Information disclosure policies: evidence from the electricity industry.
Delmas, Magali ; Montes-Sancho, Maria J. ; Shimshack, Jay P. 等
I. INTRODUCTION
Developed nations' environmental policies have evolved
substantially in the past several decades. Early pollution control
programs involved command and control approaches. Policies then
frequently included pollution charges, tradable permits, and other
market-based instruments. Most recently, a "third wave" of
environmental policy has emerged that emphasizes information provision
as an integral part of the risk mitigation strategy. Here, government
regulation is replaced or augmented by publicly provided information
presumed to assist more cost-effective private market and legal forces.
Common examples include the toxics release inventory, lead paint
disclosures, drinking water quality notices, and eco-labels. The
empirical effects of such programs, however, remain largely
undetermined. This paper examines the impact of a prominent mandatory
disclosure program on the fuel mix percentages of large electric utility
corporations.
The prominence of mandatory information policies is not restricted
to environmental arenas. For example, developed countries' equity
markets generally require firm-level financial information provision. In
many countries, agricultural goods require country of origin and other
health labels. Domestic colleges and universities are required by law to
inform current and prospective students of crime statistics, equity
data, and performance metrics. Even significant medical errors must now
be disclosed to the community.
There are several potential advantages of information provision
policies, and theory suggests that disclosure programs may effectively
achieve their goals. Healy and Palepu (2001) provided a survey of the
evidence in capital markets. Brouhle and Khanna (2007) demonstrated that
information provision can improve product quality. In the environmental
area, Kennedy, Laplante, and Maxwell (1994), Arora and Gangopadhyay
(1995), Maxwell, Lyon, and Hackett (2000), Kirchhoff (2000), and Khanna
(2001) showed that the provision of information about pollution may
correct a market failure, improve performance, and enhance welfare.
Despite the literature's theoretical findings, the empirical
effects of disclosure programs remain inconclusive. Early studies of
securities regulation found mixed results. (See Stigler (1964), Robbins
and Werner (1964), and Benston (1973)). A more recent literature
suggested that disclosure programs in financial markets can achieve
their desired effects; La Porta and Lopez-de-Silanes (2006) and
Greenstone, Oyer, and Vissing-Jorensen (2006) found that both market
size and market returns were positively influenced by mandatory
disclosure programs. In product quality settings, Chipty and Witte
(1998) established that resource and referral agencies significantly
influenced childcare prices, but had no impact on the quality of care.
In contrast, Jin and Leslie (2003) found that mandatory hygiene grade
cards positively affected restaurant quality and health outcomes.
Studies of environmental performance yielded similarly mixed
results. Desvousges, Smith, and Rink (1992) found that information-based
programs influenced attitudes favorable to radon testing, but testing
itself only increased when mass media dissemination was coupled with
community-based implementation programs. Konar and Cohen (1997) and
Khanna, Quimio, and Bojilova (1998) found that stock movements
associated with toxics release inventory (TRI) announcements led to
increased abatement and reduced emissions. However, Bui (2005) found
that the declines in emissions after TRI reporting events may have been
attributable to regulation rather than investor pressure. Bennear and
Olmstead (2006) found that drinking water quality notices lowered
violations for some systems, but not others.
This paper is the first empirical economic study of the impacts of
mandatory information provision in the electric utility industry. The
disclosure programs considered here differ significantly from the TRI
information programs examined previously. Notably, TRI information is
not directly provided to stakeholders. Furthermore, TRI information
frequently requires expertise to process and interpret. These
distinctions are important, as the broader literature on information
policies suggests that transparency programs are most likely to achieve
agency goals when disseminated information is simple, understandable,
standardized, actionable, and designed to directly benefit at least some
of the disclosers themselves (Weil et al. 2006).
Environmental disclosure programs in electricity markets are a
promising area of exploration for the efficacy of information policies
for several reasons. First, electricity is a homogeneous commodity. From
a consumption point of view, there are no differences in the
characteristics of green or brown electricity. Therefore, this setting
may allow us to more directly attribute program-induced changes to agent
preferences. This is not true in much of the broader literature. For
example, if eco-or organic-labeled products gain market share, it is
difficult to establish whether consumers are expressing preferences for
environmental improvement or whether consumers perceive other
differences in product quality (like health, safety, and taste). Second,
electric utilities are among the leading polluters in the United States.
For example, about 40% of domestic C[O.sub.2] and 67% of domestic
S[O.sub.2] emissions are attributable to electricity generation. Third,
electric disclosure programs exhibit a number of features desirable for
econometric identification. For example, the programs were adopted at
the state level and progressively introduced over time, so all firms
were not impacted uniformly.
To what extent did mandatory disclosure laws affect fuel mix
outcomes in the electric utility industry? We address this question by
examining monthly firm-level fuel mix and program data from 145 of the
largest investor-owned electric utility companies for the period
1995-2003. We first analyze how firms' fuel mix percentages respond
to mandatory disclosure programs. We prevent bias from potential
statistical endogeneity using fixed effects and instrumental variables.
We then explore the detected response in more detail. We use ordinary
least squares (OLS) and instrument variable (IV) interaction models to
explore the effect of customer composition on disclosure responses and
standard and IV quantile regressions (QREGs) to examine how the entire
fuel mix distribution shifts.
We find three main results. First, mandatory disclosure programs
affect fuel mix outcomes. We find that the average proportion of fuel
usage attributable to fossil fuels significantly decreases and the
average proportion of fuel usage attributable to clean fuels
significantly increases in response to disclosure programs in the
electric utility industry. These results are consistent with several
economic mechanisms, including political economy, liability, and demand
based theories. Second, customer composition significantly impacts
disclosure response. We find that firms' clean fuel program
responses become considerably stronger (more positive) as the firm
proportionately serves more residential customers. Firms' fossil
fuel program responses become weaker (less negative) as they
proportionately serve more residential customers. Third, preexisting fuel mix significantly impacts disclosure program response. Our results
suggest that firms that already use substantial amounts of clean fuels
most significantly increase clean fuel percentages in response to
disclosure programs. Similarly, firms that already use relatively small
amounts of fossil fuels most significantly decrease fossil fuel usage in
response to disclosure programs.
II. THE ELECTRIC UTILITY INDUSTRY
A. Fuel Mix
In 2004, domestic electricity generation totaled 3,953,407 gigawatt hours. Of total generation, 50% was attributable to coal, 18% was
attributable to gas, and 3% was attributable to oil. Nuclear sources
generated nearly 20% of electricity. Other energy sources, like
hydropower, biomass, geothermal, solar, and wind, generated
approximately 9% (Edison Electric Institute 2005). Cleaner energy
sources such as photovoltaic and wind plants represent higher operating
expenses than nuclear or fossil fuel, but they are growing rapidly. For
example, wind power usage increased by 27% in 2004.
B. Mandatory Information Disclosure Programs
In the U.S. electricity industry, information disclosure refers to
the mandatory provision of fuel mix percentages and pollution discharge
statistics to utility consumers. For example, Minnesota's Public
Utilities Commission decreed:
The Commission recognizes that there is a need
for the consumer to be informed and educated
on environmental issues and that all Minnesota
utilities' customers ... should have similar
access to information. (Minnesota Public Utilities
Commission 2002)
The state issued an order requiring regulated utilities to disclose
information on fuel mix and air emissions to customers. Twice annually,
utilities must include a bill insert that contains a pie chart depicting
the mix of fuel sources, a bar chart of air pollutant emissions, a chart
of costs associated with different generating sources, and a discussion
of energy efficiency measures. Furthermore, the utility must list a
phone number and web address on all bills so that consumers can access
environmental information. Other states' disclosure programs are
similarly motivated and implemented, although specific details may vary.
For example, several states' disclosure programs require quarterly
(rather than biannual) inserts.
Figure 1 indicates which states had disclosure programs in 2005. By
that year, 25 states had adopted generation disclosure rules, and these
states represented over 65% of the United States population. Since
consumer preferences may factor into disclosure impacts, programs may be
particularly meaningful in deregulated states. Indeed, 23 of the 25
state-level disclosure programs were enacted in deregulated states,
including NY, IL, TX, MI, AZ, NM, and much of the mid-Atlantic and
northeastern regions. Colorado and Florida instituted mandatory
disclosure programs without deregulating their industries.
C. Other Programs in the Electric Utility Industry
In addition to the mandatory state-level disclosure programs that
are the focus of this study, many electric utilities must comply with
other information requirements. Most notably, "major" firms
are required to file Federal Energy Regulatory Commission Form Number 1,
the Annual Report for Major Electric Utilities, each and every year. (1)
These reports average 140 pages and contain general corporate
information, financial statements, supporting schedules, and information
on environmental investments. In addition, electric utilities are
required to provide information about their environmental performance to
the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency and the Energy Information
Administration (EIA). Although all of the aforementioned data are
publicly accessible through government databases, users typically must
have environmental and database expertise to interpret the information.
In marked contrast, disclosure programs are designed explicitly to
produce easily accessible and readily interpretable information.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
Several other policies may also impact firms' fuel mix
percentages. Examples include Renewable Portfolio Standards (RPS),
mandatory Green Power Initiatives, and tax incentives. RPS typically
mandate tradable credit programs with fixed quotas for renewable
generation. Mandatory green power policies require utilities operating
in the state to offer and publicize green power options to consumers.
State and local sales and corporate tax credits and exemptions provide
financial incentives for green energy generation.
III. THEORIES LINKING DISCLOSURE AND FUEL MIX OUTCOMES
Several theories allow for a link between mandatory information
disclosure programs and fuel mix outcomes. (2) Perhaps the simplest
theoretical explanations entail increased community coercion or investor
or employee pressure. In the presence of information on the relative
environmental performance of a given firm, community activists may lobby
for future regulation or attempt to harm the firm's reputation with
the consuming public (indirectly reducing demand). Employee turnover and
dissatisfaction may result from disclosed poor environmental performance
(Tietenberg 1998). Investors may express environmental preferences or
concerns over future environmental regulation by decreasing demand for
shares (Khanna, Quimio, and Bojilova (1998)). However, the information
provided by disclosure programs in the electricity industry is typically
already available to highly motivated and trained experts like lawyers,
investors, and community activists.
A more compelling theory, then, for the link between information
and environmental performance in the electricity industry might involve
the threat of future regulation or legal action. In a dynamic political
economy context, disclosure programs may simply signal the state's
willingness to impose future regulations on the industry unless firms
self-regulate. Similarly, disclosure programs may increase a reporting
firm's susceptibility to liability under legal statutes. Segerson
and Miceli (1998) and Maxwell, Lyon, and Hackett (2000) explore
firms' incentives to preempt future regulation or legal liability.
Another persuasive theory for the link between disclosure and
environmental performance is a direct demand effect. In the presence of
simple, easily interpretable, and directly provided information,
consumers may increase demand for fuels perceived as environmentally
favorable and decrease demand for fuels perceived as environmentally
unfavorable. Of course, this mechanism requires (1) that information
affect consumer awareness, (2) that consumer awareness can translate
into changes in demand, and (3) that there be current or future consumer
choice among electricity products. However, the mechanism does not
require choice among electricity providers.
An emerging literature suggests that consumer awareness changes in
response to environmental information [Desvousges, Smith, and Rink
(1992), Blamey et al. (2000), Loureiro (2003), Loureiro and Lotade
(2005), and Leire and Thidell (2005)]. In our context, disclosed
information may remind consumers of the consequences of their own
actions, notify customers that alternative fuels exist and are widely
used, and demonstrate the variability in utilities' fuel mix
percentages and emissions. Further, shifts in awareness can translate
into new consumption outcomes [Teisl, Roe, and Hicks (2002) and
Shimshack, Ward, and Beatty (2007)].
Consumers increasingly have the option to purchase greener energy
at a price premium, and therefore increasingly have choice among
consumer products. Lamarre (1997) and Delmas, Russo, and Montes (2007)
found a distinct market niche for renewable energy even at a price
premium. Thirty-six states and over 600 utilities currently offer green
power pricing programs where consumers can support cleaner energy usage
in exchange for an electricity price increase. (3) Furthermore, there
are dozens of certificate programs (many at the national level) that
allow consumers to purchase green certificates or green tags that
require the replacement of traditional types of energy with greener
alternatives. These certificates are available whether or not the
consumer has direct access to green power options from their own
provider. Many utilities were very interested in disclosure programs
when they were being considered since such policies allowed firms to
"distinguish their price structure, fuel mix, or environmental
profile in the eyes of the consumer and found mandatory standard labels
to be a credible way to do that" (National Council on Competition
and the Electric Industry 2002). In other words, disclosure programs
were perceived as an effective and particularly convincing way to
price-discriminate immediately or in the future.
Of course, all theories linking disclosure programs and fuel mix
percentages in the electric utility industry require that the supply of
a given fuel type is not completely inelastic. In other words, firms
must be able to realistically alter their fuel mix portfolios in the
short to medium run. On the margin, at least, they can. While purchasing
or building new facilities may be required to dramatically alter fuel
mix portfolios, relatively small portfolio shifts are easily obtainable.
First, utilities can alter their capacity utilization. Second, major
electric utilities can buy and sell power generation in response to
changing market conditions.
Several theories can explain the link between information
disclosure and environmental performance. Empirically, we will follow
the broader information literature and estimate the general impact of
mandatory information programs. Regressions of quantity on information
variables (and other covariates) are identified under any of the
mechanisms discussed above, and an identified response represents the
impact of disclosure programs on the equilibrium quantity of electricity
generated from the specifically analyzed fuel source.
IV. DATA
A. Data Sources and Content
Our research assesses the impact of environmental disclosure
programs on the fuel mix percentages of major electric utility firms. We
focus on fuel mix indicators from the electric power industry for two
reasons. First, fuel mix is the most readily identifiable and
interpretable measure of environmental performance on disclosure program
bill inserts and web postings. Second, information disclosure programs
are heterogeneous, yet all require generation mix information.
We analyze data from the EIA's Annual Electric Power Industry
Database and the Interstate Renewable Energy Council (IREC)'s
database of State Incentives for Renewable Energy. Monthly fuel mix data
come from Form EIA-906 (and its predecessor EIA-759). We focus on
production-based fuel mix rather than sales-based fuel mix to minimize
program-induced sales shifts across states. Disclosure program
information comes directly from the IREC database. Since it is possible
that other state-level programs like RPS and Green Power initiatives may
impact utilities' fuel mix percentages, we also analyze other
program data from the IREC database.
B. The Sample
Our sample includes monthly information from 145 major
investor-owned electric utility companies. We focus on large
investor-owned firms because these companies represent the majority of
industry electricity and pollution generation. Furthermore, EIA data
(EIA-906 and EIA-759) are imputed for smaller companies based upon
information from these larger firms. All firms with at least one plant
with a capacity of 50 megawatts or more (25 megawatts or more before
1999), all firms with nuclear generation, and all firms with significant
renewable capacity file reports with the EIA for each and every month of
operation. Since our data represent the big incumbents in the electric
utility industry, the results of our analysis should be extrapolated to
smaller firms with a degree of caution.
Our sample data are observed at the firm level. Management
decisions are centralized and disclosure program requirements operate at
the firm/product level. Disclosure program requirements and generation
product definitions cross plant boundaries, but not firm boundaries. We
observe fuel mix percentages for our 145 firms for the 108 months
spanning 1995-2003. Our sample begins in 1995 to obtain preprogram information for all impacted states; the first disclosure program was
enacted in mid-1997. The sample concludes in 2003 due to data
availability.
C. Summary Statistics
Conditional on positive generation, aggregate fossil fuels
represent approximately 74% of generation for all sample firms over all
sample periods. We define fossil fuels as coal, oil, and gas. Aggregate
clean fuels represent approximately 9% of generation. We define
"clean" fuels as renewables and hydroelectric. (4) Nuclear
represents approximately 17% of generation. Nuclear is categorized as
neither fossil fuel nor clean fuel, and it is analyzed separately in all
analyses. Note that our generation sample statistics closely correspond
to total national proportions for the sample period.
Additional summary statistics, broken down by disclosure status,
are presented in Table 1. Standard errors appear in parentheses. The
summary statistics in Table 1 indicate that firms never subject to
disclosure decreased clean fuel usage and increased fossil fuel usage
over the sample period. In contrast, firms subject to disclosure
increased clean fuel usage and decreased fossil fuel usage over the
sample period.
Results in Table 1 are suggestive of disclosure program effects on
fuel mix outcomes, but the differences between the last period and the
first period are only statistically significant at the 5% level for the
clean fuel response of firms never subject to disclosure. These simple
summary statistics also do not control for confounding factors that may
impact changes in fuel mix over time. Consequently, a more complete
empirical analysis is necessary.
V. PRIMARY METHODS
Our overall empirical strategy is to use panel data techniques to
exploit within-firm temporal variation in program status to analyze the
effect of mandatory disclosure programs on fuel mix percentages. We
first use OLS and IV regression methods to demonstrate that disclosure
programs significantly reduce the proportion of fossil fuel usage and
significantly increase the percentage of clean fuel usage. Second, we
examine the disclosure response in more detail.
The basic regression model is [y.sub.it] = [D.sub.it][delta] +
[X.sub.it][beta] + [[alpha].sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.it], where i indexes
the unit of observation (a firm) and t indexes time (months). [y.sub.it]
represents the percentage of firm i's generation in period t
attributable to the fuel source being analyzed. [D.sub.it] represents
the proportion of firm i's sales that are subject to an effective
disclosure program in period t. The elements of the vector [X.sub.it]
include all of the nonprogram explanatory variables discussed below.
[[alpha].sub.i] is an unobserved time invariant individual effect and
[[epsilon].sub.it], is the usual time variant idiosyncratic shock.
A. Primary Variables
Our key dependent variables represent fuel mix percentages. These
include the percentage of firm i's generation in period t
attributable to fossil fuels (including coal, oil, and natural gas), to
clean fuels (including hydroelectricity and renewables like wind, solar,
and biomass), or to nuclear power. Our key explanatory measure is a
continuous variable representing the proportion of firm i's sales
that are subject to an operational or effective mandatory disclosure
program in period t. If all of a firm's sales are subject to
disclosure requirements in a given month, this explanatory variable
takes a value of 1. If only 80% of a firm's electricity sales are
subject to disclosure in a given month (such that 20% of company sales
go to states without operational disclosure programs), this variable
takes a value of 0.80.
Joskow (1998) noted that restructuring of electricity supply has
the potential to significantly impact industry fuel mix outcomes. On the
one hand, competitive retail power markets may provide market incentives
for electric utilities to offer green power to consumers (Delmas, Russo,
and Montes 2007). On the other hand, competition in restructuring
markets might favor low-cost power and induce utilities to minimize
generation costs and prices to consumers by focusing on low-cost fuel.
As noted in the background section, the vast majority of disclosure
programs were enacted in deregulated states at some point after
restructuring. Consequently, we include a variable representing the
percent of firm's sales in deregulated states.
We use firm-specific fixed effects to capture unobservable fuel mix
determinants and several nearly constant fuel mix determinants that have
been identified in the previous literature. These latter covariates
include firm size, age, community political and environmental attributes
[as often proxied by League of Conservation Voter (LCV) scores],
management profiles, average regulatory stringency, and ownership type
(Delmas, Russo, and Montes 2007). The literature indicates that fossil
fuel generation percentages decrease with higher LCV scores, decrease
with size, increase with merger processes, and increase with private
ownership. (6) Fixed effects also capture differences in input and
output prices due to factors like distance to fossil fuel markets and
state-level variation in taxation.
Since plant production varies seasonally, we include quarterly
dummy variables. A priori, the impact of seasonality on fuel mix is
ambiguous. One might expect that fossil fuel percentages are higher and
clean fuel percentages are lower in the late summer months as generation
of hydro and wind is lower during these time periods. Finally, we
include annual dummies to account for broad trends in prices,
technological change, and other factors.
B. Consistency Considerations
A potential concern with our key program variable [D.sub.it] is
that it may be statistically endogenous. For example, consider the
possibility that the likelihood of program adoption is a function of the
average environmental performance of the large electric utilities
operating within the state. In terms of the basic regression model, the
concern is that the time invariant individual effect [[alpha].sub.i] is
correlated with the program variable [D.sub.it]. However, fixed effects
prevent bias from this type of correlation. In our context, the
inclusion of fixed effects prohibits the possibility of bias introduced
when program adoption is a function of the temporal average fuel mix of
the firm.
It is also possible that the program variable [D.sub.it] is
correlated with the time variant error term [[epsilon].sub.it]. For
example, consider the possibility that states choose to adopt disclosure
programs in periods in which large electric utilities operating within
that state are utilizing more fossil fuels than usual. A standard
correction for this type of statistical endogeneity is instrumental
variables. Our chosen instrument is the weighted average of program
status in states near those states in which the particular firm
operates. However, since it is possible that emissions from upwind
states influence program adoption in the state of interest, our
instrument eliminates states directly upwind and directly downwind from
the states in which the particular firm operates. (7)
The validity of this instrument requires that: (Al) state
policymakers' disclosure program decisions are influenced by
disclosure program status in nearby states, and (A2) policy choices in
states where firm i does not operate do not depend directly on the
environmental performance of firm i in period t. Al is supported by
empirical evidence that consistently reveals important spillover effects
of policy choices in one state for decisions in neighboring states. (8)
A1 is also testable. The coefficient on the instrument in the first
stage regressions is significant in both an economic and a statistical
sense (t statistics above 7). Requirement A2 is simply a maintained
assumption, hut it seems unlikely firms make production choices based
upon laws that have no influence on them or that states where firm i
does not operate decide to adopt a program based upon the environmental
performance of firm i in period t. We later examine the sensitivity of
our instrumental variable.
VI. EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS
A. Fixed Effects and Instrumental Variables Regressions
Do disclosure programs affect fuel mix percentages on average? Our
goal here is to investigate the relationship between disclosure programs
and firm's fossil fuel and clean fuel usage. Thus, we regressed
fuel mix proportion measures on the percent of a firm's sales
subject to disclosure requirements and other covariates. Simultaneous
estimation of the multiple fuel mix equations through a seeming
unrelated regression (SUR) would yield no efficiency gain, since the
covariates in each equation are identical. We ran both fixed effects
linear regressions and fixed effects instrumental variables regressions.
Results are presented in Table 2. All computed standard errors are
heteroskedastic consistent. (9) T statistics appear in parentheses.
Results in Table 2 indicate that the estimated impact of an
operational disclosure program is negative and significant at the 1%
level for fossil fuel production. The results are also economically
significant. As the proportion of the average firm's sales subject
to disclosure increases 1%, the average proportion of generation
attributable to fossil fuels drops between 0.06 percentage points (OLS
point estimate) and 0.23 percentage points (IV point estimate).
Similarly, results in Table 2 indicate that the estimated impact of
an operational disclosure program is positive and significant at the 1%
level for clean sources like hydroelectric and renewables. As the
proportion of the average firm's sales subject to disclosure
increases 1%, the average proportion of generation attributable to clean
fuels increases between 0.02 percentage points (OLS point estimate) and
0.27 percentage points (IV point estimate).
We find that deregulation negatively affected the proportion of
fuel mix attributable to clean fuels like renewable and hydro and
positively affected the proportion of fuel mix attributable to fossil
fuels. Results are consistent with the hypothesis that deregulation
could potentially trigger investments in lower cost fuel. Seasonality
also appears to play a role in fuel mix percentages. The proportion of
fossil fuel usage is higher and the proportion of clean fuel usage is
lower in the late summer and fall months. This may reflect the fact that
generation of hydro and wind is lower during these time periods. We also
find that fuel mix decisions appear to trend over time, although
nonlinearly.
Disaggregated results for specific fuel sources mimic these
aggregate results. (10) There is a statistically significant negative
relationship between disclosure programs and the proportional use of
coal. Program effects on oil and gas are economically small and
statistically insignificant. There is a statistically significant
positive relationship between disclosure programs and the proportional
use of both renewable and hydroelectric generation. Results also suggest
no statistically significant relationship between disclosure programs
and the proportional use of nuclear electricity generation (categorized
as neither fossil fuel nor clean fuel and therefore omitted from Table
2).
B. Sensitivity Analysis: RPS and Other Programs
One concern with the preceding results is omitted variables. Other
state and local regulations like RPS, mandatory Green Power Initiatives,
and tax incentives may also impact firms' fuel mix percentages. Of
course, the instrumental variable approach should prevent bias unless
the instrument is itself correlated with the omitted variable.
Furthermore, the adoption of RPS, green power, and tax incentive
programs does not generally closely coincide with the adoption of
disclosure across time, and omitted time variant factors only bias
results if they are correlated with disclosure program introductions
across both time and space. To be complete, however, we tested whether
other prominent state-level programs targeting utilities' fuel
mixes impacted our key results. Including variables indicating the
percent of the firm's sales subject to RPS, mandatory green power,
and state and local tax incentives, either individually or
simultaneously, yields regression results (signs, significance, and
point estimates) that are extremely similar to the results presented in
Table 2.
C. Sensitivity Analysis: Other Assumptions
One possible worry is the robustness of our results to the chosen
instrument. If program implementation is more likely when other
states' firms use more fossil fuels and less clean fuels than
normal, our results understate program impacts. If program
implementation is more likely when other states' firms use less
fossil fuels and more clean fuels than normal, our results overstate
program impacts. Consequently, we experimented with an instrument that
contains program information from all states adjacent to those in which
the firm operates (not just states that are neither upwind nor
downwind). Furthermore, while we cannot come up with a convincing reason
that a state where firm i does not operate (or influence due to drifting
pollution) might decide to adopt disclosure based upon firm i's
period t environmental performance, we supposed this was possible. Under
this supposition, the state where firm i does not operate (or influence
due to drifting pollution) should at least not decide to adopt a program
based upon firm i's past environmental performance. We therefore
considered additional possible instruments that include lagged program
status in neighboring states. Ali tested instruments yield similar
(signs, significance, and magnitude) coefficient estimates in the first
stage and a consistent economic story (signs, statistical significance,
and economic importance) in the second stage. Our presented instrument
yields consistently conservative empirical magnitudes.
Another possible concern is the sharpness of our study's
program variables. Perhaps utilities were broadly aware of the
disclosure programs before their effective date and changed their
behavior ahead of time. Of course, if utilities had already completely
responded to disclosure programs before the effective dates, it would be
difficult to reconcile the observed responses in our analyses. However,
as a sensitivity test, we repeated all analyses with program variables
that reflect the dates the programs were enacted. In general, we find
qualitatively similar results (in signs and significance) to those
reported here, but magnitudes are frequently smaller.
Our program variable is constructed by weighting each firm's
state-level disclosure status by the percentage of sales that occur in
each state. A possible apprehension is that the percentage of a
firm's sales attributable to each state may change in response to
the program itself. This would introduce bias. However, if we replace
our program variable with a 0/l dummy indicating whether any of a
firm's sales are subject to disclosure, we find qualitatively
similar results.
Finally, in our analysis, we control for the possibility of
persistence with fixed effects and the possibility of systematic changes
in technology with time dummies. However, as a sensitivity check, we
include an autoregressive term lagged 1 year to help control for
unobserved technology shifts. Including this lagged discharge variable
did not substantively change the results; signs, significance, and
approximate magnitude are similar to those reported.
VII. FURTHER EXPLORATION
The regressions in Table 2 demonstrate that disclosure programs
reduce fossil fuel usage and increase clean fuel usage on average.
However, it may be informative to explore these effects in more detail.
Consequently, in this section, we first use regressions with
interactions to explore whether the impact of information programs on
fuel mix depends upon customer composition. We then explore the impact
of disclosure policies beyond the mean; we utilize conditional QREGs to
investigate program effects on the entire range of the fuel mix
distribution.
A. Regression Models with Interactions
Are disclosure program impacts conditional on customer composition?
Our goal here is to examine whether the effect of disclosure programs
depends upon a firm's proportion of sales to residential consumers.
Residential consumers may be more likely to respond to disclosure
programs since the simplified, easily interpretable information may be
more novel to them. Commercial organizations may simply have sufficient
incentives and resources to obtain fuel mix information without
disclosure programs. Furthermore, groups with different preferences may
simply respond differently to disclosed information. (11)
Consequently, we regress fuel mix proportion measures on the
percent of the firm's sales subject to disclosure, the proportion
of the firm's sales to residential consumers, an interaction of the
policy variable with the residential variable, fixed effects, and other
covariates. More formally, we consider the regression model [y.sub.it] =
[D.sub.it][delta] + [R.sub.i][gamma] +[D.sub.it] [R.sub.it] [eta] +
[X.sub.it][beta] + [[alpha].sub.i] + [[epsilon].sub.it]. [D.sub.it]
still represents the proportion of firm i's sales that are subject
to an effective disclosure program in period t, [R.sub.it], represents
the proportion of firm i's sales going to residential customers,
and the elements of the row vector [X.sub.it], include all of the
nonprogram explanatory variables.
Since both the program variable [D.sub.it] and its interaction
[D.sub.it][R.sub.it] may be statistically endogenous, we again employ
instrumental variables regressions. One instrument remains the same. Our
second instrument is the interaction of the first with the residential
variable. Since this interaction in not a linear combination of the
first instrument, it is as valid as the primary instrument itself.
Results are presented in Table 3. Computed standard errors are
heteroskedastic consistent. T statistics appear in parentheses.
Table 3 coefficients on the uninteracted residential variable
indicate that, in the absence of any disclosure program, an increase in
sales to residential customers increases the proportion of fuel mix
attributable to nuclear energy and decreases the proportion attributable
to clean fuels. Coefficients on the uninteracted disclosure program
variable indicate that when firms sell to no residential customers,
programs reduce the proportion of usage attributable to fossil fuels and
increase the proportion of usage attributable to nuclear energy. As
always, however, some care should be exercised interpreting coefficients
conditioned on zeroed variables.
The interaction results in Table 3 indicate that the impact of
disclosure programs on both clean fuel usage and fossil fuel usage
becomes more positive as the percentage of residential customers rises.
In other words, as a firm proportionately serves more residential
customers, clean fuel program responses become stronger (more positive).
Alternatively, as a firm proportionately serves more residential
customers, fossil fuel program responses become weaker (less negative).
These results are not inconsistent. Examining the last column of Table
3, we see that the interaction coefficient for nuclear energy is
negative and statistically significant. As a firm proportionately serves
more residential customers, any nuclear program responses become weaker
(less positive).
Marginal disclosure program impacts clarify the interpretation of
the results in Table 3. At the first quartile of the residential
customer variable, the marginal impact of disclosure on clean fuel usage
is +0.061. (12) At the median of this variable, the marginal impact of
disclosure is +0.121; at the third quartile, the marginal impact of
disclosure is +0.175; and at the 90th percentile, the marginal impact of
disclosure is +0.244. Thus, clean fuel program response becomes stronger
(more positive) as a firm proportionately serves more residential
customers. The marginal impact of disclosure on fossil fuel usage is
-0.487 at the first quartile of the residential variable, -0.435 at the
median, -0.388 at the third quartile, and -0.328 at the 90th percentile.
Therefore, fossil fuel program response becomes weaker (less negative)
as a firm proportionately serves more residential customers. Finally,
the marginal impact of disclosure on nuclear fuel usage is +0.457 at the
first quartile of the residential variable, +0.379 at the median, +0.309
at the third quartile, and +0.220 at the 90th percentile. Nuclear fuel
program response becomes weaker (less positive) as a firm
proportionately serves more residential customers.
B. Conditional QREGs
Do disclosure program impacts vary across the fuel mix
distribution? Our goal here is to examine whether the effect of
disclosure programs depends upon firms' preexisting fuel mix
portfolios. For example, do disclosure programs impact high fossil fuel
firms the same way they impact low fossil fuel firms? To explore this
question, we use Koenker and Bassett (1978)'s conditional QREGs.
QREGs estimate functional relationships between variables for
various points on the probability distribution of the dependent
variable. Estimated parameters are interpreted as they would be in any
ordinary regression model, but the parameter estimates are allowed to
vary with the quantile of the distribution. Typically, linear models
estimate the response of the mean or expected value of some dependent
variable to one or more independent variables. Quantile models estimate
the response of the median (or the 90th percentile or the 20th
percentile, etc.) to independent variables. In contexts with
heterogeneous responses across the distribution of the dependent
variable, focusing on the mean may overstate, understate, or fail to
reveal true changes in distributions (Cade and Noon 2003). (13)
In our context, QREGs decompose the mean response revealed by the
linear regression results in Table 2 into changes across the entire
probability distribution of fuel mix levels. In particular, conditional
QREGs allow us to estimate different slope coefficients for different
fuel mix quantiles. For example, a regression on the 50th percentile of
the fossil fuel distribution estimates the effect of disclosure on the
sample median of the fossil fuel distribution. A regression on the 20th
percentile of the fossil fuel distribution estimates the effect of
disclosure on the 20th percentile of the distribution. If the disclosure
program coefficient is larger for the 20th percentile than the 50th
percentile of the fossil fuel distribution, results suggest that firms
that already use relatively limited amounts of fossil fuels reduce
fossil fuels the most in response to disclosure programs.
An additional advantage of conditional QREGs in our context relates
to censoring. In our data, some observations have proportional clean
fuel usage at or near 0 and proportional fossil fuel usage at or near 1.
Less commonly, some observations have proportional clean fuel usage at
or near 1 and proportional fossil fuel usage at or near 0. Such
censoring may bias least squares regressions, but the weighted least
absolute deviation estimation underlying the QREG method minimizes or
eliminates the impact of censoring on the uncensored quantiles.
More formally, we consider the linear model for the conditional
quantile function, [Qy.sub.it]([tau]|[D.sub.it], [X.sub.it]) =
[alpha]([tau])+ [D.sub.it] [delta]([tau]) + [X.sub.it] [beta] (tau])for
[tau] between 0 and 1. [D.sub.it] still represents the proportion of
firm i's sales that are subject to an effective disclosure program
in period t and the elements of the row vector [X.sub.it] include all of
the nonprogram explanatory variables. Note that we omit firm-level fixed
effects. Including firm-level fixed effects in QREGs would yield
coefficients that indicate an average firm's program responses
across the distribution of departures from that individual firm's
typical fuel mix levels. So, the 75th percentile coefficient in the
fossil fuel QREG would represent the disclosure response when firms are
using a particularly large amount of fossil fuels, relative to their own
typical fossil fuel levels. In contrast, our purpose is to investigate
what happens to the overall fuel mix distribution. In other words, we
wish to explore if the fuel mix distribution shifts more strongly for
firms that typically use high proportions of fossil fuels.
Of course, it is still possible that the program variable Dir is
statistically endogenous. Therefore, in addition to standard conditional
QREGs, we perform instrumental variable QREG. For basic QREGs,
estimation, variance estimation, and inference follow Koenker and
Bassett (1982) and Rogers (1993). For instrumental variable QREG, we use
the implementation by Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004) for estimation and
inference.
Table 4 presents QREG results for the impact of disclosure programs
on proportional fossil fuel usage. Here, we conduct QREGs at the 20th,
30th, 40th, 50th, and 60th percentiles because these represent the
relevant range for this distribution. There is little variation below
the 20th percentile, as 15% of observations reflect proportional fossil
fuel usage at or near 0. Similarly, there is little variation above the
60th percentile, as nearly 40% of observations reflect fossil fuel usage
at or near 1 (100%).
Results in Table 4 demonstrate that the disclosure program point
estimates tend to decrease as one moves up the distribution of fossil
fuel usage. These differences are frequently both statistically and
economically significant. For example, all matched pair differences
except (Q20 and Q30) are statistically significant for the standard
QREGs. Furthermore, the fossil fuel program response at the 20th
percentile is 1.6 (IV QREG point estimates) to 2.2 (standard QREG point
estimates) times greater than the response at the 50th percentile.
Results in Table 2 indicated that disclosure programs induce reductions
in fossil fuel usage on average. The QREG results in Table 4 suggest
that it is firms that already use relatively limited amounts of fossil
fuels that reduce these fuels the most in response to disclosure
programs.
Results for clean fuel responses to disclosure programs mirror the
fossil fuel results previously presented in Table 4. Point estimates
generally increase as one moves up the distribution of clean fuel usage,
suggesting that disclosure programs induce firms that already use
substantial amounts of clean fuel to increase clean fuel usage the most.
For both fossil fuel and clean fuel responses, care should be taken
interpreting these results. Technically, the QREGs compare differences
in the absent-disclosure and present-disclosure distributions. Rank
preservation is not guaranteed. While it is practically quite likely
that firms that are at high quantiles of the absent-disclosure
distribution also appear at similarly high quantiles of the
corresponding present-disclosure distribution, this is not required.
Thus, QREG results strongly suggest, but do not prove, that firms that
already use substantial amounts of clean fuels increase clean fuel usage
the most in response to disclosure programs.
VIII. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION
On the margin, we find a statistically and economically significant
impact of information disclosure programs in the electricity industry.
We find that mandatory disclosure programs decrease firms'
percentage of generation attributable to fossil fuels and increase
firms' percentage of generation attributable to clean fuels like
hydroelectric and renewables. As the proportion of the average
firm's sales subject to disclosure requirements increases 1%, the
average proportion of generation attributable to fossil fuels drops
between 0.06 percentage points and 0.23 percentage points. Furthermore,
as the proportion of the average firm's sales subject to disclosure
increases 1%, the average proportion of generation attributable to clean
fuels rises between 0.02 percentage points and 0.27 percentage points.
We also find that disclosure program responses are sensitive to
customer composition and preexisting fuel mix levels. Firms' clean
fuel program responses become considerably stronger (more positive) as
the firm sells to more residential consumers. Fossil fuel program
responses become considerably weaker (less negative) as the proportion
of sales to residential consumers increases. Furthermore, disclosure
program responses differ across the fuel mix distribution. Results
suggest that firms that already use relatively low levels of fossil
fuels decrease their fossil fuel percentages the most in response to
information disclosure policies. For example, the program-induced
decrease in fossil fuel usage is approximately two times greater for
firms generating approximately 38% of their energy from fossil fuels
than for firms generating approximately 83% of their energy usage from
fossil fuels.
The key implication arising from our results is that information
disclosure programs that regularly provide easily interpretable
information can achieve policy goals. This result holds even when the
provided information already exists in the public domain. Other
significant policy implications follow from our results. Most notably,
information policies may generate unintended consequences. For example,
attention should be paid to customer composition when introducing
disclosure programs in the electricity industry. When utilities serve
high proportions of residential consumers, mandatory information
programs may spur particularly significant increases in clean fuel
usage. However, in these circumstances, these increases come at the
relative expense of nuclear fuel usage and not fossil fuel usage. This
may be consistent with stakeholder preferences, but it is unlikely to be
consistent with air pollution-oriented policy goals. Second, the
preexisting fuel mix results suggest that disclosure programs induce
firms that use significant amounts of clean fuels to use more clean
fuels. In contrast, firms that predominantly use fossil fuels respond
relatively weakly to disclosure programs. If the marginal benefits of
pollution abatement are larger at high fossil fuel firms than at low
fossil fuel firms, disclosure programs may induce inefficient abatement
allocations.
This paper suggests promising avenues for future research that are
beyond the present scope. First, our results indicate that mandatory
information disclosure programs affect the economic incentives and the
behavior of utilities. However, assessing the full welfare effects of
information-based policies requires a differentiation between new
generation and ownership changes. Second, our results and anecdotal
evidence suggest that the direct demand theory provides a credible link
between mandatory information disclosure programs and fuel mix outcomes.
For example, sensitivity of program response to customer composition
supports direct demand effects. However, a full understanding of the
implications of these information-based policies requires precise
identification of the underlying mechanism or mechanisms. Third, we
demonstrate that information programs affect fuel mix outcomes. While
fuel mix is correlated with emissions, gauging the social value of the
policies involves an empirical evaluation of program-induced impacts on
environmental quality. Finally, our results are suggestive for other
settings. While mandatory provision programs are becoming increasingly
common in other countries, the extent of policy-induced changes may be
sensitive to cross-country institutions.
REFERENCES
Arora, S., and S. Gangopadhyay. "Toward a Theoretical Model of
Voluntary Overcompliance." Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 28, 1995, 289-309.
Baicker K. "The Spillover Effects of State Spending,"
Journal of Public Economics, 89, 2005, 529-44.
Bennear, L., and S. Olmstead. "The Impacts of the 'Right
to Know': Information Disclosure and the Violation of Drinking
Water Standards." Mimeo, Duke University, 2006.
Benston, G. "Required disclosure and the Stock Market: An
Evaluation of the Securities Market Act of 1934." American Economic
Review, 63, 1973, 132-55.
Blamey, R., J. Bennett, J. Louviere, M. Morrison, and J. Rolfe.
"A Test of Policy Labels in Environmental Choice Modeling
Studies." Ecological Economics, 32, 2000, 269-286.
Brouhle, K., and M. Khanna. "Information and the Provision of
Quality Differentiated Products." Economic Inquiry, 45, 2007,
377-94.
Bui, L. "Public Disclosure of Private Information as a Tool
for Regulating Emissions: Firm-level Responses by Petroleum Refineries
to the Toxics Release Inventory." Mimeo, Brandeis University, 2005.
Busch, P., and H. Jorgens. "The International Sources of
Policy Convergence: Explaining the Spread of Environmental Policy
Innovations." Journal of European Public Policy, 12, 2005, 860-84.
Cade, B., and B. Noon. "A Gentle Introduction to Quantile
Regression for Ecologists." Frontiers in Ecology and the
Environment, 1, 2003, 412-20.
Cade, B., J. Terell, and R. Schroeder. "Estimating Effects of
Limiting Factors with Regression Quantiles." Ecology, 80, 1999,
311-23.
Chernozhukov, V., and C. Hansen. "Instrumental Variable
Quantile Regression." Mimeo, Massachusetts Institute of Technology,
2004.
Chipty, T., and A. Witte. "Effects of Information Provision in
a Vertically Differentiated Market." NBER Working Paper No. 6493,
1998.
Delmas, M., M. Russo, and M. Montes. "Deregulation and
Environmental Differentiation in the Electric Utility Industry."
Strategic Management Journal, 28, 2007, 189-209.
Desvousges, W. H., V. K. Smith, and H. H. Rink. "Communicating
Radon Risks Effectively: The Maryland Experience." Journal of
Public Policy and Marketing, 11, 1992, 68-78.
Dominici, F., L. Sheppard, and M. Clyde. "Health Effects of
Air Pollution: A Statistical Review." International Statistical
Review, 71, 2003, 243-276.
Edison Electric Institute. EEI's Statistical Yearbook of the
Electric Power Industry. Washington, DC: Edison Electric Institute,
2005.
Fredriksson, P. G., and D. L. Millimet. "Strategic Interaction
and the Determinants of Environmental Policy across US States."
Journal of Urban Economics, 51, 2002, 101-22.
Greenstone, M., P. Oyer, and A. Vissing-Jorensen. "Mandated
Disclosure, Stock Returns, and the 1964 Securities Act." Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 121, 2006, 399-460.
Jin, G., and P. Leslie. "The Effect of Information on Product
Quality: Evidence from Restaurant Hygiene Grade Cards." Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 118, 2003, 409-51.
Joskow, P. "Electricity Sectors in Transition." Energy
Journal, 19(2), 1998, 25-52.
Healy, P., and K. Palepu. "Information Asymmetry, Corporate
Disclosure, and the Capital Markets: A Review of the Empirical
Disclosure Literature." Journal of Accounting and Economics, 3 l,
2001, 405-40.
Kennedy, P., B. Laplante, and J. Maxwell. "Pollution Policy:
The Role for Publicly Provided Information." Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 1994, 31-43.
Khanna, M. "Non-Mandatory Approaches to Environmental
Protection." Journal of Economic Surveys, 15, 2001, 291-324.
Khanna, M., W. Quimio, and D. Bojilova. "Toxic Release
Information: A Policy Tool for Environmental Information." Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management, 36, 1998, 243-66.
Kirchhoff, S. "Green Business and Blue Angels."
Environmental and Resource Economics, 15, 2000, 403-20.
Koenker, R. Quantile Regression. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 2005.
Koenker, R., and G. Bassett. "Regression Quantiles."
Econometrica, 46, 1978, 33-50.
--. "Robust Tests for Heteroskedasticity based on Regression
Quantiles." Econometrica, 50, 1982,43-61.
Konar, S., and M. Cohen, "Information as Regulation: The
Effect of Community Right to Know Laws on Toxic Emissions." Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management, 32, 1997, 109-24.
Lamarre, L. "Utility Customers go for the Green." EPRI Journal, 22(2), 1997, 6-15.
La Porta, R., and F. Lopez-de-Silanes. "What Works in
Securities Laws?" Journal of Finance, 61, 2006, 1-33.
Leire, C., and A. Thidell. "Product-Related Environmental
information to Guide Consumer Purchases A Review and Analysis of
Research on Perceptions, Understanding and Use Among Nordic
Consumers." Journal of Cleaner Production, 13, 2005, 1061-70.
Loureiro. M. "Rethinking New Wines: Implications of Local and
Environmentally Friendly Labels." Food Policy, 28, 2003, 547-60.
Loureiro, M., and Lotade, J. "Do Fair Trade and Eco-Labels in
Coffee Wake Up the Consumer Conscience?" Ecological Econotnics,
53(1), 2005, 129-38.
Maxwell, J., T. Lyon, and S. Hackett. "Self-Regulation and
Social Welfare: The Political Economy of Corporate
Environmentalism." Journal of Law and Economics, 43, 2000, 583-618.
Minnesota Public Utilities Commission. Order Clarifying Disclosure
Requirements and Setting Procedural Schedule. Docket No.
E,G-999/CI-00-1343, September 2002.
National Council on Competition and the Electric Industry.
"Electric Product Disclosure: A Status Report." Consumer
Information Series, 2002.
Robbins, S., and W. Werner. "Professor Stigler
Revisited." Journal of Business, 37, 1964, 406-13.
Rogers, W. "Calculation of Quantile Regression Standard
Errors." Stata Technical Bulletin, 13, 1993, 18-19.
Segerson, K., and T. Miceli. "Voluntary Environmental
Agreements: Good or Bad News for Environmental Protection?" Journal
of Environmental Economics and Management, 36, 1998, 109-130.
Shimshack, J., M. Ward, and T. Beatty. "Mercury Advisories:
Information, Education, and Fish Consumption." Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, 53, 2007, 158-79.
Stigler, G. "Public Regulation of the Securities Market."
Journal of Business, 37, 1964, 117-42.
Teisl, M., B. Roe, and R. Hicks. "Can Eco-Labels Tune a
Market? Evidence from Dolphin-Safe Labeling of Canned Tuna."
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 2002, 339-59.
Tietenberg, T. "Disclosure Strategies for Pollution
Control." Environment and Resource Economic. v, 11, 1998, 587-602.
Weil, D., A. Fung, M. Graham, and E. Fagotto. "The
Effectiveness of Regulatory Disclosure Policies." Journal of Policy
Analysis and Management, 25, 2006, 155-81.
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2009.00227.x
ABBREVIATIONS
EIA: Energy Information Administration
IREC: Interstate Renewable Energy Council
IV: Instrumental Variables
LCV: League of Conservation Voters
OLS: Ordinary Least Squares
QREG: Quantile Regression
RPS: Renewable Portfolio Standards
TRI: Toxic Release Inventory
(1.) Major electric utilities are classified as those with annual
sales or transmission service that exceeds one of the following: (1) one
million megawatt hours of total annual sales, (2) 100 megawatt hours of
annual sales for resale, (3) 500 megawatt hours of gross interchange
out, or (4) 500 megawatt hours of wheeling for others (deliveries plus
losses).
(2.) See Khanna (2001) for an excellent overview of the literature
on nonmandatory environmental policies, including information disclosure
programs.
(3.) U.S. Department of Energy, Energy Efficiency and Renewable
Energy pages. Retrieved October 2006 from
http://www.eere.energy.gov/greenpower/markets/.
(4.) Here and throughout the paper, we refer to fuels as
"clean" if they generate low levels of common air pollutants relative to fossil fuels and are not nuclear. This definition is
debatable but consistent with issuing agencies' goals that
emphasize air quality over other environmental or social objectives.
(5.) Ideally, one might also interact disclosure program variables
with deregulation indicators lo see if program responses become stronger
in restructured markets. However, since only two states implemented
disclosure without restructuring, such results are quite sensitive to
model specification and are not reported.
(6.) These factors are not literally fixed over the sample period,
but practical empirical measures vary little over our sample. For
example, data on LCV, ownership, and size exhibit no statistically
meaningful variation. Reassuringly, the inclusion or omission of these
variables with fixed effects does not affect the signs, significance, or
approximate magnitudes of any estimated coefficient.
(7.) Upwind and downwind states are determined by following
prevailing westerly, southwesterly, and southerly winds. Pollution
transport follows these winds fairly closely. See, for example, the
Ozone Transport Assessment Group's Map of Ozone Pollution
Transport, available online as the Air Quality Analysis Workgroup
Results Summary at http://capita.wust1.edu/OTAG/.
(8.) For example, Fredriksson and Millimet (2002) find a positive
association between states' environmental policies, and that
association is strongest among neighboring states. Baicker (2005) finds
strong spillover effects for neighboring states' public spending as
well. Busch and Jorgens (2005) even find a number of policy convergence
mechanisms operating across international political boundaries.
(9.) Later QREGs suggest that slope parameters are sensitive to the
distribution of the dependent variables, suggesting the presence of
heteroskedasticity.
(10.) Disaggregated results are available from the authors.
(11.) Indeed, one might expect residential and commercial customers
to have different preferences even in the absence of disclosure
programs. For example, residential customers may be more likely to
express green preferences or commercial customers may have greater
incentives to keep costs down and therefore demand more fossil fuels
than residential consumers. Alternatively, commercial consumers may be
more willing to purchase green power products to appease employees,
investors, or their own customers.
(12.) For the percent of firm's sales subject to residential
consumers, Q25 = 0.281, Q50 = 0.330, Q75 = 0.374, and Q90 = 0.430. The
marginal impacts for the program variable can be calculated as: [partial
derivative]y/[partial derivative]D - [delta] + [R.sub.[eta]]. For the
clean fuel regressions in Table 3, [delta] = -0.285 and [eta] = 1.23.
Therefore, the marginal program effect for the clean fuel regression,
evaluated at the first quartile of the residential customer variable, is
-0.285 + 1.23(0.281) = 0.061.
(13.) QREGs are increasingly used in economics, especially in areas
such as labor, education, health, and environment, where heterogeneous
responses to covariates have important implications (Cade, Terell, and
Schroeder 1999; Koenker 2005). An especially common econometric
application is censoring (Koenker 2005). Methodologically, QREG
estimates are obtained by minimizing least absolute deviations (errors)
with conventional linear programming models. Neat, closed-form solutions
are not obtained, but the intuition is very similar to OLS models that
minimize the sum of squared deviations.
(14.) In a recent meta-analysis of the air pollution epidemiology
literature, Dominici, Sheppard, and Clyde (2003) found consistent
support for upward sloping dose-response curves. Ceteris paribus,
marginal air pollution damages are greater in the neighborhood of higher
polluting facilities than in the neighborhood of lower polluting
facilities. Emissions per KWh are known to increase with fossil fuel
usage, ceteris paribus.
MAGALI DELMAS, MARIA J. MONTES-SANCHO and JAY P. SHIMSHACK *
* We thank the journal editor, two anonymous referees, and seminar
participants at the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists
(AERE) sessions at the AEA meetings, the University of Maryland, Harvard
University, Harvard's Center for Business and Government, Yale
University, the Santa Barbara Workshop on Environmental Economics, the
World Congress of Environmental and Resource Economists, the AERE
sessions at the Agricultural and Applied Economics Association (AAEA)
meetings, and the International Society for New Institutional Economics
(ISNIE) conference. Special thanks are also due to Timothy Beatty, Trudy
Cameron, Meredith Fowlie, Gary Libecap, Madhu Khanna, John Lynham, Erin
Mansur, Gib Metcalf, and Kerry Smith. J.P.S. thanks the Donald Bren School of Environmental Science and Management for space and support.
Delmas: Associate Professor, Institute of the Environment,
University of California, Los Angeles CA 90095. Phone 1-310-825-9310,
Fax 1-310-825-9663, E-mail
[email protected]
Montes-Sancho: Assistant Professor, Department of Business
Administration, Carlos III University, C/Madrid 126, Getafe, 28903
Madrid, Spain. Phone 34-91-624-8639, Fax 34-91-624-9607, E-mail
[email protected]
Shimshack. Assistant Professor, Department of Economics, Tulane
University, New Orleans, LA 70118. Phone 1-504-862-8353, Fax
1-504-865-5869, E-mail jshimsha@ tulane.edu
TABLE 1
Mean Fuel Mix Percentage Statistics: Firms Subject to Disclosure
versus Firms Not Subject to Disclosure
First Period Last Period
Group (Month 1) (Month 108) Difference
Clean fuels
Firms not subject to .121 (0.049) .113 (0.050) -.008 (0.004)
disclosure during
the sample period
Firms subject to .104 (0.029) .109 (0.031) +.005 (0.022)
disclosure during
the sample period
Fossil fuels
Firms not subject to .754 (0.052) .774 (0.053) +.020 (0.018)
disclosure during
the sample period
Firms subject to .701 (0.035) .698 (0.042) -.003 (0.034)
disclosure during
the sample period
TABLE 2
Firm-Level Regression Results: Aggregate
Dependent Variable: Percentage of Fuel
Mix Attributable to Fossil Fuels
Instrumental
Variables
Variable Description Linear Regression Regression
Disclosure program -0.057 *** (-8.39) -0.227 ** (-2.45)
Deregulation 0.016 *** (3.14) 0.077 ** (2.33)
Season 2 dummy 0.004 (1.15) 0.005 (1.25)
Season 3 dummy 0.016 *** (4.49) 0.017 *** (4.48)
Season 4 dummy -0.001 (-0.23) 0.002 (0.38)
Year dummies 8-year FEs 8-year FEs
Fixed effects 144 firm-level FEs 144 firm-level FEs
Dependent Variable: Percentage of Fuel
Mix Attributable to Clean Fuels
Instrumental
Variables
Variable Description Linear Regression Regression
Disclosure program 0.022 *** (4.86) 0.268 *** (3.43)
Deregulation -0.005 (-1.09) -0.094 *** (-3.21)
Season 2 dummy 0.002 (0.51) 0.001 (0.24)
Season 3 dummy -0.013 *** (-4.10) -0.014 *** (-3.99)
Season 4 dummy -0.002 (-0.72) -0.006 (-1.56)
Year dummies 8-year FEs 8-year FEs
Fixed effects 144 firm-level FEs 144 firm-level FEs
Notes: The dependent variables are the percentage of fuel mix
attributable to the source indicated in the column heading. The key
independent variable, the disclosure program variable, ranges from 0
to 1. It indicates the percentage of firm sales subject to operational
disclosure programs. All analyses consist of 14,168 observations from
145 firms over the 108 sample months. FE indicates fixed effects.
**, *** indicate statistical significance at the 5%, and 1% levels.
TABLE 3
Disclosure and Customer Composition Instrumental Variable
Regression Results
Dependent variables
Percent Fossil Percent Clean
Fuels Fuels
Percent of sales to -0.009 (-0.05) -0.672 *** (-3.85)
residential
Disclosure program -0.788 *** (-3.15) -0.285 (-1.27)
Disclosure X residential 1.07 *** (3.16) 1.23 *** (2.90)
interaction
[X = multi sign]
Deregulation 0.156 *** (2.78) -0.027 (-0.65)
Season dummies 3 season dummies 3 season dummies
Year dummies 8 year dummies 8 year dummies
Fixed effects 142 firm-level FEs 142 firm-level FEs
Dependent
variables
Percent Nuclear
Percent of sales to 0.430 ** (2.53)
residential
Disclosure program 0.907 *** (3.58)
Disclosure X residential -1.60 *** (-4.34)
interaction
[X = multi sign]
Deregulation -0.150 *** (-2.76)
Season dummies 3 season dummies
Year dummies 8 year dummies
Fixed effects 142 firm-level FEs
Notes: The dependent variables are the percentage of fuel mix
attributable to the source indicated in the column heading. The key
independent variable, the disclosure program variable, ranges from 0
to 1. It indicates the percentage of firm sales subject to operational
disclosure programs. Analyses use 13,957 observations from 143 firms
over the 108 sample months. Two firms are missing residential data.
FE indicates fixed effects.
**, *** indicate statistical significance at the 5%, and 1%, levels.
TABLE 4
Conditional QREGs: Fossil Fuels
Standard QREG
Q20 Q30 Q40
Disclosure -.323 *** -.294 *** -.201 ***
program (-19.9) (-19.2) (-13.5)
Season 2 -.001 .024 .023
dummy (-0.02) (1.60) (1.61)
Season 3 .056 *** .049 *** .041 ***
dummy (3.51) (3.33) (2.89)
Season 4 .001 -.001 .012
dummy (0.04) (-0.01) (0.86)
Year 8 year 8 year 8 year
dummies dummies dummies dummies
Standard QREG
Q50 Q60
Disclosure -.149 *** -.017 ***
program (-21.1) (-19.2)
Season 2 .015 .001
dummy (2.16) (0.01)
Season 3 .019 *** .001
dummy (2.79) (0.01)
Season 4 -.010 .001
dummy (-1.47) (0.01)
Year 8 year 8 year
dummies dummies dummies
Instrumental Variable QREG
Q20 Q30 Q40
Disclosure -.525 *** -.985 -.467 ***
program (-9.18) (-0.04) (-9.34)
Season 2 .003 .001 .018
dummy (0.18) (0.01) (1.64)
Season 3 .040 .025 .033 ***
dummy (2.40) (0.30) (3.22)
Season 4 .026 .003 .017
dummy (1.58) (0.03) (1.60)
Year 8 year 8 year 8 year
dummies dummies dummies dummies
Instrumental Variable QREG
Q50 Q60
Disclosure -.326 *** .094
program (-4.35) (0.24)
Season 2 .002 -.001
dummy (0.20) (-0.02)
Season 3 .002 .001
dummy (0.21) (0.02)
Season 4 .002 -.001
dummy (0.20) (-0.02)
Year 8 year 8 year
dummies dummies dummies
Notes: The dependent variables are the percentage of fuel mix
attributable to the source indicated in the column heading. The key
independent variable, the disclosure program variable, ranges from 0
to 1. It indicates the percentage of firm sales subject to operational
disclosure programs. All analyses consist of 14,168 observations from
145 firms over the 108 sample months. QREGs omit the deregulation
variable due to the limited sampling variability near the tails.
*** Statistical significance at the 1% level.