首页    期刊浏览 2024年12月03日 星期二
登录注册

文章基本信息

  • 标题:Who pays the bar tab? Beer consumption and economic growth in the united states.
  • 作者:Cesur, Resul ; Kelly, Inas Rashad
  • 期刊名称:Economic Inquiry
  • 印刷版ISSN:0095-2583
  • 出版年度:2014
  • 期号:January
  • 语种:English
  • 出版社:Western Economic Association International
  • 摘要:--Phillip J. Cook, Paying the Tab: The Costs and Benefits of Alcohol Control (2007)
  • 关键词:Alcoholism;Economic growth

Who pays the bar tab? Beer consumption and economic growth in the united states.


Cesur, Resul ; Kelly, Inas Rashad


What drug provides Americans with the greatest pleasure and the greatest pain? The answer, hands down, is alcohol. The pain comes not only from drunk driving and lost lives but also addiction, family strife, crime, violence, poor health, and squandered human potential. Young and old, drinkers and abstainers alike, all are affected. Every American is paying for alcohol abuse.

--Phillip J. Cook, Paying the Tab: The Costs and Benefits of Alcohol Control (2007)

I. INTRODUCTION

Alcohol consumption has severe social and economic consequences: lost productivity, disability, early death, crime, family neglect, personality deterioration, to name a few (Cook 2007). At the individual level, the effects of alcohol consumption have been explored considerably by researchers in different fields, including economics, medicine, public health, criminology, and sociology. However, few studies have examined the economic impact of alcohol use at the aggregate level.

Probably, due to the research deficiency regarding its aggregate effects, some disagreement exists about the overall net benefits of alcohol use. On the one hand, scholars who have done extensive research on individual outcomes claim that the overall costs of alcohol use outweigh its benefits. For example, Cook and Moore (2002, 120) state in their review article, "The production and sale of alcoholic beverages account for a small share of national product in the United States and in other advanced economies. However, the deleterious effects of alcohol consumption on health and safety constitute a substantial economic burden, reducing our overall standard of living."

On the other hand, organizations formed by the producers and distributors of alcoholic beverages claim that the alcoholic beverage industry contributes significantly to the U.S. economy through job creation and tax revenues. According to Beer Serves America (2011), an organization sponsored by the Beer Institute and the National Beer Wholesalers Association (NBWA):
   Directly and indirectly, the beer industry employs
   approximately 1.8 million Americans, paying them
   over $71 billion in wages and benefits. The industry
   pays over $44 billion in business, personal and consumption
   taxes, including $5.3 billion in excise taxes
   and $5.8 billion in sales, gross receipts, and other
   taxes. (1)


Similarly, the Distilled Spirits Council of the United States (DISCUS 1999), the national trade association representing America's leading distillers and about 70% of all distilled spirits brands sold in the United States, states that the alcohol beverage industry is a major contributor to the U.S. economy through job creation, wages, and taxes. (2)

Room and Jernigan (2000) point out that the benefits reaped from the alcohol industry in terms of economic development should be weighed against the negative impacts on economic development in addition to public health. They go on to say that alcohol's contribution to total production can vary tremendously from country to country (generating 3% of total manufacturing value added in Argentina or the Netherlands, but as little as 0.07% in Iran). Aside from the aforementioned contributions of the alcohol industry to the economy often cited by the industry itself, supply-side efforts also play a role in the consumption of alcohol. This can be done through influencing government regulation of the market for alcohol and selling cheap alcohol in bulk, which has "a devastating public health impact" (Stockwell and Crosbie 2001). Indeed, the economic burden of excessive alcohol consumption has been found to be substantial, recently estimated at $223.5 billion (Bouchery et al. 2011).

Although a few studies have examined the impact of macroeconomic conditions on drinking prevalence and patterns, such as those by Ruhm and Black (2002) and Ruhm (1995), we are not aware of any studies exploring the impact of alcohol consumption on economic growth. This study fills that void by using annual, state-level U.S. data for the period 1971-2007 to examine the effect of alcohol use on per capita personal income growth and per capita gross domestic product (GDP) growth (hereafter, economic growth) in a general equilibrium framework. Although incorporating all alcoholic beverages into the analysis would be ideal, our focus is exclusively on beer consumption for the following reasons. Beer is the major source of alcohol consumption in the United States, making up approximately 55% of total ethanol consumption (LaVallee and Yi 2011; Ruhm et al. 2011). (3) It is the beverage of choice among Americans, particularly among youths (Chaloupka, Grossman, and Saffer 2002), making it more policy-relevant for tax changes as youths are more price-sensitive and are more likely to binge-drink (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention 2012). The potential endogeneity of beer consumption can be addressed by using the excise beer tax rate as an instrumental variable. As wine and liquor are sold through state stores in many states, it is difficult to determine tax rates for wine and liquor. (4) Therefore, in line with previous studies and following the convention in the health economics literature, we use per capita beer sales as a proxy for alcohol consumption at the state-level. (5)

We refer to the relevant literature, examining the effects of alcohol consumption on a variety of outcomes, to identify the microeconomic channels through which drinking may affect economic growth. In a regression of economic growth on beer consumption, we address the potential endogeneity of per capita beer consumption by utilizing the levels of beer excise tax rates as instrumental variables. We show that, once the potential endogeneity is accounted for, per capita ethanol consumption taken through beer is negatively associated with short-run economic growth measures. These results are robust to various specification checks, including reduced form relationships between economic growth variables and different types of excise taxes. (6)

Our study contributes to the economics literature in several important respects. First, we document that, parallel to a large body of literature in different disciplines, the aggregate costs of the "bar tab" are indeed borne by society as a whole. Second, to our knowledge this is the first study providing evidence on the potential relationship between consumption-related negative externalities and aggregate economic well-being in a general equilibrium framework. The findings of this study suggest that Pigouvian taxes may serve as externality-correcting instruments, leading to increased efficiency in terms of aggregate economic growth. Finally, our results suggest that exploring the relationships between health behaviors and other types of aggregate economic outcomes may produce valuable information for policy makers (i.e., exploring the aggregate effect of beer consumption on health care expenditures).

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II reviews a broad range of literature to discuss the various microeconomic channels through which drinking may affect worker productivity and national savings and, thus, economic growth. Section III introduces the econometric model. Section IV presents the data. Section V presents the ordinary least squares (OLS) results. (7) Section VI shows the Instrumental Variables (IV) estimates. Section VII examines the reduced form relationships between beer excise tax rates and economic growth to explore the validity of the findings in Section VI. Section VIII performs additional robustness checks. Conclusions are given in Section IX.

II. BACKGROUND AND CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK

It is well documented in the economics literature that labor productivity, population growth, human capital accumulation, and physical capital accumulation are among the more important determinants of economic growth. (8) Alcohol consumption can affect economic growth through its effect on various microeconomic sources of economic growth, as aggregate-level relationships are based on microeconomic foundations.

Drinking-related lost workdays, which represent a direct negative shock to the labor supply of a worker, can result from sickness absences, driving under the influence (DUI) arrests, alcohol-related injury work leaves, incarcerations due to alcohol-induced criminal activity, and alcohol-dependence-related withdrawals from the labor force. Several studies show a direct association between alcohol use and reduced workplace performance measured through absenteeism, poor relations with coworkers, and accidents. (9) Various survey-based studies point to the fact that overindulgence in alcohol impedes productivity at work, leading to reduced earnings and fringe benefits, reduced on-the-job performance, and reduced employment opportunities. (10)

The relationship between alcohol use and morbidity-mortality is also well documented. In about two-thirds of all injury deaths, the victim or other involved party had been drinking enough to be intoxicated by the usual standard (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention 2004; Smith, Branas, and Miller 1999). Alcohol consumption is linked to car accidents, disease burden around the world, and sexually transmitted infections. (11) Morbidity reduces the returns to human capital by lowering labor productivity as well as increasing lost workdays. Injury-related spending shifts funds from productive investments to injury treatment and related rebuilding expenditures. (12) Therefore, morbidity is likely to have a negative impact on economic growth through lost workdays and the reallocation of savings from productive uses to injury prevention and damage-replacement spending.

Macroeconomic studies examining the impact of health on economic growth often use life expectancy at birth as a proxy for health at the aggregate level. Acemoglu and Johnson (2007) employ an instrumental variables strategy to estimate the causal effect of life expectancy on income growth. (13) They find that increases in life expectancy (and the associated increases in population) appear to reduce income per capita. On the other hand, some studies find that lower mortality directly affects economic growth. Specifically, Kalemli-Ozcan, Ryder, and Weil (2000) and Kalemli-Ozcan (2002) report that increased life expectancy leads to greater long-run economic growth since longevity increases investment in human capital through education, while fertility decreases in response to increased longevity; thus, in the long run, life expectancy has a positive impact on economic growth. Ashraf, Lester, and Weil (2009) find that the impact of positive health shocks on income growth depends on which part of the population is most affected by the disease. For example, in the short run, eradicating tuberculosis raises per capita income, whereas eradicating malaria lowers it. The differential effects of eradicating these diseases on income arise largely because tuberculosis strikes mostly prime-aged workers, while malaria affects mainly young children (Ashraf, Lester, and Weil 2009).

When it comes to evaluating the impact of mortality on per capita income growth, one must consider the employment status of those who die. (14) A person's death decreases population, which has a positive impact on per capita income if that person is not in the labor force. If the person is employed, however, the loss of productive labor has a negative impact on per capita income. The aggregate effect depends on the mix of individuals in and out of the labor force. Deaths of prime-aged workers who are in the labor force and deaths of people who are not in the labor force do not have the same effect on per capita income growth. Consequently, the net effect of alcohol-induced deaths on economic growth depends on the employment status of the deceased.

Various studies undertaken in different parts of the world show that alcohol use is costly to societies. According to the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (2000) report, the economic cost of drinking in the United States for 1992 was about $148 billion. This report makes its calculations based on medical expenses, lost present and future earnings due to alcohol-related illnesses, deaths and crimes, costs of crashes, fires, and criminal justice expenses. Alcohol-related hospital charges in 1998 in New Mexico were $51 million in comparison to $35 million collected as alcohol taxes. In Canada, the economic costs of alcohol amount to approximately US$18.4 billion, representing 2.7% of the GDP (World Health Organization 2001). Studies in other countries have estimated the cost of alcohol-related problems to be around 1% of the GDP (Collins and Lapsley 1996; Rice et al. 1990). Alcohol-related externalities also impose large costs to the economies in the European Union. Total tangible costs of alcohol were estimated to be 125 billion [euro] in the EU in 2003. These costs are those associated with the criminal justice system, health care, and lost workdays. Barker (2002) finds that in New Zealand in 1999, alcohol excise taxes only account for half of alcohol-related direct costs.

Different studies advocate increases in alcohol excise taxes, arguing that they would produce favorable outcomes, particularly through reducing the negative externalities associated with alcohol consumption. Manning et al. (1989) show that alcohol excise taxes cover only about half the costs imposed on others. According to Parry, West, and Laxminarayan (2009), the

optimal excise taxes in the United States should be three to ten times more than current levels.

On the other hand, despite the fact that heavy drinking lowers productivity at work, several studies examining the impact of moderate drinking on wages find a positive relationship between the two. (15) Stated differently, these studies provide evidence in favor of the hypothesis that there is a drinker's bonus for moderate drinkers. Similarly to the drinker's bonus hypothesis, there are studies focusing on the potential health benefits of alcohol consumption. Hoffmeister et al. (1999) find that light alcohol consumption reduces the risk of cardiovascular disease and total mortality risk. Additional studies showing the beneficial effects of alcohol consumption on cardiovascular health include Gronbaek (2001), Klatsky (2002), Rehm et at. (2003), and Thun et al. (1997). (16)

III. EMPIRICAL IMPLEMENTATION

Although the existing literature is suggestive of the potential effects of alcohol use, they do not necessarily represent the causal effect of alcohol consumption. Drinking and low economic productivity may be due to unobservable personal characteristics of those who drink heavily and have low on-the-job productivity. Similarly, the positive association between moderate drinking and improved health/higher wages may be driven by unobservable individual traits. On the basis of the literature discussed above, the net impact of alcohol consumption on economic growth depends on the relative magnitudes of opposing factors and remains an empirical question.

The following OLS model is estimated:

(1) [Y.sub.s,t] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] [A.sup.s,t] + [[beta].sub.2][Z.sub.s,t] + [[eta].sub.s] + [[tau].sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.s,t]

where subscripts s and t refer to state and year, respectively. Depending on the model estimated, [Y.sub.s,t] is either the yearly state-level per capita personal income (PCPI) or per capita GDP growth. A refers to the variable of interest, state-level per capita ethanol consumption taken through beer. Z represents a vector of control variables. State-fixed effects, year dummies, and the idiosyncratic error term are denoted by [[eta].sub.s], [[tau].sub.t], and [[epsilon].sub.s,t], respectively. State-fixed effects control for timeinvariant state characteristics, such as culture surrounding drinking. Year dummies control for common time trends and time shocks, such as changes in the prevalence of drinking at the national level. (17)

The vector Z includes lagged values for PCPI (or per capita GDP) to control for the impact of convergence on economic growth as well as the potential effect of state-level PCPI (or per capita GDP) on alcohol sales. (18) The ratio of total public expenditures to personal income (GDP) accounts for the effect of state government size on economic growth. The average total tax rate controls for the effect of taxes on productive activities. Percent of population under 18 and above 64 crudely controls for the impact of labor force participation on economic growth. Individuals under 18 and above 64 are expected to drink less and produce less. Hence, omitting this variable would lead to an underestimation of the potential negative effect of alcohol consumption on income growth. The percent of the population older than 17 and younger than 25 is specified in the estimation equation to capture the joint effect of changes in the percentage of this age group on income growth and alcohol use. People in the 18-24 age group engage in more episodes of binge drinking (Centers for Disease Control and Prevention 2012), which is why we control for this age group separately. State-level education variables, which are percent with a high school degree, percent with some college education, and percent with a college degree, are also specified to account for the impact of past human-capital accumulation on income growth. Controlling for state-level education variables also helps to account for omitted variables if education is associated with both alcohol consumption patterns and economic growth. Variables pertaining to ethnic composition (percent Black and percent other race) are specified to reflect the effect, if any, of ethnic composition on income growth and alcohol consumption. For instance, controlling for population characteristics would account for the potential correlation between drinking patterns and worker productivity.

OLS estimates may be biased for several reasons. Research stressing the psychological responses to economic conditions predicts that alcohol use will rise during economic downturns as a tool for stress control. (19) Even though overall per capita alcohol consumption can fall during economic downturns due to an income effect, alcohol consumption may nevertheless go up as people self-medicate to ease their stresses. Using BRFSS data from 1984 to 1995, Dee (2001) finds that overall drinking and the probability of having 60 or more drinks falls during economic downturns; however, the probability of binge drinking increases. Thus, Dee concludes that the prevalence of binging is countercyclical. Nevertheless, various studies provide evidence against this view. Studying the impact of job stress, research in psychology implies that drinking may increase with the intensity of employment. (20) Furthermore, other studies find that alcohol consumption is positively related to income (Skog 1986; Sloan, Reilly, and Schenzler 1995). Ettner (1997), using the 1988 National Health Interview Survey (NHIS), shows that nonemployment significantly reduces both alcohol consumption and dependence symptoms with the exception of mixed evidence with respect to involuntary employment. She finds that job loss increases the consumption of alcohol in the overall sample, but reduces dependence symptoms among individual drinkers. Ruhm and Black (2002) and Ruhm (1995) find that intake of hard liquor declines in bad economic times, leading to a decrease in alcohol abuse as well. Thus, stress-induced drinking during economically depressed periods might be partially or fully offset by reductions due to decreased earnings (Ruhm and Black 2002). Using individual-level data from the BRFSS for the period 1987-1999, Ruhm and Black (2002) find that the decrease in per capita alcohol consumption measures in bad economic times is concentrated among heavy drinkers, while light drinking increases. Based on these studies, whether alcohol consumption is procyclical or countercyclical is ambiguous.

Depending on the magnitudes of the opposing factors, OLS estimates of the effect of beer sales on economic growth may be biased in either direction. To address the potential endogeneity of beer sales in this context, we undertake an instrumental variables (IV) methodology, described as follows.

A. Instrumental Variables

Our IV method employs the levels of beer excise taxes as instruments. (21) More specifically, the following first-stage relationship between per capita alcohol consumption measures and alcohol excise taxes is postulated:

(2) [A.sub.s,t] = [alpha] + [[beta].sub.1] [T.sub.s,t] + [[beta].sub.2][Z.sub.s,t] + [[eta].sub.s] + [[tau].sub.t] + [[epsilon].sub.s,t]

where T is the per gallon beer excise tax rate. The levels of beer excise tax rates are used as instruments for the corresponding per capita alcoholic beverage type with the assumption that these alcoholic beverages are purchased in national markets, so alcohol excise taxes proxy for alcohol prices. (22) In addition to a national market assumption, the validity of alcohol excise tax rates as instruments depends on whether the following two conditions hold. First, there has to be a statistically significant relationship between beer excise tax rates and per capita beer consumption. Second, the beer excise tax rates should not otherwise influence income growth beyond their indirect effect through alcohol consumption. Stated differently, the following exclusion restriction should hold: Cov([T.sub.s,t], [[epsilon].sub.s,t]) = 0, where [[epsilon].sub.s,t] represents the error term in the second-stage equation.

The evidence on the effectiveness of beer excise tax rates in predicting alcohol sales is mixed. Other factors may cast doubt on the power of beer excise taxes in serving as proxies for beer prices. Much of the variation in excise tax rates over time is induced through changes in inflation instead of changes in the levels of nominal values of excise tax rates, in addition to the fact that state tax rates usually comprise a small share of the alcoholic beverage prices (Young and Bielinka-Kwapisz 2002). Using American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association (ACCRA) price data, Young and Bielinka-Kwapisz (2002) document that beer excise taxes are poor predictors of alcohol prices; nevertheless, in a follow-up study, Young and Bielinka-Kwapisz (2003) find that ACCRA price data are not reliable due to substantial measurement error, but employing state and federal tax rates as instruments mitigates the problem. By using detailed cross-sectional barcode data, Ruhm et al. (2011) also show that ACCRA price data are not reliable indicators of alcohol prices. According to Ruhm et al., in a cross-sectional setting, the total tax elasticities of beer consumption are indistinguishable from zero (both in terms of magnitude and statistical significance), while higher tax rates seem to have a small inverse effect on beer drinking participation. It is worth mentioning that, even though the findings of Ruhm et al. (2011) are very informative, in our framework their findings are of minimal concern because the variation in beer tax rates in our study is generated not only by the cross-sectional variation but also by the longitudinal variation in beer tax rates. Furthermore, Ruhm et al. data are for the period 2000-2004. With the exception of the 1991 federal alcohol tax increase, alcohol excise tax rates exhibit strong downward trends in the period 1971-2007. During the 2000s, on average, the real values of beer excise tax rates are lower than the real values of beer tax rates during the 1970s and 1980s. Hence, in our framework, we expect that beer excise tax rates exhibit enough variation to serve as instruments in predicting per capita alcohol sales measures. In the final analysis, the statistical significance of the relationship between beer excise tax rates and beer consumption can be empirically tested.

A legitimate concern related to the exclusion restriction is the possibility that alcohol excise tax rates may affect economic growth through other channels. For example, if alcohol excise tax rates affect economic growth through their effect on state budgets, then the validity of alcohol excise tax rates as instrumental variables could be called into question. Similarly, if state-level economic growth determines state alcohol excise tax rates, and/or state policies on economic growth are linked to alcohol excise tax rates, alcohol excise taxes may not serve as suitable instrumental variables in estimating the effect of alcohol consumption on economic growth. By estimating the reduced form relationships between economic growth and the different types of excise tax rates, one can (imperfectly) test the validity of these concerns. If the reduced form models provide uniform results (similar effects on economic growth measures) for the different types of alcohol excise tax rates regardless of the effects of excise taxes on drinking behavior (i.e., beer excise taxes and alcohol use), then utilizing alcohol excise tax rates as instrumental variables would be questionable. To address these concerns, we estimate the effects of different types of excise tax rates on economic growth in Section VII. If the various types of alcohol excise tax rates have differential effects on economic growth and the suggested relationship is likely through the effect of excise taxes on consumption behavior, the findings would provide evidence in favor of the hypothesis that alcohol excise tax rates do not violate the exclusion restriction; nevertheless, the opposite would cast doubt on the legitimacy of excise tax rates as suitable instruments.

Another concern is that if beer excise tax rates have an impact on income growth through their correlations with policies taking place at the national level within the same year, the exclusion restriction may be violated. To mitigate this concern, we control for year dummies to account for the effect of annual changes at the national level. Hence, this potential problem is minimized in our framework. Finally, if alcohol excise tax rates affect income growth through their potential effect on business activity, the exclusion restriction, discussed above, may be violated. The validity of this concern is also examined in Section VII when we provide reduced form estimates of economic growth on different alcohol excise tax rates. If the estimated coefficients on the alcohol excise tax rates are negative and statistically significant in the reduced form specifications, then the validity of alcohol excise tax rates can be at risk because an inverse relationship between excise tax rates and income growth would suggest deadweight losses induced by inefficient taxation. However, if the estimated effects are positive and statistically significant, the validity of alcohol excise tax rates as instruments will be much less questionable since a reduced form positive relationship suggests that the influence of alcohol excise tax rates is through their effect on behavior. (23)

IV. DATA

Descriptive statistics for the data are shown in Table 1. Data on yearly state-level per capita alcohol sales measures for the population 14 years and older for the period 1971-2007 come from the National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism (NIAAA 2010). Per capita beer, wine, and liquor consumption reflect the gallons of per capita pure ethanol calculated through the sales of beer, wine, and liquor, respectively.

Data on state-level PCPI and per capita GDP come from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). The regional CPI data are obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (1982-1984= 100). Economic growth measures, PCPI growth, and per capita GDP growth are calculated by using the regional CPI-adjusted values of PCPI and per capita GDP.

Data on state-level average total tax to personal income (GDP) ratio and average total expenditure to personal income (GDP) ratio come from the various issues of the Statistical Abstract of the United States. The population age composition data are obtained from the U.S. Census Bureau (2011).

Data on state-level beer excise taxes are taken from the U.S. Brewers Association's Brewers' Almanac for the period 1971-1999. Data on state-level excise liquor and wine taxes for the period 1971-1999 are taken from DISCUS. For the period 2000-2007, data on alcohol excise taxes come from the Tax Foundation (2011). Taxes used in the analysis are adjusted using the regional CPI. In all cases, alcohol excise taxes are calculated by summing up the federal and state excise taxes. (24) Data on the education and ethnic composition variables are obtained from the March Current Population Survey.

V. OLS RESULTS

In all models estimated in this article, standard errors are robust to arbitrary heteroskedasticity and serial correlation at the state level. OLS estimates of PCPI growth are presented in Panels A and B of Table 2. In Panel A, column 1 controls for the lagged PCPI, state total tax to personal income ratio, state total expenditure to personal income ratio, regional inflation, and percent of population under 18 and above 64. As we move from column 2 to 4, the following variables are sequentially added to the models estimated: percent of population in the age group 18-24, educational attainment indicators, and race composition indicators. Although generally statistically insignificant, results show an inverse association between per capita beer sales and PCPI growth. In column 1, a one-gallon increase in per capita beer consumption is linked to a 0.71 percentage point decrease in PCPI growth. In column 4, the model with the most comprehensive control variables, a one-gallon increase in per capita beer consumption is associated with a 0.48 percentage point lower

PCPI growth. Based on column 4, if OLS estimates were to represent the causal relationship between per capita beer consumption and PCPI growth, at the mean level, a 10% increase in per capita beer consumption would cause a 0.062 percentage point decrease in PCPI growth.

Panel B replicates the same exercise for GDP growth. OLS estimates of GDP growth on per capita beer consumption do not suggest a meaningful measurable relationship between the two.

Some of the results associated with the control variables merit discussion. In column 4, the coefficients on lagged PCPI suggest that a thousand dollar increase in PCPI (corresponding to a 7.14% increase in PCPI at the mean level) is associated with a 0.72 percentage point lower PCPI growth rate. The sign of the estimated coefficient on lagged PCPI supports the convergence hypothesis, which predicts that states with higher per capita PCPI are expected to have slower PCPI growth rates. State total tax collections to state personal income ratio and state total expenditures to state personal income ratio are negatively linked to PCPI growth with statistically significant coefficients at less than the 5% level. The coefficient on regional inflation is negative and statistically significant at less than 1% level in all cases. The coefficients on education and race indicators do not seem to be strongly linked to PCPI growth. It should be noted that the estimated coefficients on the control variables just discussed, as well as the ones on the variable of interest (per capita beer consumption), do not always reflect their causal effect on PCPI growth.

VI. INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES RESULTS

A. First-Stage Results

Table 3 presents the first-stage estimation of per capita beer sales on the excise beer tax rate. According to the results, a one-dollar increase in the per gallon beer excise tax rate is associated with a 0.365-gallon decrease in per capita beer sales, and the estimated coefficient is statistically significant at less than the 1% level. At the mean level, the implied beer excise tax elasticity of per capita beer sales is -0.163. (25) That is, a 10% increase in the beer excise tax rate leads to a 1.63% decrease in per capita beer sales. This finding runs parallel to that of previous studies (Ruhm et al. 2011).

B. Second-Stage Results

Table 4 presents the IV estimates for the economic growth measures. Panel A shows the results for the estimates of PCPI growth, whereas Panel B presents the results for the estimates of per capita GDP growth. The first stage F-statistics values (> 100 in Panel A, and >50 in Panel B) indicate a strong first-stage relationship between excise beer tax and beer sales.

The estimated coefficient in Panel A, column 1 suggests that, conditional on other controls, a one-gallon increase in per capita beer consumption leads to a 3.5 percentage point decrease in state-level PCPI growth. Controlling for the percent of population (> 17 and <25) reduces the estimated coefficient from -0.035 to -0.030 in magnitude. In column 3, controlling for state-level education variables increases the estimated coefficient from -0.030 to -0.032 in magnitude. In column 4, results from the model with the most comprehensive controls are presented; a one-gallon increase in per capita beer consumption is associated with a 3.15 percentage point decrease in state PCPI growth. That is, at the mean level, a 10% increase in per capita beer sales leads to a 0.409 percentage point decrease in state PCPI growth. The magnitude and significance of the coefficients on beer consumption remain virtually unaltered across the columns, increasing our confidence in the estimates.

Similar to the results shown in Panel A, the IV estimates of per capita GDP growth on per capita beer sales shown in Panel B suggest an inverse and statistically significant relationship between per capita GDP growth and per capita beer consumption.

VII. REDUCED FORM ESTIMATES OF INCOME GROWTH ON EXCISE TAXES

Examining the reduced form relationships between alcohol and cigarette excise taxes and economic growth measures may produce valuable information, particularly in exploring the validity of beer excise taxes as instruments in our framework.

Panels A and B in Table 5 present the regression results for PCPI growth and per capita GDP growth on alcohol and cigarette excise tax rates, respectively. (26) The results for the excise beer, wine, liquor, and cigarette tax rates, separately and then jointly, are presented in columns i through 5, respectively. The results focusing on the beer excise tax rate are reported in column I. According to the findings, the level of the beer excise tax rate has a positive and statistically significant effect on PCPI growth and per capita GDP growth. On the basis of the estimated coefficients in column 5, a 25% increase in the beer excise tax rate leads to a 0.242 percentage point increase in PCPI growth and a 0.346 percentage point increase in per capita GDP.

The estimated coefficients on the wine, liquor, and cigarette excise tax rates are not statistically significant in any of the models estimated. In column 5, when all four types of excise taxes are jointly estimated, the results are similar to those obtained in columns 1 to 4.

The differential relationships between the various types of excise taxes and the measures of economic growth presented in this section provide evidence supporting using excise tax rates as instruments. If the relationship between the beer excise tax rate and economic growth variables were through state tax revenues or due to other state characteristics affecting economic growth and taxation simultaneously, such relationships between economic growth measures and the different types of excise tax rates would be very similar. Furthermore, it is informative that even though the impacts of wine/liquor and cigarette excise taxes on behavior are different (i.e., excise cigarette taxes seem to affect cigarette sales while excise wine/liquor taxes do not seem to affect wine/liquor sales), neither type seems to have a measurable effect on economic growth in an annual state-level framework for different reasons. That is, even though wine and liquor consumption would have a negative effect on aggregate productivity, wine/liquor excise tax rates do not seem to be related to economic growth, possibly because their power to predict per capita wine/liquor consumption is very limited. On the other hand, although the cigarette excise tax rate strongly predicts per capita cigarette consumption, it does not seem to be significantly related to economic growth (results available upon request), potentially for the reason that smoking-induced costs are expected to have a much smaller effect on economic productivity in the short run in comparison to that induced by drinking.

Overall, these findings suggest that excise tax rates can potentially affect aggregate productivity to the degree that they can affect the consumption behavior in our framework. Hence, these findings suggest that our instrumental variables specifications do not violate the exclusion restriction.

VIII. ADDITIONAL ROBUSTNESS CHECKS

To examine the robustness of our findings we perform additional robustness checks in Tables A1 and A2.

Owing to complementarities between beer drinking and nonbeer alcoholic beverages, the estimates of the effect of per capita beer consumption on economic growth may be misleading if increases/decreases in beer drinking are compensated by corresponding changes in per capita wine and liquor consumption. Therefore, in Table A1, Panel A, economic growth measures are estimated on per capita beer consumption while controlling for per capita wine and liquor consumption. The estimates are robust to controlling for per capita wine and liquor consumption and therefore rule out the possibility that the coefficient on per capita beer consumption is contaminated by simultaneous changes in beer and liquor consumption.

NIAAA data also include per capita alcohol consumption measures for the population 21 years and older. (27) In Panel B, we present IV estimates of economic growth measures on per capita beer sales 21 and older. Results are very similar to those with per capita beer sales 14 and older.

To examine whether outliers in the data may be driving the results, in Panel C we regress PCPI and per capita GDP growth on per capita beer sales by excluding the state-year observations at the top and bottom 10% of the distribution, respectively. Results, which are similar to the main estimates, suggest that our findings are not driven by outliers in the data. In Panel D, we present the results for the 5-year averages for the period 1971-2005. The estimates are similar to the main results.

To further investigate the robustness of our findings, in Table A2, Panel A, we present estimates of income growth measures on per capita total ethanol/alcohol sales. By doing so, we also provide a test of whether the estimated coefficient on per capita beer consumption is representative of the changes in per capita total ethanol change. Results run parallel to the ones for per capita beer sales specifications. In Panels B, C, and D of Table A2, we perform robustness checks similar to the ones performed in the corresponding panels of Table A1. The estimates of economic growth measures on per capita total ethanol sales are similar to those on per capita beer use measures. Therefore, these results are suggestive that changes in per capita ethanol consumption through beer are representative of changes in per capita total ethanol consumption. Nevertheless, it should be noted that we cannot dismiss the possibility that the coefficient estimate on per capita total ethanol consumption may be driven by per capita beer consumption.

IX. DISCUSSION

A vast body of literature on alcohol use documents that beer consumption generates negative externalities that are large in magnitude, and increases in excise beer taxes would reduce such externalities. This article provides evidence of an inverse relationship between drinking and state-level income growth. Our results suggest that the cost of drinking may indeed be borne by society as a whole.

In particular, our preferred estimates suggest that a standard deviation increase in per capita beer consumption (of 0.241 gallons) from the mean (of 1.299 gallons) would lead to a 0.76 percentage point increase in PCPI growth and a 1.54 percentage point increase in per capita GDP growth. Nevertheless, we should note that the aim of this study was not to predict economic growth in the long run, but rather to estimate the potential effect that drinking might have on economic growth in the short run (i.e., in a state-level yearly framework). Since per capita beer sales have remained relatively stable over time, they cannot explain a high portion of the variation in income growth over the entire period (1971 to 2007). (28) Another naive interpretation of these results would be to claim that prohibition would increase prosperity. Prohibition may affect business activity through multiple channels including loss in tourism revenues, increases in illegal activity, and changes in market structure, in addition to its potential effect on drinking. Even though this study provides evidence that alcohol use has a small but statistically significant effect on income growth, our findings cannot be used to draw conclusions regarding prohibition as a policy tool.

There are several limitations to this study. In this article, we are able to explore net effects on the economy, but we do not empirically test mechanisms. While we argue as to reasons for using beer consumption as a proxy for alcohol abuse, we do not directly test for abuse. Moreover, while we use several methods to address the potential endogeneity of beer consumption, establishing causality remains a difficult task.

Our results do, contrary to the claims of the Distilled Spirits Council and Beer Serves America, suggest that alcohol excise taxes do not harm economic activity at the aggregate level. If anything, our results show that beer excise tax rates are directly linked to economic growth. As a policy prescription, our reduced form estimates suggest that an increase in the real beer excise tax of 26 cents (one standard deviation) over the current mean of 31 cents (based on 2011 data) would potentially increase PCPI growth by 0.43 percentage points, or 27% from the mean, and lower the economic costs associated with alcohol consumption. While no prior studies to our knowledge have examined the effects of excise beer taxes on economic growth, many analyze the effects of taxes in general (particularly income taxes) on growth, and the magnitudes we find are reasonable. (29) Owing to the negative externalities associated with excessive alcohol consumption, analyzing the effects of these types of excise taxes on economic growth in more detail should be high on economists' research agendas.

ABBREVIATIONS

ACCRA: American Chamber of Commerce Researchers Association

BEA: Bureau of Economic Analysis

CPI: Consumer Price Index

DISCUS: Distilled Spirits Council of the United States

DUI: Driving Under the Influence

GDP: Gross Domestic Product

IV: Instrumental Variables

NBWA: National Beer Wholesalers Association

NIAAA: National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism

OLS: Ordinary Least Squares

PCPI: Per Capita Personal Income

doi: 10.1111/ecin.12048

APPENDIX
TABLE A1
IV Estimates of PCPI and GDP Growth on Per Capita Beer Sales,
Robustness Estimates

                                         (1)           (2)
Dependent Variable                    PCPI Growth   GDP Growth

Panel A: Controlling for per capita wine and liquor sales

Per capita beer sales 14 and older    -0.0465 **    -0.0664 *
                                       (0.0228)      (0.0348)
Observations                             1.776        1,776
[R.sup.2]                                0.562        0.523
First stage F test                       43.86        55.04
First stage F test p value               0.00          0.00

Panel B: Estimates of growth on per capita beer sales 21 and older

Per capita beer sales 21 and older    -0.0370 **    -0.0520 **
                                       (0.0169)      (0.0263)
Observations                             1,776        1,776
[R.sup.2]                                0.556        0.516
First stage F test                       54.50        61.95
First stage F test p value               0.00          0.00

Panel C: Estimates of growth measures excluding potential outliers

                                          Excluding Top 10%

Per capita beer sales 14 and older    -0.0458 **    -0.0727 *
                                       (0.0229)      (0.0373)
Observations                             1,598        1,598
[R.sup.2]                                0.563        0.543
First stage F test                       44.30        50.22
First stage F test p value               0.00          0.00

Panel D: Estimates of growth measures, 5-year averages sample
Per capita beer sales 14 and older     -0.0343 *     -0.0512
                                       (0.0192)      (0.0381)
Observations                              336          336
[R.sup.2]                                0.482        0.292
First stage F test                       23.95        29.74
First stage F test p value               0.00          0.00

                                          (3)          (4)
Dependent Variable                    PCPI Growth   GDP Growth

Panel A: Controlling for per capita wine and liquor sales
Per capita beer sales 14 and older

Observations
[R.sup.2]
First stage F test
First stage F test p value

Panel B: Estimates of growth on per capita beer sales 21 and older
Per capita beer sales 21 and older

Observations
[R.sup.2]
First stage F test
First stage F test p value

Panel C: Estimates of growth measures excluding potential outliers

                                         Excluding Bottom 10%

Per capita beer sales 14 and older     -0.0581 *    -0.0814 *
                                       (0.0343)      (0.0492)
Observations                             1,599        1,599
[R.sup.2]                                0.528        0.493
First stage F test                       15.27        21.13
First stage F test p value               0.00          0.00

Panel D: Estimates of growth measures, 5-year averages sample
Per capita beer sales 14 and older

Observations
[R.sup.2]
First stage F test
First stage F test p value

Notes: Robust standard errors corrected for clustering on the state
are in parentheses. All models control for full set of controls used
in column 4 of Table 4 as well as state- and year-fixed effects.

*** 17 < .01, ** p < .05, * p < .1.

TABLE A2
IV Estimates of PCPI and GDP Growth on Per Capita Total
Ethanol/Alcohol Sales

                                         (1)          (2)
Dependent Variable                   PCPI Growth   GDP Growth

Panel A: Estimates of growth on per capita total ethanol/alcohol sales

Per capita total ethanol/alcohol     -0.0314 **    -0.0442 *
  sales 14 and older                  (0.0142)      (0.0228)
Observations                            1.776        1.776
[R.sup.2]                               0.531        0.487
First stage F test                      12.31        13.96
First stage F test p value              0.00          0.00

Panel B: Estimates of growth on per capita ethanol/alcohol sales 21
  and older

Per capita total ethanol/alcohol      -0.0247 *    -0.0349 **
  sales 21 and older                  (0.0110)      (0.0177)
Observations                            1.776        1,776
[R.sup.2]                               0.526        0.481
First stage F-test                      12.23        13.42
First stage F test p value              0.00          0.00

Panel C: Estimates of growth measures
                                          Excluding Top 10%

Per capita total ethanol/alcohol     -0.0371 **    -0.0581 *
  sales 14 and older                  (0.0178)      (0.0312)
Observations                            1.598        1.598
[R.sup.2]                               0.550        0.510
First stage F test                      20.12        19.68
First stage F test p value              0.00          0.00

Panel D: Estimates of growth measures, 5-Year averages sample

Per capita total ethanol/alcohol      -0.0216 *     -0.0333
  sales 14 and older                  (0.0121)      (0.0254)
Observations                             336          336
[R.sup.2]                               0.431        0.201
First stage F test                      6.99          7.60
First stage F test p value              0.01          0.00

                                         (3)          (4)
Dependent Variable                   PCPI Growth   GDP Growth

Panel A: Estimates of growth on per capita total ethanol/alcohol sales
Per capita total ethanol/alcohol
  sales 14 and older
Observations
[R.sup.2]
First stage F test
First stage F test p value

Panel B: Estimates of growth on per capita ethanol/alcohol sales 21
  and older
Per capita total ethanol/alcohol
  sales 21 and older
Observations
[R.sup.2]
First stage F-test
First stage F test p value

Panel C: Estimates of growth measures excluding potential outliers
                                        Excluding Bottom 10%

Per capita total ethanol/alcohol      -0.0286 *     -0.0330
  sales 14 and older                  (0.0150)      (0.0225)
Observations                            1.599        1.599
[R.sup.2]                               0.525        0.508
First stage F test                      11.55        14.24
First stage F test p value              0.00          0.00

Panel D: Estimates of growth measures, 5-Year averages sample
Per capita total ethanol/alcohol
  sales 14 and older
Observations
[R.sup.2]
First stage F test
First stage F test p value

Notes: Robust standard errors corrected for clustering on the state
are in parentheses. All models control for full set of controls used
in column 4 of Table 4 as well as state- and year-fixed effects.

*** p < .01, ** p < .05. * p < .1.


REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., and S. Johnson. "Disease and Development: The Effect of Life Expectancy on Economic Growth." Journal of Political Economy, 115(6), 2007, 925-85.

Ashraf, Q. H., A. Lester, and D. N. Weil. "When Does Improving Health Raise GDP?" in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2008, Vol. 23, edited by D. Acemoglu, K. Rogoff, and M. Woodford. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2009, 157-204.

Baker, D. B. "The Study of Stress at Work." Annual Review of Public Health, 6, 1985, 367-81.

Barker, F. "'Consumption Externalities and the Role of Government: The Case of Alcohol." New Zealand Treasury Working Paper 02/25, 2002.

Beer Serves America. "Economic Impact." 2011. Accessed January 14, 2012. http://www.beerservesamerica.org/ economic/default.aspx.

Berger. M.C., and J.P. Leigh. "The Effect of Alcohol Use on Wages." Applied Economics, 20, 1988, 1343-51.

Blum, T. C., P.M. Roman, and J. K. Martin. "Alcohol Consumption and Work Performance." Journal of Studies on Alcohol. 54(1), 1993, 61-70.

Bouchery, E. E., H. J. Harwood, J. J. Sacks, C. J. Simon, and R. D. Brewer. "Economic Costs of Excessive Alcohol Consumption in the U.S." American Journal of Preventive Medicine, 41(5), 2006, 516-24.

Bray, J. W. "Alcohol Use, Human Capital, and Wages." Journal of Labor Economics, 23(2), 2005, 279-312.

Brenner, M. H., and A. Mooney. "Unemployment and Health in the Context of Economic Change." Social Science Medicine, 17(16), 1983, 1125-38.

Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. "WISQARS Fatal Injuries: Mortality Reports." 2004. Accessed December 15, 2011. http://webappa.cdc.gov/sasweb/ ncipc/mortrate.html.

--. "Binge Drinking: Nationwide Problem, Local Solutions." 2012. Accessed December 15, 2011. http://www.cdc.gov/vitalsigns/BingeDrinking/#.

Chaloupka F. J., M. Grossman, and H. Saffer. "The Effects of Price on Alcohol Consumption and Alcohol-Related Problems." Alcohol Research and Health, 26(1), 2002, 22-34.

Chaloupka F. J., H. Saffer, and M. Grossman "Alcohol-Control Policies and Motor Vehicle Fatalities." Journal of Legal Studies, 22(1), 1993, 161-86.

Chatterji, P., and J. DeSimone. "High School Alcohol Use and Young Adult Labor Market Outcomes." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 12529. 2006.

Chesson, H., P. Harrison, and W. J. Kassler. "Sex Under the Influence: The Effect of Alcohol Policy on Sexually Transmitted Disease Rates in the United States." Journal of Law and Economics, 43(1), 2000, 215-38.

Collins, D. J., and H. M. Lapsley. "The Social Costs of Drug Abuse in Australia in 1988 and 1992." National Drug Strategy Monograph Series, 30, 1996.

Cook, P. J. Paying the Tab: The Costs and Benefits of Alcohol Control. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2007.

Cook, P. J., and M. J. Moore. "This Tax's for You: The Case for Higher Beer Taxes." National Tax Journal, 47(3), 1994, 559-73.

--. "The Economics of Alcohol Abuse and Alcohol Control Policies." Health Affairs, 21(2), 2002, 120-33.

Dee, T. S. "Alcohol Abuse and Economic Conditions: Evidence from Repeated Cross-Sections of Individual-Level Data." Health Economics, 10(3), 2001, 257-70.

Distilled Spirits Council of the United States (DISCUS). History of Beverage Alcohol Tax Changes. Washington, DC: DISCUS, 1999.

Ettner, S. L. "Measuring the Human Cost of a Weak Economy: Does Unemployment Lead to Alcohol Abuse?" Social Science Medicine, 44(2), 1997, 251-60.

Fenwick, R., and M. Tausig. "The Macroeconomic Context of Job Stress." Journal of Health and Social Behavior, 35(3), 1994, 266-82.

Freeman, D. G. "Alternative Panel Estimates of Alcohol Demand, Taxation and the Business Cycle." Southern Economic Journal, 67(2), 2000, 325-44.

French, M. T., and G. A. Zarkin. "Is Moderate Alcohol Use Related to Wages? Evidence from Four Worksites." Journal of Health Economics, 14(3), 1995, 319-44.

Greenfield, T. K., and J. D. Rogers. "Who Drinks Most of the Alcohol in the U.S.? The Policy Implications." Journal of Studies on Alcohol, 60(1), 1999, 78-89.

Gronbaek, M. "Factors Influencing the Relation between Alcohol and Mortality With Focus on Wine." Journal of Internal Medicine, 250, 2001, 291-308.

Gwartney, J. D., and R. A. Lawson. "The Impact of Tax Policy on Economic Growth, Income Distribution, and Allocation of Taxes." Social Philosophy and Policy, 23, 2006, 28-52.

Hamilton, V., and B. Hamilton. "Alcohol and Earnings: Does Drinking Yield a Wage Premium?" Canadian Journal of Economics, 30(1), 1997, 135-51.

Harwood, H. J., D. M. Napolitano, P. L. Kristiansen, and J. J. Collins, eds. Economic Costs to Society of Alcohol and Drug Abuse and Mental Illness. Research Triangle Park, NC: Research Triangle Institute, 1984.

Hilton, M. E., and W. B. Clark. "Changes in American Drinking Patterns and Problems, 1967-1984." Journal of Studies on Alcohol, 48(6), 1987, 515-22.

Hingson, R., and M. Winter. Epidemiology and Consequences of Drinking and Driving. Bethesda, MD: National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism of the National Institute of Health, 2003.

Hoftmeister, H., F. P. Schelp, G. B. Mensink, E. Dietz, and D. Bohning. "The Relationship Between Alcohol Consumption, Health Indicators and Mortality in the German Population." International Journal of Epidemiology, 28(6), 1999, 1066-72.

Johansson, E., P. Bockerman, and A. Uutela. "Alcohol Consumption and Sickness Absence, Evidence from Micro-Data." European Journal of Public Health, 19(1). 2009, 19-22.

Kalemli-Ozcan, S. "Does the Mortality Decline Promote Economic Growth?" Journal of Economic Growth, 7(4), 2002, 311-49.

Kalemli-Ozcan, S., H. E. Ryder, and D. Weft. "Mortality Decline, Human Capital Investment, and Economic Growth." Journal of Development Economics, 62(1), 2000, 1-23.

Karasek, R. A., and T. Theorell. Healthy Work: Stress, Productivity, and the Reconstruction of Working Life. New York: Basic Books, 1990.

Kenkel. D.S., and P. Wang. "Are Alcoholics in Bad Jobs?" in The Economic Analysis of Substance Use and Abuse, edited by F. J. Chaloupka, M. Grossman, W. K. Bickel, and H. Saffer. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1999, 251-78.

Klatsky, A. L. "Alcohol and Cardiovascular Diseases: A Historical Overview." Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, 957, 2002, 7-15.

LaVallee, R. A., and H. Yi. "Apparent Per Capita Alcohol Consumption: National, State, and Regional Trends, 1977-2009." National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism, 2011. Accessed January 20, 2012. http://pubs.niaaa.nih.gov/publications/Surveillance92/ CONS09.pdf.

Lehman, W. E. K., and D. D. Simpson. "Employee Substance Use and On-the-Job Behaviors." Journal of Applied Psychology, 77(3), 1992, 309-21.

Levitt, S. D., and J. Porter. "How Dangerous Are Drinking Drivers?" Journal of Political Economy, 109(61), 2001, 1198-237.

Manning, W.G., E.B. Keeler, J.P. Newhouse, E. M. Sloss, and J. Wasserman. "The Taxes of Sin: Do Smokers and Drinkers Pay Their Way?" Journal of the American Medical Association, 261(11), 1989, 1604-9.

Markowitz, S. "The Effectiveness of Cigarette Regulations in Reducing Cases of Sudden Infant Death Syndrome." Journal of Health Economics, 27(1), 2008, 106-33.

Markowitz, S., R. Kaestner, and M. Grossman. "An Investigation of the Effects of Alcohol Consumption and Alcohol Policies on Youth Risky Sexual Behaviors." American Economic Review, 95(2), 2005, 263-66.

McDonald, Z., and M. A. Shields. "The Impact of Alcohol Consumption on Occupational Attainment in England." Economica, 68, 2001, 455-63.

Murray, C. J. L., and A. D. Lopez. The Global Burden of Disease: A Comprehensive Assessment of Mortality and Disability from Diseases, Injuries and Risk Factors in 1990 and Projected to 2020. Global Burden of Disease and Injury Series, Vol. I. Cambridge, MA: Harvard School of Public Health on behalf of the World Health Organization and the World Bank, 1996.

National Institute on Alcohol Abuse and Alcoholism. Apparent Per Capita Ethanol Consumption for the United States, 1970-2007. 2010. Accessed September 20, 2011. http://www.niaaa.nih.gov/Resources/DatabaseResources/QuickFacts/AlcoholSales/cons um01.htm.

Norstrom T. "Per Capita Alcohol Consumption and Sickness Absence." Addiction, 101(10), 2006, 1421-27.

Orzechowski, W., and R. C. Walker. The Tax Burden on Tobacco, Vol. 40. Arlington, VA: Orzechowski & Walker, 2005.

Parry, I. W. H., S. E. West, and R. Laxminarayan. "Fiscal and Externality Rationales for Alcohol Policies." B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 9(1), 2009, 1-48.

Pierce, R. S., M. R. Frone, M. Russell, and M. L. Cooper. "Relationship of Financial Strain and Psychosocial Resources to Alcohol Use and Abuse: The Mediating Role of Negative Affect and Drinking Motives." Journal of Health and Social Behavior, 35(4), 1994, 291-308.

Rashad, I., and R. Kaestner. "Teenage Sex, Drugs and Alcohol Use: Problems Identifying the Cause of Risky Behaviors." Journal of Health Economics, 23(3), 2004, 493-503.

Rehm, J., G. Gmel, C.T. Sempos, and M. Trevisan. "Alcohol-Related Morbidity and Mortality." Alcohol Research and Health, 27(1), 2003, 39-51.

Rice, D. P., S. Kelman, L. S. Miller, and S. Dunmeyer. The Economic Costs of Alcohol and Drug Abuse and Mental Illness: 1985. Report submitted to the Office of Financing and Coverage Policy of the Alcohol, Drug Abuse, and Mental Health Administration (US Department of Health and Human Services, Institute for Health & Aging, University of California, San Francisco), 1990.

Room, R., and D. Jernigan. "The Ambiguous Role of Alcohol in Economic and Social Development." Addiction, 95(12s4), 2000, 523-35.

Rosenbaum, D.P., S.F. Bennett, B.D. Lindsay. D. L. Wilkinson, B.D. Davis, C. Taranowski, and P. J. Lavrakas. Executive Summary: The Community, Responses to Drug Abuse National Demonstration Program Final Process Report. Chicago, IL: Center for Research in Law and Justice, University of Illinois, 1992.

Ruhm, C. J. "Economic Conditions and Alcohol Problems." Journal of Health Economics, 14(5), 1995, 583-603.

--. "Alcohol Policies and Highway Vehicle Fatalities." Journal of Health Economics, 15(4), 1996, 435-54.

Ruhm, C.J., and W. E. Black. "Does Drinking Really Decrease in Bad Times?" Journal of Health Economics, 21, 2002, 659-78.

Ruhm, C.J., A.S. Jones, W.C. Kerr, T.K. Greenfield, J. V. Terza, R. S. Pandian, and K. McGeary. "What U.S. Data Should Be Used to Measure the Price Elasticity of Demand for Alcohol." National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 17578, 2011.

Skog, O.-J. "An Analysis of Divergent Trends in Alcohol Consumption and Economic Development." Journal of Studies on Alcohol, 47(1), 1986, 19-25.

Sloan, F. A., B.A. Reilly, and C. Schenzler. "Effects of Tort Liability and Insurance on Heavy Drinking and Drinking and Driving." Journal of Law and Economics, 38(1), 1995, 49-78.

Smith G. S., C. C. Branas, and T. R. Miller. "Fatal Non-traffic Injuries Involving Alcohol: A Meta-Analysis." Annals of Emergency Medicine, 33(5), 1999, 659-68.

Sokejima, S., and S. Kagamimori. "Working Hours as a Risk Factor for Acute Myocardial Infarction in Japan: A Case-Control Study." British Medical Journal, 317(19), 1998, 775-80.

Stockwell, T., and D. Crosbie. "Supply and Demand for Alcohol in Australia: Relationships Between Industry Structures, Regulation and the Marketplace." International Journal of Drug Policy, 12(2), 2001, 139-52.

Tax Foundation. Tax Data. 2011. Accessed November 18, 2011. http://www.taxfoundation.org/news/show/245. html.

Tekin, E. "Employment, Wages, and Alcohol Consumption in Russia." Southern Economic Journal, 71(2), 2004, 397-417.

Thun, M.J., R. Peto, A. D. Lopez, J. H. Monaco, S. J. Henley, C. W. Heath Jr., and R. Doll. "Alcohol Consumption and Mortality among Middle-Aged and Elderly U.S. Adults." New England Journal of Medicine, 337(24), 1997, 1705-14.

Tomljanovich, M. "The Role of Fiscal Policy in State Economic Growth." Contemporary Economic Policy, 22 (3), 2004, 318-30.

Traynor, T. L. "The Impact of Driver Alcohol Use on Crash Severity: A Crash Specific Analysis." Transportation Research: Part E: Logistics and Transportation Review, 41(5), 2005, 421-37.

United State Census Bureau. The Statistical Abstract (various years). Accessed December 14, 2011. http://www. census.gov/compendia/statab/.

U.S. Department of Health and Human Services Report. The Economic Costs of Alcohol Abuse in the United States. 2000. Accessed July 17, 2008. http://pubs.niaaa. nih.gov/publications/economic-2000/index.htm.

West, R., J. Wilding, D. French, R. Kemp, and A. Irving. "Effect of Low and Moderate Doses of Alcohol on Driving Hazard Perception Latency and Driving Speed." Addiction, 88(4), 1993, 527-32.

Winton, M., N. Heather, and I. Robertson. "Effects of Unemployment on Drinking Behavior: A Review of the Relevant Evidence." International Journal of Addictions, 21(12), 1986, 1261-83.

World Health Organization. "Mental Health: New Understanding, New Hope." World Health Report 2001. 2001.

Young, D. J., and A. Bielinska-Kwapisz. "Alcohol Taxes and Beverage Prices." National Tax Journal, 55(1), 2002, 57-73.

--. "Alcohol Consumption, Beverage Prices and Measurement Error." Journal of Studies on Alcohol, 64(2), 2003, 235-38.

* We thank Rexford Santerre, Jorge Martinez, Sally Wallace, Neven Valev, Angela Snyder, Dhaval Dave, Robert E. Rosenman, two anonymous reviewers, and participants at the 2009 Eastern Economic Association meetings for their valuable comments and suggestions. We are grateful to Sara Markowitz for allowing us to use her data on cigarette sales and taxes from Markowitz (2008). We are grateful to Marc Tomljanovich for allowing us to use his data from Tomljanovich (2004) in the earlier versions of this paper. R.C. thanks the Center for Real Estate and Urban Economic Studies of the Business School at the University of Connecticut for the statistical software purchase.

Cesur: Assistant Professor, Department of Finance, School of Business, University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT 06269. Phone 1-860-486-6315, Fax 1-860 486-0634, E-mail [email protected]

Kelly: Associate Professor, Department of Economics, Queens College of the City University of New York, Flushing, NY 11367. Phone 1-718-997-5440, Fax 1-718997-5466, E-mail [email protected]

(1.) See http://www.beerservesamerica.com/about.aspx.

(2.) See http://www.discus.org/about/.

(3.) This statistic takes into account ethanol content and has already made the conversion; since beer has a relatively low ethanol content compared to other alcoholic beverages, if raw sales not taking ethanol into account were looked at, this percentage would be much higher. The Alcohol Epidemiologic Data System uses an estimate of average ethanol content in the alcoholic beverages to convert the gallons of sold or shipped beer, wine, and spirits into gallons of ethanol--pure alcohol--before calculating per capita consumption estimates. The ethanol conversion coefficients are 0.045 for beer, 0.129 for wine, and 0.411 for spirits (LaValee and Yi 2011).

(4.) There are 18 such "control" states for liquor and five such states for wine (Ruhm et al. 2011).

(5.) See Chaloupka, Saffer, and Grossman (1993), Cook (2007), Cook and Moore (1994, 2000), Freeman (2000), Markowitz, Kaestner, and Grossman (2005), Ruhm (1996), and Young and Bielinska-Kwapisz (2002, 2003). Note that we also estimate income growth measures on per capita beer consumption controlling for per capita wine and liquor consumption as well as total ethanol consumption in Section VIII as a robustness check. Results from the robustness check exercises, presented in Tables A1 and A2, have similar implications.

(6.) We also conduct a falsification exercise using cigarette consumption and cigarette excise taxes similar to that conducted by Rashad and Kaestner (2004). This exercise reveals that cigarette consumption has no significant effect on per capita GDP or per capita personal income (results available upon request). Since smoking is not without its negative externalities, this exercise is comforting in that it may arguably suggest that the results we obtain are conservative. Data for this exercise on cigarette excise taxes and per capita cigarette sales come from Markowitz (2008), who obtained data from Orzechowski and Walker (2005).

(7.) In all specifications, we control for state-fixed effects. Therefore, by OLS we refer to an OLS with state-fixed effects methodology. The term OLS is used for simplicity.

(8.) A host of other factors can be listed as the determinants of economic growth. For the sake of providing a clear argument, we restrict the discussion to the factors more relevant to our study.

(9.) See French and Zarkin (1995), Johansson, Bockerman, and Uutela (2009), Lehman and Simpson (1992), Norstrrm (2006), and Rosenbaum et al. (1992).

(10.) See Blum, Roman, and Martin (1993), Harwood et al. (1984), Hilton and Clark (1987), Kenkel and Wang (1999), and Rice et al. (1990).

(11.) See Chesson, Harrison, and Kassler (2000), Hingson and Winter (2003), Levitt and Porter (2001), Markowitz, Kaesmer, and Grossman (2005), Murray and Lopez (1996), Traynor (2005), and West et al. (1993).

(12.) While one can argue that money is being put into circulation through injury treatment and rebuilding expenditures, this money could be better put to use productively through investment in new business enterprises. We thank an anonymous reviewer for pointing this out.

(13.) They instrument for life expectancy using predicted mortality, which is created by interacting baseline mortality rates with exogenous worldwide health shocks.

(14.) As discussed above, the impact of mortality and longevity may have differential effects in the short and long run. The focus of this study is on short-run income growth.

(15.) See Berger and Leigh (1988), Bray (2005), Chatterji and DeSimone (2006), French and Zarkin (1995), Hamilton and Hamilton (1997), McDonald and Shields (2001), and Tekin (2004).

(16.) Our aggregate models do not distinguish between alcohol use and alcohol abuse. However, our measures are a good reflection of abuse, as those who abuse alcohol are responsible for most of its consumption (Greenfield and Rogers 1999). Our 2007 data indicate that there is a strong, positive correlation between per capita beer consumption and binge drinking (males having five or more drinks on one occasion or females having four or more drinks on one occasion, obtained from the Behavioral Risk Factor Surveillance System), significant at the 1% level.

(17.) In addition to the state and year-fixed effects, state-specific time trends could be specified. However, beer excise taxes exhibit strong long-term downward trends since the 1970s, with the exception of the 1990 federal excise tax increases. In particular, the state and time-fixed effects along with individual state time trends and time-fixed effects explain 97.2% of the variation in the beer tax. Therefore, because state and regional trends are strongly collinear with the instrument utilized, we do not control for state-specific time trends in our models.

(18.) The current value of the state-level PCPI (or per capita GDP) is jointly determined with the growth rate; therefore, lagged values of PCPI (or per capita GDP) are utilized in the specifications to account for the effect of convergence as well as the effect of PCPI on alcohol use. An alternative is to use initial per capita personal income. Because state-fixed effects are controlled for, the initial per capita personal income cannot be used. A common practice in aggregate level income growth estimations is to average the data over 5-year intervals to account for the effect of business cycles, which last about 4 to 5 years. In such specifications, the initial per capita income for each 5-year period is controlled for to account for the convergence effect. Because we restrict our analysis to yearly data to capture the changes in beer use by utilizing annual state-level per capita beer consumption, we do not use 5-year averages in our main estimates; nevertheless, in Appendix Tables A1 and A2 we present results from regression models using 5-year averages for the period 1971-2005. The results obtained from these specifications are similar to our main results.

(19.) See, for example, Brenner and Mooney (1983), Pierce et al. (1994), and Winton, Heather, and Robertson (1986).

(20.) See Baker (1985), Fenwick and Tausing (1994), Karasek and Theorell (1990), and Sokejima and Kagamimori (1998).

(21.) Alternative instruments, such as dry county laws, were considered. However, dry county laws are not valid instruments in our framework because they may have a direct impact on business activity, since they automatically crowd out some businesses out of the county. People from dry counties may go to bars and restaurants in neighboring counties or states; thus, dry county laws may diminish business activity in addition to reducing alcohol use in the county and/or state. Moreover, because time variation in such laws is relatively limited, state-fixed effects generally capture the impact of such laws.

(22.) Instead of alcohol excise taxes, alcohol prices may be employed as instruments. In our framework, prices of alcoholic beverages are not suitable instruments since it is likely that beverage prices may be influenced by economic growth (or the business cycle). Because the potential relationship between beverage prices and income growth violates the exclusion restriction, alcohol prices are not used as instruments. In addition, the most commonly used price data, which come from the ACCRA, are subject to significant measurement error (Ruhm et al. 2011; Young and Bielinka-Kwapisz 2002).

(23.) Table 5 presents the reduced form regressions of income growth on alcohol excise tax rates. The results, presented and discussed in Section VII, provide evidence in favor of the view that alcohol excise tax rates are suitable instruments in our framework.

(24.) This is done to present the taxes that individuals face, for the purpose of showing accurate means. However, since federal excise taxes are constant across states, all variations are due to the state-year variation in state excise taxes. Results are robust to using state-level beer excise tax rates excluding the federal beer excise tax rate.

(25.) Beer excise tax elasticity of per capita beer consumption = [(-0.3561 / 1.299) * 100]/[(1/0.581) * 100] = -0.0163.

(26.) We also include cigarette excise tax rates in this model for the sake of completeness, as we used these taxes in the falsification exercise outlined in footnote 6.

(27.) NIAAA data contain information on gallons of alcoholic beverage (beer, wine, and liquor) sales per capita as well. Estimates based on per capita alcoholic beverage sales measures are very similar to those obtained by utilizing per capita ethanol sales measures.

(28.) A one standard deviation increase in per capita beer sales, which corresponds to 18.5%, is a very large increase given that annual changes are relatively small; the annual period average is 0.33% and in most years, in absolute value, it is less than 2%.

(29.) Gwartney and Lawson (2006), for example, estimate that a 10 percentage point reduction in a country's top marginal tax rate (mainly for marginal tax rates in excess of 50%) will increase the economic growth rate by approximately three-tenths of a percentage point.
TABLE 1
Descriptive Statistics

Variable                               All Years    1970s      1980s

Per capita beer sales (14 plus), in      1.299      1.279      1.363
  gallons                               (0.241)    (0.277)    (0.247)
Per capita wine sales (14 plus), in      0.296      0.272      0.320
  gallons                               (0.154)    (0.155)    (0.163)
Per capita liquor sales (14 plus),       0.872      1.132      0.929
  in gallons                            (0.403)    (0.531)    (0.362)
Per capita ethanol/Alcohol sales         2.468      2.683      2.611
  (14 plus), in gallons                 (0.668)    (0.854)    (0.671)
CPI-adjusted beer excise tax per         0.581      0.897      0.470
  gallon (levels, 1982-1984 dollars)    (0.276)    (0.355)    (0.161)
CPI-adjusted wine excise tax per         0.963      1.107      0.698
  gallon (levels, 1982-1984 dollars)    (0.526)    (0.755)    (0.432)
CPI-adjusted liquor excise tax per      13.836      23.406     12.731
  gallon (levels, 1982-1984 dollars)    (6.322)    (5.200)    (1.810)
CPI-adjusted cigarette excise tax        3.820      3.837      2.825
  per 10 packs (levels, 1982-1984       (1.774)    (1.034)    (0.655)
  dollars)
Per capita personal income in           13.984      11.235     12.700
  thousands (1982-1984 dollars)         (3.047)    (1.548)    (1.984)
Per capita personal income growth        0.017      0.022      0.016
                                        (0.028)    (0.038)    (0.029)
Total tax to state personal income       0.064      0.062      0.063
  ratio                                 (0.012)    (0.011)    (0.013)
Total public expenditure to state        0.103      0.082      0.079
  personal income ratio                 (0.037)    (0.017)    (0.018)
Per capita gross domestic product       16.648      13.737     15.067
  (GDP) in thousands (1982-1984         (3.833)    (2.133)    (2.771)
  dollars)
Per capita GDP growth                    0.016      0.022      0.012
                                        (0.036)    (0.044)    (0.044)
Total tax to state GDP ratio             0.054      0.051      0.053
                                        (0.010)    (0.009)    (0.009)
Total public expenditure to state        0.087      0.067      0.067
  GDP                                   (0.032)    (0.013)    (0.014)
Regional inflation                       0.045      0.070      0.053
                                        (0.028)    (0.026)    (0.032)
Percent of population (<18 and >64)      0.395      0.423      0.391
                                        (0.025)    (0.021)    (0.021)
Percent of population (>17 and <25)      0.113      0.129      0.122
                                        (0.016)    (0.009)    (0.012)
Percent with less than high school       0.232      0.355      0.263
  degree                                (0.105)     (0.076    (0.073)
Percent with a high school degree        0.355      0.343      0.364
                                        (0.042)    (0.036)    (0.041)
Percent with some college or             0.210      0.153      0.188
  vocational degree                     (0.060)    (0.042)    (0.044)
Percent with a college degree            0.202      0.143      0.185
                                        (0.061)    (0.032)    (0.041)
Percent White                            0.842      0.907      0.866
                                        (0.116)    (0.067)    (0.095)
Percent Black                            0.096      0.081      0.090
                                        (0.092)    (0.069)    (0.088)
Percent other race                       0.062      0.012      0.044
                                        (0.080)    (0.020)    (0.053)
Observations                             1776        432        480

Variable                                1990s      2000s

Per capita beer sales (14 plus), in     1.283      1.263
  gallons                              (0.212)    (0.209)
Per capita wine sales (14 plus), in     0.274      0.324
  gallons                              (0.132)    (0.159)
Per capita liquor sales (14 plus),      0.703      0.721
  in gallons                           (0.254)    (0.229)
Per capita ethanol/Alcohol sales        2.260      2.308
  (14 plus), in gallons                (0.497)    (0.465)
CPI-adjusted beer excise tax per        0.522      0.440
  gallon (levels, 1982-1984 dollars)   (0.120)    (0.090)
CPI-adjusted wine excise tax per        1.107      0.954
  gallon (levels, 1982-1984 dollars)   (0.385)    (0.288)
CPI-adjusted liquor excise tax per      10.559     8.548
  gallon (levels, 1982-1984 dollars)   (1.516)    (1.227)
CPI-adjusted cigarette excise tax       3.435      5.525
  per 10 packs (levels, 1982-1984      (1.074)    (2.658)
  dollars)
Per capita personal income in           14.855     17.591
  thousands (1982-1984 dollars)        (2.077)    (2.330)
Per capita personal income growth       0.016      0.016
                                       (0.020)    (0.019)
Total tax to state personal income      0.066      0.064
  ratio                                (0.012)    (0.012)
Total public expenditure to state       0.111      0.147
  personal income ratio                (0.033)    (0.030)
Per capita gross domestic product       17.678     20.612
  (GDP) in thousands (1982-1984        (2.934)    (3.582)
  dollars)
Per capita GDP growth                   0.017      0.013
                                       (0.026)    (0.023)
Total tax to state GDP ratio            0.056      0.055
                                       (0.010)    (0.011)
Total public expenditure to state       0.093      0.127
  GDP                                  (0.028)    (0.028)
Regional inflation                      0.029      0.027
                                       (0.010)    (0.007)
Percent of population (<18 and >64)     0.389      0.376
                                       (0.018)    (0.012)
Percent of population (>17 and <25)     0.099      0.101
                                       (0.009)    (0.010)
Percent with less than high school      0.175      0.126
  degree                               (0.053)    (0.037)
Percent with a high school degree       0.364      0.345
                                       (0.042)    (0.042)
Percent with some college or            0.239      0.264
  vocational degree                    (0.044)    (0.040)
Percent with a college degree           0.222      0.265
                                       (0.045)    (0.051)
Percent White                           0.826      0.760
                                       (0.109)    (0.135)
Percent Black                           0.103      0.114
                                       (0.100)    (0.104)
Percent other race                      0.071      0.127
                                       (0.071)    (0.110)
Observations                             480        384

Note: Values in parentheses are standard deviations.

TABLE 2
OLS Estimates of State-Level PCPI Growth on Alcohol Consumption
Sales Measures

                                           (1)            (2)

Panel A: Estimates of PCPI Growth on Per Capita Beer Sales

Per capita beer sales                    -0.0071       -0.0079 *
                                         (0.0047)       (0.0046)
Lagged per capita personal income       -0.0067 **     -0.0063 **
                                         (0.0026)       (0.0026)
State total tax PI ratio                -0.4743 **     -0.4884 **
                                         (0.1927)       (0.1840)
State total expenditure to PI ratio     -0.2187 **     -0.2025 **
                                         (0.0961)       (0.0975)
Regional inflation                     -0.7546 ***    -0.7968 ***
                                         (0.1182)       (0.1148)
Percent of population (<18 and >64)    -0.1955 ***      -0.0747
                                         (0.0722)       (0.0979)
Percent of population (> 17 and <25)                   0.2936 **
                                                        (0.1360)
Percent with a high school degree

Percent with some college or
  vocational degree
Percent with a college degree

Percent Black

Percent other race

[R.sup.2]                                 0.565          0.567

Panel B: Dependent Variable Is Per Capita GDP Growth
Per capita beer sales                     0.0048         0.0031
                                         (0.0101)       (0.0097)
[R.sup.2]                                 0.537          0.540
Observations                              1.776          1,776
Number of states                            48             48

                                           (3)            (4)

Panel A: Estimates of PCPI Growth on Per Capita Beer Sales
Per capita beer sales                    -0.0034        -0.0048
                                         (0.0050)       (0.0050)
Lagged per capita personal income       -0.0069 **     -0.0072 **
                                         (0.0029)       (0.0030)
State total tax PI ratio               -0.4976 ***     -0.4716 **
                                         (0.1807)       (0.1780)
State total expenditure to PI ratio     -0.1974 **     -0.1982 **
                                         (0.0949)       (0.0952)
Regional inflation                     -0.7910 ***    -0.7693 ***
                                         (0.1135)       (0.1084)
Percent of population (<18 and >64)      -0.1059        -0.1097
                                         (0.1039)       (0.1050)
Percent of population (> 17 and <25)    0.2871 **      0.2995 **
                                         (0.1403)       (0.1412)
Percent with a high school degree        -0.0169        -0.0200
                                         (0.0227)       (0.0223)
Percent with some college or             -0.0725        -0.0701
  vocational degree                      (0.0465)       (0.0493)
Percent with a college degree             0.0216         0.0186
                                         (0.0393)       (0.0380)
Percent Black                                            0.0350
                                                        (0.0278)
Percent other race                                       0.0014
                                                        (0.0149)
[R.sup.2]                                 0.569          0.570

Panel B: Dependent Variable Is Per Capita GDP Growth
Per capita beer sales                     0.0085         0.0072
                                         (0.0098)       (0.0098)
[R.sup.2]                                 0.542          0.542
Observations                              1,776          1,776
Number of states                            48             48

Notes: Robust standard errors corrected for clustering on the state
are in parentheses. All models control for state- and year-fixed
effects. In Panel B, each column includes the same control
variables that are specified in the corresponding column shown in
Panel A.

*** p < .01, * p < .05. * P < .1.

TABLE 3
First-Stage Estimates of Per Capita Beer Sales
on Excise Taxes

Variables                                                Beer

Real beer excise tax                                 -0.3651 ***
                                                       (0.0519)
Lagged per capita personal income                       0.0019
                                                       (0.0079)
State total tax PI ratio                                0.5815
                                                       (0.8395)
State total expenditure to PI ratio                    -0.1764
                                                       (0.4731)
Regional inflation                                     -0.5616
                                                       (0.5383)
Percent of population (<18 and >64)                    -0.5647
                                                       (1.1658)
Percent of population (> 17 and <25)                  3.1545 **
                                                       (1.3623)
Percent with a high school degree                     0.9040 ***
                                                       (0.2168)
Percent with some college or vocational degree        0.9452 ***
                                                       (0.2568)
Percent with a college degree                           0.0917
                                                       (0.2317)
Percent Black                                           0.1719
                                                       (0.2973)
Percent other race                                     -0.0978
                                                       (0.2013)
Observations                                            1,776
[R.sup.2]                                               0.565
Number of states                                          48

Notes: Robust standard errors corrected for clustering on
the state are in parentheses. All models control for state- and
year-fixed effects.

*** p < .01, ** p < .05, * p < .1.

TABLE 4
Instrumental Variable Estimates of Per Capita Income Growth and
GDP Growth on Beer Sales

                                                  (1)           (2)

Panel A: PCPI Growth
Per capita beer sales                         -0.0352 **    -0.0303 **
                                               (0.0142)      (0.0142)
[R.sup.2]                                        0.551         0.555
First stage F test                              105.962       106.104
First stage F test P value                       0.000         0.000

Panel B: Per Capita GDP Growth
Per capita beer sales                         -0.0494 **     -0.0395 *
                                               (0.0209)      (0.0209)
[R.sup.2]                                        0.523         0.532
First stage F test                              91.669        100.190
First stage F test p value                       0.000         0.000
Observations                                     1.776         1.776
Number of states                                  48            48

Controls for
Lagged PCPI                                       Yes           Yes
Total tax to personal income ratio                Yes           Yes
Total expenditure to personal income ratio        Yes           Yes
Regional inflation                                Yes           Yes
Percent of population (< 18 and >64)              Yes           Yes
Percent of population (> 17 and <25)              No            Yes
Education controls                                No            No
Race controls                                     No            No

                                                  (3)           (4)

Panel A: PCPI Growth
Per capita beer sales                         -0.0322 **    -0.0315 **
                                               (0.0141)      (0.0143)
[R.sup.2]                                        0.565         0.565
First stage F test                              105.544       100.175
First stage F test P value                       0.000         0.000

Panel B: Per Capita GDP Growth
Per capita beer sales                          -0.0508 *     -0.0640 *
                                               (0.0298)      (0.0329)
[R.sup.2]                                        0.528         0.522
First stage F test                              72.914        56.772
First stage F test p value                       0.000         0.000
Observations                                     1,776         1,776
Number of states                                  48            48

Controls for
Lagged PCPI                                       Yes           Yes
Total tax to personal income ratio                Yes           Yes
Total expenditure to personal income ratio        Yes           Yes
Regional inflation                                Yes           Yes
Percent of population (< 18 and >64)              Yes           Yes
Percent of population (> 17 and <25)              Yes           Yes
Education controls                                Yes           Yes
Race controls                                     No            Yes

Notes: Robust standard errors corrected for clustering on the state are
in parentheses. All models control for state- and year-fixed effects.

*** p < .01. ** p < .05. * P < .1.

TABLE 5
Reduced Form Estimates of PCPI Growth and Per Capita GDP Growth on
Excise Taxes

                                      (1)          (2)          (3)

Panel A: Estimates of PCPI Growth
Real beer excise tax               0.0167 **
                                    (0.0081)
Real wine excise tax                              0.0016
                                                 (0.0015)
Real liquor excise tax                                         0.0002
                                                              (0.0007)
Real cigarette excise tax

[R.sup.2]                            0.573        0.570        0.570

Panel B: Estimates of GDP Growth
Real beer excise tax                0.0238 *
                                    (0.0125)
Real wine excise tax                              0.0001
                                                 (0.0025)
Real liquor excise tax                                         0.0014
                                                              (0.0011)
Real cigarette excise tax

[R.sup.2]                            0.545        0.542        0.543
Observations                         1,776        1,776        1,776
Number of states                       48           48           48

                                      (4)          (5)

Panel A: Estimates of PCPI Growth
Real beer excise tax                             0.0158 *
                                                 (0.0082)
Real wine excise tax                              0.0010
                                                 (0.0012)
Real liquor excise tax                           -0.0003
                                                 (0.0008)
Real cigarette excise tax            0.0007       0.0005
                                    (0.0005)     (0.0005)
[R.sup.2]                            0.571        0.573

Panel B: Estimates of GDP Growth
Real beer excise tax                             0.0227 *
                                                 (0.0124)
Real wine excise tax                             -0.0028
                                                 (0.0021)
Real liquor excise tax                            0.0014
                                                 (0.0011)
Real cigarette excise tax            0.0010       0.0007
                                    (0.0008)     (0.0008)
[R.sup.2]                            0.542        0.546
Observations                         1,776        1,776
Number of states                       48           48

Notes: Robust standard errors corrected for clustering on the state
are in parentheses. All models control for full set of controls used
in column 4 of Table 4 as well as state- and year-fixed effects.

*** p < .01, ** p < .05, * p < .1.
联系我们|关于我们|网站声明
国家哲学社会科学文献中心版权所有