Do states free ride in antitrust enforcement?
Feinberg, Robert M. ; Husted, Thomas A.
I. INTRODUCTION
Recent research has examined the role of state governments in the
United States in antitrust enforcement over the past 20 years. What has
not been explored is the extent to which states make strategic decisions
on their involvement in antitrust litigation. In particular, while most
state antitrust cases involve purely local matters, a significant number
of these concern more than one state; states then need to decide whether
to invest in leading an investigation or letting other states take the
lead and participating in some lesser role, which includes simply
signing on to a settlement. We view the decision by a state to delay
entry into antitrust litigation to be a type of "free-tiding"
behavior. (1) In this paper we analyze this issue of "free
riding" by states in antitrust activity.
II. PREVIOUS LITERATURE
One of the defining characteristics of a pure public good is the
nonexcludability of the benefits from its consumption. As benefits can
be received by individuals without having to pay for the goods, this
nonexcludability creates the possibility for a "free-rider
problem." As a consequence of this free-tiding behavior, the
private market cannot exact a price for this good and this may mean the
private market will provide a suboptimal amount of the good. Free riders
are usually used as justification for government intervention into the
private market to allocate these so-called public goods in order to
correct the market failure. While this behavior would seem rational, it
is not easily observed so the extent of free riding is not generally
known. Researchers have employed experimental game evidence to measure
the extent of free riding, with results ranging from none to an extreme
amount. Factors found in this literature that appear to decrease the
degree of free-riding behavior under certain conditions include smaller
group size (Isaac, Walker, and Thomas 1984), experience through repeated
game play (Fischbacher and Gachter 2010), pregame communication among
participants, and an ability to exclude players from the group or other
sanctions (Delmas and Keller 2005).
While the free-rider problem and the experimental evidence have
focused on private market decision makers, it is straightforward to
extend these behaviors to self-interested governments. One possibility
is that governments reduce the amount of certain appropriations as a
result of private contributions. Becker and Linsday (1994) find a
considerable degree of government free-riding behavior in the context of
appropriations to public higher education institutions. An alternative
source of free riding does not involve the private sector, but is
between government activities, particularly those with significant
spillover effects. Lee (1988) considers the issue of free riding among
countries in their efforts devoted to fighting terrorism. More recently,
Sav (2010) finds a similar impact. Chati and Kehoe (2007) provide a
theoretical discussion of what they call a free-rider problem among
members of a monetary union in their fiscal and regulatory policies,
caused by an inability of the monetary authority to commit to their
policies.
Sigman (2002) finds that water pollution control is affected by the
degree of spillovers crossing international borders. Somewhat closer to
the focus of this paper, Konisky and Woods (2010) investigate whether
U.S. states free tide in environmental regulatory actions. Their results
are somewhat mixed; while they report some impact in reducing state
enforcement of the Clean Air Act in their counties adjacent to
international borders, they do not find this pattern in counties
bordering other U.S. states.
A recent theoretical paper by Choi and Gerlach (2012) raises the
concern that national antitrust enforcement in a global economy (with
multi-market contact among exporters) may be suboptimal due to free
riding on the antitrust activity of other countries. However, no
empirical evidence is provided. No previous work has examined whether
state antitrust enforcement can be viewed in terms of free riding.
Recent work (Feinberg and Reynolds 2010) has documented the significant
amount of state antitrust activity ongoing and explained this activity
in terms of economic and political factors, as well as noting its impact
on business entry and relocation decisions at the state level (Feinberg
and Husted 2011).
A significant number of antitrust cases concern more than one state
and, as a result, the outcome of these cases could potentially benefit
several states. Free tiding by states in the decision to participate in
multistate antitrust litigation is similar to the situations described
above. States have the option of joining the litigation at any stage of
the process, ranging from initiating the litigation to joining the
litigation at settlement. Each state's attorney general has the
authority to make the decision to enter into these multistate antitrust
lawsuits. Provost (2010) argues the state attorney general's
decision will depend on policy motivations, related to the interests of
the state population, and political considerations, related to the
attorney general's political party or electoral ambitions. The
importance and intensity of these motivations and political
circumstances will vary considerably across the states, so it is highly
likely that each state will behave differently in the timing of its
entry into the litigation process. A key aspect is that states can
benefit from such an outcome even if they do not lead the antitrust
investigation or even if they take an active role from the beginning. As
a result, on the assumption that other states will bear the greater cost
of initiating the case, there is considerable incentive for state
governments to act "selfishly" and reduce costs by deferring
and joining any antitrust suit later in the investigation. In the
following we explore the role of free riding by states in this area.
III. DATA AND METHODOLOGY
Based on the Antitrust Multistate Litigation Database (for the
years 1990-2006) put together by the National Association of Attorneys
General, we analyze all state-by-case observations where more than one
state was involved at any stage of the case (as either "lead
plaintiff," "participating state," or "settling
state"); we interpret this as the set of cases in which there were
expected to be benefits beyond a single state--so the possibility of
free riding would exist. There are a total of 1,181 observations,
involving 47 distinct cases and all 50 states.
We define two alternative "free-tiding" -dependent
variables, participation as other than the lead plaintiff (NotLead),
which might be thought of as "weak" free tiding, and
participation only at the settlement stage of the case (Settlement),
which could be viewed as "strong" free tiding. As these
dependent variables are binary, we estimate this model using a probit analysis.
The included explanatory variables define the underlying legal,
economic, and political circumstances of these cases. The type of case
may be an important indicator both of the complexity--hence cost--and
likely benefits of involvement in the litigation. Horizontal conspiracy
(Horizontal Case) and merger cases (Merger Case) raise relatively
straightforward economic and legal issues and have potential benefits to
the plaintiff which are likely to be reasonably well predicted ex ante.
Other cases, which may seem more costly and with more uncertain
benefits, for example, vertical issues, monopolization, restrictive
contracts, and so forth might be expected to lead to greater free-riding
behavior.
As described above, states can enter into antitrust cases later and
still enjoy the benefits from any settlement. It is expected, then, that
states with more resources are less likely to free ride. We measure
these resources along several dimensions: the size of the state economy
(gross state product [GSP]), the relative importance of government
expenditures in the state (Gov't Share of GSP), and per capita
income (Income). We expect to observe that larger, more affluent,
states, with larger government sectors (and hence greater resources
available) are more likely to take the lead on antitrust
enforcement--and hence less likely to free ride on other states'
activity. The existence of federal resources as a result of its
involvement in these cases (Federal Involvement) should reduce the need
for immediate state involvement and, therefore, increase the amount of
state free riding.
As described earlier, one of the key determinants of free riding is
the number of individual parties involved in the transaction. We include
a measure of the number of states included in any stage of the
multistate litigation (Number of States) to capture this effect. Two
variables are included to describe the political circumstances involving
the state attorney general (AG)--whether the AG is from the Republican
party (Grand Old Party [GOP] AG) and whether the AG is appointed
(Appointed AG). Feinberg and Reynolds (2010) found that Republican AGs
and appointed AGs were less likely to participate in antitrust cases; we
examine whether this reluctance extends to a more limited role (more
free riding) where they do participate. Summary statistics for the
dependent and independent variables are presented in Table 1.
IV. RESULTS
Marginal estimates, evaluated at the mean values of the independent
variables, from a probit estimation of the probability of participating
in a case as other than the lead plaintiff are presented in Tables 2 and
3. Results from the "weak" form of free riding, where the
state is participating in a nonlead role, are presented in Table 2. The
results from the "strong" form of free riding, where the state
enters only at the settlement stage, are presented in Table 3. While
there are differences in the marginal effects between the two models,
there are some consistent findings. In both models, the number of states
participating in the litigation increases the free-riding behavior and
the resources available to the state government, measured by both the
state GSP and the relative size of the government sector, decreases both
weak and strong free-riding behavior, as expected. In addition,
political effects do not seem to motivate either the weak or strong
forms of free-tiding behavior.
We do find some interesting differences in coefficient estimates
between the weak and strong free-riding models. States are less likely
to free tide in a strong way (i.e., only participating at the settlement
stage) on horizontal and merger cases; the implication then is that
there is more likely to be strong free riding on more
complicated/controversial cases where benefits (and perhaps costs) are
more difficult to determine (and more uncertain) ex ante; for these, as
the case proceeds, better information may emerge and states may join in.
We also find that the presence of federal involvement in a case has a
sizeable positive effect on strong (but not weak) free tiding; states
seem assured that sufficient resources will be available to pursue a
case and they can then join in at the end. (2)
V. CONCLUSION
Free tiding by government entities has been little studied. No
previous empirical research has examined whether state governments
engage in free riding in their enforcement of state and federal
antitrust statutes. In this paper, we provide evidence that availability
of governmental resources, potential number of states involved, the type
of antitrust case, and the help of the federal government all play their
expected roles in determining this type of free riding.
The social welfare implications of this free-tiding behavior are
unclear. Traditional analyses of free tiding view it as leading to
suboptimal provision of some activity by individuals--leading to the
role of government to step in and resolve this market failure. Does free
riding by states imply suboptimal antitrust case-filing activity? One
might view the ability of the federal government to step in and file
cases as a mechanism that deals with any such suboptimal state
enforcement. However, analysis of this issue is beyond the scope of this
paper.
ABBREVIATIONS
AG: Attorney General
GOP: Grand Old Party
GSP: Gross State Product
doi: 10.1111/j.1465-7295.2012.00477.x
REFERENCES
Becker, E., and C. M. Lindsay. "Does the Government Free
Ride?" Journal of Law and Economics, 37(1), 1994, 277-96.
Chaff, V. V., and P. J. Kehoe. "On the Need for Fiscal
Constraints in a Monetary Union." Journal of Monetary Economics,
54(8), 2007, 2399-408.
Choi, J. P., and H. Gerlach. "International Antitrust
Enforcement and Multi-Market Contact." International Economic
Review, 53(2), 2012, 635-58.
Delmas, M., and A. Keller. "Free Riding in Voluntary
Environmental Programs: The Case of the U.S. EPA WasteWater
Program." Policy Sciences, 38, 2005, 91-106.
Feinberg, R. M., and K. M. Reynolds. "The Determinants of
State-Level Antitrust Activity." Review of Industrial Organization,
37(3), 2010, 179-96.
Feinberg, R. M., and T. A. Husted. "Patterns of Establishment
Entry and State-Level Antitrust Activity." Journal of Competition
Law and Economics, 7(4), 2011, 813-23.
Fischbacher, U., and S. Gachter. "Social Preferences, Beliefs,
and the Dynamics of Free Riding in Public Goods Experiments."
American Economic Review, 100(1), 2010, 541-56.
Isaac, R.M., J.M. Walker, and S.H. Thomas. "Divergent Evidence
on Free Riding: An Experimental Examination of Possible
Explanations." Public Choice, 43(2), 1984, 113-49.
Konisky, D. M., and N. D. Woods. "Exporting Air Pollution?
Regulatory Enforcement and Environmental Free Riding in the United
States." Political Research Quarterly, 63(4), 2010, 771-82.
Lee, D. R. "Free Riding and Paid Riding in the Fight against
Terrorism." American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 78(2),
1988, 22-26.
Provost, C. "An Integrated Model of U.S. State Attorney
General Behavior in Multi-State Litigation." State Politics and
Policy Quarterly, 10(1), 2010, 1-24.
Sav, G. T. "Private Giving Crowding Government Funding in
Public Higher Education." American Journal of Economics and
Business Administration, 2(3), 2010, 293-99.
Sigman, H. "International Spillovers and Water Quality in
Rivers: Do Countries Free Ride?" American Economic Review, 92(4),
2002, 1152-59.
(1.) Our definition of free-riding behavior follows the previous
literature on government free-tiding behavior reviewed below.
Specifically, we define government free riding as the state's
decision to delay entry or not initiate antitrust activity. As we note
later, unlike what is implied by the classic public finance definition
of free riding, we are not able to determine whether there is less than
an "optimal" amount of antitrust activity as a result.
(2.) We also incorporate interaction terms between Federal and all
of the explanatory variables into the two probit models to test for the
possibility that the presence of federal government's intervention
affects the determinates of the state's decision to free ride.
Under weak free riding, these additional interaction terms were all
statistically insignificant. Under the strong free-riding model, some of
these interaction terms were statistically significant. The negative
coefficients on the three interactive terms with the size of the state
government [Ln(GSP), Ln(Income), and Gov't Share of GSP] attenuate the effect of Federal and the positive coefficient with Appointed AG
reinforces the positive effect of Federal. Coefficient estimates are
available on request.
Feinberg: Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, American
University, 4400 Massachusetts Ave., N.W., Washington DC 20016. Phone
202-885-3788, Fax 202-885-3790, E-mail
[email protected]
Husted: Professor of Economics, Department of Economics, American
University, 4400 Massachusetts Ave., N.W., Washington DC 20016. Phone
202-885-3773, Fax 202885-3790, E-mail
[email protected]
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics, N = 1181
Standard
Variable Mean Deviation Minimum Maximum
Dep Vars
NotLead 0.909 0.287 0 1
Settlement 0.189 0.392 0 1
Indep Vars
Federal Involvement 0.667 0.471 0 1
Horizontal Case 0.256 0.436 0 1
Merger Case 0.109 0.312 0 1
Number of States 41.41 14.71 3 51
Gov't Share of GSP 0.128 0.035 0.069 0.281
GSP 208315.2 243206.1 14010 1512852
Income 50529.4 7836.05 30478.8 72679
GOP AG 0.332 0.471 0 1
Appointed AG 0.087 0.282 0 1
TABLE 2
Probit Results: Dependent Variable = "Weak"
Free Riding (NotLead = Participation in a
Case Other Than as the Lead Plaintiff)
Independent Variable Marginal Effects
Federal Involvement -0.002 (0.14)
Horizontal Case 0.002 (0.12)
Merger Case -0.013 (0.55)
Number of States 0.0019 (4.28) ***
Gov't Share of GSP -0.437 (2.12) **
Ln(GSP) -0.057 (8.70) ***
Ln(Income) -0.006 (0.15)
GOP AG 0.0093 (0.81)
Appointed AG 0.012 (0.46)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.259
N = 1,181.
z-Statistics in parentheses next to estimated coefficients.
** Statistical significance at 5%; *** significance at 1%.
TABLE 3
Probit Results: Dependent Variable = "Strong"
Free Riding (Settlement = Participation in a
Case Only at Settlement)
Independent Variable Marginal Effects
Federal Involvement 0.174 (8.51) ***
Horizontal Case -0.177 (7.91) **
Merger Case -0.151 (3.14) ***
Number of States 0.0039 (2.79) ***
Gov't Share of GSP -0.659 (2.72) ***
Ln(GSP) -0.061 (9.18) ***
Ln(Income) -0.037 (0.83)
GOP AG 0.0064 (0.56)
Appointed AG 0.020 (0.81)
Pseudo [R.sup.2] 0.254
N = 1.181.
z-Statistics in parentheses next to estimated coefficients.
** Statistical significance at 5%; *** significance at 1%.