首页    期刊浏览 2025年02月28日 星期五
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Productivity changes of Asian economies by taking into account software piracy.
  • 作者:Ding, Cherng G. ; Liu, Na-Ting
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2009
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:Ethics may create economic advantages for countries (Donaldson 2001). One common claim for the impact of good ethics on economic performance is tied to the social promotion of economic incentives. The protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs) is required to provide motivation for innovation (Ginarte and Park 1997). The respect for property rights in general, and for IPRs in particular, is crucial for the establishment of a well-functioning market system and economic development (Chen and Puttitanun 2005). If people fail to respect intellectual property and engage in intellectual property violations such as software piracy, then the incentive to create new and better forms of intellectual property would diminish. Because of computer software's manifest and increasing importance in global economy and the centrality of IPRs to the development of the software industry (Sell 2003, Chapter 5; Shadlen, Schrank, and Kurtz 2005), software piracy is a particular ethical issue that deserves discussion.
  • 关键词:Business ethics;Copyright infringement;Fair use (Copyright law);Fair use (Copyright);Software piracy

Productivity changes of Asian economies by taking into account software piracy.


Ding, Cherng G. ; Liu, Na-Ting


I. INTRODUCTION

Ethics may create economic advantages for countries (Donaldson 2001). One common claim for the impact of good ethics on economic performance is tied to the social promotion of economic incentives. The protection of intellectual property rights (IPRs) is required to provide motivation for innovation (Ginarte and Park 1997). The respect for property rights in general, and for IPRs in particular, is crucial for the establishment of a well-functioning market system and economic development (Chen and Puttitanun 2005). If people fail to respect intellectual property and engage in intellectual property violations such as software piracy, then the incentive to create new and better forms of intellectual property would diminish. Because of computer software's manifest and increasing importance in global economy and the centrality of IPRs to the development of the software industry (Sell 2003, Chapter 5; Shadlen, Schrank, and Kurtz 2005), software piracy is a particular ethical issue that deserves discussion.

The protection of IPRs in developing countries has been a debated issue in recent years. This debate is often placed in a north-south framework, where the predominant view is that southern (developing) countries tend to lose from protecting IPRs. While less IPR protection may cause imitations of foreign technologies, which reduce the market power of foreign firms and benefit domestic consumers, a developing country still needs to strengthen IPR protection to encourage innovations and international technology diffusion (Park and Ginarte 1996). In developing countries, IPR protection will foster dynamic competition (Rapp and Rozek 1990). New improved products or new uses for established products will be introduced. Local industries will get the foreign help they need to survive and to exploit their comparative advantage in world markets. The lower software piracy rates of the north have a positive effect on economic growth by encouraging innovation. On the other hand, the higher software piracy rates of the south also have a positive effect on economic growth by stimulating the dissemination of new software applications. However, in the long run, there are some arguments of why developing countries need to enhance the protection of IPRs and reduce software piracy rates. Diwan and Rodrik (1991) argue that without the southern protection of IPRs, northern countries would not develop technologies largely needed by the south. Yang and Maskus (2001) point out that northern firms may react to the lack of IPR protection in the south by making their technologies more difficult to imitate. Park and Lippoldt (2005) indicate that IPR protection and effective enforcement can be instrumental in enabling firms in developing nations to access and exploit technologies through international technology diffusion. Thus, even if infringement may lead to short benefits, weak IPR protection produces little innovation, and then, there is no interest in defending IPR. This could bring a vicious circle (Park and Ginarte 1996). Protecting IPRs should be a public policy for developing countries seeking sustained economic growth (Rapp and Rozek 1990).

For the past two decades, Asia has emerged as one of the most important economic regions. The "Asian Tigers," China, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand, are particularly attractive. Their economic growth rates are more than twice those of Canada and the United States in 2003 (World Bank 2003). These Asian economies, however, have higher software piracy rates. Table 1 presents estimated rates of software piracy in 11 Asian economies and 7 non-Asian economies from 1994 to 2002. The 18 economies are all Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation (APEC) members. The Asian economies include China, Japan, the Newly Industrialized Economies (NIEs; Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan), and the ASEAN-5 (Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Thailand, and Vietnam), the five selected members of the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN). The non-Asian economies include four industrialized countries (Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States) and three developing countries (Chile, Mexico, and Peru). In most Asian economies, although there exists dramatic improvement in the protection of software, rates of change and overall levels of protection vary widely and do not exhibit convergence.

Data envelopment analysis (DEA; Charnes, Cooper, and Rhodes 1978) has been used to evaluate the relative macroeconomic performance of economies (e.g., Lovell, Pastor, and Turner 1995; Ramanathan 2005). In general, DEA is performed at a given point of time. The Malmquist productivity index, one of its extensions, is a commonly used approach for measuring productivity change over a period of time. Fare et al. (1994b) use the Malmquist index to analyze productivity growth for 17 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries by considering labor and capital as inputs and gross domestic product (GDP) as an output. Chang and Luh (2000) use the same approach to perform productivity analysis for ten Asian economies. The Malmquist index allows for further decomposition of productivity change into efficiency change and technical change, which may help explain the differences of growth patterns among different economies.

Since intellectual property protection plays an important role in economic development, it should be taken into account when evaluating an economy's performance. However, performance evaluation with the consideration of ethical factors such as software piracy is rarely seen in the literature. In this study, we will discuss how the productivity growth is influenced by including the ethical factor of software piracy. The analysis will be conducted for the above-mentioned 11 Asian economies and 4 non-Asian industrialized economies.

II. METHOD

The measurement of productivity change is based on the distance function defined by (e.g., Fare et al. 1994b; Ma et al. 2002)

(1) [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) = min{[theta]:([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]/[theta]) [member of] [S.sup.t]},

where [theta] determines the maximal feasible proportional expansion of output vector [Y.sup.t] for a given input vector [X.sup.t] under production technology [S.sup.t] at time period t. [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) [less than or equal to] 1 if and only if the input and output combination ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) belongs to the technology set [S.sup.t]. If [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]) = 1, then the production is on the frontier of technology, and the production is technically efficient.

The Malmquist index of productivity change between time period t and time period t + 1 by using technology at time period t as the reference is given by (Caves, Christensen, and Diewer 1982; Ma et al. 2002)

(2) [M.sup.t] = [D.sup.t]([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]).

Similarly, the Malmquist index by using technology at time period t + 1 as the reference is given by

(3) [M.sup.t+1] = [D.sup.t+1] ([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t+1]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]).

Taking the geometric mean of [M.sup.t] and [M.sup.t+1] in Equations (2) and (3), with the assumption of constant returns to scale (CRS) technology, Fare et al. (1994b) propose the following index:

(4) MALM - [[([D.sup.t.sub.c]([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t+c]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t])) x ([D.sup.t+1.sub.c]([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])/([D.sup.t+1.sub.c]([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t])).sup.1/2],

where subscript c denotes the CRS benchmark technology. MALM can be calculated using the linear programming approach outlined in Fare, Grosskopf, and Lovell (1994a). MALM in Equation (4) can be decomposed into the efficiency change (EFFCH) and the technical change (TECHCH) (Fare et al. 1994b; Ma et al. 2002) as follows:

(5) Efficiency change(EFFCH) = [D.sup.t+1.sub.c] ([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t.sub.c] ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]),

(6) Technical change (TECHCH) = [[D.sup.t.sub.c] ([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])/[D.sup.t+1.sub.c] ([X.sup.t+1], [Y.sup.t+1])), x ([D.sup.t.sub.c] ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t])/[D.sup.t+1.sub.c] ([X.sup.t], [Y.sup.t]))].sup.1/2].

EFFCH (catching up) measures the change in the relative position of a unit to the production frontier between time periods t and t + 1 under CRS technology. It can also be explained by how much closer an economy gets to the world frontier. TECHCH (innovation) measures the shift in the frontier observed from the unit's input mix over the period. It is regarded as how much the world frontier shifts at each economy's observed input mix. The product of these two components yields a productivity change. That is, MALM = EFFCH x TECHCH. Values of MALM or any of its components greater than unity reflect improvement in productivity, whereas values less than unity denote regress or deterioration.

III. DATA

Our sample contains 18 APEC economies: Australia, Canada, Chile, China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, New Zealand, Peru, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, Thailand, the United States, and Vietnam. The data are collected for the three input variables, capital per capita, labor force per capita, and software piracy loss per capita, and one output variable, GDP per capita, over the period 1994-2002. The reason why software piracy loss is an input variable is that it is regarded as a cost, and hence, its lowest value is preferred. The sources of data include the Asian Development Bank (2004), the World Bank (2003), and the Business Software Alliance (BSA 2003). The monetary values are in 1995 prices. The labor force per capita is calculated by dividing total labor force (whose unit is person) by total population.

For software piracy, we follow a number of studies in which the data provided by BSA are used (e.g., Knapp 2000; Marron and Steel 2000; Shadlen, Schrank, and Kurtz 2005; Teran 2001). BSA gives annual data, from 1994 onward, of estimated software piracy levels for more than 80 economies. Software piracy loss is estimated by three steps (Shadlen, Schrank, and Kurtz 2005). First, an economy's existing and newly purchased hardware infrastructure is used to estimate its software demand. Second, the data on legitimate software sales are obtained from local distributors and retailers. Third, piracy loss is the difference between estimated demand and legitimate sales. Piracy rates can then be obtained by dividing piracy loss by the estimated software demand and multiplying by 100. Specifically, software piracy loss = legitimate sales/(1 - piracy rate)--legitimate sales. Software piracy loss per capita, which is the estimated loss due to software piracy within the economy divided by its total population, is used in this study to measure software piracy.

Table 2 provides summary statistics for the input and output variables. The fact that industrialized countries, having lower piracy rates, experienced more piracy loss is due to the size of their software markets. In such enormous markets, even small piracy rates can lead to much loss. On the other hand, developing economies have higher piracy rates but less piracy loss since their software markets are smaller.

IV. RESULTS AND DISCUSSIONS

Productivity growth is analyzed for China, Japan, the NIEs, the ASEAN-5, and the other four APEC economies over the period 1994-2002 with the Deap 2.1 software (Coelli 1996). The NIEs and the ASEAN-5 are grouped based on economical and geographical proximity. China and Japan are independent individuals. Australia, Canada, New Zealand, and the United States, four non-Asian industrialized economies, are included in contrast to Asian economies. Analysis is first performed with two inputs, capital per capita and labor force per capita, and one output, GDP per capita. Analysis is further performed by taking software piracy loss per capita as an additional input.

A. Mean Productivity Change

The mean Malmquist productivity changes as well as the two components, the mean efficiency changes and the mean technical changes, without/with consideration of software piracy are calculated for each economy and summarized in Table 3. It is clear from Table 3 that, when software piracy is taken into account, the mean MALM productivity changes for the 11 Asian economies decrease except for Japan and South Korea, while those for the four non-Asian industrialized economies mostly increase. In most Asian economies, the main source leading to deterioration in productivity is the slide in efficiency change (the reduction in EFFCH), indicating weak catching-up capabilities to the frontier. On the other hand, the productivity improvements in the industrialized economies are due to technical progress (the increase in TECHCH).

B. Patterns of Productivity Growth

To provide perspective on the changing patterns over time, the cumulative Malmquist index as well as its components, the cumulative efficiency change and the cumulative technical change, are calculated as the sequential multiplicative results of the annual indices. The average cumulative changes of productivity (cumulative MALM) for the 11 Asian economies without/with consideration of software piracy are shown in Figure 1 using 1994 as the base year. Overall, the movement of the cumulative MALM including software piracy over the period 1994-2002 follows that ignoring software piracy, but the former is below the latter for every year. The gap between these two trends condenses in 1997 and 1998, whereas it gradually widens again after 1998. This phenomenon is in contrast to the productivity growth patterns for the four non-Asian industrialized economies shown in Figure 2, in which their average cumulative MALM including software piracy is above that ignoring software piracy except in 1995. The gap of these two trends gradually widens after 1998. The two opposite results provide some interesting information. The fast-developing Asian economies are not doing as well as we thought they were when the ethical issue of software piracy is taken into account. Comparatively, the four non-Asian industrialized economies, whose economic growth is not so quick as the Asian Tigers in recent decades, display greater productivity growth when taking software piracy into consideration.

[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]

The 11 Asian economies were further divided into China, Japan, the NIEs, and the ASEAN-5 to understand their patterns of productivity growth. Figure 3 displays the cumulative MALM and its components for China. The cumulative MALM including software piracy is below that ignoring software piracy, and the deterioration in productivity growth is, as seen before, due to the substantial decline in the cumulative EFFCH. However, it is noteworthy that cumulative TECHCH with the consideration of software piracy is above that without. One possible reason is that, in developing countries, new technologies and technology transfer may be achieved through foreign direct investment and intellectual property reform could be a facilitator. Nonetheless, without efficiency in the enforcement of IPR protection, intellectual property reform alone will not suffice to close the technology gap between developed and developing countries (Park and Lippoldt 2003). Weak protection of IPRs may encourage imitation only, but imitation activities discourage incentives to do future research and limit the diffusion of future new technologies (Park and Ginarte 1996).

[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]

There exists a particular phenomenon for Japan. From Figure 4, the pattern without considering software piracy is pretty smooth with indices exceeding unity just a bit. However, when software piracy is included, the cumulative MALM shows a fluctuation, increasing before 1998, dropping in 1999 and 2000, but slowly rising again after 2000. Overall, the cumulative change of productivity is better after considering software piracy. One reason why it goes down in 1999 and 2000 is that there exists a sudden rise of Japan's software piracy rate from 1999 to 2000 (from 31% to 37%; Table 1), but at the same time, the software piracy rates of other economies in our sample do not rise so much relatively. We also find that productivity growth in Japan is due to the TECHCH progress since the cumulative MALM and the cumulative TECHCH coincide.

[FIGURE 3 OMITTED]

As for the NIEs (Figure 5), the average cumulative MALM without/with consideration of software piracy is almost identical in movement after 1998. The lower values of the average cumulative MALM when considering software piracy before 1998 result from the decrease in the average cumulative EFFCH. After 1998, the trend of coincidence is due to the slight increase in the average cumulative TECHCH but slight decrease in EFFCH, indicating that the former is offset by the latter. Attention should be given to efficiency enhancement.

From Figure 6 for the ASEAN-5, the average cumulative MALM with consideration of software piracy is below that without. The difference comes from the much worse cumulative EFFCH even though the cumulative TECHCH is slightly better.

From Figure 7, the average cumulative MALM including software piracy for the four non-Asian industrialized economies is higher than that ignoring software piracy except in 1995. The gap becomes wide after 1998. The TECHCH contributes to the growth of productivity. Innovation performs well for the last 2 yr.

[FIGURE 4 OMITTED]

Discussions

In industrialized economies, although software piracy loss is greater, its ratio to GDP is lower. In contrast, in developing economies, the software piracy loss is less, but its ratio to GDP is higher. The lower ratio of software piracy loss to GDP reflects stronger IPR protection and can lead to better productivity growth. Weak IPR protection can reduce the productivity.

[FIGURE 5 OMITTED]

In many developing economies such as China and the ASEAN-5, demand for software is being met by piracy. Governments have invested billions of dollars in building technology infrastructures, but such huge investments go unprotected without enhanced education and enforcement campaigns for ending the piracy problem. Developing countries have generally taken a different approach to property claims (Deardorff 1990). The fact that property is so linked to liberty and self-actualization is an argument employed by developing countries for destroying rather than bolstering monopoly powers in property. Nevertheless, developed countries argue that strong protection of intellectual property is essential to provide incentives for future innovations and to ensure the competitive profitability of companies that spend on research and development (R&D). In order to promote economic growth for Asian economies, efforts should be made to first increase catching-up capabilities by better resource allocation such as building strong economic institutions to secure intellectual property by means of regulations, government controls, legislation, and sound education. A growing empirical literature has demonstrated that countries with strong economic institutions protecting traditional property and contracts can have important impacts on economic performance (e.g., Hall and Jones 1996; Knack and Keefer 1995). Marron and Steel (2000) think that countries with weak economic institutions protecting IPRs have significantly higher piracy rates, and lower levels of education may make people so unfamiliar with IPRs that they are likely to become violators. The presence of weak institutions may reflect disregard for IPRs.

[FIGURE 6 OMITTED]

[FIGURE 7 OMITTED]

By scrutinizing the varying growth pattern and its components among economies further, we find that after taking software piracy into account, the industrialized economies experience higher productivity growth and the TECHCH is the main contributor. Resource allocation for IPR protection in these countries has been well implemented, and therefore, the space to improve efficiency is quite limited. However, economic improvement can be achieved by enhancing innovation and technical change. The issue of IPR is related to R&D activities (Kumar 1996). Ginarte and Park (1997) find that countries investing heavily in R&D tend to have strong protection for intellectual property because R&D is based upon incentives to innovate. Putting emphasis on IPR protection can inspire innovation and in turn lead to productivity improvement. Stronger intellectual property protection, resulting in lower piracy rates, has the potential to improve economic growth by making more investment activities possible, particularly in R&D (Park and Ginarte 1997).

A policymaker's choice of level of IPR protection should depend on weighing the benefits and costs (Ginarte and Park 1997; Rapp and Rozek 1990). The benefits of IPR protection are that it would stimulate innovation, increase the quality and variety of goods, and enhance productivity growth. IPR protection can also provide another potential benefit that a nation develops better trade relations with other economies (Ginarte and Park 1997). On the other hand, the costs of IPR protection include the restraint of dissemination of new technologies and the supply of new goods (or processes) at higher prices. Furthermore, excessive IPR protection could reduce threats from potential rivals (who could imitate existing products) and lead to less motivation to upgrade existing intellectual property or to develop new inventions (Park and Lippoldt 2005). Indeed, finding a balance between incentives for innovation on one hand and wide access to new technologies on the other deserves to be deliberated.

V. CONCLUSIONS

Productivity analysis by taking account of software piracy opens up a new way to simultaneously pursue economic growth and ethical wealth. This paper attempts to address the issue by conducting comparative productivity analysis for 11 Asian economies and 4 non-Asian industrialized economies over the period 1994-2002. The 18 APEC economies are included so as to construct a benchmark frontier. When the software piracy index (software piracy loss per capita in this study) is incorporated into the calculation of the Malmquist productivity change index, productivity growth in developing economies decreases (due to reduction in efficiency), while productivity growth in industrialized economies increases (due to technical progress).

The empirical results obtained imply again that resources should be focused on the enforcement of IPR protection in developing economies and on technological innovation in developed economies so that productivity can be improved.

Other ethical issues such as corruption may be considered. It is widely agreed that corruption is an unethical problem that affects all elements of society, especially the poor, and significantly hampers business activity and economic development (Voyer and Beamish 2004). Past research suggests that bribery and other forms of corruption reduce investment and economic growth. For example, Mauro (1998) indicates that corruption lowers economic growth and breeds poverty over time. At the same time, poverty itself might cause corruption. Transparency International, a lobbying coalition against corruption in international business, contends that corruption is not merely a problem in Third World nations but is a threat to clean government in Europe as well (Holman 1994). Productivity analysis by including corruption as well as other ethical factors deserves future research.

ABBREVIATIONS

APEC: Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation

ASEAN: Association of Southeast Asian Nations

BSA: Business Software Alliance

CRS: Constant Returns to Scale

DEA: Data Envelopment Analysis

GDP: Gross Domestic Product

IPRs: Intellectual Property Rights

NIEs: Newly Industrialized Economies

R&D: Research and Development

REFERENCES

Asian Development Bank. "Key Indicators 2004: Poverty in Asia: Measurement, Estimates, and Prospects. 2004. Accessed 3 Jan 2005. http://www.adb.org/Documents/Books/Key_Indicators/2004/default.asp.

Business Software Alliance. Eighth Annual BSA Global Software Piracy Study. Washington, DC: Business Software Alliance, 2003.

Caves, D. W., L. R. Christensen, and W. W. Diewer. "Multilateral Comparisons of Output, Input, and Productivity Using Superlative Index Numbers." Economic Journal, 92, 1982, 73-86.

Chang, C. C., and Y. H. Luh. "Efficiency Change and Growth in Productivity: The Asian Growth Experience." Journal of Asian Economics, 10, 2000, 551-70.

Charnes, A., W. W. Cooper, and E. Rhodes. "Measuring the Efficiency of Decision Making Units." European Journal of Operational Research, 2, 1978, 429-44.

Chen, Y., and T. Puttitanun. "Intellectual Property Rights and Innovation in Developing Countries." Journal of Development Economics, 78, 2005, 474-93.

Coelli, T. J. A Guide to Deap Version 2.1. A Data Envelopment Analysis Computer Program. Armidale, Australia: Department of Econometrics, University of England, 1996.

Deardorff, A. V. "Should Patent Protection Be Extended to All Developing Countries?" World Economy, 13, 1990, 497-506.

Diwan, I., and D. Rodrik. "Patents Appropriate Technology, and North-South Trade." Journal of International Economics, 30, 1991, 27-48.

Donaldson, T. "The Ethical Wealth of Nations." Journal of Business Ethics, 31, 2001, 25-36.

Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, and C. A. K. Lovell. Production Frontiers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994a.

Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, M. Norris, and Z. Zhang. "Productivity Growth, Technical Progress, and Efficiency Change in Industrialized Countries." American Economic Review, 84, 1994b, 66-83.

Ginarte, J. C., and W. G. Park. "Determinants of Patent Rights: A Cross-National Study." Research Policy, 26, 1997, 283-30l.

Hall, R. E., and C. I. Jones. "The Productivity of Nations." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5812, 1996.

Holman, M. "A Cancer in Business." Financial Times, n32485, 1994, S18.

Knack, S., and P. Keefer. "Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures." Economics and Politics, 7, 1995, 207-27.

Knapp, I. L. "The Software Piracy Battle in Latin America: Should the United States Pursue Its Aggressive Bilateral Trade Policy Despite the Multilateral TRIPS Enforcement Framework?" University of Pennsylvania Journal of International Economic Law, 21, 2000, 173-210.

Kumar, N. "Intellectual Property Protection, Market Orientation and Location of Overseas R&D Activities by Multinational Enterprises." World Development, 24, 1996, 673-88.

Lovell, C. A. K., J. T. Pastor, and J. A Turner. "Measuring Macroeconomic Performance in the OECD: A Comparison of European and Non-European Countries." European Journal of Operational Research, 87, 1995, 507-18.

Ma, J., D. G. Evans, R. J. Fuller, and D. F. Stewart. "Technical Efficiency and Productivity Change of China's Iron and Steel Industry." International Journal of Production Economics, 76, 2002, 293-312.

Marron, D. B., and D. G. Steel. "Which Countries Protect Intellectual Property? The Case of Software Piracy." Economic Inquiry, 38, 2000, 159-74.

Mauro, P. "Corruption: Causes, Consequences, and Agenda for Further Research." Finance & Development, 35, 1998, 11-4.

Park, W. G., and J. C. Ginarte. "Intellectual Property Rights in a North-South Economic Context." Science Communication, 17, 1996, 379-87.

--. "Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Growth." Contemporary Economic Policy, 15, 1997, 51-61.

Park, W. G., and D. Lippoldt. "The Impact of Trade-Related Intellectual Property Rights on Trade and Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries." OECD Papers: Special Issue on Trade Policy, 4, 294, 2003, 1-40.

--. "International Licensing and the Strengthening of Intellectual Property Rights in Developing Countries during the 1990s." OECD Economic Studies, 40, 2005, 7-48.

Ramanathan, R. "An Analysis of Energy Consumption and Carbon Dioxide Emissions in Countries of the Middle East and North Africa." Energy, 30, 2005, 2831-42.

Rapp, R. T., and R. P. Rozek. "Benefits and Costs of Intellectual Property Protection in Developing Countries." Journal of World Trade, 24, 1990, 75-102.

Sell, S. Private Power, Public Law: The Globalization of Intellectual Property Rights. London: Cambridge University Press, 2003.

Shadlen, K. C., A. Schrank, and M. J. Kurtz. "The Political Economy of Intellectual Property Protection: The Case of Software." International Studies Quarterly, 49, 2005, 45-71.

Teran, H. "Intellectual Property Protection and Offshore Software Development: An Analysis of the U.S. Software Industry." Minnesota Intellectual Property Review, 2, 2001, 1-50.

Voyer, P. A., and P. W. Beamish. "The Effect of Corruption on Japanese Foreign Direct Investment." Journal of Business Ethics, 50, 2004, 211-24.

World Bank. "World Development Indicators." CD-ROM, 2003.

Yang, G., and K. E. Maskus. "Intellectual Property Rights, Licensing, and Innovation in an Endogenous Product Cycle Model." Journal of International Economics, 53, 2001, 169-87.

CHERNG G. DING and NA-TING LIU *

* We thank Jin-Li Hu, Erwin T. J. Lin, Shih-Fang Lo, and Wen-Min Lu for helpful discussions. We also thank an anonymous referee for constructive comments and suggestions. This research was partially supported by the National Science Council of Taiwan, R.O.C.

Ding: Professor, Institute of Business and Management, National Chiao Tung University, 118 Chung-Hsiao West Road, Section 1, Taipei, 100, Taiwan. Phone 886-2-2349-4932, Fax 886-2-23494922, E-mail [email protected]

Liu: Assistant Professor, Department of Business Administration, Ming Chuan University, 250 Chung-Shan North Road, Section 5, Taipei, 111, Taiwan. Phone 886-2-2882-4564 ext. 2880, Fax 886-2-28809727, E-mail [email protected]

doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2007.00117.x

Online Early publication August 22, 2008
TABLE 1 Estimated Rates of Software Piracy for 18 APEC
Economics, 1994-2002
 %
Economy 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998

East Asian
 China 97 96 96 96 95
 Japan 66 65 41 32 31
NIEs
 Hong Kong 62 62 64 67 59
 Singapore 61 53 59 56 52
 South Korea 75 76 70 67 64
 Taiwan 72 70 66 63 59
ASEAN-5
 Indonesia 97 98 97 93 92
 Malaysia 82 77 80 70 73
 Philippines 94 91 92 83 77
 Thailand 87 82 80 84 82
 Vietnam 100 99 99 98 97
Non-Asian
 industrialized
 Australia 37 35 32 32 33
 Canada 46 44 42 39 40
 New Zealand 43 40 35 34 32
 United States 31 26 27 27 25
Developing
 Chile 70 68 62 56 53
 Mexico 78 74 67 62 59
 Peru 86 84 74 66 64

Economy 1999 2000 2001 2002

East Asian 91 94 92 92
 China 31 37 37 35
 Japan
NIEs 56 57 53 56
 Hong Kong 51 50 51 48
 Singapore 50 56 48 50
 South Korea 54 53 53 43
 Taiwan
ASEAN-5 85 89 88 89
 Indonesia 71 66 70 68
 Malaysia 70 61 63 68
 Philippines 81 79 77 77
 Thailand 98 97 94 95
 Vietnam
Non-Asian
 industrialized 32 33 27 32
 Australia 41 38 38 39
 Canada 31 28 26 24
 New Zealand 25 24 25 23
 United States
Developing 51 49 51 51
 Chile 56 56 55 55
 Mexico 63 61 60 60
 Peru

Source: Business Software Alliance (2003).

TABLE 2 Summary Statistics of Economic Inputs and Output, 1994-2002

 Output(a) (Per Capita)
 GDP Capital
 Standard Standard
Economy Mean Deviation Mean Deviation
East Asian
 China 729.49 138.25 285.37 55.04
 Japan 43,771.35 1,175.07 12,018.15 505.55
NIEs
 Hong Kong 23,791.05 1,174.40 7,458.88 684.33
 Singapore 26,187.44 2,640.05 8,161.60 1,185.95
 South Korea 12,635.38 1,378.01 4,109.15 474.67
 Taiwan 12,356.44 595.80 2,586.77 356.24
ASEAN-5
 Indonesia 1,040.94 59.76 254.63 80.30
 Malaysia 4,561.42 277.03 1,509.54 375.19
 Philippines 1,137.59 47.40 255.62 20.54
 Thailand 2,834.53 146.63 805.54 316.92
 Vietnam 337.82 48.85 100.07 21.58
Non-Asian
 industrialized
 Australia 22,407.79 1,577.91 5,565.50 754.21
 Canada 21,419.64 1,587.90 4,352.36 511.92
 New Zealand 17,344.55 930.09 3,824.26 240.19
 United States 29,866.28 1,773.27 6,056.86 779.52
Developing
 Chile 5,039.70 410.61 1,145.28 169.48
 Mexico 3,521.61 228.94 967.39 169.45
 Peru 2,293.73 79.94 500.46 61.36

 Input' (Per Capita)
 Labor Software Piracy Loss
 Standard Standard
Economy Mean Deviation Mean Deviation
East Asian
 China 0.5987 0.0014 0.89 0.51
 Japan 0.5354 0.0020 10.05 3.28
NIEs
 Hong Kong 0.5237 0.0051 16.59 4.56
 Singapore 0.5007 0.0056 12.44 2.84
 South Korea 0.5018 0.0111 8.70 4.14
 Taiwan 0.4355 0.0044 6.09 0.87
ASEAN-5
 Indonesia 0.4752 0.0117 0.58 0.30
 Malaysia 0.4085 0.0085 4.03 0.69
 Philippines 0.4175 0.0064 0.55 0.22
 Thailand 0.6000 0.0073 1.31 0.51
 Vietnam 0.5126 0.0041 0.29 0.19
Non-Asian
 industrialized
 Australia 0.5078 0.0023 7.85 1.92
 Canada 0.5346 0.0025 10.69 2.28
 New Zealand 0.4970 0.0039 5.12 2.14
 United States 0.5108 0.0032 9.80 2.31
Developing
 Chile 0.4036 0.0077 3.01 0.57
 Mexico 0.4035 0.0111 1.66 0.34
 Peru 0.3699 0.0121 1.12 0.41

Source: Asian Development Bank (2004), Business Software Alliance
(2003), and World Bank (2003).

(a) The monetary values are in 1995 prices.

TABLE 3 Decomposition of the Mean Malmquist Productivity Changes
without/with Consideration of Software Piracy

 Mean Annual Change

 Malmquist (MALM)

Economy Without With
East Asian
 China 0.995 0.975
 Japan 1.011 1.012
NIEs
 Hong Kong 1.007 0.999
 Singapore 1.036 1.031
 South Korea 1.039 1.044
 Taiwan 1.029 1.022
ASEAN-5
 Indonesia 1.072 1.056
 Malaysia 1.047 1.047
 Philippines 1.007 1.003
 Thailand 1.086 1.045
 Vietnam 0.969 0.912
Non-Asian
 industrialized
 Australia 0.993 1.007
 Canada 0.992 0.992
 New Zealand 0.998 1.071
 United States 0.997 1.018
Developing
 Chile 1.014 1.012
 Mexico 0.999 1.014
 Peru 1.025 1.025

 Mean Annual Change

 Efficiency Change (EFFCH)

Economy Without With
East Asian
 China 0.980 0.951
 Japan 1.000 1.000
NIEs
 Hong Kong 1.002 0.992
 Singapore 1.028 1.020
 South Korea 1.043 1.043
 Taiwan 1.021 1.003
ASEAN-5
 Indonesia 1.059 1.035
 Malaysia 1.034 1.018
 Philippines 0.992 0.998
 Thailand 1.074 1.030
 Vietnam 0.956 0.917
Non-Asian
 industrialized
 Australia 1.002 0.977
 Canada 0.998 0.998
 New Zealand 1.002 1.003
 United States 1.000 1.000
Developing
 Chile 1.002 1.002
 Mexico 0.985 0.980
 Peru 1.014 1.027

 Mean Annual Change

 Technical Change (TECHCH)

Economy Without With
East Asian
 China 1.015 1.025
 Japan 1.011 1.012
NIEs
 Hong Kong 1.005 1.007
 Singapore 1.008 1.011
 South Korea 0.996 1.001
 Taiwan 1.008 1.019
ASEAN-5
 Indonesia 1.012 1.020
 Malaysia 1.013 1.029
 Philippines 1.015 1.005
 Thailand 1.011 1.015
 Vietnam 1.014 0.995
Non-Asian
 industrialized
 Australia 0.991 1.031
 Canada 0.994 0.994
 New Zealand 0.996 1.068
 United States 0.997 1.018
Developing
 Chile 1.012 1.010
 Mexico 1.014 1.035
 Peru 1.011 0.998

Notes: These numbers are the geometric means of annual changes
in each economy over the period 1994-2002.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有