser extent. In general, MFIs aim at forming long-term relationships with their client groups. Follow-up loans are frequently made subject to whether previous loans have been repaid. These two features are intended to encourage compliance with repayment obligations. It can be argued that this aspect of microcredit schemes is at least as important for generating repayment discipline as peer pressure between the group members. It might even be the central instrument through which peer pressure between MFI group members is generated. Creating dynamic incentives may become vital if microcredit schemes are to be applied to other economies. In the urban contexts of transition economies, for instance, it may be more difficult to form self-selected borrowing groups than in closer-knit rural communities. For this reason Armendariz de Aghion and Morduch (2000) argue that in such economies the focus on group lending should be abandoned, and suitable dynamic incentive schemes should be sought.

The empirical evidence on how the various design features of microcredit schemes affect their success is still limited and controversial. Morduch (1999) promotes the need for well-designed experiments to identify the impact of MFI design features on their performance. However, controlled experiments in which single properties of institutions are systematically varied are difficult to carry out in the field due to problems of data accessibility and comparability. (8) Furthermore, many relevant variables, for example, the individual project risk, are unobservable. Therefore, we introduce an alternative approach to the empirical analysis of microfinance institutions. In an interactive laboratory experiment, we can control for specific parameters and observe behavior in simulated MFI scenarios directly. Furthermore, we can identify which factors influence behavior by changing particular variables of the experimental environment, holding all other aspects unchanged.

As a starting point for our research agenda, we construct a stylized MFI scenario. To study free-riding behavior connected to group lending, we model a situation in which repayment is not compatible with selfish own-income maximization. To implement dynamic incentives, follow-up loans are subject to full repayment in the past. In our experiment, each member of a group of n players invests in an individual risky project. Whether the project succeeds is known only to the individual investor. Subjects decide individually whether to contribute to the group repayment. However, only those with successful projects are able to contribute. The experiment ends if too few contribute, that is, if the group as a whole cannot fulfill its repayment obligation. We focus on three instrumental variables identified as crucial for MFI success: (I) the group size, which we set to n = 2, n = 4, and n = 8 in three conditions; (2) the dynamic incentive structure; and (3) the intensity of social ties between group members. In a "group recruitment treatment" subjects already had to enroll as a group to capture the influence of social ties.

We observe a high and robust performance of group lending institutions in all our treatments. In fact, repayment rates are generally higher than those achievable by individual lending. Although individual contribution rates decrease slightly with larger groups, the impact of free riding is alleviated by the greater dispersion of risks. We clearly identify the importance of dynamic incentives. Toward the end of the experiment, repayment rates decrease substantially. Furthermore, we find that social ties only have a relatively moderate effect on repayment rates. Closer-knit groups have higher repayment rates than those composed of strangers, but this effect is significant only in the beginning of the experiment.

II. RELATED EXPERIMENTAL STUDIES

To our knowledge, laboratory experiments on microcredit institutions have not yet emerged in the literature. However, because microcredit institutions allow group members to free ride at the cost of the group, valuable insights may be gained from the literature on public good games. In such games, each subject of a group of n persons can decide to invest an amount x (up to a certain limit y) in a public good. Everybody in the group of n individuals receives a return of cx, where c < 1, but nc > 1. Thus, it is a dominant strategy for rational players not to invest, but the Pareto-efficient solution is realized if everybody cooperates by investing the maximum amount. In experimental public good games, subjects typically contribute considerable amounts but fail to reach the social optimum.

Inspired by the microfinance theme, Barr and Kinsey (2002) conduct an experiment on such a public good game in Zimbabwean villages. Though they do not aim at modeling a microfinance scenario, their research question is closely linked to common MFI practices. Many MFIs target women as their clients, partly because they consider women's empowerment as a goal as such but also because women are often seen as more reliable borrowers. (9) The authors test this conjecture by analyzing women's and men's behavior in the standard public goods game. The differences they find are small but qualitatively supportive of the MFI practice: Women tend to contribute more to the public good than men.

The studies most akin to our experimental set-up are the public good experiments by Suleiman et al. (2002) and Renner (2006). In both studies players' endowments y are stochastic and private information. Thus, as in our design, players cannot identify whether other players' failure to contribute is due to bad luck or shirking. In the first study, the authors compare this environment with a standard public good setting with fixed endowments and find less free riding. Renner (2006) compares stochastic endowments with either public or private information and finds that contribution rates are lower if information on individuals' endowments is private.

In threshold public good games, (10) a fixed prize is given to each of the group members if the sum of K is collected from voluntarily contributions by the n group members. The prize money exceeds K, such that it is efficient that the public good be provided. Our setting resembles features of this game in that the reward for contributing (the continuation of play) is a discrete variable and requires a minimum number of contributors. Croson and Marks (2000) provide a survey and synthesis of experimental work on threshold games and present an experiment examining variations of the threshold. They find that subjects tend to contribute more if the step return on contributions increases, that is, if the threshold relative to the prize is lowered. The transferability of results from threshold games is, however, only limited, as the strategic situation is very different: In the threshold game, efficient strategic equilibria involve positive contributions, and the equilibrium level of contribution is not invariant to changes in threshold or prize. This is different from our model, in which the subgame-perfect equilibrium invariably predicts no contributions at all.

Several authors have examined the role of social factors in experimental public good games. All these studies, however, deal with symmetric situations in which endowments are the same for all and known to all players. Gachter and Fehr (1999) investigate whether social approval incentives reduce free-riding behavior in a repeated public good game. Subjects have the opportunity for social approval toward their group members after the experiment. It turned out that social approval alone could not enhance cooperation. However, if in addition subjects could familiarize themselves with each other before the experiment cooperation increases significantly. (11) This suggests that ex ante familiarity may be important in establishing cooperation. In another study Van Dijk et al. (2002), and Brandts et al. (2002) investigate the development of social connectedness as a result of repeated interaction in a public good setting and find that social attachment becomes stronger after successful cooperation.

The effect of group size has been studied first by Isaac et al. (1994) in public good experiments with 4, 10, 40, and 100 participants. They find that contrary to the common conjecture, contributions even increase with very large groups. A similar result is obtained by Carpenter (2002), who compares groups of 5 and 10 subjects. However, in both studies, marginal social benefits increase hugely as the group size increases, which may account for this effect. Unless there are strong synergies between the individual projects within an MFI borrowing group, this is typically not a characteristic of microfinance institutions.

Unlike in most public good games, repayment in a microfinance scenario does not solely depend on the willingness but also depends on the ability to repay. Through no fault of their own, individuals whose project fail cannot contribute to repayment, and hence they rely on fellow group members helping them. Individuals' sense of solidarity is assessed in the solidarity game experimented by Selten and Ockenfels (1998). Three players each roll a die to determine whether they win a prize. Winners can transfer money to losers. Contrary to the game theoretic prediction, the great majority make substantial transfers, where females show more solidarity than males.

None of these studies has been carried out with a microfinance background in mind. Consequently, there is no study examining group cooperation in a dynamic environment with follow-up benefits conditional on compliant behavior. The incentive structure in the existing studies is quite different from a typical microfinance environment. Therefore, the findings of these studies cannot be immediately transferred to the MFIs in question. Hence the need for a new experiment.

III. MODEL AND EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN

We consider a very simple experimental setup capturing essential features of group lending. Because MFIs come in many different forms, we were forced to make design choices. In the present study, we focus on the conflict between free riding and cooperation in the borrower group, thus, we assume that individual repayment cannot be enforced. To focus on the conflict between group and individual interest, we assume that individuals have no means of verifying the success or failure of their fellow borrowers' individual projects. (12) Furthermore, by assuming that the success of the individual projects is uncorrelated, we abstract from complications that arise if risks are connected, for example, if their success depends on seasonal conditions. Finally, we consider a symmetric situation in which there are no differences in the individuals' strategic situation.

The Model

A group of n individuals receives a loan, for the repayment of which all group members are jointly liable. The loan enables each group member to invest in an individual risky project. All projects are of the same type, and the probability of success of any given project is 5/6. In case of success, the investor receives a project payoff of 420 talers (the fictitious experimental currency). If the project fails, however (the probability of which being 1/6), the subject receives a project payoff of zero. As mentioned, we assume that the risks of the individual projects are independent from one another, so we represent the projects' successes as independent random draws.

After all projects have been carried out, the group loan has to be repaid. For repayment to ensue, we assume that each individual is supposed to repay 210 talers, and hence the group is liable to repay a total amount of 21 On talers (for example, if we assume a loan of 175 talers per individual and an interest rate of 20%). Those individuals whose projects failed cannot contribute to the repayment; to ensure that this condition pertains, we assume that no investor receives income from another source and that none possesses savings which could be used to repay the loan in the eventuality that the project fails.

Individuals whose project succeeds decide whether to contribute to the group repayment. As mentioned, information on the project's success or failure is private; no other group member can ascertain whether an individual's default is strategic or due to the failure of the project. Hence, we model an idealized scenario in which the repayment of loans must ensue in the absence of means to enforce repayment.

To model joint liability in a simple and straightforward way, the debt of 210n talers is split evenly among those individuals who are able and willing to contribute. Thus, the fewer individuals contribute, the higher the burden for the single contributor. Because contributions can only be financed from the current round's project payoffs, full repayment is only possible if at least half of the group members contribute.

Only if the group fulfills its repayment obligation does the game continue into a further round, which proceeds in the same way with the same group members (a maximum of 10 rounds can be played). If more than half the group members default (regardless of whether the default is strategic or due to project failure), then the group cannot repay the full amount, in which case no further rounds are played and the subjects of the group obtain no further payoffs during the experiment. With this feature, we model the practice of many MFIs, which make follow-up loans conditional on the full repayment of previous loans.

After each round, players are informed about the number of contributors in the respective round (but not their identities), their own project payoff, and their round payoff (comprised of one's own project payoff minus the player's share of the repayment burden).

The game theoretic prediction, assuming that players maximize their own income, is that no contributions at all are made thus bringing play to an end after the first round. The intuition is straightforward. In the last round, it is obvious that no player would ever contribute. Now consider the penultimate round. Table 1 shows the payoff distribution a player would get given the number of other players willing and able to play, for eight-player groups (n = 8). (13) The entries in italics mark the cases in which the number of players contributing suffices for the game to reach the final round. The payoffs are composed of the (sure) payoffs in the penultimate round plus the lottery that the player gets in the final round. It can easily be seen that the payoff distribution a player gets from not contributing stochastically dominates the one he or she would obtain by contributing. This is true regardless of the actual number of other players willing and able to repay. Therefore, it can never be profitable to contribute in the penultimate round, and hence one would predict that no game enters round 10. By induction, it follows that in a subgame-perfect equilibrium, no contributions are made in any round, and play will end after the first round, in which no contributions are made.

Through the unambiguous game theoretic property of the subgame-perfect equilibrium the game draws an idealized picture of a microfinance situation in which repayment cannot be established by players' own payoff maximization alone. Therefore, the game allows us to study the impact of joint liability in a microfinance relationship, because repayment in the group's interest stands in sharp contrast to equilibrium behavior.

It is worthwhile to look at a hypothetical benchmark of individual lending. A single individual can repay the loan if the project is successful. This occurs with a probability of 5/6. Contrary to the case of group lending, an individual would prefer to repay in all rounds bar the last, because the benefits of future credit outweigh the short-term profits of shirking. However, since projects may fail, expected repayment rates cannot exceed 5/6. Thus, although group lending creates free-riding incentives (according the game-theoretic prediction there would be no repayment at all), the dispersion of risks makes it possible to generate higher repayment rates and more profitable loans for the lender. This, however, requires deviation from own-payoff maximization, and one of our research questions is precisely whether group lending mechanisms are able to outperform the benchmark of individual expected repayment rates of 5/6. Note that this benchmark is the best-case scenario for the lender under individual borrowing, assuming that every borrower always repays. If some individual borrowers should not repay due to boundedly rational behavior, then the advantage of group lending is even greater.

Treatments

We designed our experiment to examine two major issues in the design of microfinance schemes. The first issue concerns the effect of different group sizes on repayment performance. In absence of strategic default, larger group sizes provide some insurance against uncorrelated individual risks. However, it is unclear how group size behaviorally affects the tendency to free ride. If free riding is more pronounced in larger groups, this might counteract the insurance effect of larger groups. To test for the effect of group sizes, we conducted experiments with group sizes of n = 2, n = 4, and n = 8. (14)

The second issue we address is the effect of social ties on behavior in a microcredit group. Typically, MFI borrowers are self-selected groups whose members have known each other for some time. Thus, we induce different levels of social ties by applying two distinct recruitment techniques: In the individual recruitment (IR) treatments, subjects register individually for the experiment, thus minimizing social ties between participants interacting with each other. In the group recruitment (GR) treatment, potential participants are required to register for the experiment in groups of four. The latter method ensures that groups are self-selected, because subjects need to form groups to register themselves for the experiment. This method resembles the self-selection process required by real-life microlenders. As in their procedures, borrower groups are formed before they enter the microfinance scheme. (15) To assess the level of acquaintance between the group members, we requested the subjects to indicate the intensity of their contact to the other group members on a scale from 1 (no contact) to 7 (frequent contact), separately for each of the other group mem bers. We distinguish between professional and private contacts. It seems plausible that social ties are more pronounced if the contacts are intensive and private. All statements were made anonymously. (16)

We conducted our GR treatment with a group size of n = 4, given our concern that a group size of two would allow couples (with a common household budget) to register as a group. If the two players effectively act as one, then the social conflict is removed and the incentive structure is reversed. In fact contributing in all rounds except the last one is socially as well as individually optimal. On the other hand we did not conduct experiments with n = 8 for practical reasons: It would have proved too difficult to find self-selected groups of eight subjects. Table 2 indicates the factorial design of our experiment, and in brackets, the number of subjects in the corresponding treatment and the number of statistically independent group observations.

Experimental Procedures

The experiment was conducted in the Erfurter Laboratorium ffir experimentelle Wirtschaftsforschung (eLab) at the University of Erfurt, Germany. Most of the 248 subjects were students from various disciplines, where students of economics, law, and sociology constituted the largest fractions. To minimize presentation effects, we designed our experiment in a completely context-free fashion. We presented the microfinance situation to the experimental subjects without connecting it to a microfinance story. We opted for a neutral presentation to avoid the uncontrolled effects of possible connotations raised by hypothetical stories and to ensure best possible comparability with other experimental results.

Each session began with an introductory talk, after which the written instructions were handed out to the subjects (translations are provided in the appendix, and the original text in German is available on request). The instructions were read aloud and explained in detail. After the introduction, the subjects were seated in cubicles, visually separated from one another by curtains. In the IR treatments, the cubicle numbers were randomly attributed to the subjects, and no subject was informed about the identity of the other players in his group. In the GR treatment, the subjects who had registered together formed a group. This was known to the subjects and further emphasized by decision sheets in different colors for the different groups in a session.

In each round, the success or failure of a project was determined through independent random draws for each subject, with a probability of 1/6 for the failure of the project. Each subject rolled a die to determine his or her project's success or failure for each round. To overcome the difficulty of monitoring the veracity of subject's reports about their draw, we asked subjects at the very beginning of the session (before they knew the rules of the game) to roll a die 10 times and to enter the outcomes in the first column of their decision sheet. Later in the experiment in each round the "losing number" that was the same for all subjects was determined by a randomly selected participant rolling a die. This number was publicly announced. All subjects whose individual number drawn in advance for this round matched the losing number met with the project failure and thus a project payoff of zero. Note that our method of drawing random numbers generates independent draws for each subject in every round.

Each round proceeded as follows. The subjects were each handed one decision sheet, on which the complete history of play was presented on one page. The subjects indicated their repayment decision by ticking "yes" or "no" boxes for the current round. After all subjects had completed their decisions, the experimenter collected the sheets. The losing number for the current round was then drawn. By letting the subjects make their repayment decisions before the losing number was drawn, we gathered decisions also in the case that an individual's project had failed. (17) The experimenters computed the results of the rounds and distributed the decision sheets containing the results.

All groups in the session completed this procedure 10 times, (18) even when their group's play had actually ended as a result of repayment default. This ensured, first, that the constitution of the groups were not revealed by diverging duration of play (this would have distorted both anonymity and the statistical independence of the groups), and second, that a preference for a short playing time could not counteract the monetary incentives.

Immediately after the session, the subjects were paid anonymously in cash. The exchange rate was set to 0.01 [euro] (DM 0.02) per taler. (19) Additionally subjects received a 2.50 [euro] show-up fee. The total earnings in the session ranged from 2.50 [euro] to 34 [euro] with an average of 11.40 [euro] for less than 1.5 hours. This is considerably more than a student's normal hourly wage in Erfurt.

IV. RESULTS

The design of our experiment focuses on the impact of group size, social ties, and the dynamics of play. Most behavioral effects in our data express themselves in the overall number of contributions we observe in the treatment. However, before we conducted the experiment, we decided to also look at the contribution rates for the rounds 1-9 only. Because the game is certain to end after the tenth round, we may expect that behavior in that round to be substantially different. Furthermore, we also analyze the first-round behavior. Statistical tests on first-round behavior can be advantageous because at the very beginning of play each individual decision is a statistically independent observation. We exclusively use nonparametric tests in this study because the small number of independent observations would make any assumption on the underlying distributions problematic. To test for treatment differences, we chose to apply Fisher's two-sample permutation test to all pairwise comparisons of the contribution rates in the independent subject groups. This method tests whether two independent samples are likely to be drawn from the same distribution. Rejection of the null hypothesis indicates that the entries from one sample tend to be smaller or greater than those from the other sample. This test is an alternative to the more widely used Mann-Whitney U-test. It can be seen as more powerful because it uses more information. Rather than only considering ranks of the variables, it uses the actual values. (20) A discussion of the properties of permutation tests can be found in Moir (1998) and Nirel and Gorfine (2003).

Repayment Performance

Table 3 shows how many participants agreed to contribute (chose yes on the decision sheet) on average in the four treatments of our experiment. Additionally, it reports average contribution rates in the first round as well as averages over the first nine rounds. In the first round, between 81.3% (treatment IR8) and 98.1% (GR4) of the subjects decide to contribute if their project turns out to be successful. The contribution rates over all rounds of the experiment are lower but still considerably high. Notice that according to the selfish equilibrium prediction, we should observe no contributions at all.

From the lender's point of view the most interesting question regarding different MFI designs is how they affect the repayment rate. To address this question in our experimental framework one could look at the actual repayment rates realized in the sessions. However, these are highly influenced by the realizations of the random draws. Thus, we rather look at expected repayment rates, which we define as the repayment rate that the lender could expect if we take observed default rates as a proxy for the probability that a borrower defaults strategically. Denote by [psi] the probability that a borrower is willing to repay. Then, actual repayment probability is 5/6 [psi], because he or she can only repay when the project is successful. Given this probability, the number of group members actually contributing is binomially distributed with a single event probability of 5/6 [psi]. Thus, the expected repayment rate ERR can be computed as

(1) ERR([psi]) = [[n/2-1.summation over (k=0)] 420 x k x B(n, k, 5/6 [psi]) + [n.summation over (k=n/2)] 210 x n x B(n, k, 5/6 [psi])] /[210 x n],

where B denotes the noncumulated binomial distribution. The repayment (in talers) in the case that less than n/2 group members actually repay is given by the first sum of the numerator. In this case, the loan is only partially repaid, but those who pay must give their entire project payoff of 420. The second sum computes the expected repayment in case that the whole loan is repaid. (21)

Figure 1 depicts the expected repayment rates for the four treatments of the experiment, using for [psi] the observed rates of contribution decisions in the corresponding round and treatment.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

As mentioned earlier, individual lending can at maximum generate a repayment rate of 5/6 = 83.3%. Recall that according to the theoretical predictions, individual borrowers would always repay, groups never repay.

In our experiment, however, lenders would prefer group lending to individual lending. In all treatments, expected repayment rates are above this theoretical benchmark most of the time and are substantially higher in earlier rounds. Thus, group lending outperforms individual lending, even though our set-up does not provide any monitoring opportunities to the borrowers.

The Effect of the Group Size

Although large groups allow for a greater dispersion of risks one could expect that they are also prone to more free riding. Indeed, Table 3 suggests that contribution levels tend to decrease with the size of the group, but only to a moderate extent. The statistical analysis provides only weak support. The nonparametric Jonckheere test, applied to the rates of yes choices in rounds 1-9 in the single independent groups, rejects the null hypothesis of equal rates in favor of the hypothesis of decreasing rates at a weak significance level of p = 0.08 (one-sided). (22) Of all pairwise comparisons, we can reject the null hypothesis of equal contribution rates only for the comparison of the contribution rates in rounds 1-9 for IR8 versus IR4. The rates tend to be weakly significantly (p = 0.0219, one-sided, Fisher's two-sample permutation test) lower in the IR8 condition. All other differences are not statistically significant (p = 0.296 for IR2 versus IR4 and p = 0.166 for IR2 versus IR8, one-sided, Fisher's two-sample permutation test).

Table 3 also indicates a decreasing average duration of play. However, the Jonckheere test does not reject the null hypothesis of an equal number of played rounds. Notice that the continuation of play is not only determined by the subjects' decisions but also by the chance moves determining success and failure of the individual projects.

Dynamics of Play

Because we have a finite number of rounds the dynamic incentives become weaker over time, as there are fewer rounds left in which profits can be made. Thus, we should expect contribution rates to decrease toward the end of play. Figure 2 shows that this is indeed the case. Though still more than two-thirds of subjects contribute in round 7, late-round contribution rates fall substantially. However, they do not reach zero, even in the last round of play. It seems surprising that even in the last round a considerable number of subjects contribute, though no further rounds can be expected. (23)

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

The decreasing trend of the contribution decisions can be observed not only in the aggregate data but also in the single groups. We compute for each session separately nonparametric Spearman rank correlation coefficients between the number of yes choices and rounds. Table 4 reports these rank correlation coefficients. Using these as summary statistics, the binomial test rejects the null hypothesis that positive and negative correlation coefficients are equally likely at a significance level of at least [alpha] = 0.05 (one-sided) for all four treatments. (24)

The Effect of Social Ties

In the GR treatment, the groups who registered together can be expected to be a self-selected group in which social ties are stronger than in the anonymously matched groups of the IR treatment. The question arises whether these stronger social ties result in higher repayment rates due to a higher impact of group solidarity in self-selected groups. Our data provide mixed evidence with this respect. Although the first-round contribution rate significantly rises from 86.5% in IR4 to 98.1% in GR4 (p = 0.027 according to the Fisher exact test), we obtain an overall contribution rate that is even slightly lower in GR4 than in IR4 (75.5% versus 79.9%). Thus, the comparison of the contribution rate over the two treatments does not provide strong evidence for an effect of social ties on repayment rates. These results are in line with those of the survey study by Wydick (1999), who finds a "surprisingly small degree to which social ties within borrowing groups affect group performance."

Within the GR4 treatment, we find some evidence that the extent to which the group members are socially tied matters. As mentioned earlier, we asked for statements about the level of acquaintance between the group members. When we correlate the level of private social contacts to the overall contribution rate in the groups, we obtain a Spearman rank correlation coefficient of [r.sub.s] = 0.412, which is weakly significant at [alpha] = 0.10 (one-sided). Thus, stronger private contacts between the group members seem to have a positive effect on repayment decisions. The same analysis with the level of professional contact does not yield a significant result.

V. SUMMARY AND DISCUSSION

We introduce an experimental microfinance game to separate the impact of essential characteristics of group lending contracts on repayment performance. Small loans are given to groups who are jointly liable for repayment. Incentives to repay are provided through the prospect of follow-up loans. We report an experiment to investigate the influence of those features on strategic default of group members. Treatments involve different group sizes and a condition in which self-selected subject groups register for the experiment together.

We observe high willingness to repay in all treatments, though game theory would recommend free riding. Indeed, the experimental lending groups reach high repayment rates and are able to sustain the flow of further credits for several periods. The willingness to contribute declines as the experiment proceeds, but it remains remarkably high, even in the later periods, where the incentives to keep up the borrowing relationship diminish.

We also examine the question of group size, which is much discussed in MFI policy. A dilemma arises when the advantage of larger groups through the insurance effect is counteracted by less cooperation and more free riding. Our results show that the performance of the experimental microcredit groups is surprisingly robust with respect to group size. Though the larger groups indeed manifest a higher tendency toward shirking, their superior dispersion of risk makes them perform at least as well as smaller groups in our parameter constellation.

Our results are also robust against variations of social ties between the members of the experimental borrower groups. Overall performance is not significantly worse with strangers than with good acquaintances. Self-selected groups exhibit a higher willingness to contribute in the beginning of the experiment, but their behavior is less stable, possibly because friends are less willing to tolerate supposed free riding by others. Of course when looking at this result, one has to be aware that in our experiment the acquaintance of the self-selected groups was exclusively formed before the experiment. During the experiment these groups did not have closer contact to each other compared to groups in the other treatments. In the naturally occurring setting, members of better acquainted groups would presumably also know more about the current likelihood that an individual was successful. This would reduce the possibility of attributing nonrepayment to the result of a bad draw from nature.

We believe that the experimental method is especially well suited to gaining a deeper understanding of how and why group lending schemes succeed or fail in practice. The present study provides a framework in which the effects of central MFI features can be disentangled. Of course, the present study should be seen as a starting point rather than a comprehensive exploration. To keep things simple, we have developed a very basic model that naturally lacks many of the complexities of real life group lending contracts. Furthermore, our experiment has been conducted in our laboratory using an student subject pool. MFIs are implemented all over the world within a great variety of economic and cultural backgrounds, such that the replication of our findings in different societies with different subject pools seems a promising research agenda for the future.

APPENDIX: THE WRITTEN INSTRUCTIONS

The original instructions were written in German. They are available on request from the authors. The following instructions are those for the treatment IR8. The instructions for the treatments IR2 and IR4 differ only in the corresponding numbers. The instructions for treatment GR4 contain one different sentence, which is indicated below.

Experimental Instructions

During the experiment you belong to a group consisting of 8 randomly chosen members.

{GR4 treatment: During the experiment you belong to a group consisting of the 4 members with whom you have registered}.

The composition of each group does not change throughout the experiment.

The experiment starts with the first round. Whether there will be a following round depends on the group's result of the previous round. A maximum of 10 rounds are played.

Contribution to the Group Payment? In every round, each member of a group decides whether to contribute to a group payment or whether not to contribute.

In each round, the group has to raise a total amount of 1,680 talers in order to reach a further round.

Who is able to pay and who pays how much?

For each group member, it is randomly determined whether he receives an amount of 420 talers. For this, in every round the experimenter asks a randomly chosen participant to roll a die. If the number is identical to the number for the respective round, which a participant has written down in the first column before the beginning of the experiment, this participant receives 0 talers. If the numbers do not match, the participant receives 420 talers. Thus, the decision whether a participant receives 420 talers takes place at random and independently of all other participants.

A group member can only contribute to the group payment if he has received 420 talers in this round. A group member who has 0 talers cannot contribute. His payoff is 0 talers.

The amount of 1,680 talers that must be raised by the group will be divided equally between those group members who decided to contribute to the group payment and who in addition are able to contribute, that is, have received 420 talers. The more members of a group are willing and able to contribute, the less the amount each member has to pay. This amount will be subtracted from the 420 talers received by each paying member.

The contributions and round payoffs of a paying member result as follows:
Number of Round Payoff
Paying Contribution for a
Group per Paying Group Raises Paying
Members Member 1,680 Talers? Member

0 -- No [right arrow] no
 further round
1 420 No [right arrow] no 0
 further round
2 420 No [right arrow] no 0
 further round
3 420 No [right arrow] no 0
 further round
4 420 Yes [right arrow] 0
 further round
5 336 Yes [right arrow] 84
 further round
6 280 Yes [right arrow] 140
 further round
7 240 Yes [right arrow] 180
 further round
8 210 Yes [right arrow] 210
 further round


All members who have received 420 talers and have decided not to contribute to the group payment obtain this 420 talers as the payoff for this round.

Structure of the Experiment

The structure of all rounds is identical. Each group member decides whether he wants to contribute to the group payment by ticking "yes" or "no" in column 2 of the decision sheet. The decision is taken only for the current round. Thus, please tick only the box which corresponds with the current round, but not those for the following rounds.

The experimenters collect all decision sheets and a randomly chosen participant rolls a die. This number is publicly announced and recorded in column 3 by the experimenter. The provisional round payoff results as explained above (column 4): If the numbers of column 1 and 3 match, the group member receives 0 for this round; if the numbers differ he receives a provisional round payoff of 420. The experimenter determines the number of paying group members (column 5) and writes down the final round payment for each member in column 6. Column 7 informs whether the group succeeded in raising the amount of 1,680 talers, and the experiment continues with the next round.

For each participant the total payoff is determined (in talers) at the end of the experiment and is converted into at an exchange rate of 1.00 [euro] per 100 talers. Additionally each participant receives an amount of 2.50 [euro].

The total amount is paid in cash to each participant at the end of the experiment.

Please note: All decisions are made anonymously, that is, at the end of a round each member is only informed about his own decision, his own payoff, and the number of paying group members. During the experiment all participants sit in a cubicle. No conclusions can be drawn regarding the identity of the other group members, their decisions or payoffs.

To make sure that anonymity is guaranteed, it is necessary to adhere to the following rules:

* During the experiment it is forbidden to speak or to communicate in any way.

* All members are asked to stay in their cubicles till the end of the experiment.

Even if in a round a group does not succeed in raising the amount of 1,680 talers, which means that no further rounds are taking place for this group, all participants have to stay in their cubicles until the end of the experiment. The experimenters continue to hand out and to collect the decision papers also for this group. Of course, those group members do not have to take decisions anymore.

ABBREVIATIONS

GR: Group Recruitment

IR: Individual Recruitment

MFI: Microfinance Institution

REFERENCES

Abbink, Klaus, Bernd Irlenbusch, and Elke Renner. "An Experimental Bribery Game." Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 18, 2002, 428-54.

Armendariz de Aghion, Beatriz. "On the Design of a Credit Agreement with Peer Monitoring." Journal of Development Economics, 60, 1999, 79-104.

Armendariz de Aghion, Beatriz, and Christian Gollier. "Peer Group Formation in an Adverse Selection Model." Economic Journal, 110, 2000, 632-43.

Armendariz de Aghion, Beatriz, and Jonathan Morduch. "Microfinance beyond Group Lending." Economics of Transition, 8, 2000, 401 20.

Bagnoli, Mark, and Michael McKee. "Voluntary Contribution Games: Efficient Private Provision of Public Goods." Economic Inquiry, 29, 1991, 351 66.

Barr, Abigail, and Bill Kinsey. "Do Men Really Have no Shame?" Working paper, University of Oxford, 2002.

Besley, Timothy, and Stephan Coate. "Group Lending, Repayment Incentives and Social Collateral." Journal of Development Economics, 46, 1995, 1-18.

Bohnet, Iris, and Bruno S. Frey. "The Sound of Silence in Prisoner's Dilemma and Dictator Games." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 38, 1999, 43-57.

Bolnik, Bruce R. "Evaluating Loan Collection Performance: An Indonesian Example." World Development, 16, 1988, 501-10.

Brandts, Jordi, Arno Riedl, and Frans van Winden. "Competitive Rivalry and Social Ties. An Experimental Study." Mimeo, Institut d'Analisi Economica (CSIC), Barcelona, 2002.

Buckley, Graeme. "Rural and Agricultural Credit in Malawi: A Study of the Malawi Mudzi Fund and the Smallholder Agricultural Credit Administration," in Finance against Poverty, edited by David Hulme and Paul Mosley. London: Routledge, 1996.

Carpenter, Jeffrey P. "Punishing Free-Riders: How Group Size Affects Mutual Monitoring and the Provision of Public Goods." Games and Economic Behavior, forthcoming.

Coats, Jennifer C., and William S. Neilson. "Beliefs about Other-Regarding Preferences in a Sequential Public Goods Game." Economic Inquiry, 43, 2005, 614-22.

Conlin, Michael. "Peer Group Micro-Lending Programs in Canada and the United States." Journal of Development Economics, 60, 1999, 249-69.

Croson, Rachel T. A., and Melanie B. Marks. "Step Returns in Threshold Public Goods: A Meta- and Experimental Analysis." Experimental Economics, 2, 2000, 239-59.

Dawes, Robyn M., Jeanne McTavish, and Harriet Shaklee. "Behavior, Communication, and Assumptions about Other People's Behavior in a Commons Dilemma Situation." Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, 1977, 1-11.

Devereux, John, and Rauymond P. H. Fishe. "An Economic Analysis of Group Lending Programs in Developing." Developing Economies, 31, 1993, 102-21.

Gachter, Simon, and Ernst Fehr. "Collective Action as a Social Exchange." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 39, 1999, 341-69.

Ghatak, Maitreesh. "Screening by the Company You Keep: Joint Liability Lending and the Peer Selection Effect." Economic Journal, 110, 2000, 601-31.

Ghatak, Maitreesh, and Timothy W. Guinnane. "The Economics of Lending with Joint Liability: Theory and Practice." Journal of Development Economics, 60, 1999, 195-228.

Gneezy, Uri. "Probability Judgments in Multi-Stage Problems: Experimental Evidence of Systematic Biases." Acta Psychologica, 93, 1996, 59-68.

Goetz, Anne Marie, and Rina Sen Gupta. "Who Takes the Credit? Gender, Power and Control over Loan Use in Rural Credit Programmes in Bangladesh." Worm Development, 24, 1996, 45-63.

Guinnane, Timothy W. "A Failed Institutional Transplant: Raiffeisen Credit Cooperatives in Ireland 1894-1914." Explorations in Economic History, 31, 1994, 38-61.

Hulme, David. "Impact Assessment Methodologies for Microfinance: Theory, Experience and Better Practice." World Development, 28, 2000, 79-98.

Impavido, Gregorio. "Credit Rationing, Group Lending and Optimal Group Size." Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 69, 1998, 243-60.

Isaac, R. Mark, and James M. Walker. "Communication and Free Riding Behavior: The Voluntary Contribution Mechanism." Economic Inquiry, 26, 1988, 585-608.

--. "Costly Communication: An Experiment in Nested Public Goods Problem," in Laboratory Research in Political Economy, edited by Thomas Palfrey. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1991, pp. 269-86.

Isaac, R. Mark, Kenneth F. McCue, and Charles R. Plott. "Public Goods Provision in an Experimental Environment." Journal of Public Economics, 26, 1985, 51-74.

Isaac, R. Mark, James M. Walker, and Arlington W. Williams. "Group Size and the Voluntary Provision of Public Goods." Journal of Public Economics, 54, 1994, 1-36.

Kabeer, Naila. "Conflicts over Credit: Re-Evaluationg the Empowerment Potential of Loans to Women in Rural Bangladesh." World Development, 29, 2001, 63-84.

Ledgerwood, Joanna. Microfinance Handbook. Washington, DC: World Bank, 1999.

Moir, Robert. "A Monte Carlo Analysis of the Fisher Randomization Technique: Reviving Randomization for Experimental Economists." Experimental Economies, 1, 1998, 87-100.

Morduch, Jonathan. "The Microfinance Promise." Journal of Economics Literature, 37, 1999, 1569-614.

Morduch, Jonathan, and Beatriz Armendariz de Aghion. The Economics of Microfinance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University and MIT Press, 2005.

Mosley, Paul, and Rudra Prasad Dahal. "Credit for the Rural Poor: A Comparison of Policy Experiments in Nepal and Bangladesh." Manchester Papers on Development, 3, 1987, 45-59.

Nirel, Ronit, and Malka Gorfine. "Nonparametric Analysis of Longitudinal Binary Data: An Application to the Intergroup Prisoner's Dilemma Game." Experimental Economies, 6, 2003, 327-41.

Renner, Elke. "When in Doubt ...--Cooperation and Punishment under Incomplete Information." Working paper, University of Nottingham, 2006.

Selten, Reinhard, and Axel Ockenfels. "An Experimental Solidarity Game." Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 34, 1998, 517-39.

Stiglitz, Joseph E. "Peer Monitoring and Credit Markets." World Bank Economic Review, 4, 1990, 351-66.

Stiglitz, Joseph E., and Andrew Weiss. "Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information." American Economic Review, 71, 1981, 393-410.

Suleiman, Ramzi, Taly Weiss, and Gary Bornstein. "The Enhancing Effect of Uncertainty about Individual Endowments on the Provision of Public Goods." Mimeo, Hebrew University Jerusalem, 2002.

Van Dijk, Frans, Joep Sonnemans, and Frans van Winden. "Social Ties in a Public good Experiment." Journal of Public Economics, 85, 2002, 275-99.

Varian, Hal R. "Monitoring Agents with Other Agents." Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 146, 1990, 153-74.

Wenner, M. "Group Credit. A Means to Improve Information Transfer and Loan Repayment Performance." Journal of Development Studies, 32, 1995, 263-81.

Wydick, Bruce. "Can Social Cohesion Be Harnessed to Repair Market Failures? Evidence from Group Lending in Guatemala." Economic Journal, 109, 1999, 463-75.

(1.) Examples include BancoSol and PRODEM in Bolivia; Banka Rakyat and Badan Kredit in Indonesia; BRAC in Bangladesh; Pride Africa in Kenya, Tanzania, Malawi, and Uganda; and FINADEV in Benin.

(2.) See Conlin (1999), Armendariz de Aghion and Morduch (2000), or Morduch and Armendariz de Aghion (2005) for an overview.

(3.) Therefore, MFIs are often referred to as joint liability lending institutions, though some institutions also give small loans to individuals with good reputation (Armendariz de Aghion and Morduch 2000).

(4.) Conlin (1999) argues that replicating the MFI concept in Western cities requires that schemes rely less on social ties. See also Wenner (1995).

(5.) Guinnane (1994) conjectures that such an effect may have contributed to the failure of Irish credit cooperatives in the nineteenth century.

(6.) FINCA's scheme differs from others with respect to the internal organization of borrower groups. Villages in FINCA projects form self-governed groups to which the loan is given. The distribution of credit is left largely to the group members themselves.

(7.) This argument is supported in empirical investigations by Mosley and Dahal (1987) and Devereux and Fishe (1993). Theoretical investigations into the tension between positive insurance and negative free-riding effects are provided by Impavido (1998) and Armendariz de Aghion (1999).

(8.) These difficulties are discussed in Bolnik (1988) and Hulme (2000).

(9.) There is some evidence that women's repayment discipline is higher due to a better sense of responsibility (Ledgerwood 1999, p. 38). Morduch (1999, p. 1583) reports studies finding that male lending groups at Grameen have higher default rates than female groups. For critical accounts of the women-focused policy, see Goetz and Sen Gupta (1996) and Kabeer (2001).

(10.) See Bagnoli and McKee (1991) and Coats and Neilson (2005) for discussions of simultaneous and sequential contributions, respectively.

(11.) This is in line with earlier findings by Dawes et al. (1977), Isaac et al. (1985), Isaac and Walker (1988, 1991), Bohnet and Frey (1999). Although they examine different questions, they all find that preplay communication increases cooperation.

(12.) This is in line with the assumptions made by Besley and Coate (1995) in a theoretical study. The issue of peer screening and peer monitoring in group lending is addressed by Stiglitz and Weiss (1981), Stiglitz (1990), Varian (1990), Ghatak and Guinanne (1999), Armendariz de Aghion and Gollier (2000), and Ghatak (2000).

(13.) The argument is completely analogous for n = 2 and n = 4. It can easily be generalized for a wide range of other parameter constellations. Notice that the argument does not require assumptions about the subject's attitude to risk.

(14.) This roughly covers the range of most typical MFIs. Only few lend to groups with more than eight borrowers.

(15.) When they register for our experiment, however, subjects did not know the task they would perform. This was explained to them only in the actual session. This ensured that the state of information about the task was the same for all subjects at the outset of a session.

(16.) For different research questions, other techniques have been applied to study the impact of social ties. Gachter and Fehr (1999) and Bohnet and Frey (1999) invite strangers, but allow subjects in one condition to get acquainted with each other in a preplay communication stage. Van Dijk et al. (2002) and Brandts et al. (2002) study the evolvement of social ties through interaction and assess social ties using psychological tests before and after play.

(17.) This creates an element of strategy elicitation, which may or may not affect participants' behavior in the game. It does not seem likely, however, that this elicitation method would differentially affect repayment across treatments.

(18.) We conducted each session with at least two groups to ensure that subjects (in the IR treatment) could not identify which of the other subjects belong to their group.

(19.) Some of the sessions were conducted before and others after the euro was introduced in Germany. The exchange rate between DM and euro was 1.95583 DM for 1 euro, thus very close to the adjustment we made.

(20.) The downside is that it is computationally intensive. Software for this test is available from the authors on request.

(21.) The insurance effect of larger groups was principally understood by the subjects. In a postexperimental questionnaire, we asked subjects to estimate the probability to reach the final round for different group sizes (n [member of] {2, 4, 8}) and round numbers (n [member of] {5, 10, 20}) given that all group members are willing to contribute. On average the influence of the two dimensions was assessed qualitatively correct, though overall probabilities were quantitatively underestimated. The latter result replicates previous findings by Gneezy (1996) and Abbink et al. (2002) in the sense that dynamic effects are not sufficiently taken into account.

(22.) The analysis of group size effects is based on the three treatments with individual recruitment.

(23.) Possibly a solidarity motive accounts for this type of behavior. If a subject expects other subjects to contribute, then own contribution can ease the fellow players' burden of repayment.

(24.) Notice that the exclusion of round 10 is conservative to our findings.

KLAUS ABBINK, BERND IRLENBUSCH, and ELKE RENNER *

* We are indebted to Christiane Pilz and Tim Wenniges for valuable research assistance. We thank an anonymous coeditor, an anonymous referee, Matthew Ellman, Mark Peacock, and seminar participants in Barcelona, Exeter, Jena, Kiel, London, Nottingham, and Warwick for helpful comments and suggestions. Financial support from the European Union through the TMR research network ENDEAR (FMRX-CT98-0238), the Spanish Ministerio de Educacion, Cultura y Deporte, the Nuffield Foundation, the University of Erfurt, and the University of Nottingham is gratefully acknowledged. Part of this research has been carried out while Abbink was a visitor at the Institut d'Analisi Economica, Barcelona. He gratefully acknowledges that institution's hospitality and support.

Abbink: School of Economics, University of Nottingham, University Park, Nottingham NG7 2RD, United Kingdom. Phone 441159514768, Fax 441159514159, E-mail [email protected]

Irlenbusch: London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, United Kingdom. Phone 442079557840, Fax 442079556887, E-mail [email protected]

Renner: School of Economics, University of Nottingham, University Park, Nottingham NG7 2RD, United Kingdom. Phone 441159515399, Fax 441159514159, E-mail [email protected]
TABLE 1
Payoff with and without Own Contribution in the Penultimate
Round (n = 8)

 Number of Other Players
 Willing and Able to Repay

Decision 0 1 2 3

Contributed 0 0 0 420; 5/6#
 0; 1/6#

Not contributed 420 420 420 420

 Number of Other Players Willing
 and Able to Repay

Decision 4 5 6 7

Contributed 504; 5/6# 560; 5/6# 600; 5/6# 630; 5/6#
 84; 1/6# 140; 1/6# 180; 1/6# 210; 1/6#
Not contributed 840; 5/6# 840; 5/6# 840; 5/6# 840; 5/6#
 420; 1/6# 420; 1/6# 420: 1/6# 420; 1/6#

Notes: The entries in italics are lotteries, where each line
represents one outcome. Within each line the semicolon separates the
payoff and the probability of winning this payoff.

Note: Lotteries are indicated with #.

TABLE 2 The Treatments of Our Experiment

 Recruitment Method

Group Size Group Individual

n = 2 IR2 (16/32)
n = 4 GR4 (13/52) IR4 (13/52)
n = 8 IR8 (14/112)

Note: In parentheses are the numbers of independent groups/subjects.

TABLE 3
Contribution Decisions and Average
Duration of Play

Treatment IR2 IR4 IR8 GR4

Yes choices all rounds 78.8% 77.9% 72.4% 75.5%
Yes choices rounds 1-9 81.1% 80.8% 72.4% 79.2%
Yes choices in round 1 84.4% 86.5% 81.3% 98.1%
Average number of 7.5 7.0 5.1 7.0
 rounds played

TABLE 4
Spearman Rank Correlation Coefficients of
Yes Choices over the Played Rounds
(Excluding Round 10)

 Treatment

Group IR2 IR4 IR8 GR4

 1 -0.665 -0.949 -0.500 -0.878 *
 2 -0.822 ** 0.866 -- -0.677 *
 3 -0.577 -0.866 * -- -0.264
 4 -0.104 -- -0.500 -0.598
 5 -- -0.596 -0.866 -0.279
 6 0.000 -0.866 -0.896 ** -0.624
 7 -- 0.000 -0.767 * -0.772
 8 -0.632 -0.518 -0.821 -0.606
 9 -- -0.621 -0.671 -0.876
10 -0.518 -- -0.738 -0.949
11 0.000 -0.418 -1.000 * -0.655
12 -0.274 -0.577 -0.982 * --
13 -0.730 * -0.645 -0.316 -0.757 *
14 0.000 -0.775
15 -0.671
16 -0.866

* Significant at [alpha] = 0.05 (two-sided).

** Significant at [alpha] = 0.01 (two-sided)

-- Number of played rounds lower than three.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有