Climbing to the top? Foreign direct investment and property rights.
Ali, Fathi ; Fiess, Norbert ; Macdonald, Ronald 等
I. INTRODUCTION
The impact of foreign direct investment (FDI) on host countries is
a well-researched topic and the bulk of the literature focuses on the
impact of FDI on economic growth. However, with the rapid growth of FDI
inflows during the 1990s and the growing competition among countries to
attract FDI inflows, researchers are showing substantial interest in
studying new aspects of the impact of FDI on host countries. Most of the
work in this area argues that greater competition to attract FDI has led
to "bidding wars" where governments in host countries have
been forced to adopt policies with an adverse economic impact, such as a
reduction in tax rates, deterioration in environmental standards, and of
workers' rights (see e.g., Oman 2000). Some of these adverse
impacts, known as the "race to the bottom" effects, are
supported by empirical evidence. For example, Garretsen and Peeters
(2007) find that FDI inflows promote lower corporate tax rates. However,
foreign investors not only search for lower tax rates but also demand
better institutional quality. Governments competing to attract FDI may
therefore have an incentive to supply a more efficient institutional
framework. FDI may therefore contribute to economic development through
improving institutional quality in the host country. This aspect of FDI
effects has to our knowledge not been studied previously.
Institutional quality has been identified as one of the most
important, if not the most important, determinant of economic growth.
Hall and Jones (1999) find that differences in income growth are largely
explained by differences in institutional quality. Knack and Keefer
(1995) identify property rights as crucial for growth and investment.
Although there is general consensus that institutions matter for growth,
little is known about how efficient institutions are created and what
explains differences in institutional quality between and within
countries. The empirical evidence on the determinants of property rights
links institutions to culture, history, and geography (see e.g., Levine
2005). If property rights are mainly determined by culture, history, or
geography, what then explains institutional changes over time? Or, put
differently, if property rights were only determined by time-invariant
factors, there would be little scope for developing countries to achieve
high-quality institutions. There appears to be a clear need to link
institutions to time varying, if not controllable, variables. Such
evidence would provide a basis for institutional reform that enables
developing countries to build high-quality institutions.
The hypothesis that this article introduces and empirically
investigates is whether FDI inflows have a positive impact on property
rights in the host country. Testing this hypothesis has both academic
and practical merit. First, it explores a new dimension of how FDI
impacts the host country. Second, it provides an explanation as to why
property rights differ across countries.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section II
introduces arguments that link property rights to FDI inflows. Our
empirical results are presented in Section III and Section IV concludes.
II. FDI AND PROPERTY RIGHTS
There is growing evidence that greater integration into the global
economy impacts institutional quality. For example, Bonaglia, Braga de
Macedo, and Bussolo (2001) provide robust empirical support that higher
import openness lowers corruption. Li and Reuveny (2003) establish that
trade openness and portfolio investment have a negative impact on
democracy, whereas FDI has a positive one. Larrain and Tavares (2004)
present evidence that FDI is a robust predictor of corruption and that
larger FDI inflows reduce the level of corruption in the host country.
A1-Marhubi (2004) finds that trade openness has a positive impact on
governance indictors and concludes that openness may encourage
governments to adopt better governance to reap the full benefits of the
integration into the world economy. Mosley and Uno (2007) find FDI to be
positively and significantly correlated with labor rights, whereas trade
openness has a negative impact.
We argue that FDI affects property rights both through the demand
and supply channels. Investors demand property fight protection to
capture potential rents and benefits; governments, on the other hand,
may be induced to supply property rights when it is advantageous to do
so.
Why would foreign investors create a demand for better
institutions? On one hand, there is growing evidence that foreign
investors consider institutional quality, especially property rights, as
an important factor when allocating FDI (Ali, Fiess, and MacDonald
2008). On the other hand, Poynter (1985) argues that multinational
corporations attempt to change government policy on host countries by
entering domestic political processes, and Navaretti and Venables (2006)
find that foreign investors at times rely on domestic interest groups
with a vested interest to pressurize government to change the FDI
incentives to their favor. Moreover, according to Libman (2006),
multinational corporations have played an important role in shaping the
institutional reform agenda in some transitional countries. It seems
therefore plausible that foreign investors, with a lasting commitment to
the host country, have an incentive to lobby for institutional change
when faced with poor property rights and an inefficient business
climate. Hence, FDI inflows should create demand for better
institutional quality and property rights.
Why would governments respond to the demand of foreign investors?
North (1981) argues that the government acts as a discriminating monopolist, offering property rights protection to different
constituents' groups in return for tax revenue. In this context,
governments might find it beneficial to protect the property rights of
foreign investors to attract further FDI inflows which ultimately
strengthen the government's position. Although this might explain
why governments protect property rights and enforce contracts, it does
not explain why governments would commit to this role if they found it
more advantageous to renege on their commitments; North and Weingast
(1989) argue, for example, that governments may try to alter property
rights after the investments took place.
Reputation and institutional arrangements may prevent governments
from reneging on their commitments, or at least make it costly for them
to do so. Concerns that existing investors may stop reinvesting or even
consider reallocating, while FDI from new investors may not materialize,
make governments value the long run costs of reneging on their
commitment. Thus, building a good reputation can induce governments to
honor commitments today as to retain the opportunity to attract FDI
inflows in the future. Bullow and Rogoff (1989) show that reputation
alone may not be sufficient to prevent governments from reneging on
commitments and more complex institutional arrangement are necessary. In
this context, Buthe and Milner (2005) stress that governments try to
assure foreign direct investors about their commitments by binding
themselves by various kinds of agreements and treaties, such as
bilateral investment treaties, preferential trade agreements, and
multilateral agreements. These international commitments are more
credible than domestic commitments, as reneging is more costly.
Since the beginning of the 1980s many countries have introduced
changes to their regulatory frameworks to create strong incentives for
foreign investors. In all, 194 out of 208 changes to FDI regulations in
71 countries aimed at created a more favorable climate for FDI in 2001
alone (United Nations Conference on Trade and Development 2002). In
addition, many countries strengthened their commitment to a better
regulatory framework for FDI by entering into bilateral investment
treaties; the number of such treaties has increased rapidly over recent
decades. It seems plausible to us that these changes to domestic
regulation and increased commitments to investment treaties at least in
part reflect host governments' responding to foreign
investors' demand for a better investment climate, including for
better institutions.
In sum, we expect that in a search for higher profits foreign
investors will demand more secure property rights; host governments,
aware of the potential benefits of FDI for growth and development, will
respond. In an attempt to retain established FDI and attract new FDI,
governments will further try to signal a high level of commitment by
binding themselves through various international treaties. It seems
therefore entirely plausible to expect that FDI inflows have a positive
impact on institutional quality and in particular on the protection of
property rights.
III. EMPIRICAL RESULTS
The previous section laid out a hypothesis about the impact of FDI
inflows on property rights. We now attempt to empirically verify this
hypothesis. To ensure comparability of our analysis with existing work
on the determinants of institutional quality, we first replicate the
cross-sectional analysis of La Porta et al. (1999), Beck, Demirguc-Kunt,
and Levine (2003), and Levine (2005). We then expand on their work in
several directions, which significantly adds to the literature on
determinants of institutional quality and property rights. In
particular, we extend the cross-sectional analysis in La Porta et al.
(1999), Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2003), and Levine (2005) to a
dynamic panel setting which allows us to study variations over time. We
further control for the possibility that some of the regressors, in
particular FDI, could be endogenous. Moreover, as North (1990) argues
that previous levels of institutional quality determine current levels
(see below), the use of a dynamic panel framework will enable us to test
this hypothesis. Finally, to check the robustness of our results, we
present results generated from alternative estimation techniques.
According to La Porta et al. (1999), theories that explain
determinants of institutional quality, and in particular property rights
protection and contract enforcement, can be grouped into three broad
categories: economic, political, and cultural. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and
Levine (2003) and Levine (2005) add the endowments view. Although
economic theory stresses the role of social efficiency when creating
institutions, political theory focuses on redistribution. Cultural
theories emphasize the role of social beliefs, and endowment theory
points to geographic determinants of institutions, in particular natural
resource endowments and climate. (1)
We estimate the following model:
Proty = [B.sub.1] + [B.sub.2]polit + [B.sub.3]Econ + [B.sub.4]FDI +
[B.sub.5]Cultr + [B.sub.6]Endo + [B.sub.7]V + [epsilon].
where Proty is the property rights index.
Econ is a vector of variables that captures the impact of economic
development. Demsetz (1967) and North (1981) argue that institutions are
created when it is efficient to do so. To repeat the example provided by
La Porta et al. (1999), private property rights are created when land
becomes scarce and when their benefits exceed the cost of their
enforcement. As institutions are considered generally efficient, poor
property rights are taken as a reflection of insufficient resources and
high costs, rather than one of bad institutions. Economic development is
accredited with greater demand for good institutions, and governments
will oblige if benefits exceed enforcement costs.
Polit is a vector of variables of political determinants of
institutions. According to Marx (1872), North (1990), and Olson (1993),
institutions are designed by the elite to retain existing power
structures, and history provides many examples where institutions were
shaped by the ability of powerful groups to extract rents, rather than
by social efficiency: Russian czars, Ottoman sultans, and Tokugawa
shoguns all created institutions that increased their absolute authority
and control, resulting in a poor definition and enforcement of property
rights (see La Porta et al. 1999 and references therein). Political
divergence within a society (social, ethnic, class, or other) is hence
linked to a negative impact on government performance and property
rights enforcement.
Political theories further argue that civil law, compared with
common law, has an adverse impact on property rights. Common Law was
partly developed to limit the authority of the crown and to protect
property rights; civil law was developed in an effort to restrain
sovereigns' authority over their subjects (Levine 2005).
Cultr is a vector of variables associated with Culture Theory.
According to Weber (1958), Banfield (1958), Putnam (1993), and Landes
(1998), institutions are a reflection of the beliefs in a society. In
some societies, intolerance and distrust run so high that governments
cannot function effectively, which produces poor institutional quality
and insufficient property rights protection (La Porta et al. 1999).
Landes (1998) argues that Catholicism and Islam are hostile to
institutional development. The reason for this, according to Landes
(1998) and Putnam (1993), is that these two religions tend to foster
"vertical bonds of authority," which limits the security of
property rights and private contracting (Levine 2005).
Endo is a vector of variables representing the endowments view. The
endowment theory, represented by Engerman and Sokoloff (1997) and
Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001), states that institutions today
have been shaped by factor endowments and initial conditions at the time
of colonization. Two versions of the endowment theory exist: Engerman
and Sokoloff (1997) emphasize that natural resource riches often gave
rise to highly unequal societies, where the ruling elite prevented the
development of egalitarian institutions and favored institutions that
fostered their hegemony (Levine 2005). Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson
(2001) establish a link between settler strategies of European
colonialists and institutional quality in developing countries today. In
areas where disease produces high mortality rates, Europeans did not
settle, but set up "extractive" colonies (e.g., Congo). The
institutions of these "extractive colonies" favored the elite
and facilitated wealth extraction; institutions that supported property
rights were only created in areas where European colonists actually
settled (e.g., Australia).
FDI is the ratio of FDI inflows to gross domestic product. V is a
vector of control variables and [epsilon] is the disturbance term.
A. Results from Cross-sectional Estimations
To investigate the impact of FDI inflows on property rights, we
first make use of the same data set as La Porta et al. (1999). To
measure property rights protection, La Porta et al. (1999) use the
Property Rights Index in 1997. This index broadly tracks the degree of
legal protection of private property; the extent to which the government
protects and enforces laws that protect private property; the
probability that the government will expropriate private property; and a
country's legal protection of private property. This index takes
values between 1 and 5, with higher values indicating greater protection
of private property.
As already mentioned above, La Porta et al. (1999) empirically
evaluate the contribution of political, cultural, and economic theories
in explaining institutional quality; they also control for geography.
Political theory is tested by the degree of ethnolinguistic
fractionalization as well as the origin of commercial law. The
ethnolinguistic fractionalization index is an average of several
measures of ethnic diversity. The index ranges from 0 to 1 and is
expected to have a negative impact on property rights. The higher the
ethnic and linguistic division, the poorer are property rights. A
country's Company Law or Commercial Code can stem from five
different origins: (1) English Common Law; (2) French Commercial Code;
(3) German Commercial Code; (4)Scandinavian Commercial Code; and
(5)Socialist/Communist laws. Given their historical context, it is
expected that relative to English Law, French, German, Scandinavian, and
Socialist Laws have a negative impact on property rights.
A country's relative share of Roman Catholics, Protestants,
and Muslims (religious composition of population) is taken as a proxy
for cultural determinants of institutional quality (La Porta et al.
1999). It is expected that relative to Protestantism, Catholicism and
Islam have a negative impact on property rights.
La Porta et al. (1999) use the logarithm of the average of GNP per
capita in current U.S. dollars during 1970-1995 as a proxy for economic
determinants of institutional quality. Per capita income is expected to
have a positive impact on the property rights index. La Porta et al.
(1999) further use latitude, scaled to take values between 0 and 1, to
control for geography. They argue that latitude impacts institutional
quality as more temperate regions have more productive agriculture and
healthier climates, which allowed them to develop better economically
and possibly also institutionally.
The results are summarized in Table 1. Model 1 replicates model 3
of Table 4 in La Porta et al. (1999). Model 1 is our benchmark model to
which we add the other variables discussed above and in which we
explicitly test the impact of FDI on property rights. Model 1 replicates
La Porta et al. (1999)'s finding that political variables,
represented by ethnolinguistic fractionalization and French legal
origin, have the expected negative impact on property rights. In model
2, we control for the impact of economic and geographic factors by
including log of GNP per capita and latitude. The results show that both
of them have the expected positive impact on property rights; however,
ethnolinguistic fractionalization loses its significance. In model 3, we
add the average of FDI-GDP ratio during 1970-1995 to test the impact of
FDI on property rights index. Model 3 shows that FDI has a positive and
significant impact on property rights. The fact that FDI maintains its
significance after controlling for the income level means that FDI
affects property rights beyond its impact on economic development and
income level. We retain FDI as a regressor in all further model
specifications. In model 4, we control for the impact of cultural
factors on property rights by including the percentage of the population
which belongs to Catholic, Muslim, or other non-Protestant faith. The
results show that FDI does not lose significance once we control for the
cultural determinants of property rights; however, the results show that
culture factors do not have significant impact on property rights once
we control for other factors.
Model 5 shows the results based on data from Beck, Demirguc-Kunt,
and Levine (2003) and Levine (2005). Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine
(2003) and Levine (2005) use the same data as La Porta et al. (1999) but
restrict their sample to countries of either British or French legal
origin, as most countries are based on these legal traditions, which are
also the most distinct.
The other difference between La Porta et al. (1999) and Beck,
Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2003) and Levine (2005) is that the latter
two studies introduce the endowment factor as an additional determinant
of institutional quality. Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2003) and
Levine (2005) follow Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001) and use the
settler mortality rate, the log of the annualized deaths per thousand
European soldiers in European colonies in the early 19th century, to
test endowment theory. The model shows that French legal origin has the
expected negative impact on property rights, whereas Ethnic
Fractionalization has the expected negative sign but is insignificant.
The results also show that FDI maintains a significant and positive
impact on property rights. Model 5 shows that non-Protestant religions
have a negative but insignificant impact on property rights index.
Settler mortality has a negative and statistically significant
correlation with Property Rights, which confirms the endowment theory
expectations.
Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2003) and Levine (2005) argue that
the longer a country has spent in independence, the more time it has had
to develop sound institutions and hence the better its property rights
might have become. They therefore use the percentage of years since 1776
that a country has been independent to control for the impact of
independence on property rights. The results show that independence does
not have a significant impact on property rights, though it has the
expected sign.
So far there has been no consideration of the endogeneity problem.
It should be noticed that the above results may be subject to
endogeneity bias. In fact, there is a large body of literature showing
that FDI is determined by institutional quality and property rights.
Thus, in model 6, we have tried to control for the endogeneity by using
an instrumental variable (IV) approach. The choice of appropriate
instruments should be driven by the literature on FDI determinants. A
good instrument should be highly correlated with FDI but not with the
disturbance term in the property rights regression. Several empirical
studies show that real exchange rates and infrastructure quality are
among the significant determents of FDI inflows (Blonigen 1997; Dunning and Lundan 2008; Froot and Stein 1991). Therefore, we instrumented FDI
with real exchange rates and infrastructure measured by the number of
landlines per thousand people, in addition to continental dummies for
Africa and Latin America. The result of the IV regression, reported in
Table 1 model 6, shows that the estimated coefficient on FDI is still
significantly positive, which can be interpreted as the impact of FDI on
property rights is robust to the endogeneity problem.
The above results clearly show that the correlation between FDI and
property rights is highly significant in a cross-sectional setting.
These results can be interpreted as offering baseline support to our
hypothesis that FDI has a positive impact on institutional quality and
that countries that attracted more FDI enjoy greater property rights
protection. However, these results are not without limitations, as they
do not consider changes in property rights over time. This issue is
taken up in more detail below.
B. Results from Panel Data Estimations
The cross-sectional approach helps us to explain the differences in
property rights across countries, that is, identifying which
characteristics explain why one country has a higher degree of property
rights protection than another. A panel framework is, however, needed to
assess bow institutions are affected by FDI over time, and how different
determinants interact dynamically. To investigate the time dimension of
variations in property rights, we use a sample of 70 developing
countries over the period 1981-2005. Data availability restricts the
sample size and the time period covered. Appendix A describes the sample
and data sources used in the subsequent analysis. Property rights index
is constructed by combining two indexes: Law and Order and Investment
Profile, both of which are published by Political Risk Services Group.
The index is scaled to take values between 0 and 12, with higher values
meaning better protection of property rights. Law and Order index
assesses the strength and impartiality of the legal system, popular
observance of the law, and the effectiveness of sanctions. Investment
Profile index assesses contract viability, expropriation risk, and
profits repatriation.
We construct a panel dataset where data are averaged over each of
the 5-year periods between 1981 and 2005. Within our sample, some
countries have made remarkable improvements in their property rights
indices, whereas others experienced deterioration (Table 2 and Figure A1
in Appendix A). Morocco's property rights index, for example,
increased from 4.5 in 1981-1985 to 9.94 in 2000-2005. Bolivia, which
started from a very low score of 2.12 in the 1980s, reached a high score
of 7.4 in 2000-2005, and Chile and Tunisia witnessed similar large
increases. Zimbabwe's score, on the other hand, declined from 4.25
in 1984-1985 to 2.47 in 2000-2005, and Cote d'Ivoire and Venezuela
also experienced a fall in their property rights indices.
We start our panel analysis with a random effects model. This model
specification allows us to capture the impact of the time-invariant
variables that represent culture, political, and endowment theories. One
problem with this technique is that it does not allow for the
endogeneity of some of regressors, particularly FDI. To reduce the
problem of endogeneity, we have lagged all endogenous variables for one
period, that is, 5 years. We also use a system generalized method of
moment (GMM) estimator where lagged differences and levels of the
endogenous variables are used as instruments.
The results are reported in Table 3. Model 1 includes political
variables, ethnolinguistic fractionalization index, and French legal
origin in addition to lagged FDI inflows. Both of the political
variables have the expected sign, although not statistically
significant. FDI has the expected positive sign and is highly
significant. In model 2, we add variables representing cultural theory;
the results show that Catholicism has a negative and significant
correlation with the property rights index, whereas Islam has no
significant correlation with property rights. The FDI term is still
significant and positive and ethnolinguistic fractionalization index
becomes significantly related to property rights, whereas French legal
origin dummy becomes positively but insignificantly correlated with
property rights.
Model 3 controls for endowment and economic effects, by including
settler mortality and GDP per capita growth. (2) The results show that
while settler mortality has a negative but insignificant impact, lagged
economic growth has a positive and significant impact on property
rights, which confirms economic theory. FDI remains significant even
after controlling for the impact of economic growth, which supports the
claim that FDI influences property rights beyond its contribution to
economic growth and development.
Using settler mortality reduces the sample size from 70 to 57
countries as we have only limited country coverage for settler
mortality. To deal with this problem, we replace the settler mortality
rate with the ratio of primary exports to GDP. This variable is widely
used in the literature as a measure of natural resources abundance
(Sachs and Warner 1995), and as such it also accords with Engerman and
Sokoloff's endowments view. Model 4 shows the results; the
coefficient on primary export ratio suggests that natural resource
endowments have a negative correlation with property rights, which give
some support to Engerman and Sokoloff's view; however, it is not
significant. Controlling for natural resources endowment does not affect
the significance of FDI; interestingly the dummy for Catholicism becomes
statistically significant.
Rodrik (2000) argues that openness to trade could help developing
countries to build sound institutions. A growing number of imperial
evidence shows that trade has a positive impact on some aspects of
institutions such as corruption (see e.g., Al-Marhubi 2004; Bonaglia,
Braga de Macedo, and Bussolo 2001). Thus, in model 5, we control for
trade openness by including the lagged trade GDP ratio. The result shows
that the trade ratio has a positive and significant impact on property
rights; the negative impact of natural resource abundance becomes
significant, whereas the dummy for Catholicism loses its significance.
Interestingly, FDI maintains its positive and significant correlation
with property rights, whereas political and cultural variables lose
their significance.
In model 6, we use fixed effects to investigate the role of FDI in
determining property rights. This technique concentrates on
within-country variations and provides insights as to how variations in
FDI explain variations of property rights in each country around its own
mean. Fixed effects allow us to investigate what causes property rights
to change over time within each country. However, this advantage comes
at the cost of dropping time-invariant variables. Model 6 shows that FDI
remains significant, and so does GDP growth. The trade ratio also enters
positively and significantly. This result suggests that these three
variables did play a positive role in determining changes in property
rights index during the period studied. (3) The endowment variable, on
the other hand, loses significance, although it maintains a negative
sign. This may be due to the fact that the primary exports to GDP ratio
varies little over time. This implies that the endowments view can
explain differences in property rights across countries, but not over
time.
So far, we have dealt with the endogeneity of FDI by using the
lagged value of FDI inflows. A more appropriate way to address
endogeneity is to use an IV approach. Arellano and Bond (1991) show that
in a dynamic panel setting, lagged differences of endogenous variables
can be used as effective instruments. Including the lagged value of the
property rights index further allows us to study to what extent past
institutional quality determines present institutional quality. North
(1990) argues that history matters for institutional change, in a sense
that institutional quality in the past has an impact in the current
institutional quality. North states that the institutional framework
provides society with opportunities (both political and economic) and
agents try to benefit from these opportunities within the existing
institutional framework; they, however, also try to maximize profits by
altering the existent institutional framework. North (1990) argues that
the very nature of the existing institutional quality may provide
incentives for agents to alter it. To illustrate, in an inefficient
institutional framework, certain organizations will form with the
specific purpose to benefit from the opportunities offered by this
inefficient framework; these new organizations will then actually devote
resources to maintain these inefficiencies. This mechanism, according to
North (1990), explains the persistence of inefficient institutions in
developing countries. On the other hand, organizations which are
embedded in an efficient institutional framework will devote resources
to maintain efficiency, as this serves their interests. According to
North (1990), this mechanism explains the development of the American
economy in the 19th century. Based on these arguments, one would expect
that lagged property rights have a positive impact on the current
institutional quality, as efficient institutions provide agents with
incentives to further increase the level of efficiency, promoting even
more efficient institutions in the future.
Model 7 shows the results from system GMM estimation. In this
model, we include the lagged dependent variable--the property rights
index--as an additional explanatory variable. In this specification, the
lagged dependent variables and the time-invariant country-specific error
terms are correlated, and both random and fixed effects models produce
inconsistent estimations. Arellano and Bond (1991) solve this problem by
using GMM. They eliminate the country-specific error term by taking the
first difference of the model and then use the lagged levels of the
dependent variable as instruments for the first differences of the
dependent variable. The same procedure can be applied to any endogenous
variable within the set of explanatory variables. This technique is
often called difference GMM (Baum 2005). Arellano and Bover (1995) and
Blundell and Bond (1998) acknowledge a potential weakness in difference
GMM, since the lagged levels are often poor instruments for the
first-differenced variables (Baum 2005). They propose, therefore, to use
lagged levels and lagged differences as instruments. This technique is
generally referred to as system GMM. Both difference and system GMM
require an absence of second-order serial correlation in the residuals
of the differenced model. As standard errors of the difference and
system GMM estimators are shown to have a severe downward bias (Baum
2005), Windmeijer (2005)'s finite-sample correction is applied to
correct for this bias. A Hansen test of the over-identifying
restrictions is used to test for overall appropriateness of the
instruments.
In model 7, we treated FDI inflows, economic growth, and the trade
ratio as endogenous variables. We find that the basic assumption of no
second-order serial correlation is satisfied. The Hansen test approves
the validity of the instruments for model 7. The results show that the
lagged value of property fights has a positive and significant impact on
the current level of property fights index, which supports North's
hypothesis. More importantly, FDI still has a positive and significant
impact on institutional quality index. Economic growth maintains its
significance, whereas trade ratio loses its significance. Interestingly,
all culture and political variables lose their significance apart from
French legal origin, which becomes significant but with the wrong sign.
This can be interpreted as the evidence on political and culture theory
is sensitive to model specifications or sample changes. This may call
for other proxies of political factors. One attempt could be by
replacing the ethnolinguistic fractionalization index, which primarily
measures ethnic division, with an index that captures the degree of
tension resulting from racial, ethnic, or language divisions. (4) It
seems reasonable to assume that the degree of social tension that
results from ethnic and religious division is more important for
institutional quality than ethnic division per se. One can cite many
cases in developed countries where ethnic linguistic groups live in
relative harmony without negative implications on institutional quality.
For example, Canada and Belgium have ethnolinguistic indices of 0.376
and 0.364, which are above the sample average, but have ones of the
highest score of property rights index, 10.73 and 11.95, respectively.
An additional advantage of using ethnic tension index rather than ethnic
division is the former is time variant and hence allows us to study the
impact of political variables on institutional quality over time.
The results are shown in model 8. As can be seen from model 8, this
change has led to substantial improvements in our results. Political
factors, represented by ethnic tension index, now have the expected
sign: improvements in the ethnic tension index have a positive and
significant impact on property rights. (5) However, French legal origin
is still significant but with the wrong sign. More interestingly,
culture factors become significant with the fight signs and FDI
maintains its significance, which can be viewed as additional support
for our main hypothesis.
To summarize our results, FDI appears to be a robust predictor of
property rights. The impact of FDI on institutional quality is not
sensitive to model specifications, control variables, or estimation
techniques. This supports our hypothesis that FDI inflows have a
positive impact on the quality of property rights.
C. Robustness Check: FDI Stock versus Flows
The previous analysis is based on data of FDI inflows. Although it
can be argued that FDI inflows capture the degree of the mobility of
FDI, and hence the pressure that host governments face to improve
institutions, it could be possible that property rights in a given host
country depend more on the stock of foreign investment than on their
flows. The argument could be made that FDI stocks measure the total
stake of foreign investors, whereas flows only measure an increase in
that stake and may capture investors who have not invested previously in
the country at all. As such, FDI flows could be more of a response to
improvements of property fights protection, while the quality of
property fights protection has been influenced by the current stock of
FDI. In order to check the robustness of our results we reran our
regressions with FDI stocks rather than flow data as the independent
variable. The results show that using FDI stocks also supports the
hypothesis that FDI has a positive impact on institutional quality in
the host country (see Tables Al and A2 in Appendix A).
IV. CONCLUSION
This article introduces a hypothesis about the impact of FDI
inflows on property fights in host countries and provides an empirical
assessment. The results show that FDI inflows have a positive and highly
significant impact on property fights. These results seem very robust
and are not affected by model specification, control variables, or
estimation techniques. The main conclusion of this article is that FDI
inflows can explain differences in property fights across countries and
over time. In particular, FDI inflows have a positive influence on
property fights in the host country.
This conclusion has several important implications for academic and
practical purposes. First, it reveals a new mechanism by which FDI can
positively affect economic performance in the host country; given the
importance of institutional quality in determining economic growth, this
new mechanism may be comparable (i.e., similar in amount and quality) to
other positive effects of FDI. Our results suggest that foreign
investors do not only import high-quality manufacturing and production
technology to the host country but also import high-quality social
technology and institutions.
Our findings are also a significant step toward a better
understanding of the determinants of institutional quality and
institutional change. Integration into the world economy and FDI inflows
in particular are established as new determinants of property rights. A
policy framework and a business environment which are more conducive to
attracting FDI are therefore also expected to improve institutional
quality.
ABBREVIATIONS
FDI: Foreign Direct Investment
IV: Instrumental Variable
GMM: Generalized Method of Moment
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2010.00319.x
APPENDIX A: SAMPLE AND SOURCES OF DATA
The analysis covers 70 developing countries over the period
1981-2005. All the variables are computed as 5-year averages, covering
the periods 1981-1985, 1986-1990, 1991-1995, 1996-2000, and 2001-2005.
Countries in the sample: Angola, Argentina, Bangladesh, Bolivia,
Botswana, Brazil, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Chile, Colombia, Congo Dem.
Rep., Congo Rep., Costa Rica, Cote d'Ivoire, Dominican Republic,
Ecuador, Egypt Arab Rep., El Salvador, Ethiopia, Gabon, The Gambia,
Ghana, Guatemala, Guinea, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hong Kong, India,
Indonesia, Jamaica, Jordan, Kenya, Korea Rep., Lebanon, Madagascar,
Malawi, Malaysia, Mali, Mexico, Morocco, Mozambique, Namibia, Nicaragua,
Niger, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru,
Philippines, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Singapore, South Africa, Sri Lanka,
Sudan, Suriname, Syrian Arab Republic, Tanzania, Thailand, Trinidad and
Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, Uruguay, Venezuela RB, Zambia, and
Zimbabwe.
[FIGURE A1 OMITTED]
Variable Definition Source
FDI Net FDI inflows as United Nations,
Percentage of GDP UNCTAD's World
Investment
Directory
GDP growth GDP Growth (annual %) World Bank, World
Development
Indicators
Property rights Average of indices Calculated from ICRG
of Law and Order & Data, PRS Group
Investment Profile,
scale 0-12.
Ethnic tensions Tensions among ethnic Calculated from ICRG
groups, scale 0-12 Data, PRS Group
Natural resources Ratio of primary World Bank, World
abundance exports to GDP Development
Indicators
Trade Export + imports as World Bank, World
percentage of GDP Development
Indicators
FDIS Inward FDI stock as United Nations,
percentage of GDP UNCTAD's World
Investment
Directory.
TABLE A1
Property Rights and STOCK FDI: Cross-sectional Regressions
(Dependent Variable: Property Rights Index 1997) (a)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
OLS OLS OLS
Ethnic fractionalization -0.826 *** 0.332 0.282
(-2.76) (1.26) (1.03)
French legal origin -0.704 *** -0.559 *** -0.517 ***
(-3.51) (-3.84) (-3.33)
Socialist legal origin -1.386 *** -1.114 *** -1.053 ***
(-3.65) (-4.26) (-3.81)
German legal origin 1.084 *** 0.068 0.253
(4.91) (0.28) (0.93)
Scandinavian legal origin 0.879 *** -0.531 ** -0.332
(3.08) (-2.03) (-1.14)
Latitude 0.417 *** 0.382 ***
(5.79) (5.18)
Log GNP per capita 1.638 *** 1.575 ***
(3.30) (3.17)
FDIS-GDP ratio 0.006 *
(1.83)
Catholic
Muslim 0.002
Other religion 0.005
Independence
Settler mortality
Intercept 3.981 *** 0.191 0.340
(16.97) (0.38) (0.64)
No. of observations 124 124 121
F 91 48 38
Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
OLS OLS (b) IV
Ethnic fractionalization 0.354 -0.105 0.177
(1.24) (-0.26) (0.15)
French legal origin -0.568 *** -0.760 *** -0.684
(-2.92) (-2.67) (-0.85)
Socialist legal origin -1.204 ***
(-3.83)
German legal origin 0.236
(0.92)
Scandinavian legal origin -0.001
(-0.00)
Latitude 0.359 ***
(3.85)
Log GNP per capita 1.785 ***
(3.06)
FDIS-GDP ratio 0.006 0.024 *** 0.080 **
(1.62) (3.93) (2.18)
Catholic 0.006 -0.010 -0.024
(1.10) (-1.13) (-1.16)
Muslim -0.006 -0.019
(0.44) (-0.83) (-1.28)
Other religion -0.010 -0.029
(1.06) (-1.29) (-1.13)
Independence 0.701 1.645
(1.28) (1.53)
Settler mortality -0.179 ** -0.077
(-2.25) (-0.38)
Intercept 0.027 4.696 *** 4.193 **
(0.03) (6.56) (2.27)
No. of observations 121 69 36
F 29 9 6
(a) Values in parentheses are White heteroskedastic adjusted
t-values. *, **, and *** denote significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%,
respectively.
(b) FDI is instrumented by the by real exchange rate, infrastructure,
and continental dummies for Africa and Latin America. The validity of
these instruments is supported by Sargan test [chi square](3) = 5.36
(p > [chi square] = (0.147)).
TABLE A2
Property Rights and STOCK FDI: Panel Data Regressions (Dependent
Variable: Property Rights Index [1981-2005] 5-Year Intervals)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
RE (a) RE (a) RE (a)
Ethnic fractionalization -0.857 ** -1.079 ** -0.300
(-1.98) (-2.39) (-0.53)
French legal origin -0.348 0.124 0.384
(-1.21) (0.33) (0.86)
Economic growth 0.193 ***
(5.99)
FDIS-GDP ratio 0.028 *** 0.027 *** 0.027 ***
(4.53) (4.49) (5.11)
Catholic -0.013 ** -0.008
(-1.99) (-1.10)
Muslim -0.006 -0.005
(-0.98) (-0.71)
Settler mortality -0.128
(-0.87)
Resource endowments
Trade
Lagged property right
Ethnic tensions
Intercept 6.320*** 6.753 *** 6.059 ***
(17.91) (15.70) (7.59)
No. of groups 70 70 57
No. of observations 273 273 219
Wald )(2 31.54 (3) 36.74 (5) 98.04 (7)
Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
RE (a) RE (a) FE (b)
Ethnic fractionalization -0.202 -0.131
(-0.40) (-0.25)
French legal origin 0.400 0.418
(1.01) (1.05)
Economic growth 0.167 *** 0.162 *** 0.133 ***
(5.02) (4.73) (3.78)
FDIS-GDP ratio 0.033 *** 0.030 *** 0.026 ***
(5.17) (4.05) (4.02)
Catholic -0.012 * -0.010
(-1.78) (-1.59)
Muslim -0.009 -0.008
(-1.45) (-1.30)
Settler mortality
Resource endowments -0.021 * -0.024 ** -0.004
(-1.85) (-2.01) (-0.13)
Trade 0.003 0.006
(0.96) (0.86)
Lagged property right
Ethnic tensions
Intercept 5.923 *** 5.733 *** 5.020 ***
(12.27) (11.11) (10.54)
No. of groups 68 68 67
No. of observations 237 237 237
Wald )(2 74.53 (7) 85.18 (8) --
Modell Model 8
Sys GMM (c) Sys GMM (d)
Ethnic fractionalization -0.447 *
(-1.75)
French legal origin 0.340 0.525 **
(1.26) (2.34)
Economic growth 0.232 *** 0.232
(3.57) (3.62)
FDIS-GDP ratio 0.011 *** 0.007 **
(3.02) (2.00)
Catholic -0.003 -0.007*
(-0.95) (-1.94)
Muslim -0.004 -0.006*
(-0.83) (-1.76)
Settler mortality
Resource endowments -0.001 0.001
(-0.31) (0.14)
Trade -0.001 0.001
(-0.37) (0.30)
Lagged property right 0.509 *** 0.501 ***
(5.08) (5.47)
Ethnic tensions 0.267 ***
-4.94
Intercept 2.418 *** 1.417 **
-3.13 -2.18
No. of groups 67
No. of observations 237 237
Wald )(2 497.30 (12) 741.25 (12)
(a) Random effects model, z-values reported in parentheses.
(b) Fixed effects model, t-values reported in parentheses.
(c) System GMM. Arellano-Bond test for AR (2) in first differences:
z = -0.76, p > z = 0.449. Hansen test of overidentification
restrictions: [chi square](28) = 25.14, p > [chi square] = 0.620.
(d) System GMM. Arellano-Bond test for AR (2) in first differences:
z = -0.89, p > z = 0.371. Hansen test of overidentification
restrictions: [chi square](32) = 32.19, p > [chi square] = 0.457.
Models 7 and 8 include time dummies. *, **, and ***
denote significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
REFERENCES
Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. Robinson. "The Colonial
Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation."
American Economic Review, 91, 2001, 1369-401.
Ali, F., N. Fiess, and R. MacDonald. "Do Institutions matter
for Foreign Direct Investment?" Working Paper, University of
Glasgow, 2008-26, 2008.
A1-Marhubi, F. "The Determinants of Governance: A
Cross-country Analysis." Contemporary Economic Policy, 22, 2004,
394-406.
Arellano, M., and S. Bond. "Some Tests of Specification for
Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment
Equations." The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 1991, 277-97.
Arellano, M., and O. Bover. "Another Look at the Instrumental
Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 68(1), 1995, 29-51.
Banfield, E. The Moral Basis of a Backward Society. New York: Free
Press, 1958.
Baum. C. An Introduction to Modern Econometrics Using Stata.
College Station, Texas: Stata Press, 2005.
Beck, T., A. Demirguc-Kunt, and R. Levine. "Law, Endowments,
and Finance." Journal of Financial Economics, 70, 2003, 137-81.
Blonigen, B. "Firm-Specific Assets and the Link between
Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct Investment." American Economic
Review, 87, 1997, 447-65.
Blundell, R., and S. Bond. "Initial Conditions and Moment
Restrictions in Dynamic Panel Data Models." Journal of
Econometrics, 87(1), 1998, 115-43.
Bonaglia, F., J. Braga de Macedo, and M. Bussolo. "How
Globalisation Improves Governance." OECD Development Centre Working
Papers 181, OECD Development Centre, 2001.
Bullow, J., and K. Rogoff. "A Constant Recontracting Model of
Sovereign Debt." Journal of "Political Economy, 97, 1989,
155-78.
Buthe, T., and H. Milner. 2005 "The Politics of Foreign Direct
Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through Policy
Commitment via Trade Agreements and Investment Treaties?"
http://www.princeton.edu/~hmilner/working%20papers/Buthe
Milner_FDI_v5.pdf. Accessed April 15, 2005.
Demsetz, H. "Toward a Theory of Property Rights."
American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 57, 1967, 347-59.
Dunning, J., and S. Lundan. Multinational Enterprises and the
Global Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 2008.
Engerman, S., and K. Sokoloff. "Factor Endowments, Inequality,
and Paths of Development among New World Economies," in How Latin
America Fell Behind, edited by S. Haber. Stanford, CA: Stanford
University Press, 1997, 260-304.
Froot, K., and J. Stein. "Exchange Rates and Foreign Direct
Investment: An Imperfect Capital Market Approach." Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 106, 1991, 1191-217.
Garretsen, H., and J. Peeters. "Capital Mobility,
Agglomeration and Corporate Tax Rates: Is the Race to the Bottom for
Real?" Economic Studies, 53, 2007, 263-93.
Hall, R., and C. Jones. "Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much
More Output per Worker Than Others?" Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 114, 1999, 83-116.
International Monetary Fund. World Economic Outlook: Growth and
Institutions. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 2003.
Knack, S., and P. Keefer. "Institutions and Economic
Performance: Cross-country Tests Using Alternative Institutional
Measures." Economics and Politics, 7, 1995, 207-27.
Landes, D. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations. New York: W.W.
Norton, 1998.
La Porta, R., F. Lopez-de-Silanes, A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny.
"The Quality of Government." Journal of Law, Economics, and
Organization, 15, 1999, 222-79.
Larrain, B., and J. Tavares. "Does Foreign Direct Investment
Decrease corruption?" Cuadernos De Economia, 41, 2004, 217-30.
Levine, R. "Law, Endowment and Property Rights." Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 19, 2005, 61-88.
Li, Q., and R. Reuveny. "Economic Globalization and Democracy:
An Empirical Analysis." British Journal of Political Science, 33,
2003, 29-54.
Libman, A. "Government-Business Relations and Catching Up
Reforms in the CIS." European Journal of Comparative Economics,
3(2), 2006, 263-88.
Marx, K. Das Kapital. London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1974 (1872).
Mosley, L., and S. Uno. "Racing to the Bottom or Climbing to
the Top?" Comparative Political Studies, 40, 2007, 923-48.
Navaretti, G., and A. Venables. Multinational Firms in the World
Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2006.
North, D. C. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York:
W.W. Norton, 1981.
--. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990.
North, D., and B. Weingast. "Constitutions and Commitment: The
Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century
England." The Journal of Economic History., 56, 1989, 803-32.
Olson, M. "Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development."
American Political Science Review, 87, 1993, 567-76.
Oman, C. Policy Competition for Foreign Direct Investment: A Study
of Completion among Governments to Attract FD1. Paris: OECD Development
Centre, 2000.
Poynter, T. Multinational Enterprises and Government Intervention.
London: Croom Helm, 1985.
Putnam, R. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1993.
Rodrik, D. (2000). "Trade Policy as Institutions Reform."
Accessed March 10, 2008. http://ksghome.
harvard.edu/~drodrik/Reform.PDF.
Sachs, J., and A. Warner. Natural Resource Abundance and Economic
Growth. NBER Working Paper No. 5398. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1995.
United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. World
Investment Reports: Transnational Corporation and Export
Competitiveness. New York: UNCTAD, United Nations, 2002.
Weber, M. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New
York: Charles Scribner's Sons, 1958.
Windmeijer, F. "A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of
Linear Efficient Two-Step GMM Estimators." Journal of Econometrics,
126, 2005, 25-51.
(1.) This section is a summary of the discussions in La Porta et
al. (1999) and Beck, Demirguc-Kunt, and Levine (2003).
(2.) We also used GDP per capita to control for economic effect but
it provided poor results.
(3.) Note that, as in the previous models, we lagged all of these
variables one period, that is, 5 years, in order to mitigate the problem
of the endogeneity.
(4.) The Ethnic Tension index is published by PRS Group. See
Appendix A for details about this index.
(5.) Note that the index is scaled to take values between 0 and 12,
with higher values meaning less tension.
Ali: Economics Department, University of Garyounis, Bengazi, P.O.
Box 1308, Libya. Phone 218-64-224-0730, Fax 218-61-224-0731, E-mail
fali@ garyounis.edu
Fiess: The World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC. Phone
202-473-7585, Fax 202-522-2119, E-mail nfiess @worldbank.org
Macdonald: Department of Economics, Adam Smith Building, University
of Glasgow, Glasgow, GI2 8RT, UK. Phone 44-141-330-1988, Fax
44-141-330-4940, E-mail r.macdonald @lbss.gla.ac.uk
TABLE 1
Property Rights and FDI: Cross-sectional Regressions
(Dependent Variable: Property Rights Index 1997) (a)
Model l Model 2 Model 3
OLS OLS OLS
Ethnic fractionalization -0.826 *** 0.332 0.387
(-2.76) (1.26) (1.39)
French legal origin -0.704 *** -0.559 *** -0.483 ***
(-3.51) (-3.84) (-3.14)
Socialist legal origin -1.386 *** -1.114 *** -1.133 ***
(-3.65) (-4.26) (-4.47)
German legal origin 1.084 *** 0.068 0.285
(4.91) (0.28) (1.07)
Scandinavian legal origin 0.879 *** -0.531 ** -0.394
(3.08) (-2.03) (-1.42)
Latitude 1.638 *** 1.964 ***
(3.30) (3.83)
Log GNP per capita 0.417 *** 0.365 ***
(5.79) (5.09)
FDI-GDP ratio 0.110 **
(2.57)
Catholic
Muslim
Other religion
Independence
Settler mortality
Intercept 3.981 *** 0.191 0.262
(16.97) (0.38) (0.51)
No. of observations 124 124 121
F 91 48 39
Model 4 Model 5 Model 6 (b)
OLS OLS IV
Ethnic fractionalization 0.474 -0.103 -0.257
(1.64) (-0.24) (-0.34)
French legal origin -0.560 *** -0.728 ** -0.604
(-2.99) (-2.37) (-1.15)
Socialist legal origin -1.273 *** -- --
(-4.30)
German legal origin 0.270 -- --
(1.08)
Scandinavian legal origin -0.030 -- --
(-0.06)
Latitude 2.178 *** -- --
(3.67)
Log GNP per capita 0.342 *** -- --
(3.82)
FDI-GDP ratio 0.113 *** 0.182 *** 0.468 **
(2.71) (2.74) (2.16)
Catholic 0.007 -0.011 -0.031
(1.27) (-1.22) (-1.59)
Muslim 0.003 -0.007 -0.018
(0.56) (-0.85) (-1.39)
Other religion 0.006 -0.012 -0.033
(1.06) (-1.40) (-1.40)
Independence 0.502 1.379
(0.91) (1.67)
Settler mortality -0.191 ** 0.023
(-2.07) (0.19)
Intercept -0.091 5.039 *** 4.988 ***
(-0.12) (6.65) (4.59)
No. of observations 121 69 36
F 31 7 6
(a) Values in parentheses are White heteroskedastic adjusted
t-values. *, **, and *** denote significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%,
respectively. F is F-statistics.
(b) FDI is instrumented by the real exchange rate, infrastructure,
and continental dummies for Africa and Latin America. The validity
of these instruments is supported by Sargan test [chi square](3) =
5.36 (p > [chi square] = (0.147)).
TABLE 2
Changes in Averages of Property Rights Index
Country 1981-1885 1986-1990 1991-1995 1996-2000 2001-2005
Morocco 4.542 4.542 7.567 9.875 9.938
Bolivia 2.125 3.092 5.150 7.533 7.400
Chile 5.417 7.000 8.108 9.475 10.483
Tunisia 4.500 4.500 7.025 9.367 9.225
Venezuela, RB 6.104 6.892 6.883 6.300 4.925
Cote d'1voire 7.167 6.775 5.908 6.208 5.517
Zimbabwe 4.250 4.708 5.750 6.050 2.475
TABLE 3
Property Rights and FDI: Panel Data Regressions (Dependent Variable:
Property Rights Index [1981-2005] 5-year intervals)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3
RE (a) RE (a) RE (a)
Ethnic fractionalization -0.671 -0.947 ** -0.327
(-1.50) (-2.07) (-0.59)
French legal origin -0.352 0.232 0.490
(-1.23) (0.63) (1.15)
Economic growth -- -- 0.163 ***
(4.65)
FDI-GDP ratio 0.237 *** 0.241 *** 0.172 ***
(6.50) (6.59) (4.93)
Catholic -- -0.016 ** -0.011
(-2.47) (-1.57)
Muslim -- -0.007 -0.005
(-1.25) (-0.76)
Settler mortality -- -- -0.174
(-1.31)
Resource endowments -- -- --
Trade -- -- --
Lagged property right -- -- --
Ethnic tensions -- -- --
Intercept 6.342 *** 6.860 *** 6.596 ***
(18.59) (16.97) (9.50)
No. of groups 70 70 57
No. of observations 278 278 224
Wald [chi square] 51.44(3) 58.62(5) 86.72(7)
Model 4 Model 5 Model 6
RE (a) RE (a) FE (b)
Ethnic fractionalization -0.246 -0.074 --
(-0.47) (-0.14)
French legal origin 0.373 0.415 --
(0.91) (1.02)
Economic growth 0.133 *** 0.129 *** 0.119 ***
(3.87) (3.71) (3.27)
FDI-GDP ratio 0.200 *** 0.173 *** 0.162 ***
(5.00) (4.59) (3.13)
Catholic -0.014 ** -0.011 --
(-2.20) (-1.63)
Muslim -0.010 -0.008 --
(-1.58) (-1.19)
Settler mortality -- -- --
Resource endowments -0.019 -0.025 ** -0.009
(-1.62) (-2.13) (-0.28)
Trade -- 0.007 ** 0.014 **
(2.49) (1.98)
Lagged property right -- -- --
Ethnic tensions -- -- --
Intercept 6.432 *** 5.877 *** 4.991 ***
(14.42) (11.33) (10.60)
No. of groups 68 68 68
No. of observations 240 240 240
Wald [chi square] 69.37(7) 77.67(8) --
Model 7 Model s
Sys GMM (c) Sys GMM (d)
Ethnic fractionalization 0.019 --
(0.07)
French legal origin 0.648 ** 0.688 ***
(2.47) (3.05)
Economic growth 0.209 *** 0.236 ***
(2.71) (3.38)
FDI-GDP ratio 0.116 ** 0.124 ***
(2.24) (2.71)
Catholic -0.004 -0.008 **
(-1.08) (-2.12)
Muslim -0.004 -0.006 *
(-1.06) (-1.88)
Settler mortality -- --
Resource endowments -0.010 -0.005
(-1.38) (-0.76)
Trade 0.004 0.004 *
(1.49) (1.87)
Lagged property right 0.619 *** 0.492 ***
(5.90) (4.83)
Ethnic tensions -- 0.231 ***
(4.67)
Intercept 1.081 1.211 *
(1.3) (1.73)
No. of groups 68 68
No. of observations 240 240
Wald [chi square] 644.64(12) 902.91(12)
(a) Random effects model, z-values reported in parentheses.
(b) Fixed effects model, r-values reported in parentheses.
(c) System GMM. Arellano-Bond test for AR (2) in first differences:
z = -1.01, p > z = 0.312. Hansen test of overidentification
restrictions: [chi square](32) = 34.29, p > [chi square] = 0.359.
(d) System GMM. Arellano-Bond test for AR (2) in first differences:
z = -1.24, p > z = 0.215. Hansen test of overidentification
restrictions: [chi square](32) = 33.67, p > [chi square] = 0.386.
Models 7 and 8 include time dummies.
**, and *** denote significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.