Productivity changes of Asian economies by taking into account software piracy.
Ding, Cherng G. ; Liu, Na-Ting
I. INTRODUCTION
Ethics may create economic advantages for countries (Donaldson
2001). One common claim for the impact of good ethics on economic
performance is tied to the social promotion of economic incentives. The
protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs) is required to provide
motivation for innovation (Ginarte and Park 1997). The respect for
property rights in general, and for IPRs in particular, is crucial for
the establishment of a well-functioning market system and economic
development (Chen and Puttitanun 2005). If people fail to respect
intellectual property and engage in intellectual property violations
such as software piracy, then the incentive to create new and better
forms of intellectual property would diminish. Because of computer
software's manifest and increasing importance in global economy and
the centrality of IPRs to the development of the software industry (Sell
2003, Chapter 5; Shadlen, Schrank, and Kurtz 2005), software piracy is a
particular ethical issue that deserves discussion.
The protection of IPRs in developing countries has been a debated
issue in recent years. This debate is often placed in a north-south
framework, where the predominant view is that southern (developing)
countries tend to lose from protecting IPRs. While less IPR protection
may cause imitations of foreign technologies, which reduce the market
power of foreign firms and benefit domestic consumers, a developing
country still needs to strengthen IPR protection to encourage
innovations and international technology diffusion (Park and Ginarte
1996). In developing countries, IPR protection will foster dynamic
competition (Rapp and Rozek 1990). New improved products or new uses for
established products will be introduced. Local industries will get the
foreign help they need to survive and to exploit their comparative
advantage in world markets. The lower software piracy rates of the north
have a positive effect on economic growth by encouraging innovation. On
the other hand, the higher software piracy rates of the south also have
a positive effect on economic growth by stimulating the dissemination of
new software applications. However, in the long run, there are some
arguments of why developing countries need to enhance the protection of
IPRs and reduce software piracy rates. Diwan and Rodrik (1991) argue
that without the southern protection of IPRs, northern countries would
not develop technologies largely needed by the south. Yang and Maskus
(2001) point out that northern firms may react to the lack of IPR
protection in the south by making their technologies more difficult to
imitate. Park and Lippoldt (2005) indicate that IPR protection and
effective enforcement can be instrumental in enabling firms in
developing nations to access and exploit technologies through
international technology diffusion. Thus, even if infringement may lead
to short benefits, weak IPR protection produces little innovation, and
then, there is no interest in defending IPR. This could bring a vicious
circle (Park and Ginarte 1996). Protecting IPRs should be a public
policy for developing countries seeking sustained economic growth (Rapp
and Rozek 1990).
For the past two decades, Asia has emerged as one of the most
important economic regions. The "Asian Tigers," China,
Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, and
Thailand, are particularly attractive. Their economic growth rates are
more than twice those of Canada and the United States in 2003 (World
Bank 2003). These Asian economies, however, have higher software piracy
rates. Table 1 presents estimated rates of software piracy in 11 Asian
economies and 7 non-Asian economies from 1994 to 2002. The 18 economies
are all Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) members. The Asian
economies include China, Japan, the Newly Industrialized Economies
(NIEs; Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan), and the ASEAN-5
(Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam), the five
selected members of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN).
The non-Asian economies include four industrialized countries
(Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States) and three
developing countries (Chile, Mexico, and Peru). In most Asian economies,
although there exists dramatic improvement in the protection of
software, rates of change and overall levels of protection vary widely
and do not exhibit convergence.
Data envelopment analysis (DEA; Charnes, Cooper, and Rhodes 1978)
has been used to evaluate the relative macroeconomic performance of
economies (e.g., Lovell, Pastor, and Turner 1995; Ramanathan 2005). In
general, DEA is performed at a given point of time. The Malmquist
productivity index, one of its extensions, is a commonly used approach
for measuring productivity change over a period of time. Fare et al.
(1994b) use the Malmquist index to analyze productivity growth for 17
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries by
considering labor and capital as inputs and gross domestic product (GDP)
as an output. Chang and Luh (2000) use the same approach to perform
productivity analysis for ten Asian economies. The Malmquist index
allows for further decomposition of productivity change into efficiency
change and technical change, which may help explain the differences of
growth patterns among different economies.
Since intellectual property protection plays an important role in
economic development, it should be taken into account when evaluating an
economy's performance. However, performance evaluation with the
consideration of ethical factors such as software piracy is rarely seen
in the literature. In this study, we will discuss how the productivity
growth is influenced by including the ethical factor of software piracy.
The analysis will be conducted for the above-mentioned 11 Asian
economies and 4 non-Asian industrialized economies.
II. METHOD
The measurement of productivity change is based on the distance
function defined by (e.g., Fare et al. 1994b; Ma et al. 2002)
(1) [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) = min{[theta]:([X.sup.t],
[Y.sup.t]/[theta]) [member of] [S.sup.t]},
where [theta] determines the maximal feasible proportional
expansion of output vector [Y.sup.t] for a given input vector [X.sup.t]
under production technology [S.sup.t] at time period t.
[D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) [less than or equal to] 1 if and only if
the input and output combination ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) belongs to the
technology set [S.sup.t]. If [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) = 1, then
the production is on the frontier of technology, and the production is
technically efficient.
The Malmquist index of productivity change between time period t
and time period t + 1 by using technology at time period t as the
reference is given by (Caves, Christensen, and Diewer 1982; Ma et al.
2002)
(2) [M.sup.t] = [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t+1],
[Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]).
Similarly, the Malmquist index by using technology at time period t
+ 1 as the reference is given by
(3) [M.sup.t+1] = [D.sup.t+1] ([X.sup.t+1],
[Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t+1]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]).
Taking the geometric mean of [M.sup.t] and [M.sup.t+1] in Equations
(2) and (3), with the assumption of constant returns to scale (CRS)
technology, Fare et al. (1994b) propose the following index:
(4) MALM - [[([D.sup.t.sub.c]([X.sup.t+1],
[Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t+c]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t])) x
([D.sup.t+1.sub.c]([X.sup.t+1],
[Y.sup.t+1])/([D.sup.t+1.sub.c]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t])).sup.1/2],
where subscript c denotes the CRS benchmark technology. MALM can be
calculated using the linear programming approach outlined in Fare,
Grosskopf, and Lovell (1994a). MALM in Equation (4) can be decomposed into the efficiency change (EFFCH) and the technical change (TECHCH)
(Fare et al. 1994b; Ma et al. 2002) as follows:
(5) Efficiency change(EFFCH) = [D.sup.t+1.sub.c] ([X.sup.t+1],
[Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t.sub.c] ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]),
(6) Technical change (TECHCH) = [[D.sup.t.sub.c] ([X.sup.t+1],
[Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t+1.sub.c] ([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])), x
([D.sup.t.sub.c] ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t])/[D.sup.t+1.sub.c] ([X.sup.t],
[Y.sup.t]))].sup.1/2].
EFFCH (catching up) measures the change in the relative position of
a unit to the production frontier between time periods t and t + 1 under
CRS technology. It can also be explained by how much closer an economy
gets to the world frontier. TECHCH (innovation) measures the shift in
the frontier observed from the unit's input mix over the period. It
is regarded as how much the world frontier shifts at each economy's
observed input mix. The product of these two components yields a
productivity change. That is, MALM = EFFCH x TECHCH. Values of MALM or
any of its components greater than unity reflect improvement in
productivity, whereas values less than unity denote regress or
deterioration.
III. DATA
Our sample contains 18 APEC economies: Australia, Canada, Chile,
China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru,
Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, the United
States, and Vietnam. The data are collected for the three input
variables, capital per capita, labor force per capita, and software
piracy loss per capita, and one output variable, GDP per capita, over
the period 1994-2002. The reason why software piracy loss is an input
variable is that it is regarded as a cost, and hence, its lowest value
is preferred. The sources of data include the Asian Development Bank (2004), the World Bank (2003), and the Business Software Alliance (BSA 2003). The monetary values are in 1995 prices. The labor force per
capita is calculated by dividing total labor force (whose unit is
person) by total population.
For software piracy, we follow a number of studies in which the
data provided by BSA are used (e.g., Knapp 2000; Marron and Steel 2000;
Shadlen, Schrank, and Kurtz 2005; Teran 2001). BSA gives annual data,
from 1994 onward, of estimated software piracy levels for more than 80
economies. Software piracy loss is estimated by three steps (Shadlen,
Schrank, and Kurtz 2005). First, an economy's existing and newly
purchased hardware infrastructure is used to estimate its software
demand. Second, the data on legitimate software sales are obtained from
local distributors and retailers. Third, piracy loss is the difference
between estimated demand and legitimate sales. Piracy rates can then be
obtained by dividing piracy loss by the estimated software demand and
multiplying by 100. Specifically, software piracy loss = legitimate
sales/(1 - piracy rate)--legitimate sales. Software piracy loss per
capita, which is the estimated loss due to software piracy within the
economy divided by its total population, is used in this study to
measure software piracy.
Table 2 provides summary statistics for the input and output
variables. The fact that industrialized countries, having lower piracy
rates, experienced more piracy loss is due to the size of their software
markets. In such enormous markets, even small piracy rates can lead to
much loss. On the other hand, developing economies have higher piracy
rates but less piracy loss since their software markets are smaller.
IV. RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS
Productivity growth is analyzed for China, Japan, the NIEs, the
ASEAN-5, and the other four APEC economies over the period 1994-2002
with the Deap 2.1 software (Coelli 1996). The NIEs and the ASEAN-5 are
grouped based on economical and geographical proximity. China and Japan
are independent individuals. Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the
United States, four non-Asian industrialized economies, are included in
contrast to Asian economies. Analysis is first performed with two
inputs, capital per capita and labor force per capita, and one output,
GDP per capita. Analysis is further performed by taking software piracy
loss per capita as an additional input.
A. Mean Productivity Change
The mean Malmquist productivity changes as well as the two
components, the mean efficiency changes and the mean technical changes,
without/with consideration of software piracy are calculated for each
economy and summarized in Table 3. It is clear from Table 3 that, when
software piracy is taken into account, the mean MALM productivity
changes for the 11 Asian economies decrease except for Japan and South
Korea, while those for the four non-Asian industrialized economies
mostly increase. In most Asian economies, the main source leading to
deterioration in productivity is the slide in efficiency change (the
reduction in EFFCH), indicating weak catching-up capabilities to the
frontier. On the other hand, the productivity improvements in the
industrialized economies are due to technical progress (the increase in
TECHCH).
B. Patterns of Productivity Growth
To provide perspective on the changing patterns over time, the
cumulative Malmquist index as well as its components, the cumulative
efficiency change and the cumulative technical change, are calculated as
the sequential multiplicative results of the annual indices. The average
cumulative changes of productivity (cumulative MALM) for the 11 Asian
economies without/with consideration of software piracy are shown in
Figure 1 using 1994 as the base year. Overall, the movement of the
cumulative MALM including software piracy over the period 1994-2002
follows that ignoring software piracy, but the former is below the
latter for every year. The gap between these two trends condenses in
1997 and 1998, whereas it gradually widens again after 1998. This
phenomenon is in contrast to the productivity growth patterns for the
four non-Asian industrialized economies shown in Figure 2, in which
their average cumulative MALM including software piracy is above that
ignoring software piracy except in 1995. The gap of these two trends
gradually widens after 1998. The two opposite results provide some
interesting information. The fast-developing Asian economies are not
doing as well as we thought they were when the ethical issue of software
piracy is taken into account. Comparatively, the four non-Asian
industrialized economies, whose economic growth is not so quick as the
Asian Tigers in recent decades, display greater productivity growth when
taking software piracy into consideration.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The 11 Asian economies were further divided into China, Japan, the
NIEs, and the ASEAN-5 to understand their patterns of productivity
growth. Figure 3 displays the cumulative MALM and its components for
China. The cumulative MALM including software piracy is below that
ignoring software piracy, and the deterioration in productivity growth
is, as seen before, due to the substantial decline in the cumulative
EFFCH. However, it is noteworthy that cumulative TECHCH with the
consideration of software piracy is above that without. One possible
reason is that, in developing countries, new technologies and technology
transfer may be achieved through foreign direct investment and
intellectual property reform could be a facilitator. Nonetheless,
without efficiency in the enforcement of IPR protection, intellectual
property reform alone will not suffice to close the technology gap
between developed and developing countries (Park and Lippoldt 2003).
Weak protection of IPRs may encourage imitation only, but imitation
activities discourage incentives to do future research and limit the
diffusion of future new technologies (Park and Ginarte 1996).
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
There exists a particular phenomenon for Japan. From Figure 4, the
pattern without considering software piracy is pretty smooth with
indices exceeding unity just a bit. However, when software piracy is
included, the cumulative MALM shows a fluctuation, increasing before
1998, dropping in 1999 and 2000, but slowly rising again after 2000.
Overall, the cumulative change of productivity is better after
considering software piracy. One reason why it goes down in 1999 and
2000 is that there exists a sudden rise of Japan's software piracy
rate from 1999 to 2000 (from 31% to 37%; Table 1), but at the same time,
the software piracy rates of other economies in our sample do not rise
so much relatively. We also find that productivity growth in Japan is
due to the TECHCH progress since the cumulative MALM and the cumulative
TECHCH coincide.
[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]
As for the NIEs (Figure 5), the average cumulative MALM
without/with consideration of software piracy is almost identical in
movement after 1998. The lower values of the average cumulative MALM
when considering software piracy before 1998 result from the decrease in
the average cumulative EFFCH. After 1998, the trend of coincidence is
due to the slight increase in the average cumulative TECHCH but slight
decrease in EFFCH, indicating that the former is offset by the latter.
Attention should be given to efficiency enhancement.
From Figure 6 for the ASEAN-5, the average cumulative MALM with
consideration of software piracy is below that without. The difference
comes from the much worse cumulative EFFCH even though the cumulative
TECHCH is slightly better.
From Figure 7, the average cumulative MALM including software
piracy for the four non-Asian industrialized economies is higher than
that ignoring software piracy except in 1995. The gap becomes wide after
1998. The TECHCH contributes to the growth of productivity. Innovation
performs well for the last 2 yr.
[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]
Discussions
In industrialized economies, although software piracy loss is
greater, its ratio to GDP is lower. In contrast, in developing
economies, the software piracy loss is less, but its ratio to GDP is
higher. The lower ratio of software piracy loss to GDP reflects stronger
IPR protection and can lead to better productivity growth. Weak IPR
protection can reduce the productivity.
[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]
In many developing economies such as China and the ASEAN-5, demand
for software is being met by piracy. Governments have invested billions
of dollars in building technology infrastructures, but such huge
investments go unprotected without enhanced education and enforcement
campaigns for ending the piracy problem. Developing countries have
generally taken a different approach to property claims (Deardorff
1990). The fact that property is so linked to liberty and
self-actualization is an argument employed by developing countries for
destroying rather than bolstering monopoly powers in property.
Nevertheless, developed countries argue that strong protection of
intellectual property is essential to provide incentives for future
innovations and to ensure the competitive profitability of companies
that spend on research and development (R&D). In order to promote
economic growth for Asian economies, efforts should be made to first
increase catching-up capabilities by better resource allocation such as
building strong economic institutions to secure intellectual property by
means of regulations, government controls, legislation, and sound
education. A growing empirical literature has demonstrated that
countries with strong economic institutions protecting traditional
property and contracts can have important impacts on economic
performance (e.g., Hall and Jones 1996; Knack and Keefer 1995). Marron
and Steel (2000) think that countries with weak economic institutions
protecting IPRs have significantly higher piracy rates, and lower levels
of education may make people so unfamiliar with IPRs that they are
likely to become violators. The presence of weak institutions may
reflect disregard for IPRs.
[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]
[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]
By scrutinizing the varying growth pattern and its components among
economies further, we find that after taking software piracy into
account, the industrialized economies experience higher productivity
growth and the TECHCH is the main contributor. Resource allocation for
IPR protection in these countries has been well implemented, and
therefore, the space to improve efficiency is quite limited. However,
economic improvement can be achieved by enhancing innovation and
technical change. The issue of IPR is related to R&D activities
(Kumar 1996). Ginarte and Park (1997) find that countries investing
heavily in R&D tend to have strong protection for intellectual
property because R&D is based upon incentives to innovate. Putting
emphasis on IPR protection can inspire innovation and in turn lead to
productivity improvement. Stronger intellectual property protection,
resulting in lower piracy rates, has the potential to improve economic
growth by making more investment activities possible, particularly in
R&D (Park and Ginarte 1997).
A policymaker's choice of level of IPR protection should
depend on weighing the benefits and costs (Ginarte and Park 1997; Rapp
and Rozek 1990). The benefits of IPR protection are that it would
stimulate innovation, increase the quality and variety of goods, and
enhance productivity growth. IPR protection can also provide another
potential benefit that a nation develops better trade relations with
other economies (Ginarte and Park 1997). On the other hand, the costs of
IPR protection include the restraint of dissemination of new
technologies and the supply of new goods (or processes) at higher
prices. Furthermore, excessive IPR protection could reduce threats from
potential rivals (who could imitate existing products) and lead to less
motivation to upgrade existing intellectual property or to develop new
inventions (Park and Lippoldt 2005). Indeed, finding a balance between
incentives for innovation on one hand and wide access to new
technologies on the other deserves to be deliberated.
V. CONCLUSIONS
Productivity analysis by taking account of software piracy opens up
a new way to simultaneously pursue economic growth and ethical wealth.
This paper attempts to address the issue by conducting comparative
productivity analysis for 11 Asian economies and 4 non-Asian
industrialized economies over the period 1994-2002. The 18 APEC
economies are included so as to construct a benchmark frontier. When the
software piracy index (software piracy loss per capita in this study) is
incorporated into the calculation of the Malmquist productivity change
index, productivity growth in developing economies decreases (due to
reduction in efficiency), while productivity growth in industrialized
economies increases (due to technical progress).
The empirical results obtained imply again that resources should be
focused on the enforcement of IPR protection in developing economies and
on technological innovation in developed economies so that productivity
can be improved.
Other ethical issues such as corruption may be considered. It is
widely agreed that corruption is an unethical problem that affects all
elements of society, especially the poor, and significantly hampers
business activity and economic development (Voyer and Beamish 2004).
Past research suggests that bribery and other forms of corruption reduce
investment and economic growth. For example, Mauro (1998) indicates that
corruption lowers economic growth and breeds poverty over time. At the
same time, poverty itself might cause corruption. Transparency
International, a lobbying coalition against corruption in international
business, contends that corruption is not merely a problem in Third
World nations but is a threat to clean government in Europe as well
(Holman 1994). Productivity analysis by including corruption as well as
other ethical factors deserves future research.
ABBREVIATIONS
APEC: Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation
ASEAN: Association of Southeast Asian Nations
BSA: Business Software Alliance
CRS: Constant Returns to Scale
DEA: Data Envelopment Analysis
GDP: Gross Domestic Product
IPRs: Intellectual Property Rights
NIEs: Newly Industrialized Economies
R&D: Research and Development
REFERENCES
Asian Development Bank. "Key Indicators 2004: Poverty in Asia:
Measurement, Estimates, and Prospects. 2004. Accessed 3 Jan 2005.
http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Key_Indicators/2004/default.asp.
Business Software Alliance. Eighth Annual BSA Global Software
Piracy Study. Washington, DC: Business Software Alliance, 2003.
Caves, D. W., L. R. Christensen, and W. W. Diewer.
"Multilateral Comparisons of Output, Input, and Productivity Using
Superlative Index Numbers." Economic Journal, 92, 1982, 73-86.
Chang, C. C., and Y. H. Luh. "Efficiency Change and Growth in
Productivity: The Asian Growth Experience." Journal of Asian
Economics, 10, 2000, 551-70.
Charnes, A., W. W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. "Measuring the
Efficiency of Decision Making Units." European Journal of
Operational Research, 2, 1978, 429-44.
Chen, Y., and T. Puttitanun. "Intellectual Property Rights and
Innovation in Developing Countries." Journal of Development
Economics, 78, 2005, 474-93.
Coelli, T. J. A Guide to Deap Version 2.1. A Data Envelopment
Analysis Computer Program. Armidale, Australia: Department of
Econometrics, University of England, 1996.
Deardorff, A. V. "Should Patent Protection Be Extended to All
Developing Countries?" World Economy, 13, 1990, 497-506.
Diwan, I., and D. Rodrik. "Patents Appropriate Technology, and
North-South Trade." Journal of International Economics, 30, 1991,
27-48.
Donaldson, T. "The Ethical Wealth of Nations." Journal of
Business Ethics, 31, 2001, 25-36.
Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, and C. A. K. Lovell. Production Frontiers.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994a.
Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, M. Norris, and Z. Zhang. "Productivity
Growth, Technical Progress, and Efficiency Change in Industrialized
Countries." American Economic Review, 84, 1994b, 66-83.
Ginarte, J. C., and W. G. Park. "Determinants of Patent
Rights: A Cross-National Study." Research Policy, 26, 1997,
283-30l.
Hall, R. E., and C. I. Jones. "The Productivity of
Nations." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No.
5812, 1996.
Holman, M. "A Cancer in Business." Financial Times,
n32485, 1994, S18.
Knack, S., and P. Keefer. "Institutions and Economic
Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional
Measures." Economics and Politics, 7, 1995, 207-27.
Knapp, I. L. "The Software Piracy Battle in Latin America:
Should the United States Pursue Its Aggressive Bilateral Trade Policy
Despite the Multilateral TRIPS Enforcement Framework?" University
of Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law, 21, 2000,
173-210.
Kumar, N. "Intellectual Property Protection, Market
Orientation and Location of Overseas R&D Activities by Multinational
Enterprises." World Development, 24, 1996, 673-88.
Lovell, C. A. K., J. T. Pastor, and J. A Turner. "Measuring
Macroeconomic Performance in the OECD: A Comparison of European and
Non-European Countries." European Journal of Operational Research,
87, 1995, 507-18.
Ma, J., D. G. Evans, R. J. Fuller, and D. F. Stewart.
"Technical Efficiency and Productivity Change of China's Iron
and Steel Industry." International Journal of Production Economics,
76, 2002, 293-312.
Marron, D. B., and D. G. Steel. "Which Countries Protect
Intellectual Property? The Case of Software Piracy." Economic
Inquiry, 38, 2000, 159-74.
Mauro, P. "Corruption: Causes, Consequences, and Agenda for
Further Research." Finance & Development, 35, 1998, 11-4.
Park, W. G., and J. C. Ginarte. "Intellectual Property Rights
in a North-South Economic Context." Science Communication, 17,
1996, 379-87.
--. "Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth."
Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 1997, 51-61.
Park, W. G., and D. Lippoldt. "The Impact of Trade-Related
Intellectual Property Rights on Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in
Developing Countries." OECD Papers: Special Issue on Trade Policy,
4, 294, 2003, 1-40.
--. "International Licensing and the Strengthening of
Intellectual Property Rights in Developing Countries during the
1990s." OECD Economic Studies, 40, 2005, 7-48.
Ramanathan, R. "An Analysis of Energy Consumption and Carbon
Dioxide Emissions in Countries of the Middle East and North
Africa." Energy, 30, 2005, 2831-42.
Rapp, R. T., and R. P. Rozek. "Benefits and Costs of
Intellectual Property Protection in Developing Countries." Journal
of World Trade, 24, 1990, 75-102.
Sell, S. Private Power, Public Law: The Globalization of
Intellectual Property Rights. London: Cambridge University Press, 2003.
Shadlen, K. C., A. Schrank, and M. J. Kurtz. "The Political
Economy of Intellectual Property Protection: The Case of Software."
International Studies Quarterly, 49, 2005, 45-71.
Teran, H. "Intellectual Property Protection and Offshore
Software Development: An Analysis of the U.S. Software Industry."
Minnesota Intellectual Property Review, 2, 2001, 1-50.
Voyer, P. A., and P. W. Beamish. "The Effect of Corruption on
Japanese Foreign Direct Investment." Journal of Business Ethics,
50, 2004, 211-24.
World Bank. "World Development Indicators." CD-ROM, 2003.
Yang, G., and K. E. Maskus. "Intellectual Property Rights,
Licensing, and Innovation in an Endogenous Product Cycle Model."
Journal of International Economics, 53, 2001, 169-87.
CHERNG G. DING and NA-TING LIU *
* We thank Jin-Li Hu, Erwin T. J. Lin, Shih-Fang Lo, and Wen-Min Lu
for helpful discussions. We also thank an anonymous referee for
constructive comments and suggestions. This research was partially
supported by the National Science Council of Taiwan, R.O.C.
Ding: Professor, Institute of Business and Management, National
Chiao Tung University, 118 Chung-Hsiao West Road, Section 1, Taipei,
100, Taiwan. Phone 886-2-2349-4932, Fax 886-2-23494922, E-mail
[email protected]
Liu: Assistant Professor, Department of Business Administration,
Ming Chuan University, 250 Chung-Shan North Road, Section 5, Taipei,
111, Taiwan. Phone 886-2-2882-4564 ext. 2880, Fax 886-2-28809727, E-mail
[email protected]
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00117.x
Online Early publication August 22, 2008
TABLE 1 Estimated Rates of Software Piracy for 18 APEC
Economics, 1994-2002
%
Economy 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998
East Asian
China 97 96 96 96 95
Japan 66 65 41 32 31
NIEs
Hong Kong 62 62 64 67 59
Singapore 61 53 59 56 52
South Korea 75 76 70 67 64
Taiwan 72 70 66 63 59
ASEAN-5
Indonesia 97 98 97 93 92
Malaysia 82 77 80 70 73
Philippines 94 91 92 83 77
Thailand 87 82 80 84 82
Vietnam 100 99 99 98 97
Non-Asian
industrialized
Australia 37 35 32 32 33
Canada 46 44 42 39 40
New Zealand 43 40 35 34 32
United States 31 26 27 27 25
Developing
Chile 70 68 62 56 53
Mexico 78 74 67 62 59
Peru 86 84 74 66 64
Economy 1999 2000 2001 2002
East Asian 91 94 92 92
China 31 37 37 35
Japan
NIEs 56 57 53 56
Hong Kong 51 50 51 48
Singapore 50 56 48 50
South Korea 54 53 53 43
Taiwan
ASEAN-5 85 89 88 89
Indonesia 71 66 70 68
Malaysia 70 61 63 68
Philippines 81 79 77 77
Thailand 98 97 94 95
Vietnam
Non-Asian
industrialized 32 33 27 32
Australia 41 38 38 39
Canada 31 28 26 24
New Zealand 25 24 25 23
United States
Developing 51 49 51 51
Chile 56 56 55 55
Mexico 63 61 60 60
Peru
Source: Business Software Alliance (2003).
TABLE 2 Summary Statistics of Economic Inputs and Output, 1994-2002
Output(a) (Per Capita)
GDP Capital
Standard Standard
Economy Mean Deviation Mean Deviation
East Asian
China 729.49 138.25 285.37 55.04
Japan 43,771.35 1,175.07 12,018.15 505.55
NIEs
Hong Kong 23,791.05 1,174.40 7,458.88 684.33
Singapore 26,187.44 2,640.05 8,161.60 1,185.95
South Korea 12,635.38 1,378.01 4,109.15 474.67
Taiwan 12,356.44 595.80 2,586.77 356.24
ASEAN-5
Indonesia 1,040.94 59.76 254.63 80.30
Malaysia 4,561.42 277.03 1,509.54 375.19
Philippines 1,137.59 47.40 255.62 20.54
Thailand 2,834.53 146.63 805.54 316.92
Vietnam 337.82 48.85 100.07 21.58
Non-Asian
industrialized
Australia 22,407.79 1,577.91 5,565.50 754.21
Canada 21,419.64 1,587.90 4,352.36 511.92
New Zealand 17,344.55 930.09 3,824.26 240.19
United States 29,866.28 1,773.27 6,056.86 779.52
Developing
Chile 5,039.70 410.61 1,145.28 169.48
Mexico 3,521.61 228.94 967.39 169.45
Peru 2,293.73 79.94 500.46 61.36
Input' (Per Capita)
Labor Software Piracy Loss
Standard Standard
Economy Mean Deviation Mean Deviation
East Asian
China 0.5987 0.0014 0.89 0.51
Japan 0.5354 0.0020 10.05 3.28
NIEs
Hong Kong 0.5237 0.0051 16.59 4.56
Singapore 0.5007 0.0056 12.44 2.84
South Korea 0.5018 0.0111 8.70 4.14
Taiwan 0.4355 0.0044 6.09 0.87
ASEAN-5
Indonesia 0.4752 0.0117 0.58 0.30
Malaysia 0.4085 0.0085 4.03 0.69
Philippines 0.4175 0.0064 0.55 0.22
Thailand 0.6000 0.0073 1.31 0.51
Vietnam 0.5126 0.0041 0.29 0.19
Non-Asian
industrialized
Australia 0.5078 0.0023 7.85 1.92
Canada 0.5346 0.0025 10.69 2.28
New Zealand 0.4970 0.0039 5.12 2.14
United States 0.5108 0.0032 9.80 2.31
Developing
Chile 0.4036 0.0077 3.01 0.57
Mexico 0.4035 0.0111 1.66 0.34
Peru 0.3699 0.0121 1.12 0.41
Source: Asian Development Bank (2004), Business Software Alliance
(2003), and World Bank (2003).
(a) The monetary values are in 1995 prices.
TABLE 3 Decomposition of the Mean Malmquist Productivity Changes
without/with Consideration of Software Piracy
Mean Annual Change
Malmquist (MALM)
Economy Without With
East Asian
China 0.995 0.975
Japan 1.011 1.012
NIEs
Hong Kong 1.007 0.999
Singapore 1.036 1.031
South Korea 1.039 1.044
Taiwan 1.029 1.022
ASEAN-5
Indonesia 1.072 1.056
Malaysia 1.047 1.047
Philippines 1.007 1.003
Thailand 1.086 1.045
Vietnam 0.969 0.912
Non-Asian
industrialized
Australia 0.993 1.007
Canada 0.992 0.992
New Zealand 0.998 1.071
United States 0.997 1.018
Developing
Chile 1.014 1.012
Mexico 0.999 1.014
Peru 1.025 1.025
Mean Annual Change
Efficiency Change (EFFCH)
Economy Without With
East Asian
China 0.980 0.951
Japan 1.000 1.000
NIEs
Hong Kong 1.002 0.992
Singapore 1.028 1.020
South Korea 1.043 1.043
Taiwan 1.021 1.003
ASEAN-5
Indonesia 1.059 1.035
Malaysia 1.034 1.018
Philippines 0.992 0.998
Thailand 1.074 1.030
Vietnam 0.956 0.917
Non-Asian
industrialized
Australia 1.002 0.977
Canada 0.998 0.998
New Zealand 1.002 1.003
United States 1.000 1.000
Developing
Chile 1.002 1.002
Mexico 0.985 0.980
Peru 1.014 1.027
Mean Annual Change
Technical Change (TECHCH)
Economy Without With
East Asian
China 1.015 1.025
Japan 1.011 1.012
NIEs
Hong Kong 1.005 1.007
Singapore 1.008 1.011
South Korea 0.996 1.001
Taiwan 1.008 1.019
ASEAN-5
Indonesia 1.012 1.020
Malaysia 1.013 1.029
Philippines 1.015 1.005
Thailand 1.011 1.015
Vietnam 1.014 0.995
Non-Asian
industrialized
Australia 0.991 1.031
Canada 0.994 0.994
New Zealand 0.996 1.068
United States 0.997 1.018
Developing
Chile 1.012 1.010
Mexico 1.014 1.035
Peru 1.011 0.998
Notes: These numbers are the geometric means of annual changes
in each economy over the period 1994-2002.