Male marital wage differentials: training, personal characteristics, and fixed effects.
Rodgers, William M., III ; Stratton, Leslie S.
I. INTRODUCTION
There is substantial evidence that married white men earn between
8% and 15% more than unmarried white men in the United States, even
after controlling for education and informal job market experience
(e.g., potential or actual experience). Cross-section analysis indicates
that both the level and the growth rate of wages increase during
marriage. These results suggest that men may become more productive
after marriage, an effect often attributed to the increased
specialization possible following the formation of a multiperson
household. However, panel estimates indicate that much of the
differential is explained by individual-specific fixed effects, which
suggest that more productive men are more likely to marry. While these
results and implications are well known, the precise nature of the
implied productivity differentials has received little attention in the
literature. Using the 1979 cohort of the National Longitudinal Survey of
Youth (NLSY79), we investigate the structure or source of the observed
differential.
We do so by first extending the analysis to a sample of African
American men in the United States. To our knowledge, ours is the first
study to conduct a detailed analysis of the marital wage gap among
African American men that is fully comparable to that already available
for white men. This extension is informative because African American
households are known to exhibit less specialization along gender lines
and because marital patterns are quite different by race.
Next, we explore formal job training as one avenue to productivity
enhancement. We outline a simple story suggesting that married men may
be more receptive to training opportunities than unmarried men and
present some evidence suggesting that firms may be more willing to offer
training to married as compared to unmarried men. Previous analysis has
focused on labor market experience or years married as proxies for both
informal and formal job training. We significantly improve upon this by
using direct information on formal job training to see if wage changes
at or following the time of marriage are driven by training-induced
productivity differentials.
Third, we explore the nature of the selection effect or the
possibility that it is more productive men who marry. The NLSY79 has an
extensive array of information on personal characteristics that might be
associated with both marriage and earnings. If certain personal
characteristics are associated with both marriage and earnings, but not
typically included in wage analyses, then the marital controls in
standard wage equations may simply be proxying for these
characteristics. Controlling for such characteristics directly should
identify the nature of the selection effect and reduce the significance
of the marital indicators in cross-section estimates. The attributes we
examine include cognitive skills, parental background, and personality
traits.
Our final contribution is to estimate panel models to eliminate all
observable and unobservable individual-specific, time-invariant factors
and to reconcile these results with those obtained from cross-section
models. Specifically, we exploit the different identification conditions
between panel and cross-section models, examining the role of
respondents who are always married, never married, or always
separated/divorced. Technically, such individuals contribute to the
identification of the cross section but not the panel estimates of the
marital wage differential. Thus, these individuals may explain the
substantial differences often observed between panel and cross-section
estimates of the white male marital wage differential.
II. LITERATURE REVIEW
Evidence of the marital wage differential for white men in the
United States is extensive (see Ribar 2004, for a review). Some of this
differential has been attributed to a selection effect, to the fact that
men who marry earn more throughout their lives than men who do not
marry. Some has been attributed to changes in the wage function that
occur at or around the time of marriage (henceforth called the change
effect). This change effect has been modeled both as a faster rate of
wage growth and as a discrete jump in wages that occurs around the time
of marriage. Most of the empirical literature focuses on identifying to
what extent the differential is attributable to the selection and to
what extent it is attributable to the change effect. Relatively little
effort has been expended trying to identify the underlying reasons for
these wage patterns. (1)
The most cited explanation offered for the change effect derives
from Becker's (1991) work on the theory of the family. Becker noted
that when two single-person households are joined to form a single,
two-person household, there are gains to be had from specialization and
the division of labor as well as economies of scale in household
production. Women have historically specialized in home-based activities
and men in market-based activities. Time may be thus allocated because
of social norms or expectations regarding "acceptable"
activities for men and women (see Shelton and John 1996, for a review of
theoretical work including the social construction of gender) because of
gender differences in comparative advantage or because of gender
differentials in labor market opportunities that lead households to
rationally allocate more market time to the partner with the highest
earnings potential--typically the man. This specialization allows
married men to devote more time and energy to market activities, and
thus, men's productivity and wages rise following marriage. (2)
This specialization hypothesis relies on the assumption that
following marriage men change their behavior. Evidence based on activity
reports is mixed. Hersch and Stratton (2000) and South and Spitze (1994)
found that men's total reported housework time does not differ by
marital status but that married men report more time spent on home
maintenance chores than on "routine" or "female
type" housework such as cooking and cleaning. Gupta (1999) reported
that this is not just a selection effect but that men actually reduce
the time they spend on routine or female-type housework when they marry.
Hersch and Stratton (2000) estimated wage equations controlling for time
spent on housework as well as selection but found that while men who
spend more time on housework earn less, controlling for housework time
does not change the magnitude or significance of the male marital wage
effect.
Few data sets contain information on how time is spent off the job
and an alternate approach has been to relate men's behavioral change to spousal activity--the hypothesis being that men whose wives
are not employed in the market are more able to specialize than men
whose wives are employed. Daniel (1991), Gray (1997), and Chun and Lee
(2001) reported that married men whose wives work fewer hours receive
higher wages than married men whose wives work longer hours. Their
results were robust to fixed effects and/or instrumental variables
estimation to control for the possible endogeneity of the wife's
employment decision with the husband's wage. Jacobsen and Rayack
(1996), however, found a premium that was not robust to fixed effects or
instrumental variables estimation, and Loh (1996) found the opposite
effect, a positive return for men in dual earner households. In general,
wives' working status may be related to men's wages, but the
evidence is inconclusive. This may be because men's reported
housework time is not sensitive to the employment status of their spouse as reported by Hersch and Stratton (2000) and South and Spitze (1994).
It may be that housework is not reallocated in dual career households so
much as it is outsourced.
Alternatively there exists some literature using time series data
to test the specialization hypothesis. Blackburn and Korenman (1994)
tried unsuccessfully to relate time series evidence of a declining gross
white male marital wage differential to the increasing labor force
participation rate of women in the United Sates. More promising are
results by Gray and Vanderhart (2000), who presented evidence that the
male marital wage differential declined in the 1970s in those states
that instituted a unilateral divorce law. Such laws, by making divorce
easier, should make intrahousehold specialization less attractive and so
reduce the differential.
Cross-country comparisons have also been made. Evidence, as from
Schoeni (1995), that married men in many developed countries receive
higher wages than their unmarried counterparts suggests that the
differential is not unique to the United States. More recent in-depth
studies of the marital wage differential abroad have identified some
significant cross-country differences. Given substantial cross-country
differences in norms and in the institution of marriage, these studies
hold some promise for helping to identify the nature of the
differential. Bardasi and Taylor (2004) found evidence that married men
earn more than never married men in Great Britain but that none of the
differential takes the form of faster postmarriage wage growth and only
a small fraction is not attributable to selection. Richardson (2003)
used Swedish data and found that wages actually appear to decline with
years married in Sweden. She offered no clear explanation for this
effect, but Datta Gupta, Smith, and Stratton (2007) attribute a similar
result observed using a recent cohort of Danish men to the substantially
lower intrahousehold specialization observed in Denmark and in
Scandinavia more generally. Thus, the intrahousehold specialization
explanation for how marriage might influence the wage function may also
receive support by comparing populations that demonstrate different
intrahousehold specialization.
Research examining the selection component of the male marital wage
differential has been limited at best. This component was first
estimated by comparing fixed individual-specific effects estimates with
pooled cross-section estimates of the marital wage effect in Korenman
and Neumark (1991). An alternative approach has been to use data on
twins and assume the selection effect is common to twins independent of
their marital status (Krashinsky 2004). There is evidence from Gray
(1997) that selection has become increasingly important in the United
States and is of substantial importance abroad. Bardasi and Taylor
(2004) provide evidence for Great Britain; Datta Gupta, Smith, and
Stratton (2007) for Denmark; and Isacsson (2007) for Sweden.
While these articles present substantial evidence of the importance
of selection effects, they provide little insight into the nature of the
selection effect. Somehow men who marry are different from men who do
not marry in a manner that is not otherwise controlled for in the wage
equations but is linked to higher productivity on the job. In a rare
article addressing the selection component, Krashinsky (2004) reported
that ability differentials (and differences in the returns to ability)
explain a substantial fraction of the total and the selection component
of the U.S. marital wage differential. Other authors (e.g., Bardasi and
Taylor 2004) mention attitude, self-esteem, congeniality, loyalty,
honesty, dependability, leadership, industriousness, and even
appearance. The literature on personality traits and how they influence
earnings is a growing one. Bowles, Gintis, and Osborne (2001) provided a
justification for including such measures in earnings equations and a
partial review of the extant literature. Meuller and Plug (2006) are
representative of more recent work in the field. It seems logical to
suppose that many personality attributes that are likely to increase
earnings may also attract marriage partners. This attraction may be
driven by the higher earnings or by the attributes themselves. Thus, in
wage equations that fail to control for personality traits but do
control for marital status, the marital status dummy may be serving as a
proxy for the personality traits.
This issue is complicated by the fact that even today most men
marry. Many of the panel data sets used in the analysis of the male
marital wage differential include a large fraction of men who marry
before they enter the sample. This makes estimation of the marital wage
effect dependent on the wages of these men in cross-section analysis.
Panel estimates will, however, be dependent only upon those who change
marital status during the sample period. If those initially married
remain married, they do not contribute to panel-based estimates of the
marital wage differential. This identifying condition may explain why
panel and cross-section estimates of the marital wage differential are
frequently quite different. Furthermore, if more productive men marry
first then the years married measure, which is incorporated to capture
differential wage growth, may instead be spuriously correlated with
wages through its relation to marital timing. Of course, there are also
men in any sample who never marry or are always divorced. They represent
two additional groups of men whose information does not inform the panel
data estimates. Their presence may also help to explain why panel and
cross-section estimates differ.
III. METHODOLOGY
In this article, we explore further the nature of the male marital
wage differential. We do so first by replicating the analysis that has
historically focused on white men with a sample of African American men.
The structure of the marital wage gap may differ by race because there
are racial differences in time use and marital choices.
For example, unemployment rates are higher and labor force
participation rates are lower for African American men as compared to
white men. There is also some evidence from Kamo and Cohen (1998) that
African American men contribute a significantly greater share of
household housework time than white men, even after controlling for
household characteristics. If the marital wage differential is the
result of increased productivity following marriage that is attributable
to increased specialization following marriage then African American
men's wages should rise less than white men's wages.
Distinct racial differences in marital patterns have been reported,
too, by the Department of Health and Human Resources (2002). African
American women are less likely to marry, more likely to divorce, and
less likely to remarry than white women. This is the case even though
the reported degree of attachment to marriage is similar by race. These
racial differences in marital patterns have been attributed to the worse
economic situation of African American males, as men who are more
educated and employed are more likely to marry. In light of these racial
differences in marriage, it will be of some interest to compare the
relative selection component of the marital wage differential by race.
If marriage among African Americans is more selective (as reflected in
their lower marriage rates), there may be a greater selection effect for
African American as compared to white men. Or, if the pool of
marriage-eligible African American men is small, then there may be a
smaller selection effect (Wilson 1987, 83). The higher divorce rate of
African Americans as compared to whites is more consistent with there
being less selection among African American men.
In general, replicating the analysis for African American men may
help identify the nature of the marital wage differential for white men.
Second, we explore the mechanism by which selection or marriage
generally may change wages. In particular, we look at the possibility
that married men may acquire job-related human capital faster than men
who are not married. While controls for informal training, such as job
experience and/or job tenure, are standard in the marital wage
literature, additional controls for formal job training are not. If
married men receive more job training than unmarried men with the same
job experience and tenure then the observed marital wage differential
may be due not to marital status but to training differentials. If this
training is received before marriage then it could explain the selection
effect--why men who marry earn more. If it is received after marriage
then the training differential, not the marriage itself, may explain the
faster growth rate of wages following marriage and the fact that the
differential is often observed to persist following divorce (Hersch and
Stratton 2000).
Why might married men receive more job training? On the one hand,
marriage does often entail significantly greater financial
responsibilities (particularly following the arrival of children) and
may make men more receptive to job training opportunities. Job training
may be offered without regard to marital status, but married men may be
more likely to accept such opportunities. On the other hand, firms may
be more inclined to offer firm-specific training to married men than to
not married men. Optimally, both the firm and the recipient share the
cost of firm-specific training. This up-front training cost is recouped
after the training is completed. The worker then receives a higher wage
than he/she could expect to receive at any other firm, while the firm
receives a marginal value product of labor that exceeds the wage. Both
parties benefit so long as the post-training employment spell endures
long enough for each to recoup their portion of the training costs. The
danger here is turnover. The greater is expected turnover, the less
investment there will be in firm-specific training.
If married men are or are not perceived as being more stable
employees as compared to unmarried men then firms may offer married men
more training. While perceptions are difficult to measure, Table 1
presents evidence that married white men have higher tenure, lower
turnover, and lower quit-to-fire ratios than unmarried white men. Data
on tenure by marital status were obtained from the 2000 Tenure
Supplement to the Current Population Survey (CPS). These data indicate
that white, non-Hispanic men between the ages of 30 and 39 who are
married have an average tenure of 6.4 yr, while similar men who have
never married (are divorced or separated) have an average tenure of 5.0
(5.4) yr. These mean differences are statistically significant and are
not due to the presence of outliers as median tenure is also higher (3)
for married men than for never married or divorced/separated men. (4)
Regression-based estimates controlling further for age within this
sample yield similar highly statistically significant differences.
Data on turnover and quit-to-fire ratios were obtained from the
1989, 1991, and 1993 CPS files, a time period that spans that of the
NLSY79 data used in this analysis. These data indicate that only 3.0% of
married, white, non-Hispanic men aged 23-37 yr changed jobs while the
comparable turnover rate was significantly higher for never married men
(6.1%) and for separated/divorced men (6.9%). Employers will not want to
invest in training individuals who are likely to leave their firm in
short order. Employers have some control over hiring and firing but are
less able to control voluntary quits. Thus, we also report the
quit-to-fire ratio by marital status. For every 100 married men who are
fired or laid off, approximately 15 quit. This ratio is similar for
separated and divorced men (14) but significantly higher for never
married men (24). Furthermore, Shaw (1987) presents evidence that the
quit rate for married men is higher, the higher the earnings share of
the wife. Thus, both the marital wage differential and the findings that
the marital wage differential is lower for men whose wives work longer
hours may be attributable to differences in job training that arise from
differences in expected quit rates by marital status rather than to
marital status itself. (5)
Next, we explore the selectivity story by examining the role of
individual-specific factors. Men who marry may be higher earners
throughout their lifetime. It may be simply good fortune that yields
some men higher earnings and women may be more attracted to these men as
better household providers. But it may be that some individual
characteristics are associated with both higher earnings and higher
marriage rates. The NLSY data contain information on a wide array of
individual characteristics one can explore. We employ controls for
cognitive skills, family background, and personality traits/self-esteem
in our effort to identify the relevant individual attributes.
Standard wage regressions include controls for education, but there
is a large literature, including Ferguson (1995), Neal and Johnson
(1996), and Rodgers and Spriggs (2002), demonstrating that other
measures of cognitive skills are positively correlated with earnings. If
more able men (by these measures) are also more likely to marry then
marriage dummies may be proxying for cognitive skills in cross-section
analyses. Family background variables such as parental education and
maternal employment may influence the degree to which men are attractive
marriage partners and the degree to which they are likely to specialize
following marriage (Cunningham 2001). These factors may also contribute
to otherwise unobserved individual-specific ability or may be indicative
of labor market connections that lead to better job matches. Personality
traits may also be linked to both earnings and marital outcomes.
Specifically, we focus on self-esteem. If the marital wage differential
is attributable to selection and we correctly identify the
individual-specific factors that link marriage and earnings then when we
include these factors in our cross-section wage regressions, we should
find the magnitude and significance of the estimated marital wage
differential reduced. Indeed, we should find that these cross-section
estimates are substantially the same as panel estimates of the male
marital wage differential.
However, panel estimates identify the magnitude of the
individual-specific component of the marital wage differential
differently than cross-section estimates. Fixed-effect results use only
information on those who change marital status, whereas cross-section
results also compare those who are always married, never married, and
always divorced/separated. In our final analyses, we examine the extent
to which these individuals, henceforth called "stayers," drive
the marital wage differentials observed in cross-sectional analysis to
see if differences observed between panel and cross-sectional estimates
are driven by differences in the nature of the identification process.
IV. DATA
The data used in this analysis are from the 1979 cohort of the
NLSY79. The NLSY79 is a longitudinal data set of 10,000 civilian young
adults who have been interviewed annually since 1979. (6) At the
survey's beginning, the youth were 14-22 yr. We use data from the
1988 through the 1994 waves when respondents are between the ages of 23
and 37 and when information on formal training is available. The final
sample is constructed subject to the following restrictions. Respondents
are required to have completed their formal schooling as of the 1988
interview date, to not be in the military or self-employed, and to have
provided full information on wages and all other variables. (7)
Observations for which constructed hourly earnings are less than $1.00
or greater than $100 in 1982-1984 dollars (using the Consumer Price
Index for Urban Consumers [CPI-U] to convert to real dollars) are
treated as outliers and are excluded from the sample. After applying
these restrictions, our sample contains observations on 2,333 white,
non-Hispanic men (henceforth referred to as white men) and 911 African
American men. Not all respondents provide complete information annually
from 1988 to 1994. Some experience unemployment; others leave the labor
force. Pooling the observations across time generates unbalanced panels
of 11,581 white male-year observations and 4,642 African American
male-year observations.
The data contain information on race, marital status, (8) number of
children, education, occupation, industry, union status, and area of
residence. Years married is inferred based on observed annual marital
status. Data on the unemployment rate in the county of residence are
gathered on the expectation that local labor market conditions will
influence earnings. The number of employees is reported in recognition
of the positive link established between wages and firm size. In
addition, each year respondents are asked how many weeks they worked
during the previous calendar year. These responses are used to construct
a measure of actual work experience. Respondents are also asked how many
weeks they have been at their current job, thus enabling the
construction of a measure of job tenure.
Detailed firm-provided job training information has been available
in the NLSY79 since 1988. At each interview, respondents are asked to
describe whether they received any type of formal training since the
last interview. (9) Training in this case includes both on-the-job
programs such as company or apprenticeship training and off-the-job
programs such as classes at a business school, vocational center, or
correspondence school. Attendance at professional meetings and seminars
on personal finance and lifestyle improvements are further examples of
off-the-job training programs. If the respondent has received training
then he is asked how long the training lasted. We test several
alternative measures of training, reporting the result of a
specification that controls for both the incidence of training and the
log duration of training, as measured in hours.
Individual-specific attributes that might explain the selection
component of the marital wage differential include cognitive skills,
family background, and personality traits. The cognitive skills measures
we employ are based on the Armed Forces Qualification Test (AFQT)
administered to the NLSY79 sample in 1980. Several researchers have used
the composite AFQT score to represent skills. (10) This score is assumed
to be a direct measure of cognitive skills obtained via family, school,
and early labor market experiences. Researchers have found this measure
to be a significant determinant of wages; however, it is also influenced
by age and education level (Hansen, Heckman, and Mullen 2004; Rodgers
and Spriggs 1996). Since the AFQT score was administered to every
respondent in the same year, some of the respondents were older and had
more education than others when they took the test. To control for both
age and education effects, we include not the AFQT score itself, but the
residual from a regression of the AFQT score against the age and
education level of the respondent at the time the test was administered.
We focus on three components of the AFQT test: one representing word
knowledge, one representing reading comprehension, and a third
representing arithmetic reasoning.
The family background variables for which we control are parental
education and occupation. Specifically, we construct a vector of dummy
variables to identify those men whose fathers completed at least high
school, whose mothers completed at least high school, as well as the
occupation of each parent when the respondent was age 14. This approach
effectively also controls for the employment status of the mother and
hence may capture some information about the degree of specialization
within the parental household.
Finally, the NLSY79 also includes some questions regarding
personality type--with a particular focus on self-esteem. Waddell (2006)
reported evidence that self-esteem measures such as those reported here
have a significant impact on earnings and it seems likely that
self-esteem may also be related to marriage prospects. There are a total
of ten questions (see Table A1, for details) to which respondents are
asked to "strongly agree," "agree,"
"disagree," or "strongly disagree." We test
specifications that include three dummy variables for each question to
allow for all nonlinearities, but present estimates from a more
parsimonious specification in which responses are numbered one to four
and summed up in such a way that larger numbers constitute higher
self-confidence. Both specifications yield similar results. These
questions were asked in both 1982 and 1987. As our wage observations
begin in 1988, both sets of measures precede our wage estimates and we
perform analysis with both.
Pertinent sample statistics by race and marital status are
presented in Table 2. See Table A2, for information on the remaining
variables: dummy variables to identify the interview year, the region
and city size of residence, the industry and occupation of employment,
union status, and public sector employment; continuous variables
reflecting the number of children in the household, firm size, and the
local county unemployment rate; and more detailed information regarding
formal training, cognitive skills, family background, and self-esteem.
These statistics are from the pooled cross-section sample.
The variables of particular interest here are the measures of job
training, cognitive skills, family background, and self-esteem. The
measure of job training reported in Table 2 is the log of hours spent in
job training since 1988. As hypothesized, married men have received more
training than men who have never married--30%-40% more. If this training
raises wages then some of the observed marital wage differential may be
attributable to differences in job training. In the empirical
specification, cognitive skills are measured using three different
components of the AFQT scores. Table 2 reports sample means only for the
residual composite AFQT score. Detailed statistics for the three
components are substantially similar (Table A2). What matters for this
analysis is the value for married as opposed to not married men. Married
men have higher residual test scores than all not married men,
regardless of race. Again, some of the marital wage differential may be
directly attributable to these measures of individual-specific cognitive
skills. There is also evidence that family background and self-esteem
differ by marital status. The evidence here suggests that
separated/divorced men have less educated parents than all other men and
that married men have more self-esteem (higher aggregate measures) than
all not married men.
Regression analysis allows us to control for all these factors
simultaneously. If differences in job experience, job tenure, job
training, cognitive skills, family background, or self-esteem explain
the marital wage differential then the dummy variable for marital status
in a log wage regression that includes controls for all these factors
will fall to zero.
V. EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION
The wage analysis begins with pooled cross-section estimation
separately for whites and African Americans of the simple marital wage
differential with controls for years married. This specification will
identify the gross male marital wage differential and any racial
difference in this differential. Continuing to estimate models
separately by race, we add the usual wage controls to see what fraction
of the gross differential is explained by differences in education,
experience, tenure, and occupation separately by race. Then, we control
for formal job training to see to what extent these more precise
measures of productivity-enhancing activities explain any of the
estimated marital wage differential and add individual-specific factors
into the cross-section model in hopes of explaining the nature of the
selection effect, again separately by race. Next, we estimate a
fixed-effects specification to determine the extent to which we have
been successful at identifying the selection effect. Finally, we examine
the role of "stayers" in driving the cross-section results and
contributing to differences between the fixed-effects and the
cross-section estimates.
In particular, the initial specification estimates the Gross or
unadjusted marital wage differential:
(1) [LnWage.sub.it] = [[beta].sub.0] + [Mar.sub.it] [[beta].sub.1]
+ [[epsilon].sub.it],
where [Mar.sub.it] is a vector of marital status variables for
individual i at time t. This vector has two components: dummy variables
identifying those who are married and those who are not currently
married but have been separated or divorced and continuous variables
that capture years married. Never married men constitute the base case.
The coefficient to the dummy variable identifying married men captures
the gross wage differential associated with marriage. This differential
may capture wage discrimination in favor of married men, productivity
shifts following marriage, and/or reflect selectivity differentials
between men who marry and men who do not. The coefficient to the measure
of years married captures differential postmarriage wage growth. This
differential wage growth is typically attributed to the benefits of
increased specialization postmarriage that allow married men to spend
more time and effort in the market than men who are not married but
generally captures increased productivity growth following marriage that
could be attributable to training.
The next specification, labeled the Basic specification, adds a
vector [X.sub.it] of individual, job, and time-specific characteristics
such as are typically incorporated in wage analyses. The third
specification, labeled Training, incorporates a set of year-specific
indicator variables to identify periods when the respondent was in
training and a measure of log hours spent in training since 1986. We
tested alternative specifications with linear and quadratic training
duration measures, but the log specification provided the best fit.
These purely cross-sectional analyses will tell us whether there exist
racial differences in the marital wage differential and whether any of
the observed cross-sectional differences in earnings, particularly those
taking the form of faster wage growth for married men, are explained by
differential productivity attributable to job training.
Then, we explore the degree to which the cross-section estimates
can be explained by individual-specific, time-invariant factors. We do
so first by estimating an Individual-Specific specification that
includes such individual-Specific attributes as cognitive skills, family
background, and self-esteem. To the extent that these attributes are
associated with both marital status and earnings, they should capture
that component of the marital wage differential that is attributable to
selection, reducing the magnitude and significance of the Mar vector.
A common alternative approach to controlling for selectivity has
been to estimate a Fixed-Effects specification, where individual dummy
variables are included to capture all individual-specific,
time-invariant factors that influence earnings ([[epsilon].sub.it] =
[[mu].sub.i] + [[eta].sub.it], where [[mu].sub.i] is the
individual-specific factor). We do so next. A comparison of our
Fixed-Effect estimates and our Individual-Specific estimates provides us
with a standard measure of how successful we have been in controlling
for selection.
Estimates from such fixed-effects models have, however, a number of
notable weaknesses. First, they are far more sensitive than
cross-section estimates to measurement error. While we have eliminated
those individuals whose marital history is clearly inconsistent, it is
likely that our data are still imperfect, and as a result, our
fixed-effects estimates of the marital wage differential will likely be
biased toward zero. Second, even if fixed-effects estimates do identify
the magnitude of the selection effect, they provide no information as to
its nature. Finally, fixed-effects parameters are estimated only off
those who change marital status within the sample period. Though
"stayers" (those who are always married, never married, or
always divorced/separated) within our sample contribute to our
cross-section estimates of the marital wage differential, they
contribute nothing to the fixed-effects estimates.
To gauge the importance of stayers in driving our cross-section
estimates, we estimate a series of cross-section models that include
dummy variables identifying these individuals (Stayer Models). Included
here are modified Gross, Training, and Individual-Specific
specifications, identified with a "+" character in the header to indicate the addition of the stayer dummies. Our goal was to see how
including these dummy indicators alters our results.
VI. RESULTS
Selected coefficient estimates for the Gross, Basic, and Training
specifications are reported in Table 3. (11) The first three columns
present results for the white sample, the last three columns results for
the African American sample. The Gross specification for whites
indicates that married men earn about 14% (12) more than never married
men, perhaps 20% more than separated/divorced men, and that wages rise
faster following marriage by almost 1% annually. (13) There are
substantial differences by race. The Gross specification for African
Americans indicates that the marriage premium is almost 50% larger (at
19%) with no significant difference in the premium over
separated/divorced men. The wage growth differential is about the same
magnitude as that observed for white men. As do others in the
literature, we allow wage growth to revert back to premarriage levels
when a couple separates.
Including the basic controls for education; quadratics in actual
experience and tenure; a measure of the number of children, the firm
size, and the local unemployment rate; and dummies for one-digit
industry and occupation, region of residence, city size, interview year,
union status, and government employment reduces the observed white male
marital wage differential by almost 60%-5.5% and the observed higher
growth rate by almost 50%-0.5% annually. Introducing these controls also
changes the wage differential between white separated/ divorced and
never married men from a significant -6% to an insignificant +2%. These
results are comparable to those reported elsewhere in the literature.
The effect on African American men is quite similar with the
coefficients to the marital dummy and the years married variables both
declining by over half. One change for African American men is that
after including controls for experience and tenure, there is no evidence
of significantly faster wage growth following marriage. For both
samples, the three marriage-related variables remain jointly highly
statistically significant.
As observed in the sample statistics, married African American and
white men have more actual experience and job tenure. Failing to control
for these differences has a significant influence on estimates of the
differential. While the point estimates of the marital effects in the
Basic specification continue to differ by race, with married white men
experiencing a higher rate of wage growth but a lower wage differential
than their African American counterparts, these racial differences are
not statistically significant. The finding that for both white and
African American men, there is a significant marital wage differential
of approximately the same type suggests that, at least within the United
States, the factors contributing to the marital wage differential may be
common across the population.
While we have evidence that married men earn more than their
unmarried counterparts, however, the precise mechanism by which marriage
influences wages still has not been identified. Thus, we turn to our
analysis of formal training, including a measure of the log of total
training hours as well as controls for participation in current training
in the wage model. Current training is expected to lower earnings as
training entails time that likely reduces productivity on the job today
in return for higher productivity later. Employees are likely to bear
some of the cost of this training by receiving lower wages. Our results
(available upon request) indicate that this is generally the case except
that those who report receiving training during the first-year training
data are available experience a positive return to that training in
cross-section models, likely reflecting the fact that they received
productivity-enhancing training earlier. Accumulated training time, by
contrast, should increase productivity and hence wages. Results in
columns 3 and 6 of Table 3 confirm this. We find that a 1% increase in
training time increases earnings by about 1% for both white and African
American men. Controlling for training does not, however, substantially
alter the estimated marital wage premium for either population. The
parameter estimates of the marital wage differential fall, but the
difference is neither significant nor substantial. Thus, while formal
training clearly increases wages, it is not the mechanism driving the
male marital wage differential.
The results of our analysis of the individual-specific or selection
component of the male marital wage differential are presented in Table
4. Again, we report the results of three specifications separately for
the white and African American samples. The first of these is the
Training specification presented in Table 3. These results are repeated
here to make cross-equation comparisons easier.
The second specification is the Individual Specific specification
that includes controls for cognitive skills (as measured by three
components of the AFQT), parental education and occupation, and own
self-esteem that may plausibly be related to both marital status and
earnings. Indeed, we find that cognitive skills and parental occupation
are positively related to earnings for both white and African American
men. Self-esteem is also significantly related to earnings for the white
sample. However, incorporating these controls has only a small impact on
the estimated marital wage differential. The coefficients to the dummy
variables identifying married men fall by 6% for the white sample and
17% for the African American sample but remain statistically significant
in both samples. The coefficient to the years married variable in the
white sample falls by about 20%, remaining significant only at the 10%
level.
We performed several sensitivity tests on this specification. The
results reported include self-esteem measures taken from the 1980 NLSY
interview. These substantially predate the first reported wage measures
from 1988. The identical battery of questions was repeated in 1987.
Given the high degree of serial correlation in wages and the likely
relation between wages and self-esteem (with high wages increasing
self-esteem), we felt that it was important to use personality measures
from the earlier period; however, the only difference in the results is
that this measure of self-esteem was significant for African Americans.
In separate specifications (available upon request), we also included
controls for individuals' gender role attitudes. It could be that
men who marry perceive their role in the family differently than men who
do not marry and that this is somehow correlated with earnings. Thus, we
used responses to the questions, "A woman's place is in the
home-not in the office or shop," "It is much better for
everyone concerned if the man is the achiever outside the home and the
woman takes care of the home and family," and "Men should
share the work around the house with women, such as doing dishes,
cleaning, and so forth," to control for gender role attitudes. The
same attitudinal questions were asked in 1979, 1982, and 1987. In no
case did we find these variables significantly correlated with earnings.
In other specifications, we included measures of additional cognitive
skills such as mathematical knowledge, mechanical ability, and science
knowledge, but the marital wage effects were unchanged.
The third and sixth columns of Table 4 provide estimates of the
male marital wage differential from a Fixed-Effects specification that
controls for all individual-specific time-invariant factors. A
comparison of the results from this specification with those from the
Individual-Specific specification reveals substantial differences by
race. The coefficient to the dummy variable identifying currently
married individuals declines by more than 90% and becomes insignificant
(both statistically and numerically) for white men. The same coefficient
for African American men declines by less than 15% and remains
significant. The effect of years married changes sign but becomes
statistically insignificant for both samples. Since the cross-section
estimates of a higher wage growth following marriage could simply be
indicative of men with higher earnings marrying earlier in life, we
estimated additional models to control for age at first marriage. In no
case did we find that age at first marriage was significantly related to
earnings. For white men, the marital variables are jointly statistically
insignificant once individual-specific effects are incorporated. This
suggests that for white men, selection effects may explain the entire
differential. (14) Compared to white men, selection effects for African
American men are not as important, but even so, the joint marital wage
effect is only marginally significant. (15)
Thus, we are left with substantial differences between the panel
and the cross-section estimates of the marital wage differential
particularly for white men. To reconcile these differences, we examine
the models' different identification conditions. Specifically, we
concentrate on the well-known fact that fixed-effects estimates are
identified only from individuals who change marital status during the
survey period, while cross-section estimates are also influenced by the
level of wages received by those who do not change marital status. Thus,
cross-section estimates may indicate that married men earn higher wages
not because wages increase for those who marry, but because the wages of
those who are always married are higher than the wages of those who are
not married.
Within our panel, over three-quarters of the respondents do not
change marital status, so stayers, or nonswitchers, may have a
significant impact. Such a high fraction of stayers is not unusual in
the marital wage literature. Over three-quarters of the white men in
Korenman and Neumark's (1991) seminal work and in Gray's
(1997) work, as well as about two-thirds of those in Hersch and
Stratton's (2000) sample, were married when first observed in the
sample. However, while 6% of each of our samples is always separated/
divorced, the fraction always and never married differs considerably by
race. Fully 45% of white men are always married as compared to 22% never
married. These fractions are essentially reversed for African American
men, with 21% always and 44% never married.
To gauge the degree to which the differences between the
cross-section and the panel results are driven by these stayers, we
re-estimate our Gross, Training, and Individual-Specific models
including dummy variables to identify stayers of each type. These
specifications remove the average contribution of stayers (or
stayer-specific means) from the marital wage differentials. Movers,
however, still contribute to the estimates in two ways: through wage
changes experienced as marital status changes and through wage levels.
Fixed-effects estimates further remove all wage-level effects and so
will not quite be comparable. The expanded cross-section results are
reported in Table 5. The base case to which all individuals are compared
in these specifications is no longer all observations predating a first
marriage, but rather only observations predating a first marriage for
those who are observed marrying within the sample.
In the Gross+ estimates, the coefficient to the marital dummy falls
substantially and becomes statistically insignificant for both whites
and African Americans, suggesting that stayers play a major role. The
impact of separation or divorce is, however, quite different by race.
For white men, wages fall following divorce, but the difference is not
statistically significant. Instead, it is white men who are always
divorced who receive substantially and significantly lower wages. (16)
By contrast, for African American men, being always divorced is
associated with an insignificant positive wage effect, while wages fall
significantly following divorce. Interestingly, the inclusion of the
stayer controls also reduces the magnitude of the estimated wage growth
differential for married men of both races.
As more controls are added, the magnitude and significance of many
of the coefficients to the marital controls decline. For white men, the
joint impact of both current and persistent marital status remains
significant at even the 0.1% level, but a joint test of the significance
of only the current marital status variables indicates that these are
not significant at even the 10% level. Overall, controlling for the wage
level of stayers appears to explain most of the difference between the
individual-specific and the fixed-effects results for white men.
For African American men, there was less of a difference to
explain, as the fixed-effects specification still showed a significant
marital wage differential. The marital status variables do become
individually statistically insignificant with the addition of the stayer
variables, but joint tests indicate that the current status variables
are more significant than the stayer status variables. The two marital
variables that are most statistically significant in the expanded
specification are those related to separation/divorce, and as mentioned
above, these coefficient values indicate that it is African Americans
who separate, not those who are always separated, who experience lower
wages. A further analysis of the average wages of this group (results
not shown) indicates that the wages of these men are lower no matter
their marital status. Some low-wage African American men are marrying
but unable to maintain that status. The low-wage level of these men
likely depresses cross-section relative to panel estimates of the
marital wage differential.
Overall, controlling for stayers and their demographic
characteristics goes a long way toward reconciling the cross-section and
panel estimates of the marital wage differential for white men, as the
level effects across movers within the cross-section estimates do not
appear to contribute substantially to the estimated marital wage
differentials. By contrast, controlling for stayers aggravates the level
effects across movers for African American men.
VII. CONCLUSIONS
In this analysis, we explore the nature of the white male marital
wage differential. Evidence suggests that the differential is split
between a wage change component possibly driven by differential
productivity and a selection component, with selection becoming
increasingly important for more recent cohorts in the United States. The
wage change component has often been attributed to increased job skills
acquired as a result of intrahousehold specialization, but explanations
for the selection component have received little empirical attention.
Our purpose here was to focus further attention upon the mechanisms
underlying the observed differential.
We begin by extending what has traditionally been an analysis of
white men in the United States to a sample of African American men. In
one of the first analyses of African American marital wage differentials
to control for job experience, job tenure, and years married, (17) we
find little difference by race. The gross marital wage differential is
larger for African American men than for white men, but much of this
differential is explained by differences in other observable
characteristics (like experience) that are typically included in a wage
equation. Cross-section estimates of a standard wage equation suggest
that African American men may experience a larger wage jump but less
wage growth following marriage than white men, but the differences are
not statistically significant. This result suggests that some factors
common to both white and African American married men are driving the
observed male marital wage differential.
One possibility is that marriage is associated with greater job
training for men of all races. We use detailed direct information on job
training to explore this possibility and find that married men receive
more informal and formal job training than men who are not married and
that this training does significantly increase wages. However,
controlling for training does not substantially alter the estimated
marital wage differential for either the white or the African American
sample. Given our use of more direct training measures, this finding
casts some doubt on the hypothesis that the marital wage differential is
attributable to a productivity differential.
Next, we examine the selection component of the male marital wage
differential. We do so first by using some of the rich data available in
the NLSY on cognitive skills, parental background, and personality
traits all of which have previously been linked to higher productivity
and could credibly be associated with marital status. While cognitive
skills, parental occupation, and self-esteem were significantly
associated with earnings, none of these variables appear to explain more
than 15% of the selection component of the male marital wage
differential. By contrast, fixed-effects estimates that difference out
all individual-specific and time-invariant effects reveal that the vast
majority of the differential for white men (as reported elsewhere in the
literature), but relatively little of the differential for African
American men, is attributable to individual-specific, time-invariant
factors. These results suggest that selection into marriage is critical
for white but not for African American men and that marriage actually
has an impact upon wages for African American men. The small selection
effect for African American men is consistent with a story that the pool
of marriage-eligible African American men is small and the fact that
marital disruption is higher for African Americans than for whites.
To reconcile the differences between our expanded cross-section
model and the fixed-effects models, particularly for white men, we
examine the identification conditions underlying these two approaches.
Fixed-effects estimates of the marital wage differential are identified
only off those individuals who are observed changing marital status
within the sample. By controlling separately for these stayers in our
cross-section models, we are, in fact, able to substantially reconcile
our results. Much of the difference between the cross-section and the
fixed-effects estimates of the marital status effects for white men is
attributable to those men who never marry, who are always divorced, or
who are always married within the sample, explaining the fact that
fixed-effects estimates for white men show no evidence of a marital wage
differential. By contrast, these stayers explain little of the robust
marital wage effect found for African American men, and, indeed,
controlling for African American stayers highlights the relative
importance of men who separate within this sample who always receive
lower wages. This finding, too, is consistent with the notion that the
marriage-eligible pool of African Americans is smaller and hence that
more "mistakes" are made in the marriage market.
Future work examining the male marital wage differential should be
cognizant of these cross-section/panel differentials. Different racial
and ethnic samples should be further studied to capture differences in
marriage markets. Additional analysis of personality traits should be
explored to develop additional insight into the nature of the
individual-specific component of the marital wage differential. For
example, men who marry may have a more agreeable temperament than men
who do not marry. More agreeable men may be easier to work with on the
job and hence be more productive and earn higher wages, particularly
given the shift from a manufacturing to a service-based economy, where a
variety of "soft" skills such as teamwork have been found to
be important. More agreeable men also may be better marriage partners.
More work to identify how marriage affects men and women's time use
may help explain differences in wage growth following marriage.
ABBREVIATIONS
AFQT: Armed Forces Qualification Test
NLSY79: National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2008.00209.x
APPENDIX
TABLE A1
Questions Regarding Personality Traits
WORTH I feel that I'm a person of worth, at least on an
equal basis with others
GOODQUAL I feel that I have a number of good qualities
FAILURE All in all, I am inclined to feel that I am a failure
CAPABLE I am able to do things as well as most other people
PROUD I feel I do not have much to be proud of
POSATT I take a positive attitude toward myself
SATMYSELF On the whole, I am satisfied with myself
SELFRESPECT I wish I could have more respect for myself
USELESS I certainly feel useless at times
NOGOOD At times I think I am no good at all
TABLE A2
Sample Means by Race and Marital Status
White Men
Never Separated/
Variable Married Married Divorced
Never married 0.00 0.78 0.00
Always married as observed 0.75 0.00 0.00
Always divorced 0.00 0.00 0.42
Log of firm size (number of
employees) 4.05 3.72 3.60
County unemployment rate x 10 68.44 66.06 67.77
Number of children 1.45 0.10 0.32
Regional dummies
Midwest 0.30 0.29 0.24
South 0.34 0.27 0.42
West 0.20 0.26 0.22
City/metro dummies
SMSA, not central city 0.38 0.36 0.32
SMSA, central city unknown 0.27 0.31 0.33
SMSA, central city 0.08 0.15 0.09
Job characteristics
Union member 0.15 0.11 0.11
Employed in public sector 0.15 0.10 0.15
Industry
Agriculture, forestry, and
fisheries 0.03 0.04 0.05
Mining 0.02 0.01 0.01
Construction 0.11 0.13 0.17
Manufacturing 0.29 0.22 0.24
Transportation, communication,
public utilities 0.09 0.07 0.08
Wholesale and retail trade 0.17 0.24 0.19
Finance, insurance, and real
estate 0.04 0.06 0.03
Business and repair services 0.07 0.08 0.08
Personal services 0.01 0.04 0.01
Entertainment and recreation
services 0.01 0.02 0.01
Professional and related services 0.09 0.06 0.07
Public administration 0.06 0.04 0.04
Occupation
Professional, technical 0.14 0.12 0.08
Managers 0.16 0.12 0.09
Sales workers 0.06 0.06 0.03
Clerical workers 0.06 0.09 0.05
Craftsmen and foremen 0.22 0.21 0.29
Operatives 0.20 0.17 0.20
Laborers, except farm 0.07 0.10 0.12
Farmers and farm managers 0.00 0.00 0.00
Farm laborers and foremen 0.01 0.02 0.01
Service workers 0.07 0.12 0.11
Private household workers 0.00 0.00 0.00
Year dummies
1988 0.15 0.23 0.15
1989 0.16 0.20 0.16
1990 0.16 0.17 0.17
1991 0.13 0.12 0.13
1992 0.13 0.11 0.13
1993 0.13 0.09 0.13
1994 0.13 0.08 0.14
Training variables
Received training in 1989 0.01 0.01 0.01
Received training in 1990 0.00 0.00 0.00
Received training in 1991 0.01 0.01 0.02
Received training in 1992 0.01 0.00 0.00
Received training in 1993 0.04 0.02 0.01
Received training in 1994 0.01 0.01 0.01
Time in training (in h) 62.30 71.12 49.67
Ever received training 0.18 0.15 0.12
AFQT variables
Word knowledge 1.74 2.14 1.70
Paragraph comprehension 0.45 0.34 0.43
Arithmetic reasoning 2.76 1.99 1.83
Family background variables
Father's education 10.41 10.72 9.90
Father's education missing 0.07 0.08 0.09
Mother's education 10.45 10.46 10.23
Mother's education missing 0.06 0.06 0.06
Father's occupation
Missing/not employed 0.20 0.22 0.24
Professional, technical 0.11 0.09 0.05
Managers 0.12 0.12 0.08
Sales workers 0.04 0.05 0.05
Clerical workers 0.04 0.03 0.05
Craftsmen and foremen 0.20 0.18 0.21
Operatives 0.01 0.01 0.01
Laborers, except farm 0.16 0.17 0.14
Farmers and farm managers 0.03 0.04 0.05
Farm laborers and foremen 0.03 0.01 0.02
Service workers 0.02 0.02 0.03
Private household workers 0.05 0.05 0.07
Mother's occupation
Missing/not employed 0.43 0.46 0.43
Professional, technical 0.08 0.09 0.09
Managers 0.04 0.02 0.04
Sales workers 0.03 0.03 0.04
Clerical workers 0.16 0.16 0.13
Craftsmen and foremen 0.01 0.02 0.01
Operatives 0.00 0.00 0.00
Laborers, except farm 0.11 0.09 0.10
Farmers and farm managers 0.01 0.01 0.00
Farm laborers and foremen 0.00 0.00 0.00
Service workers 0.02 0.01 0.01
Private household workers 0.11 0.12 0.14
Attitude (a) 6.95 6.92 7.07
Self-esteem measures
Summary measure from 1980 22.63 21.90 22.01
Summary measure from 1987 24.10 23.24 23.00
Sample size 6,959 3,209 1,413
African American Men
Never Separated/
Variable Married Married Divorced
Never married 0.00 0.88 0.00
Always married as observed 0.58 0.00 0.00
Always divorced 0.00 0.00 0.47
Log of firm size (number of
employees) 4.65 4.01 4.24
County unemployment rate x 10 61.51 61.23 61.22
Number of children 1.67 0.26 0.32
Regional dummies
Midwest 0.15 0.18 0.16
South 0.68 0.59 0.65
West 0.07 0.07 0.08
City/metro dummies
SMSA, not central city 0.25 0.18 0.18
SMSA, central city unknown 0.36 0.33 0.39
SMSA, central city 0.18 0.28 0.25
Job characteristics
Union member 0.22 0.16 0.15
Employed in public sector 0.25 0.17 0.15
Industry
Agriculture, forestry, and
fisheries 0.01 0.04 0.01
Mining 0.01 0.00 0.01
Construction 0.12 0.14 0.13
Manufacturing 0.26 0.19 0.21
Transportation, communication,
public utilities 0.13 0.08 0.12
Wholesale and retail trade 0.15 0.21 0.19
Finance, insurance, and real
estate 0.03 0.03 0.04
Business and repair services 0.07 0.09 0.12
Personal services 0.02 0.04 0.04
Entertainment and recreation
services 0.01 0.01 0.00
Professional and related services 0.09 0.11 0.07
Public administration 0.10 0.06 0.05
Occupation
Professional, technical 0.09 0.06 0.05
Managers 0.09 0.05 0.06
Sales workers 0.02 0.02 0.03
Clerical workers 0.10 0.10 0.06
Craftsmen and foremen 0.16 0.15 0.13
Operatives 0.27 0.21 0.27
Laborers, except farm 0.12 0.19 0.17
Farmers and farm managers 0.00 0.00 0.00
Farm laborers and foremen 0.00 0.01 0.00
Service workers 0.15 0.21 0.22
Private household workers 0.00 0.00 0.00
Year dummies
1988 0.14 0.20 0.12
1989 0.14 0.18 0.14
1990 0.14 0.16 0.15
1991 0.15 0.14 0.15
1992 0.15 0.13 0.14
1993 0.14 0.11 0.15
1994 0.15 0.09 0.14
Training variables
Received training in 1989 0.01 0.01 0.00
Received training in 1990 0.01 0.01 0.00
Received training in 1991 0.01 0.01 0.03
Received training in 1992 0.01 0.00 0.00
Received training in 1993 0.02 0.00 0.01
Received training in 1994 0.01 0.01 0.01
Time in training (in h) 71.47 60.31 82.78
Ever received training 0.15 0.10 0.11
AFQT variables
Word knowledge -5.18 -5.66 -6.03
Paragraph comprehension -2.06 -2.34 -2.46
Arithmetic reasoning -3.44 -3.70 -3.94
Family background variables
Father's education 7.42 7.13 6.96
Father's education missing 0.26 0.29 0.28
Mother's education 9.85 9.71 9.28
Mother's education missing 0.09 0.10 0.11
Father's occupation
Missing/not employed 0.37 0.46 0.41
Professional, technical 0.02 0.01 0.01
Managers 0.02 0.03 0.03
Sales workers 0.01 0.00 0.00
Clerical workers 0.02 0.03 0.03
Craftsmen and foremen 0.19 0.13 0.13
Operatives 0.02 0.01 0.01
Laborers, except farm 0.18 0.18 0.18
Farmers and farm managers 0.09 0.07 0.11
Farm laborers and foremen 0.01 0.01 0.01
Service workers 0.01 0.01 0.01
Private household workers 0.07 0.05 0.07
Mother's occupation
Missing/not employed 0.41 0.44 0.43
Professional, technical 0.14 0.14 0.10
Managers 0.01 0.01 0.02
Sales workers 0.00 0.01 0.01
Clerical workers 0.09 0.09 0.10
Craftsmen and foremen 0.02 0.01 0.02
Operatives 0.00 0.00 0.00
Laborers, except farm 0.14 0.11 0.10
Farmers and farm managers 0.00 0.00 0.00
Farm laborers and foremen 0.00 0.00 0.00
Service workers 0.00 0.02 0.01
Private household workers 0.18 0.17 0.22
Attitude (a) 6.91 6.88 7.17
Self-esteem measures
Summary measure from 1980 22.94 21.70 21.96
Summary measure from 1987 23.77 22.93 22.73
Sample size 1,682 2,338 622
SMSA, standard metropolitan statistical area.
(a) Attitude is calculated off the 1979 responses to 3 questions
when available, else the 1982 responses, else the 1987 responses.
REFERENCES
Bardasi, E., and M. Taylor. "Investigating the Marriage Wage
Premium for Men in Britain." Paper presented at ESPE meetings,
Bergen, Norway, 2004.
Becker, G. S. A Treatise on the Family. Cambridge, MA: Harvard
University Press, 1991.
Blackburn, M., and S. Korenman. "The Declining Marital-Status
Earnings Differential." Journal of Population Economics, 7, 1994,
247-70.
Bowles, S., H. Gintis, and M. Osborne. "The Determinants of
Earnings: A Behavioral Approach." Journal of Economic Literature,
39, 2001, 1137-76.
Chun, H., and I. Lee. "Why Do Married Men Earn More:
Productivity or Marriage Selection?" Economic Inquiry, 39, 2001,
307-19.
Cunningham, M. "Parental Influences on the Gendered Division
of Labor." American Sociological Review, 66, 2001, 184-203.
Daniel, K. "Does Marriage Make Men More Productive?"
Unpublished manuscript, University of Chicago, 1991.
Datta Gupta, N., N. Smith, and L. S. Stratton. "Is Marriage
Poisonous? Are Relationships Taxing? An Analysis of the Male Marital
Wage Differential in Denmark." Southern Economic Journal, 74, 2007,
412-33.
Department of Health and Human Resources. "Cohabitation,
Marriage, Divorce, and Remarriage in the United States." Vital and
Health Statistics, Series 23, No. 22, 2002.
Ferguson, R. F. "Shifting Challenges: Fifty Years of Economic
Change Toward Black-White Earnings Equality." Daedalus, 124(1),
1995, 37-76.
Gray, J. S. "The Fall in Men's Return to Marriage:
Declining Productivity Effects or Changing Selection?" Journal of
Human Resources, 32, 1997, 481-504.
Gray, J. S., and M. J. Vanderhart. "On the Determination of
Wages: Does Marriage Matter?" in The Ties That Bind. Perspectives
on Marriage and Cohabitation, edited by L. J. Waite. New York: Aldine de
Gruyter, 2000, 356-67.
Gupta, S., "The Effects of Transitions in Marital Status on
Men's Performance of Housework." Journal of Marriage and the
Family, 61, 1999, 700-11.
Hansen, K., J. J. Heckman, and K. J. Mullen. "The Effect of
Schooling and Ability on Achievement Test Scores." Journal of
Econometrics, 121, 2004, 39-98.
Hersch, J., and L. S. Stratton. "Household Specialization and
the Male Marriage Wage Premium." Industrial and Labor Relations
Review, 54, 2000, 78-94.
Hill, M. S. "The Wage Effects of Marital Status and
Children." Journal of Human Resources, 14, 1979, 579-94.
Isacsson, G. "Twin Data vs. Longitudinal Data to Control for
Unobserved Variables in Earnings Functions Which Are the
Differences?" Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 69,
2007, 339-62.
Jacobsen, J. P., and W. L. Rayack. "Do Men Whose Wives Work
Really Earn Less?" American Economic Review, 86, 1996, 268-73.
Kamo, Y., and E. L. Cohen. "Division of Household Work between
Partners: A Comparison of Black and White Couples." Journal of
Comparative Family Studies, 29(1), 1998, 131-5-45.
Korenman, S., and D. Neumark. "Does Marriage Really Make Men
More Productive?" Journal of Human Resources, 26, 1991, 282-307.
Krashinsky, H. A. "Do Marital Status and Computer Usage Really
Change the Wage Structure?" Journal of Human Resources, 39, 2004,
774-91.
Loh, E. S. "Productivity Differences and the Marriage Wage
Premium for White Males." Journal of Human Resources, 31, 1996,
566-89.
Mamun, A. "Is There a Cohabitation Premium in Men's
Earnings?" Working Paper No. 2004-02, Center for Research on
Families, University of Washington, 2004.
Meuller, G., and E. Plug. "Estimating the Effect of
Personality on Male and Female Earnings." Industrial and Labor
Relations Review, 60, 2006, 3-22.
Neal, D. A., and W. R. Johnson. "The Role of Pre-Market
Factors in Black-White Wage Differences." Journal of Political
Economy, 104, 1996, 869-95.
Reed, R. W., and K. Harford. "The Marriage Premium and
Compensating Wage Differentials." Journal of Population Economies,
2, 1989, 237-65.
Ribar, D. "What Do Social Scientists Know About the Benefits
of Marriage? A Review of Quantitative Methodologies." IZA Discussion Paper No. 998, 2004.
Richardson, K. "The Evolution of the Marriage Premium in the
Swedish Labor Market 1968-1991." Unpublished manuscript, Swedish
Institute for Social Research, Stockholm University, 2003.
Rodgers, W. M. Ill, and W. E. Spriggs. "What Does the AFQT
Really Measure: Race, Wages, Schooling and the AFQT Score." Review
of Black Political Economy, 24(4), 1996, 13-46.
--. "Accounting for the Racial Gap in AFQT Scores: Comment on
Nan L. Maxwell, 'The Effect on Black-White Wage Differences of
Differences in the Quality and Quantity of Education'."
Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 55, 2002, 533-41.
Schoeni, R. F. "Marital Status and Earnings in Developed
Countries." Journal of Population Economics, 8, 1995, 351-59.
Shaw, K. L. "The Quit Propensity of Married Men." Journal
of Labor Economics, 5, Part 1, 1987, 533-60.
Shelton, B. A., and D. John. "The Division of Household
Labor." Annual Review of Sociology, 22, 1996, 299-322.
South, S. J., and G. Spitze. "Housework in Marital and
Nonmarital Households." American Sociological Review, 59, 1994,
327-47.
Stratton, L. S. "Examining the Wage Differential for Married
and Cohabiting Men." Economic Inquiry, 40, 2002, 199-212.
Waddell, G. R. "Labor-market Consequences of Poor Attitude and
Low Self-esteem in Youth." Economic Inquiry, 44, 2006, 69-97.
Wilson, C. M., and A. J. Oswald. "How Does Marriage Affect
Physical and Psychological Health? A Survey of the Longitudinal
Evidence." IZA Discussion Paper No. 1619, 2005.
WILLIAM M. RODGERS III and LESLIE S. STRATFON *
* We are grateful to seminar participants at the Danish National
Institute of Social Research, Arhus University, Uppsala University,
Amsterdam's Institute for Labor Studies, IZA, and the workshop on
Family Decisions and Family Policy held in Arhus, Denmark, as well as to
Jacobsen and referees for valuable comments. Responsibility for the
contents rests solely with the authors.
Rodgers III: Professor and Chief Economist, John J. Heldrich Center
for Workforce Development, Edward J. Bloustein School of Planning and
Public Policy, Rutgers, The State University of New Jersey, 33
Livingston Avenue 5th Floor, New Brunswick, NJ 08901. Phone
1-732-932-4100, ext 783, Fax 1-732-932-3454, E-mail
[email protected]
Stratton: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Virginia
Commonwealth University, 301 West Main Street, PO Box 844000, Richmond,
VA 23284-4000. Phone 1-804-828-7141, Fax 1-804-828-9103, E-mail
[email protected]; IZA, Bonn, Germany; and CIM, Aarhus, Denmark
(1.) Wilson and Oswald (2005) report that the same is true for the
literature relating marital status to health.
(2.) There are a number of other explanations for a male marital
wage differential. For example, married men may choose different types
of jobs, jobs that offer a compensating wage differential, as compared
with unmarried men (Reed and Harford 1989), the wife may positively
affect the husband's productivity by serving as a sounding board or
other job aid (Loh 1996), or employers may simply discriminate in favor
of married men (Hill 1979).
(3.) The test is conducted in Stata using a binomial method for
calculating confidence intervals that imposes no distributional
assumptions upon the underlying variable.
(4.) Similar differences are evident for blacks and Hispanics,
though only the difference between married and never married men is
statistically significant for nonwhites.
(5.) The relation may be considerably more complicated. Married men
may quit less because of the higher wage they receive being married.
This lower expected quit rate can make them more suitable candidates for
training and so further increase their wages. Our regression analysis
will allow us to differentiate between such training-and marriage-driven
effects.
(6.) We exclude the NLSY's original military sample as there
is an explicit marriage premium in the military. Doing this reduces the
sample by 1,280. Along with a stratified random sample, the NLSY
over-samples low-income whites, blacks, and Hispanics. In 1990, the
low-income whites were dropped from the sample. Respondents used in this
study are from the stratified random sample or the low-income black
sample.
(7.) A small number of men who were widowed are also excluded from
the sample on the grounds that such a change in marital status is, at
this age, typically unforeseen. Also excluded are a small number of men
whose marital history is incomplete or inconsistent.
(8.) We focus only on marriage, not on cohabitation in this
analysis. The evidence regarding wage differentials for cohabiting men
in the United States is mixed at best (Stratton 2002, e.g., finds a
cross-sectional but not a panel effect) and cohabitation itself is
difficult to identify.
(9.) The interval in the 1988 interview covers 1986-1988. The
intervals for the 1989-1994 interviews cover the preceding year.
(10.) See, for example, Rodgers and Spriggs (1996, 2002), Neal and
Johnson (1996), and Ferguson (1995).
(11.) Full results are available from the authors upon request. All
standard errors are robust and corrected for clustering at the
individual level.
(12.) All returns are calculated using the conversion
exp([beta])--1, where [beta] is the coefficient estimate.
(13.) In other specifications not reported here, we included a
quadratic in years married, but this variable was not statistically
significant at even the 10% level.
(14.) Following Krashinsky (2004), we compared the wages of men who
married in a given year with the wages of men who were not married in
that year. The wages of the men who married were higher than the wages
of the men who did not marry even several years before the marriage
date, confirming that these results are indeed likely attributable to
selection.
(15.) This racial difference is all the more striking as it does
not appear to be driven by the higher standard errors inherent in
fixed-effects models that have so many fewer degrees of freedom. The
effect remains significant for the smaller, not the larger, sample and
is driven at least as much by changes in the point estimate as by
changes in the standard errors. Further, while fixed-effects estimates
are more sensitive to measurement errors, there is no reason to suppose
that these are larger for the white sample than for the African American
sample.
(16.) Those for whom always divorced equals one also have a value
of one for separated/divorced. In general, the stayer variables identify
marginal effects above and beyond the marital status effects.
(17.) Mamun (2004) controls for age rather than job experience or
tenure and continues to find a faster rate of wage growth following
marriage for African American men. It is well known that age is a poor
proxy for experience. As shown here, unmarried men have less experience
and tenure than married men of the same age. In addition, Mamun does not
include the rich set of individual-specific controls included here. When
we mimic Mamun's specification, we also find a faster rate of wage
growth for married African American men.
TABLE 1
Data on Tenure, Turnover Rates, and Quit-to-Fire Ratios by
Marital Status
Marital Status
Separated,
White, Non-Hispanic Men Married Never Married Divorced
Mean tenure (b) 6.37 5.03 5.44
Median tenure 5.0 4.0 4.0
Turnover rate (c) 2.98% 6.07% 6.89%
Quit-to-fire ratio (c) 15.3 23.6 14.3
Marital Status
Statistical
White, Non-Hispanic Men Significance (a)
Mean tenure (b) a, b
Median tenure a, b
Turnover rate (c) a, b, c
Quit-to-fire ratio (c) a, c
(a) The lowercase online letters "a," "b," and "c" indicate that
married and never married means are significantly dif ferent at
the 5% level, married and separated/divorced means are
significantly different at the 5% level, and never married and
separated/divorced means are significantly different at the 5'1,,
level, respectively.
(b) Calculated using CPS 2000 Tenure Supplement for white,
non-Hispanic men aged 30-39 yr. Measured in years.
(c) Calculated using the data from the January, May, and
September 1989, 1991, and 1993 CPSs for white, non-Hispanic men
aged 23-37 yr who were not enrolled in school; married, spouse
absent; widowed; or in the military. Sample consists only of
employed and unemployed persons, excluding those between
temporary jobs. Turnover rate is calculated as percent who lost,
quit, or were laid off from theirjob. Quit-to-fire ratio is
calculated as 100 x number of quit job/(number of lost + number
of laid off).
TABLE 2
Sample Means by Race and Marital Status
White Men
Never Separated
Variable Married Married Divorced
Log hourly wage 2.11 1.92 1.90
Wage (1982-1984$) 9.34 7.95 7.58
Education 12.82 12.95 11.87
Age 30.03 28.53 29.94
Experience (in wk) 521.53 422.54 490.97
Tenure (in wk) 241.81 156.87 170.96
Years married 6.70 0.00 4.10
Log of training time (in h) 1.36 1.05 1.14
Residual composite
AFQT score 7.61 6.27 4.26
Father's education (a) 11.23 11.70 10.92
Mother's education (a) 11.07 11.14 10.86
Mother's occupation missing 0.43 0.46 0.43
Self-esteem (b) 22.63 21.90 22.01
Number of observations 6,959 3,209 1,413
African American Men
Never Separated
Variable Married Married Divorced
Log hourly wage 1.92 1.69 1.73
Wage (1982-1984$) 7.52 6.15 6.35
Education 12.70 12.21 12.02
Age 29.97 28.84 30.23
Experience (in wk) 480.90 371.20 461.00
Tenure (in wk) 209.03 129.71 126.90
Years married 5.62 0.00 3.32
Log of training time (in h) 1.41 0.95 1.36
Residual composite
AFQT score -16.88 -17.29 -20.73
Father's education (a) 9.98 10.09 9.64
Mother's education (a) 10.80 10.84 10.45
Mother's occupation missing 0.41 0.44 0.43
Self-esteem (b) 22.94 21.70 21.96
Number of observations 1,682 2,338 622
Note: Sample source--1988-1994 pooled cross sections of employed
men from the NLSY, who have completed school and are not in the
military or self-employed.
(a) Sample restricted to those with nonmissing values. Less than
10% of any white sample reported missing parental education but
almost 30% of separated/divorced African American men fail to
report their father's education level. Missing values are
identified with a dummy variable.
(b) The sum of ten categorical variables, each with values
running from 1 to 4, designed to measure self-esteem in 1980.
Variables are redefined to ensure that values indicate less
self-esteem.
TABLE 3
Estimate of the Marital Log Wage Differential Racial Differences
and Training Effects
White Men
Basic (a)
Variable Gross Specification Specification
Married 0.1273 *** (0.0254) 0.0540 *** (0.0188)
Separated/divorced -0.0579 ** (0.0291) 0.0188 (0.0203)
Years married 0.0097 *** (0.0028) 0.0052 ** (0.0026)
Log of training time
F test on marital status 46.92 *** 7.96 ***
Number of observations 11,581 11,581
[R.sup.2] 0.0396 0.4350
White Men African American Men
Training (b)
Variable Specification Gross Specification
Married 0.0503 *** (0.0187) 0.1781 *** (0.0363)
Separated/divorced 0.0170 (0.0202) 0.0107 (0.0399)
Years married 0.0051 ** (0.0026) 0.0095 * (0.0051)
Log of training time 0.0128 *** (0.0033)
F test on marital status 7.49 *** 27.81 ***
Number of observations 11,581 4,642
[R.sup.2] 0.4401 0.0550
African American Men
Basic (a) Training (b)
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0790 *** (0.0249) 0.0782 *** (0.0247)
Separated/divorced 0.0076 (0.0280) 0.0048 (0.0276)
Years married 0.0035 (0.0041) 0.0025 (0.0040)
Log of training time 0.0119 ***
F test on marital status 7.95 *** 7.41 ***
Number of observations 4,642 4,642
[R.sup.2] 0.4456 0.4520
Note: Robust standard errors corrected also of clustering by
individual are reported in parentheses below coefficient
estimates.
(a) This specification includes controls for years of education;
quadratics in experience and tenure; dummy variables to identify
11 industries, 10 occupations, 3 regions, 3 city sizes, and 5
interview years; a measure of the number of children, firm size,
and the local unemployment rate; and dummy variables to identify
union members and government employees.
(b) This specification includes all the controls listed in the
footnote "a" as well as dummy variables to indicate receipt of
training in the particular interview year.
*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level,
two-sided test; ** indicates statistical significance at the 5%
level, two-sided test; and * indicates statistical significance at
the 10% level, two-sided test.
TABLE 4
Estimates of the Marital Log Wage Differential
Individual-Specific Factors
White Men
Training Individual-Specific
Variable Specifications Specification
Married 0.0503 *** (0.0187) 0.0472 *** (0.0182)
Separated/divorced 0.0170 (0.0202) 0.0130 (0.0198)
Years married 0.0051 *** (0.0026) 0.0043 * (0.0025)
Log of training time 0.0128 *** (0.0033) 0.0108 *** (0.0033)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores Yes ***
Parents' education Yes
Parents' occupation Yes *
Self-esteem Yes ***
F test on marital status 7.49 *** 6.3 ***
Number of observations 11,581 11,581
Number of individuals 2,333 2,333
[R.sup.2] 0.4401 0.4588
White Men African American Men
Fixed-Effects Training
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0046 (0.0155) 0.0782 *** (0.0247)
Separated/divorced -0.0186 (0.0220) 0.0048 (0.0276)
Years married -0.0056 (0.0041) 0.0025 (0.0040)
Log of training time 0.0137 *** (0.0038) 0.0119 *** (0.0042)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores
Parents' education
Parents' occupation
Self-esteem
F test on marital status 1.18 7.41 ***
Number of observations 11,581 4,642
Number of individuals 2,333 911
[R.sup.2] 0.8100 0.4520
African American Men
Individual-Specific Fixed-Effects
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0649 *** (0.0248) 0.0573 ** (0.0285)
Separated/divorced -0.0016 (0.0276) 0.0484 (0.0358)
Years married 0.0034 (0.0039) -0.0090 (0.0061)
Log of training time 0.0110 *** (0.0040) 0.0028 (0.0062)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores Yes ***
Parents' education Yes
Parents' occupation Yes ***
Self-esteem Yes
F test on marital status 6.19 *** 1.89 *
Number of observations 4,642 4,642
Number of individuals 911 911
[R.sup.2] 0.4727 0.7295
Notes: Robust standard errors corrected also for clustering by
individual are reported in parentheses below coefficient
estimates. All specifications include control for years of
education; quadratics in experience and tenure; dummy variable to
identify 11 industries, 10 occupations, 3 regions, 3 city sizes,
and 5 interview years; a measure of the number of children, firm
size, and the local unemployment rate; dummy variables to
identify union members and government employees; and dummy
variables to indicate receipt of training in the particular
interview year.
*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level, two-sided
test; ** indicates statistical significance at the 5% level,
two-sided test; and * indicates statistical significance at the
10% level, two-sided test.
TABLE 5
Estimates of the Log Wage Differential Controlling for Stayers
White Men
Fixed-Effects Gross+
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0046 (0.0155) 0 0258 (0.0308)
Separated/divorced -0.0186 (0.0220) -0.0653 (0.0405)
Years married -0.0056 (0.0041) 0.0067 ** (0.0030)
Never married -0.1025 *** (0.0387)
Always married 0.0562 ** (0.0270)
Always divorced -0.1428 *** (0.0428)
Log of training time 0.0137 *** (0.0038)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores
Parents' education
Parents' occupation
Self-esteem
F test on marital status 1.18 6.33 ***
F test on stayer status 9.61 ***
Number of observations 11,581 11,581
Number of individuals 2,333 2,333
[R.sup.2] 0.8100 0.0450
White Men
Training+ Individual-Specific+
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0105 (0.0215) 0.0116 (0.0209)
Separated/divorced -0.0088 (0.0284) -0.0092 (0.0279)
Years married 0.0031 (0.0028) 0.0023 (0.0028)
Never married -0.0327 (0.0270) -0.0283 (0.0260)
Always married 0.0373 * (0.0201) 0.0367 * (0.0200)
Always divorced -0.0258 (0.0296) -0.0278 (0.0294)
Log of training time 0.0129 *** (0.0033) 0.0108 *** (0.0033)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores Yes ***
Parents' education Yes
Parents' occupation Yes *
Self-esteem Yes ***
F test on marital status 0.53 0.36
F test on stayer status 2.31 * 2.21 *
Number of observations 11,581 11,581
Number of individuals 2,333 2,333
[R.sup.2] 0.4409 0.4595
African American Men
Fixed-Effects Gross+
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0573 ** (0.0285) 0.0108 (0.0521)
Separated/divorced -0.0484 (0.0358) -0.1514 ** (0.0660)
Years married -0.0090 (0.0061) 0.0078 (0.0056)
Never married -0.1750 *** (0.0554)
Always married 0.0397 (0.0448)
Always divorced 0.0298 (0.0632)
Log of training time 0.0028 (0.0062)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores
Parents' education
Parents' occupation
Self-esteem
F test on marital status 1.89 6.53 ***
F test on stayer status 4.05 ***
Number of observations 4,642 4,642
Number of individuals 911 911
[R.sup.2] 0.7295 0.0633
African American Men
Training+ Individual-Specific+
Variable Specification Specification
Married 0.0312 (0.0360) 0.0185 (0.0338)
Separated/divorced -0625 (0.0453) -0.0733 * (0.0429)
Years married 0.0013 (0.0045) 0.0028 (0.0044)
Never married -0.0395 (0.0365) -0.0424 (0.0332)
Always married 0.0379 (0.0291) 0.0264 (0.0293)
Always divorced 0.0749 * (0.0434) 0.0753 * (0.0440)
Log of training time 0.0122 *** (0.0042) 0.0113 *** (0.0040)
Including
3 AFQT residual scores Yes ***
Parents' education Yes
Parents' occupation Yes ***
Self-esteem Yes
F test on marital status 3.39 ** 3.15 **
F test on stayer status 2.02 1.88
Number of observations 4,642 4,642
Number of individuals 911 911
[R.sup.2] 0.4537 0.4741
Notes: Robust standard errors corrected also for clustering by
individual are reported in parentheses below coefficient
estimates. Each specification includes control for years of
education; a quadratics in experience and tenure; dummy variable
to identify 11 industries, 10 occupations, 3 regions, 3 city
sizes, and 5 interview years; a measure of the number of
children, firm size, and the local unemployment rate; dummy
variables to identify union members and government employees; and
dummy variables to indicate receipt of training in the particular
interview year.
*** indicates statistical significance at the 1% level, two-sided
test; **indicates statistical significance at the 5% level,
two-sided test; *indicates statistical significance at the 10%
level, two-sided test.