The effect of direct to consumer television advertising on the timing of treatment.
Bradford, W. David ; Kleit, Andrew N. ; Nietert, Paul J. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
In August 1997, the Food and Drug Administration (FDA) relaxed the
rules governing television advertising of prescription pharmaceutical
products. Before that time, broadcast ads were permitted only to mention
either the name of a drug or a disease against which a drug was
effective but not both. After August 1997, pharmaceuticals were allowed
to mention both the disease and the drug brand name (as long a a brief
list of side effects was mentioned and 1-800 number or World Wide Web
site was provided with more detailed information). Spending for direct
to consumer advertising (DTCA for prescription drugs went from $985
million in 1996 to approximately $4.2 billion for 2005 (Donohue,
Cevasco, and Rosenthal 2007). This has led to a great deal of debate in
the medical profession and among health care insurer and managed care
organizations and an ongoing review of advertising rules by the FDA
However, very little is actually known about the effects of DTCA for the
efficient allocation o prescription drugs.
We will examine how DTCA affects physician prescribing patterns and
courses of care for patients suffering from a representative chronic
condition, osteoarthritis (OA). This condition is of special
significance, as one of the major products in this area, Merck's
"Vioxx" cyclooxygenase-2 (COX-2) inhibitor was forced to
withdraw from the market in October 2004 due to side effects on patients
with heart conditions. The side effects of Vioxx have caused
considerable criticism of Merck's advertising strategy for Vioxx
(see, e.g., editorials from the New England Journal of Medicine;
Mukherjee, Nissen, and Topol 2001; Topol 2004).
The primary goal of this paper was to determine what effect local
and national television advertising on behalf of the two main COX-2
inhibitors had on the treatment decisions that patients made in
collaboration with their physicians. In particular, we will examine the
impact of DTCA on the time patients wait after diagnosis with OA and
before initiating treatment with a COX-2 inhibitor. The paper will
proceed by first reviewing the literature on DTCA in Section II. Section
III will present a theoretical model of optimal delay to treatment.
Section IV will present details of the data and empirical model we
implement. Empirical results are presented in Section V, and Section VI
concludes with a discussion about future research.
II. BACKGROUND AND LITERATURE
A. Advertising for COX-2 Inhibitors
Historically, pharmaceutical advertising was done largely through
"detailing"--promotion directly from the manufacturer to the
physician, either through visits by representatives or contacts by
pharmacists or through advertisements in professional journals. Since
the mid-1980s, however, drug companies in the United States have
increasingly turned their marketing strategies directly toward the
consumer. This advertising largely takes place through television media
and in newspapers. This change in advertising approach has its share of
both critics and advocates.
The pharmaceutical industry in the United States is
large--accounting for more than $132 billion in retail sales in 2000
alone (NIHCM 2001). In 2000, Celebrex (celecoxib), the leading COX-2
inhibitor, had sales of approximately $2.6 billion ("Pharmacia has
setback for parecoxib" 2001)--while Vioxx (rofecoxib) sold more
than $1.2 billion in the first half of 2000 (Knight Ridder News 2001).
In support of Vioxx, Merck spent almost $161 million in DTCA in 2000
(Schumann 2001)--which was the most spent on DTCA for any prescription
pharmaceutical, making it the 39th most advertised brand of any kind in
2000 ("Top brands in network primetime-2000" 2001). Over the
same time periods, Pharmacia and Pfizer jointly spent $78 million in
DTCA supporting Celebrex.
We have chosen to examine the role of DTCA in the context of the
market for COX-2 inhibitors. During the period spanned by our data
(1999-2002), the two available COX-2 inhibitors were Vioxx and Celebrex.
These drugs are appropriate subjects of study for a number of reasons.
First, they have been heavily advertised. Second, they are significantly
more expensive than alternative pharmacologic treatments for chronic
pain. Third, data published approximately halfway through our sample
period indicated that these products may carry a significant risk of
adverse cardiac side effects. Consequently, from mid-2001, many
physicians began to question the wisdom in their use (Topol 2004).
Additionally, given the widespread suspicion of advertising for
prescription drugs, clinicians and policy makers have questioned whether
DTCA for COX-2's might be causing fatalities. Our results will
speak directly to this issue in that if DTCA had a deleterious effect
(in terms of matching high-risk patients to COX-2 use) then we will get
one sign pattern on interaction terms between advertising and patient
comorbidities. If, however, DTCA is having a positive effect (by
matching patients most suited for COX-2 inhibitors with that therapy)
then we will get the opposite sign pattern on the
advertising-comorbidity interaction terms.
For this study, we have acquired data on television advertising for
both Celebrex and Vioxx at the national (network) level and for the top
75 local media markets in the United States. These data are aggregated
to the monthly level. Celebrex was approved by the FDA in December 1998
and Vioxx was approved in May 1999. Thus, at least one of the products
was available for use over the entire 1999-2002 time period of our
analysis. Figure 1 presents the 2000-2002 trend for the spending on
national television advertising for Vioxx and Celebrex taken from our
advertising database (described below in Section III).
B. Literature on the Impact of DTCA
In economic terms, we would expect advertising for prescription
drugs to have three possible effects. First, advertisement for a
particular prescription product will provide information regarding the
symptoms and regarding the fact that effective treatments are available
about the medical condition that the drug treats. This may be labeled a
"public good" effect, as the information conveyed by
advertisements for one brand may aid sales of all brands selling
competing products. Second, advertisements may provide important
information regarding side effects, contraindications, and the like that
may prompt patients to consult with their physician regarding a
treatment modality. This component of the advertising may be labeled as
a "matching" effect since it would assist patients and
physicians in matching treatment regimes. Third, advertising may simply
lead patients to demand a product because of the aesthetic or persuasive
characteristics of the ad, or the reputational impact of the ad, rather
than the efficacy of the drug. This effect may be labeled as a
"brand" effect. Since health care markets, including
pharmaceuticals, are often characterized by moral hazard (as patients do
not generally pay the full cost of the medications they consume), the
welfare implications of this third effect are uncertain.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The studies on the impact of advertising in the prescription
pharmaceutical market that have been published to date have yielded
conflicting results. There is an arm of this literature that is
generally supportive of advertising in this market, such as work by
Telser (1975) and Leffler (1981). Keith (1995) finds that patient
suggestions regarding pharmaceuticals (aspirin for cardiovascular
disease) are important determinants in prescription decisions and that
advertising tends to lead to more appropriate care as a consequence. In
this, Keith is advancing an argument made earlier by Masson and Rubin
that posits several mechanisms that could lead to positive impacts from
advertising on the efficiency of the pharmaceutical market (including
that it might encourage people to associate symptoms with a disease and
seek care or that it might alert people to treatments they were
previously unaware of, which would encourage them to seek care) (Masson
and Rubin 1985). For a survey of the more optimistic literature in this
area, see Rubin (1991) and Kleit (1998).
Not all economists, however, are so sanguine about the prospects of
positive welfare effects from prescription pharmaceutical advertising.
Hurwitz and Caves (1988) find that--on net--promotional activities by
pharmaceutical firms tend to have the effect of preserving market share
for existing products and slowing the penetration of new compounds in
the market. King (1996) uses monthly sales data in the ulcer drug market
to test the effect that marketing efforts have on the industry. He finds
that marketing by a firm causes the demand for the firm's own
products to become more inelastic. Similarly, Rizzo (1999) finds that
DTCA significantly reduces price elasticity in the market. A reduction
in price elasticity would increase opportunities for supracompetitive
pricing.
The post-1997 era has presented an opportunity for examination of
the new policy regime for DTCA, and much of the literature has been
focused on the FDA policy shift. As Zachry and Ginsburg point out,
however, there is a paucity of studies that examine the actual impacts
of DTCA (Ginsburg 2001).
In one of the few such studies, Dubois (2003) examines the impact
of DTCA through the lens of variation in procedure and drug use. He
notes previous evidence that there is a wide geographic variety in the
use of various medications and suggests that such variations imply
underserved populations. Dubois cites several sources that indicate that
geographic variations in prescriptions have declined since the
relaxation of DTCA regulations, perhaps implying that DTCA is conveying
important medication information to previously underserved populations.
Calfee, Winston, and Stempski (2002) study whether the August 1997
policy changes at FDA increased the demand for the statin class of drugs
using monthly data from IMSHealth and Scott-Levin for a 58-mo period.
The authors, however, found that advertising did not have a
statistically significant impact on aggregate prescriptions filled.
According to the authors, "it may only be possible to detect the
effect of DTCA advertising on consumer demand with disaggregated data
that link a patient's cholesterol treatment history with the timing
of DTCA expenditures."
III. THEORETICAL MODEL
Consider a patient who has been diagnosed with some chronic
disease. On diagnosis, the patient faces a choice--either initiate or
delay treatment. The benefits of treatment are potential improvements in
symptoms of the underlying disease. The costs are monetary (the
treatment generally must be purchased at some positive market price) and
potentially psychic (people often resist taking medication) as well as
the cost of any potential side effects. To decide whether to initiate
treatment, the patient will evaluate her utility with treatment and her
utility without treatment and pick whichever path yields the highest
expected value. If the instantaneous utility associated with therapy is
not higher than the utility associated with no therapy then the patient
will choose to delay. Each period thereafter, the patient will undertake
the same utility calculus, to determine whether to begin therapy or
continue to wait.
This model is similar in form to real option theories that have
been applied to financial instruments (see, e.g., McDonald and Siegel
1986; Merton 1973), to the timing of land development (see, e.g., Arnott
and Lewis 1979; Capozza and Li 1994, 2002; Titman 1985), and even to the
timing of initial public offerings (see, e.g., Benninga, Helmantel, and
Sarig 2005). An interior optimum for the delay to an action can exist
when there is a cost to undertaking some action and when the benefits
from the action increase over time.
We will motivate our empirical research by exploring a simple model
of the timing of treatment for a stylized chronic disease. Consider a
patient who has been diagnosed with a condition, which reduces her
health. Furthermore, assume that the impact on health is
cumulative--delaying treatment implies that the health state continues
to decay. The progression of the disease can be countered by
pharmacological therapy. (Assume for the sake of simplicity that there
is only one viable therapeutic option.) The value of that therapy is
unknown, but the patient has expectations about the treatment
effect--expectations that can be affected by information, such as
physician advice, testimonials from friends, or DTCA. Thus, the
patient's instantaneous health is:
[h.sub.t] = H - [delta]t, if no treatment/H - [delta]t +
[theta](a), with treatment,
where H is the base level of health at disease onset, [delta] is
the impact of the disease on health during each time period, t
represents time, and [theta](*) is the expectations around the
pharmacologic treatment effect, which can be affected by advertising, a.
Furthermore, [[theta].sub.a] > 0 and [[theta].sub.aa] < 0.
Utility is defined across consumption of some numeraire good,
[x.sub.t], and health, [h.sub.t]. Consumers may consume 1 unit of
pharmaceutical treatment per period, at price P, or may continue to
delay therapy. Once a person chooses to initiate therapy, she will
continue to receive treatment until her death at time T. (Given the
degenerative nature of the disease assumed in this model, once it
becomes optimal to purchase treatment, it will necessarily be optimal in
every time period after that.)
Consequently, each patient will maximize the present value of
lifetime utility by selecting the optimal delay for treatment onset
according to:
(1) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where U(.) is patient utility defined across income (I) and health.
The optimal delay to onset, [d.sup.*], is defined by taking the first
partial of Equation (1) with respect to d and setting it equal to 0:
(2) [partial derivative]V/[partial derivative]d = [V.sub.d] = U(I,
H - [delta]d) -U(I - P, H - [delta]d + [theta](a)) = 0.
The usual convexity assumptions require that the second partial of
Equation (1) with respect to d be negative or:
(3) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Given these assumptions, the optimal time to treatment exists,
[d.sup.*] = [d.sup.*](I, H, [delta], r, a). Note, of course, that one
condition for an interior solution is that at time = 0, the value of
utility without therapy must be greater than the value of utility with
therapy. That is, if U(I - P, H - [delta]t + [theta](a)) > U(I, H -
[delta]t)[for all]t then the patient will choose to initiate therapy
immediately and [d.sup.*] = 0. Similarly, if U(I - P, H - [delta]t +
[theta](a)) < U(I, H - [delta]t)[for all]t then the patient will
never initiate therapy.
To illustrate the solution, note that:
(4) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
Since diminishing returns in health imply that the higher levels of
health resulting from treatment reduce the marginal utility of health,
and the complementarity between income and health will imply further
reductions in [U.sub.h] with the lower net income resulting from the
requirement that some portion of any consumed therapy is paid out of
pocket.
Comparative static analysis of the impact of advertising on the
optimally selected delay of treatment is straightforward. Inserting the
optimal delay time functional, [d.sup.*](.) into Equation (2) and
differentiating with respect to the advertising parameter, a, and
rearranging yields
(5) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII].
The sign of this effect depends on the sign of [[theta].sub.a]. If
a patient believes himself to be a good candidate for the treatment then
greater exposure to advertising, or other positive information about the
efficacy of the treatment, will reduce the optimally chosen delay to
therapy initiation. However, if the advertising conveys information that
leads the patient to believe that he is a poor candidate for the
treatment--by emphasizing adverse events or highlighting a
contraindication from which the patient suffers--then the expected
treatment effect will be reduced, which will lengthen the optimal delay.
Thus, whether the information contained in the ad is
"positive" or "negative" will depend on patient
expectations, other diagnoses, and preferences across the
characteristics of the therapy.
There are several implications from the theoretical model for the
empirical estimation. First, patients select the optimal delay from
diagnosis to therapy. Thus, we will calculate below this delay for each
person in the data by estimating a parametric duration model. Second,
since pharmacological treatments are better suited to some patients than
others, the optimal delay will be a function of the patient's other
clinical diagnoses. Finally, the model implies that this optimal delay
will be a function of income, health state, opportunity cost of
treatment, and advertising exposure--measured at the point of therapy
initiation. We will employ either direct measures or proxy measures for
each of these factors.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
IV. EMPIRICAL MODEL
A. Empirical Specification
Before specifying an empirical implementation, we note that the
decision we will model is one that is joint between the patient and the
physician. Thus, our question will be "what impact does DTCA have
on the likelihood that the physician/patient interaction will result in
a prescription?" We will model the length of the spell between
diagnosis and initiation of COX-2 inhibitor therapy. There is a long
econometric literature on duration modeling, which presents us with
various modeling options. Options range from nonparametric methods that
impose few distributional restrictions to parametric methods where the
distribution of the "time to failure" (to use the language of
much of the literature) must be explicitly specified. All versions of
the model are based on estimating the hazard function or the likelihood
of a transition (in our case, between nonuse of COX-2 inhibitors and use
of COX-2 inhibitors) between states at time [DELTA]t, conditional on the
spell (of nonuse) having persisted to time t. One common specification
for this hazard rate is to assume it is the product of some baseline
population average hazard and an individual specific term (which may or
may not depend on covariates).
The problem with this proportional hazard model is that it requires
the population average effect to be constant over time. A more flexible
approach for duration models is presented in Kalbfleisch and Prentice
(1981) and in Ridder (1990) and known as accelerated failure time (AFT)
models. These models permit the baseline hazard to increase, decrease,
or remain constant over time. Figure 2 below presents the empirical
hazards for the delay to treatment data we explore. The instantaneous
failure rates are not constant for our data, as the proportional hazard
assumption is strongly rejected for nearly all covariates in our models.
Consequently, we will estimate an AFT version of a duration model. In
addition, the decreasing hazard we observe is consistent with a Weibull
distribution--which is the distribution we will assume.
In addition to nonconstancy in the baseline hazard, we have one
other characteristic of the data to accommodate in our model choice.
Patients may exit their delay spell in one of two ways: by choosing
Vioxx as the treatment to initiate or by choosing Celebrex. These exit
strategies are not likely to be random and may consequently affect the
length of time that the delay spell itself lasts. Thus, we are faced
with the possibility of underling heterogeneity in the duration data,
which arises due to unobservable characteristics of the patient.
Competing risk versions of the AFT model can account for this
data-generating process. For applications of the competing risk models
in health care, see Hamilton (1997), Cutler (1995), and Picone, Wilson,
and Chou (2003). These models are based on the generalized method of
Heckman and Singer (1984), which model heterogeneous transition frailty as a multiplicative term with a gamma distribution.
Thus, we will model the delay to COX-2 initiation as an AFT hazard
function with heterogeneous failures in a competing risk model where the
instantaneous hazard follows a Weibull distribution, and the
unobservable heterogeneity is modeled as a gamma distribution. The
hazard rate is then:
(6) [MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII],
where [x.sub.i] are individual patient and practice
characteristics, t is the duration of the individual delay spell, and
[[alpha].sub.j] capture the group-level heterogeneity in exit (to Vioxx
or Celebrex). For some patients, it will be optimal to delay longer than
we observe them, and for some, it will be optimal to delay indefinitely.
Given that we only have data spanning the 1999-2002 time period, these
two populations will be observationally equivalent--requiring that we
take right-hand censoring into account. The model is estimated by
maximum likelihood.
Finally, one remaining issue to be addressed is whether any
selection effects are at work in the models. It seems plausible that
advertising could bring more people to the physician office--which is
what we find in prior research (Bradford et al. 2006). While this may
lead to more diagnoses of OA, it is not immediately clear that this
would bias our estimates on how long individuals wait before adopting
therapy. (Even if the shift in patient population did lead to a change
in delay, our estimates are reduced form in nature and thus agnostic with regard to what the actual mechanism of a DTCA effect might be.)
However, to assess whether such selection issues are driving the
results, we reestimated, ex-post, both versions of the model presented
below and included proxy variables for the probability that the patient
seeks a visit and the probability that the patient receives a
prescription during the month when therapy is initiated. These proxy
variables are the percent of all the physician's monthly office
visits that are to OA patients and the percent of all the
physician's monthly visits to OA patients that are associated with
a COX-2 inhibitor prescription, respectively. These variables represent
naive estimates of the probability of a visit and prescription for each
patient during the month in which the patient actually began therapy.
Since these are practice average measures, they will be exogenous to the
individual patient's characteristics but capture general influences
at the practice level on the likelihood that the patient progresses to
treatment. The estimated DTCA parameters and the parameters on the DTCA
interaction effects were highly robust to inclusion or exclusion of
these variables--thus suggesting that selection effects are not playing
a large role in generating the results we present below. For the sake of
simplicity, therefore, we do not include these models in Table 3;
however, they are available on request from the authors.
B. Data
For this study, we have acquired data on television advertising for
both Celebrex and Vioxx at the national (network) level and for the top
75 local media markets in the United States. These data are aggregated
to the monthly level. Figure 1 presents the 2000-2002 trend for the
dollars spent on national television advertising for Vioxx and Celebrex
taken from our advertising database.
As Figure 1 indicates, at the national level, monthly advertising
exposure for the two brands is roughly comparable over the entire
2000-2002 time period. Interestingly, a very different picture emerges
at the local level, where television advertising spots for Celebrex are
always greater than that of Vioxx for the entire period. The value of
ads purchased at the local level is much lower in dollar terms than at
the national level. Since patients do not generally distinguish between
the payment source of a television ad (whether the local station or
national network receives the revenue), we will include measures of the
total spending on television advertising in our empirical models.
Consequently, we will have both cross-sectional and across time
variation in DTCA exposure.
C. Clinical Data
Practice Partner, Inc. (Seattle, Washington) has marketed a
commercial electronic medical record (i.e., Practice Partner) to
physician practices for more than a decade. This product is intended to
replace paper charts and has been widely adopted--largely by practices
that are community based--for clinical reasons and not for research
purposes (nor because the practice has any affiliation with a research
group or institution). The Medical University of South Carolina collaborates with the vendor to gain access to the record extracts of
practices that were willing to have their data used for research
purposes. This led to the development of a geographically diverse
national research network of ambulatory, mostly primary care practices
that use this single electronic medical record system (known as PPRNet).
We will examine data on practices from 1999 through 2002. As of 2002
(the end of the study period), 72 practices in 25 states, with 348
physicians, were network members.
Each quarter, participating practices run a computer program,
developed and maintained by the electronic medical record vendor, to
extract patient activity of the previous quarter from the electronic
medical record system. These data are taken from the patient's
medical record--similar to chart abstraction. The data capture all
diagnoses, medications, patient characteristics (weight, blood pressure,
etc.), lab tests ordered, and lab results. Currently, the entire
research network database has information on 604,111 patients, including
3.6 million patient contacts, 3.8 million prescription records, 10.1
million vital signs, 12 million laboratory records, and 1.3 million
preventive services records. We extract a subset of this data on 22,011
patients who had ever been diagnosed with OA and who had physician
visits in the years 1999-2002. (The time period of analysis is dictated
by the availability of advertising data and not the availability of
clinical data.)
A recent assessment of a subsample of about 500,000 patients from
PPRNet practices indicates that the patient population is approximately
57% female, with a mean age ([+ or -] SD) of 43.1 [+ or -] 21.1 yr and
has a racial breakdown of approximately 85% Caucasian, 8% African
American, and 4.3% Hispanic. PPR-Net practices are located in urban,
suburban, and rural areas. Based on a four-tiered classification scheme
for the Rural-Urban Commuting Area codes (Morrill, Cromartie, and Hart
1999), PPRNet practices are highly representative of the distribution of
the U.S. population. Among the 114 practices active as of December 2005,
there are 462 physicians, 51 physician assistants, and 63 nurse
practitioners. Eighty-nine (78%) are family medicine practices; four of
these are family medicine residency programs. Twenty (18%) are internal
medicine practices and five (4%) are combined practices of primary care
physicians. Thus, the PPRNet practices appear reasonably representative
of other primary care practices in the United States.
D. Variables
The dependent variable for the models is the length of time each
patient waits before initiating therapy with one of the two COX-2
inhibitors after being diagnosed with OA. This is calculated as the
difference (in days) between the diagnosis date for OA (recorded in the
clinical data) and the prescribing date for the first instance of a
Vioxx or Celebrex prescription. However, COX-2 inhibitors are used for
many complaints in addition to OA; additionally, patients may use a
COX-2 for occasional arthritis pain even before a formal diagnosis is
made. In these cases, the "delay" would be negative. For such
negative delays, the duration between the diagnosis and the prescription
is set to 1 d. In addition, most of the patients with a diagnosis of OA
do not receive a prescription for Vioxx or Celebrex as long as they are
observed in the data. Thus, the duration models we estimate will control
for this right censoring.
The independent variables fall into several categories, such as
advertising information, patient individual clinical information, and
market/practice characteristics.
We obtained national and local advertising information from
Competitive Media Reporting, Inc., which collects data on media
advertising for all products, including pharmaceuticals, at the market
(e.g., city) level. The data are specific to the brand name of the
product. Consequently, it is possible to determine which products were
advertised, which month they were advertised, how many times they were
advertised, and how many dollars were spent on the ads. Patients and
physician practices were assigned to the nearest media markets
separately by two of the authors. When a practice was close to multiple
media markets, they were assigned to the one that was nearest (by
driving miles). In addition, we excluded all practices that are
unusually far from the nearest media market (more than 100 straight-line
miles) to avoid any bias from mismatching of practice and local media
market data.
We measure advertising exposure as the total (national and local)
dollars spent on ads broadcast for each brand advertised. We add the
separate measures for national advertising and local advertising into a
single total monthly spending variable. While it is the case that local
ads tend to be shown during different times of the day and during
different programming, it is unclear that this difference matters
empirically. We have estimated versions of our models with the national
and local ad spending included separately, and the net results are not
meaningfully different. Additionally, the parameters on national
advertising are essentially unchanged in magnitude and significance if
we exclude local advertising; so, while there may some concern that
local advertising could be endogenous (a concern that is ameliorated by
the use of individual data, typically from only one practice in each
media market), the practical biases appear negligible.
Additionally, since the theoretical model suggests that patient
characteristics at the time of the switch are the important factors in
initiating therapy, and since we have not captured precisely when in the
month therapy begins, we will measure potential advertising exposure as
the dollars spent in the month preceding the initiation of therapy.
The patient data contain limited demographic and detailed clinical
information. For patient demographic information, we include patient age
and an indicator variable for whether the patient is female. We also
include variables that capture whether the patient has ever been
diagnosed with (or treated for) other relevant comorbidities. These
include indicator variables for if the patient has ever been diagnosed
with heart disease (coronary disease or hypertension), depression,
diabetes, hyperlipidemia, or ever treated for gastrointestinal
difficulties with proton-pump inhibitors, H2 blockers, or related
products.
Imputations of additional descriptive variables can be made
secondary sources. We imputed the price of an intermediate length of
physician's office visit with an established patient from the
American Chamber of Commerce Research Association's Quarterly Price
Reports (http://www.coli.org/). These quarterly reports contain average
prices for 50 commodities (including physician office visits) for around
300 metropolitan areas. The linking between average physician visit
price and the patient was accomplished by using the average price in the
metropolitan area nearest the primary care practice site. Average county
per capita income, the percent of the county population covered by
Medicare, the percent of the county employed in the labor force, the
percent of the county population that is Caucasian and African American,
the county population, and the number of physicians per 10,000
population were also merged onto the data from the Area Resource File.
Counties were identified as the county in which the practice is located.
This information is available on an annual basis.
In addition to the impact of advertising, another source of
information that may affect physician prescribing is medical journals.
The late 1990s and early 2000s was a period when a significant amount of
research was being conducted on the efficacy and side effects of COX-2
inhibitors. We will control for clinical knowledge in two ways. First,
over the period of our study (1999-2002), there were more than 900
publications in English-language medical journals about COX-2
inhibitors. Of those, 132 were specifically in the area of OA. To
control for the effect of this research on clinical providers, we
created a data series, that measures the number of publications in each
month that had the keywords: rofecoxib, celecoxib, Vioxx, Celebrex, and
osteoarthritis. We further refined the measure by dividing it into three
series: the number of publications each month that focused on Celebrex,
the number of publications each month that focused on Vioxx, and the
number of publications each month that focused on both.
Second, in August 2001, Mukherjee, Nissen, and Topol (2001)
published an influential article in a major medical journal where they
reviewed data available from a major clinical trial, which indicated
serious statistically significant concerns about the cardiovascular risk
associated with Vioxx (rofecoxib). To a lesser, and not statistically
significant, extent, the paper raised concerns about Celebrex
(celecoxib). This was the first publication in a major outlet to raise
issues about increased risk of myocardial infarction associated with
COX-2 inhibitors in general and Vioxx in particular. These concerns were
later to be validated when Merck withdrew Vioxx from the market in
October 2004. We will include an indicator variable, which equals 1
after August 2001 and 0 otherwise to test whether the practicing
clinical community responded to this new information even in the face of
significant DTCA in favor of Vioxx and Celebrex.
E. Possible Impacts of Advertising
There are several variables that are central to understanding the
impact of advertising on patient treatment delay decisions. The first
set, obviously, are the measures of advertising spending on behalf of
Vioxx and Celebrex. In general, one would expect the impact of Vioxx or
Celebrex brand television DTCA to shorten the time that patients wait
before initiating any COX-2 inhibitor treatment--in which case the
parameter on the advertising measures will be negative and significant.
It is possible that the only effect of advertising is class level. That
is, it may not matter which drug is advertised-any advertising for a
COX-2 inhibitor may affect the demand for both approximately equally. To
evaluate this, we will estimate two versions of the model. The first
will include total dollars spent (as both a linear and a squared term)
in the previous month on both Celebrex and Vioxx as one variable. The
second will include separate measures (again, both linear and squared
terms) for Celebrex and Vioxx ad spending. If television advertising has
a pure class effect then advertisement for Vioxx and Celebrex would have
roughly equal effects when entered individually on the delay to therapy
for Celebrex (Vioxx) in the separate models we run for delay to
initiation for each brand individually.
That advertising has an effect, however, says little about the
social welfare impact of DTCA. We can, however, learn something about
the welfare effects of advertising by examining its effect on delay to
treatment for patients that are likely to benefit from, or be poor
candidates for, COX-2 inhibitor use. In particular, patients who have
required treatment for gastrointestinal problems using protonpump
inhibitors, H2 blockers, or other similar treatments are more likely to
suffer gastric irritation from nonsteriodal anti-inflammatory drugs
(NSAIDs) and so are the good candidates for COX-2 inhibitors. In this
case, we identified patients with gastrointestinal comorbidities as
those who have ever had a prescription for ranitidine (e.g., Zantac),
famotidine (e.g., Pepcid), cimetidine (e.g., Tagamet), omeprazole (e.g.,
Prilosec), esomeprazole (e.g., Nexium), lansoprazole (e.g., Previcid),
rabeprazole (e.g., Aciphex), pantoprazole (e.g., Protonix), sulcralfate
(e.g., Carafate), misoprostol (e.g., Cytotec), and Helidac, Prevpac, or
metoclopromide (e.g., Reglan). We interacted the advertising measures
with the indicator variable for gastrointestinal problems. If
advertising improves patient matching then the parameters on those
interactions will be negative and significant--indicating shorter delays
to initiation.
In contrast, there are a number of conditions that make a person a
poor candidate for use of a COX-2 inhibitor. These include a diagnosis
of heart disease (hypertension and other coronary diseases). Individuals
with these conditions should initiate therapy with a COX-2 inhibitor
less frequently, which translates into longer delay times. However, this
set of contraindications was not widely discussed in the clinical
community until the publication of the Mukherjee, Nissen, and Topol
(MNT) article in August 2001. Consequently, we will test for the
informational components of the DTCA for heart disease by including a
three-way interaction term between the advertising measures, the heart
disease indicator variable, and the indicator variable for whether the
treatment began after August 2001. If the advertising is conveying
clinically useful information then the parameter on this interaction
will be positive and significant (indicating that advertisement induces
individuals with those comorbidities to wait longer to begin treatment
after the contraindication for heart disease was published in the
clinical literature).
V. RESULTS
Table 1 presents the means and standard deviations of the variables
used in our model, including the average delay to treatment (conditional
on initiating therapy). More information on the raw delay measures is
presented in Table 2, which shows the average delay time between the
diagnosis and the first long-term use of each COX-2 inhibitor as well as
the number of people who ultimately adopt each. We find that patients
who first adopt Celebrex tend to adopt more rapidly than those who first
adopt Vioxx, with a delay of 163 d for the Celebrex users, compared with
a delay of 199 d for the Vioxx users. Interestingly, for all the
attention paid to the introduction of COX-2 inhibitors, and the large
expenditures on promotion on their behalf, 64% of the sample (11,741
patients) did not adopt one of the COX-2 inhibitors.
We estimate two versions of the hazard function presented in
Equation (6). Model 1 contains the advertising measures (as combined
national and local dollars spent) for Vioxx and Celebrex together, along
with the set of independent variables listed above. Model 2 includes
separate measures for total Vioxx and Celebrex monthly advertising,
along with the other independent variables. Thus, we will estimate the
hazard rate in Equation (6) above, where
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII]
and where TV is either the combined Vioxx and Celebrex national and
local advertising dollars or brand-specific national and local
advertising dollars, GI is the indicator for a gastrointestinal
comorbidity, CVD is the indicator for heart disease comorbidities
(cardiovascular disease and hypertension), TNM is the indicator variable
for the post-August 2001 period (which corresponds to the publication of
the Topol, Nissan, and Mukerjee article that first alerted the medical
profession to the increased risk for heart attack associated with the
use of some COX-2 inhibitors), and Z represents the remainder of the
explanatory variables discussed above. The vector Z also includes
individual practice fixed effects. Since in nearly all cases there is
only one practice per media market, our practice-level fixed effects
correspond largely to media market fixed effects. Finally, we rely on
the fixed effects to correct for clustering (repeated observations) at
the physician practice level. The coefficient estimates are presented in
Table 3.
In the first model, where the COX-2 television advertising dollars
for both brands are summed together, we find that television advertising
does have a significant effect on the delay in treatment. Total
television spending has a positive first derivative and negative second
derivative-both significant at better than the 1% level. The parameter
estimates in Table 3 are not direct measures of the net effect in terms
of days of delay. Table 4 presents these net effects for the variables
of primary interest and converts the raw effects to days of delay
induced by a 1-unit increase in the variable of interest. When
calculated at the mean of the data, a $100,000 increase in all COX-2
advertising during the month of diagnosis has the effect of lengthening the time patients wait to begin COX-2 therapy after being diagnosed with
OA by about 30 d (evaluated at the mean of the data). Note that this is
in addition to average delay periods of between 160 and 200 d delay
(Table 2).
The second model in Table 3 breaks television advertising spending
into separate measures for total monthly spending on behalf of Vioxx and
total monthly spending on behalf of Celebrex. We find that the results
are similar--in that spending on behalf of both brands tends to increase
the delay initially and then lead to a decrease--again, with statistical
significance in excess of the 1% level. There is, however, a significant
difference in terms of where on this quadratic function the two brands
are placed.
In the case of Vioxx, the relationship between total spending and
delay of therapy becomes negative at $2.4 million per month. During the
time period of our data, Merck spent approximately $3.5 million per
month on behalf of Vioxx; thus, the marginal dollar spent for Vioxx
advertising led to a reduction in the average delay before initiating
any COX-2 therapy of approximately 14 d (Table 4). In contrast, the
relationship between spending for Celebrex and the delay to therapy
adoption does not become negative until Pfizer would spend more than
$34.5 million per month. During 1999-2002, Pfizer spent $6.5 million per
month on average--and never more than $13.8 million per month. This
implies that the marginal dollar spent for Celebrex by Pfizer actually
lengthens the delay in initiating any COX-2 treatment by approximately
41 d (Table 4). Thus, the positive effect of joint advertising spending
on delay to adoption in the first model is driven completely by Celebrex
ads. This curious reverse association between Celebrex television
advertising and the use of Celebrex is consistent with other recent
research we have conducted that examined the association between
television advertising and the rate of prescribing for Vioxx and
Celebrex at the physician practice level (Bradford et al. 2006). (l)
Given that we find that television advertising on behalf of the
COX-2 inhibitors has some effect on the delay to use, the next question
to address is whether this effect is welfare enhancing or not. As
discussed above, some patients are better candidates for COX-2 use in
that they have exhibited the sorts of gastrointestinal sensitivities for
which Vioxx and Celebrex were designed. Other patients have hypertension
and coronary disease comorbidities that make them poor candidates for
using COX-2 inhibitors because these conditions have been recognized as
contraindications for COX-2 use since the publication of the TNM
article. As discussed above, we estimate models with interactions
between total television advertising (local and national) and the GI
indicator variable, the heart disease and pre-TNM indicators, and the
heart disease and post-TNM indicators.
Table 3 presents the relevant parameters. We find strong evidence
for welfare-enhancing informational effects. The interaction between
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising and the indicator variable for
gastrointestinal sensitivity is negative and highly significant in both
models. In terms of the magnitude of the effect, patients with GI
comorbidities reduce their wait time to adopt COX-2 inhibitor treatment
by between 2 and 2.4 d for every additional $100,000 in monthly COX-2
inhibitor advertising (Table 4).
The effect of advertising on patients with heart disease
comorbidities (cardiovascular disease and hypertension) depends on
whether we observe the therapy being initiated prior to the publication
of TNM or after. Prior to TNM, patients with cardiovascular
comorbidities actually adopted COX-2 inhibitor therapy more rapidly when
exposed to increased advertising. Given the information about the
potential cardiac dangers associated with COX-2 inhibitor use
(especially Vioxx), this is contrary to what would improve social
welfare. However, prior to the publication of the TNM paper, this risk
was poorly appreciated in the clinical community. However, once the TNM
paper was published, we find a strong positive impact on delay to
therapy initiation for patients with diagnosed heart disease when
exposed to greater levels of COX-2 inhibitor advertising. This is the
direction one would expect if the ads provide real information that
assists patients and physicians to more optimally match therapies. In
fact, the post-TNM interaction effect is larger than the pre-TNM
interaction effect by approximately 6-8 days. (2)
Recall that we proposed relatively strong tests of whether DTCA for
COX-2 inhibitors leads to welfare-enhancing or-reducing effects. If
increasing DTCA is associated with reductions in the time patients who
are good candidates for the therapy wait before initiating treatment and
is associated with increases in the time patients who are poor
candidates wait before initiating treatment then the advertising must be
providing useful information to the clinical matching process. In this
case, DTCA has at least some welfare-enhancing characteristics. We find
exactly this pattern in our interactions between patients with
previously treated GI difficulties (good candidates) and with previously
diagnosed heart disease (poor candidates). In addition, the expected
positive effect from the heart disease only shows up after the first
important clinical publication to demonstrate that patients with heart
disease are, in fact, at increased risk from COX-2 inhibitor use. Taken
together, this evidence strongly supports the neoclassical view of
advertising as information-and throws the strong criticism that
pharmaceutical DTCA has recently received into question.
Finally, Table 3 presents parameters which test whether patients
and clinicians respond to information from the clinical literature. As
discussed above, we included measures of gross publication rates in the
month preceding initiation of COX-2 use for papers that discuss COX-2
inhibitors (either generically or focusing on a specific brand) in the
context of care for patients with OA. While the measures of clinical
publication rates are uniformly statistically significant, there is
little consistency in the parameter values (except for publications
involving only Celebrex--which tended to always increase delay times).
We take this as evidence that clinical publications are measurably
important for the prescribing patterns of primary care clinicians in
community practice; we cannot characterize how the effect is felt. This
is likely because some publications are favorable toward the
effectiveness (and cost-effectiveness) of COX-2 inhibitors and some are
pessimistic. However, our data do not currently characterize the tenor
of the publication. More research on how clinical information and DTCA
information interact appears warranted.
VI. CONCLUSIONS
The increased use of television advertising by manufacturers of
prescription pharmaceutical has been a controversial development over
the past 5-10 yr in the United States. While the use of such
advertisement has grown dramatically since the early 1990s, to date,
there have been few studies which have empirically examined the effect
of these ads on patient care. The primary goal of this paper was to
determine what effect local and national television advertising on
behalf of the two main COX-2 inhibitors had on the treatment decisions
that patients made in collaboration with their physicians. In
particular, the treatment decision we studied is the time patients
choose to wait before initiating treatment with either Vioxx or
Celebrex. Using data on 18,235 patients from a set of geographically
dispersed community-based primary care practices, we have measured the
determinants of the delay between diagnosis for OA and onset of COX-2
inhibitor therapy. To accomplish these goals, we estimated a series of
competing risk duration regressions using an AFT model.
Despite the importance of our study, there are limitations. First,
without monthly data for pharmaceutical detailing, we were unable to
account for the impact and interaction of detailing directly. Such
physician-based marketing remains a larger component of pharmaceutical
marketing efforts than DTCA advertising. It is possible that DTCA and
detailing efforts were coordinated; if so, the DTCA effects measured
here might have included some detailing effect. Personal communication
with pharmaceutical representatives, however, suggested that since both
Vioxx and Celebrex were such important products to the manufacturers,
the representatives discussed these products at every opportunity. This
implies that there would be little correlation between the levels of
detailing and local or national variation in advertising, which in turn
would minimize the potential for bias in the results. Second, practices
also generally have a supply of pharmaceutical samples on hand to give
patients when they write a prescription. The availability of samples may
influence which product is prescribed. Again, personal communication
with physicians and pharmaceutical representatives suggested that most
physicians would typically have had a stock of samples of both on hand,
implying that the potential for omitted variables bias is limited.
Additionally, the practice-level fixed effects included in the models
capture any general tendency to favor one drug over another.
In summary, we find that increases in television advertising for
Vioxx is associated with shorter wait times between diagnosis and use.
On the other hand, Celebrex television advertising is associated with
longer delays to COX-2 adoption. Finally, we also present evidence that
the effect of DTCA may tend to improve economic efficiency in that
advertising tends to shorten the delays to adoption for patients who are
better candidates for COX-2 use and lengthens the delay to adoption for
patients who are worse candidates for the use of COX-2 inhibitors.
ABBREVIATIONS
AFT: Accelerated Failure Time
COX-2: Cyclooxygenase-2
DTCA: Direct to Consumer Advertising
FDA: Food and Drug Administration
OA: Osteoarthritis
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00215.x
REFERENCES
Arnott, R., and F. Lewis. "The Transition of Land to Urban
Use." Journal of Political Economy, 87, 1979, 161-69.
Benninga, S., M. Helmantel, and O. Sarig. "The Timing of
Initial Public Offerings." Journal of Financial Economics, 75,
2005, 115-32.
Bradford, W. D., A. Kleit, P. Neitert, T. Mcilwain, and S.
Ornstein. "The Effect of Direct to Consumer Television Advertising
on Physician Prescribing Behavior for the Treatment of
Osteoarthritis." Health Affairs, 25(5), 2006, 1371-77.
Calfee, J., C. Winston, and R. Stempski. "Direct-to-Consumer
Advertising and the Demand for Cholesterol-Reducing Drugs." Journal
of Law and Economics, 45(2, pt 2), 2002, 673-690.
Capozza, D., and Y. Li. "The Intensity and Timing of
Investment: The Case of Land." American Economic Review, 84, 1994,
889-904.
Capozza, D., and Y. Li. "Optimal Land Development
Decisions." Journal of Urban Economics, 51, 2002, 123-42.
Cutler, D. "The Incidence of Adverse Medical Outcomes Under
Prospective Payment." Econometrica, 63, 1995, 29-50.
Donohue, J., M. Cevasco, and M. Rosenthal. "A Decade of Direct
to Consumer Advertising of Prescription Drugs." New England Journal
of Medicine, 357, 2007, 673-80.
Dubois, R. "Pharmaceutical Promotion: Don't Throw the
Baby Out with the Bath Water." Health Affairs Web Exclusive, W3,
2003, 96-103.
Hamilton, B. H., and V. H. Ho. "Estimating Surgical
Volume-Outcome Relationships Applying Survival Models: Accounting for
Frailty and Hospital Fixed Effects." Health Economics, 6, 1997,
383-95.
Heckman, J., and B. Singer. "A Method for Minimizing the
Impact of Distributional Assumptions in Econometric Models for Duration
Data." Econometrica, 52, 1984, 271-320.
Hurwitz, M., and R. Caves. "Persuasion or Information?
Promotion and the Shares of Brand Name and Generic
Pharmaceuticals." Journal of Law and Economics, 31, 1988, 299-320.
Kalbfleisch, J., and R. Prentice. "Estimation of the Average
Hazard Ratio." Biometrika, 68, 1981, 105-112.
Keith, A. "Regulating Information About Aspirin and the
Prevention of Heart Attack." American Economic Review, 85, 1995,
96-99.
King, C. "Marketing, Product Differentiation and Competition
in the Pharmaceutical Industry." Working Paper, MIT Department of
Economics, 1996.
Kleit, A. N. "Using Advertising to Generate Information and
Signals for Product Quality: Lessons for Biotechnology in Canada from
Pharmaceutical Markets in the United States," in Biotechnology and
the Consumer, edited by K. A. Mathios. Boston: Kluwer, 1998, 257-75.
Knight Ridder News. "Drug Maker Merck reports 5% Increase in
Profits." Tribune Business News, July 21, 2001.
Leffler, K. "Persuasion or Information? The Economics of
Prescription Drug Advertising." Journal of Law and Economics, 24,
1981, 45-74.
Masson, A., and P. Rubin. "Matching Prescription Drugs and
Consumers: The Benefits of Direct Advertising." New England Journal
of Medicine, 313, 1985, 513-15.
McDonald, R., and D. Siegel. "The Value of Waiting to
Invest." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 101, 1986, 707-28.
Merton, R. C. "An Intertemporal Capital Asset Pricing
Model." Econometrica, 41, 1973, 867-87.
Morrill, R., J. Cromartie, and G. Hart. "Metropolitan, Urban,
and Rural Commuting Areas: Toward a Better Descriptions of the United
States Settlement System." Urban Geography, 20, 1999, 727-48.
Mukherjee, D., S. Nissen, and E. Topol. "'Risk of
Cardiovascular Events Associated with Selective COX-2 Inhibitors."
Journal of American Medical Association, 286, 2001, 954-59.
National Institute for Health Care Management.
"'Prescription Drugs and Mass Media Advertising, 2000."
Washington, DC: NIHCM Foundation, November 2001.
"Pharmacia Has Setback for Parecoxib.'" Chemical
Market Reporter, July 2001, 8.
Picone, G., R. Wilson, and S. Chou. "Analysis of Hospital
Length of Stay and Discharge Destination Using Hazard Functions with
Unmeasured Heterogeneity." Health Economics, 12, 2003, 1021-34.
Ridder, G. "The Non-Parametric Identification of Generalized
Accelerated Failure-Time Models." Review of Economic Studies, 57,
1990, 167-81.
Rizzo, J. "'Advertising and Competition in the Ethical
Pharmaceutical Industry: The Case of Hypertensive Drugs." Journal
of Law and Economics, 42, 1999, 89-116.
Rubin, P. "Economics of Prescription Drug Advertising."
Journal of Research in Pharmaceutical Economics, 3(1), 1991, 29-39.
Schumann, M. "Top 100 Megabrands: Chevrolet Leads the Race
Along Megabrand Road, but Marketers Hit 2001 Potholes." Advertising
Age, 72, 2001, I.
Telser, L. "The Theory of Supply with Application to tile Ethical Pharmaceutical Industry." Journal of Law and Economics, 18,
1975, 449-78.
Titman, S. "Urban Land Prices Under Uncertainty."
American Economic Review, 75, 1985, 505-14.
"Top Brands in Network Primetime-2000." Brandweek, April
23, 2001, 30.
Topol, E. "'Failing the Public Health-Rofecoxib, Merck
and the FDA." New England Journal of Medicine, 351. 2004, 1707-09.
Zachry, W. M., S. J., Coons, and Ginsburg, D. B. "Patient
Autonomy and the Regulation of Direct-to-Consumer Advertising."
Clinical Therapy, 23, 2001, 2024 37.
(1.) We also estimated versions of the duration of delay for Vioxx
and Celebrex separately, including spending on both brands in each
equation. In those models, we found that the general effects
demonstrated in the second column of Table 3 hold: Vioxx spending
generally has a net effect of reducing the delay to therapy adoption for
both Vioxx and Celebrex, while Celebrex has a net effect of lengthening
the delay for both brands. Those results are available on request.
(2.) Note that while the absolute magnitudes of the pre-and
post-TNM interaction effects are quite different between the two models,
the net effects are quite similar.
W. DAVID BRADFORD, ANDREW N. KLEIT, PAUL J. NIETERT and STEVEN
ORNSTEIN *
* The authors would like to thank Jack Calfee, John Cawley, and
Terry Steyer for their comments and assistance on this paper as well as
participants at the Sloan Program Conference on Consumers, Information
and the Evolving Healthcare Market Place, the 2005 Annual Health
Economics Conference (State College, Pennsylvania), and the 2005
International Health Economics Biannual Congress (Barcelona). This paper
was funded by grants from the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality (1 R01 HS011326-01A2) and from the National Heart, Lung and Blood
Institute (1 R01 HL077841-01).
Bradford: Busbee Chair in Public Policy, 201C Baldwin Hall,
Department of Public Administration and Policy, University of Georgia,
Athens, GA 30602. Phone 706-542-2731, Fax 706-583-0610, E-Mail
[email protected]
Kleit: Professor of Energy and Environmental Economics, MICASU
Faculty Fellow, Department of Meteorology, Department of Energy and
Mineral Engineering, Pennsylvania State University, 507 Walker Building,
University Park, PA 16802-5013
Nietert: Associate Professor, Department of Medicine, Medical
University of South Carolina, 135 Cannon St., Room 403J, Charleston, SC
29425. Phone (843) 876-1204, E-mail
[email protected]
Ornstein: Professor, Department of Family Medicine, Medical
University of South Carolina, Charleston, SC 29425. Phone (843)
876-1213, E-mail
[email protected]
TABLE 1
Data Description (N = 18, 235)
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation
Average delay between diagnosis with 178.422 304.496
OA and first use of COX-2 inhibitor
(for 6,494 uncensored observations)
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising 99.767 40.053
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising 11,557.730 6,317.694
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, 35.009 17.176
month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising 1,520.648 1,413.734
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising, 64.758 31.272
month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising 5,171.554 3,203.501
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000x)
Patient has received gastrointestinal 0.381 0.486
treatment
Patient has been diagnosed with heart 0.696 0.460
disease
Interaction between gastrointestinal 35.715 53.269
treatment and total COX-2 inhibitor
advertising dollars
Interaction between heart disease and 56.575 57.886
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising
dollars during pre-TNM period
Interaction between heart disease and 53.578 58.177
total COX-2 inhibitor and advertising
dollars during post-TNM period
Number of journal publications 0.344 0.996
discussing COX-2 inhibitors in
month preceding therapy
Number of journal publications 0.977 0.760
discussing Vioxx in month preceding
therapy
Number of journal publications 2.223 1.175
discussing Celebrex in month
preceding therapy
Therapy initiated in 1999 0.071 0.257
Therapy initiated in 2000 0.512 0.500
Therapy initiated in 2001 0.061 0.240
Patient age at therapy initiation 65.531 13.864
Patient is female 0.678 0.467
Patient has been diagnosed with 0.181 0.385
depression
Patient has been diagnosed with 0.179 0.383
diabetes
Patient has been diagnosed with 0.354 0.478
hyperlipidemia
County population 523,489 1,358,298
Number of physicians per 1,000 147.098 52.533
population in county
County per capita income 2,5845.46 5,223.66
Number of Medicare enrollees in county 2.277 2.279
Percent of county residents who are 47.738 6.685
employed
Percent of county population that is 80.914 8.026
Caucasian
Percent of county population that is 11.896 7.963
African American
Average price for intermediate length 56.574 7.255
physician visit
TABLE 2
Delay between OA Diagnosis and First COX-2 Use (Number of Patients)
Average Delay
for Patients Average Delay
Who Do Not for Patients
Adopt Vioxx Who Adopt Vioxx
Average delay for patients 776.9 (11,741) 199.1 (2,760)
who do not adopt Celebrex
Average delay for patients 162.7 (3,734) --
who adopt Celebrex
Total patients 18,235
TABLE 3
AFT Duration Models of Time between Diagnosis and Treatment for OA
Patients Coefficients of Model
Model 1 Combined
Vioxx and Celebrex
Variable Total Advertising
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising, month 0.0730 (17.300)
preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising -0.0002 (-11.91)
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, month
preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising
squared, month preceding therapy
($100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising,
month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Patient has received gastrointestinal -0.0182 (-0.16)
treatment
Patient has been diagnosed with heart -0.3110 (-2.51)
disease
Interaction between gastrointestinal -0.0029 (-2.17)
treatment and total COX-2
inhibitor advertising dollars
Interaction between heart disease and -0.0451 (-22.87)
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising
dollars during pre-TNM period
Interaction between heart disease and 0.0554 (32.82)
total COX-2 inhibitors advertising
dollars during post-TNM period
Number of journal publications discussing 0.1709 (5.39)
COX-2 inhibitors in month preceding
therapy
Number of journal publications discussing -0.0542 (-1.77)
Vioxx in month preceding therapy
Number of journal publications discussing 1.2403 (26.41)
Celebrex in month preceding therapy
Therapy initiated in 1999 1.9057 (5.42)
Therapy initiated in 2000 2.5651 (8.18)
Therapy initiated in 2001 -2.9144 (-9.41)
Patient age at therapy initiation 0.0157 (5.87)
Patient is female -0.0118 (-0.16)
Patient has been diagnosed with depression -0.0762 (-0.90)
Patient has been diagnosed with diabetes 0.1694 (1.85)
Patient has been diagnosed with 0.1950 (2.51)
hyperlipidemia
County population (in 1,000s) -0.00003 (-5.99)
Number of physicians per 1,000 population 0.0021 (1.18)
in county
County per capita income 0.00003 (1.52)
Number of Medicare enrollees in county -0.1345 (-1.39)
Percent of county residents who are -0.0871 (-5.30)
employed
Percent of county population that is -0.0159 (-1.30)
Caucasian
Percent of county population that is -0.2625 (-4.44)
African American
Average price for intermediate length 0.0686 (6.35)
physician visit
Constant 9.8063 (4.40)
Likelihood ratio test of overall 11, 957.97 (<0.0001)
significance p value
Model 2 Separated
Vioxx and Celebrex
Variable Total Advertising
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising, month
preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, month 0.0482 (4.17)
preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising -0.0010 (-9.12)
squared, month preceding therapy
($100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising, 0.0687 (14.79)
month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising -0.0001 (-2.39)
squared, month preceding therapy
(in $100,000s)
Patient has received gastrointestinal 0.0970 (0.87)
treatment
Patient has been diagnosed with heart -0.3271 (-2.63)
disease
Interaction between gastrointestinal -0.0037 (-2.69)
treatment and total COX-2
inhibitor advertising dollars
Interaction between heart disease and -0.0044 (-2.16)
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising
dollars during pre-TNM period
Interaction between heart disease and 0.0132 (7.03)
total COX-2 inhibitors advertising
dollars during post-TNM period
Number of journal publications discussing -0.1664 (-4.79)
COX-2 inhibitors in month preceding
therapy
Number of journal publications discussing 0.1468 (4.31)
Vioxx in month preceding therapy
Number of journal publications discussing 0.9796 (22.66)
Celebrex in month preceding therapy
Therapy initiated in 1999 -0.3832 (-1.03)
Therapy initiated in 2000 1.6536 (5.44)
Therapy initiated in 2001 -2.4908 (-8.10)
Patient age at therapy initiation 0.0163 (6.23)
Patient is female -0.0283 (-0.39)
Patient has been diagnosed with depression -0.0919 (-1.11)
Patient has been diagnosed with diabetes 0.1244 (1.38)
Patient has been diagnosed with 0.2036 (2.66)
hyperlipidemia
County population (in 1,000s) -0.00003 (-6.15)
Number of physicians per 1,000 population 0.0034 (1.95)
in county
County per capita income 0.00001 (0.48)
Number of Medicare enrollees in county -0.3372 (-3.47)
Percent of county residents who are -0.0838 (-5.30)
employed
Percent of county population that is -0.0(08 (-0.93)
Caucasian
Percent of county population that is -0.2604 (-4.53)
African American
Average price for intermediate length 0.0517 (4.85)
physician visit
Constant 12.7530 (5.89)
Likelihood ratio test of overall 13, 164.55 (<0.0001)
significance p value
Note: t statistics are given in parentheses.
TABLE 4
AFT Duration Models of Time between Diagnosis and Treatment for OA
Patients. Net Marginal Effects: Change in Days of Delay to Treatment
for a 1-Unit Change in the Explanatory Variable
Model 1 Model 2
Combined Separated
Vioxx and Vioxx and
Celerex Celebrex
Total Total
Variable Advertising Advertising
Total dollars in COX-2 advertising, 30.70 --
month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Vioxx advertising, -- -13.7
month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Total dollars in Celebrex advertising, -- 40.80
month preceding therapy (in $100,000s)
Interaction between gastrointestinal -2 -2.4
treatment and total COX-2 inhibitor
advertising dollars
Interaction between heart disease and -31 -2.8
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising
dollars during pre-TNM period
Interaction between heart disease and 38.10 8.60
total COX-2 inhibitor advertising
dollars during post-TNM period
TABLE 5
Rural/Urban Distribution of PPRNet Practices
and Patients
PPRNet PPRNet U.S.
Practices Patients Population
(%) (%) (%)
Urban core areas 64 66 71
Small town/rural area 17 15 10
Suburban area 10 12 9
Large town area 9 7 10