Public policy and agricultural transformation in Pakistan.
Khan, Mahmood Hasan
Successive governments in Pakistan have claimed that most of their
policies were aimed at alleviating rural poverty and improving the
income-earning capacity of "small" farmers. However, a close
examination of almost all of the major policies seems to indicate that
the beneficiaries have been mainly the large landowners and even
traditional landlords. This paper will argue that by promoting policies
favourable mainly to these groups governments have contributed to
persistent income inequalities and rural poverty without raising the
efficiency levels or increasing the tax revenues for the services needed
by agriculture in general and the rural poor in particular. A major part
of the argument will be that certain key policy options have not been
used effectively and that the others that have been used are
contradictory to the goals of maximizing efficiency, equity and
revenues.
STATE OF AGRICULTURE AND RURAL POVERTY
Agriculture is still a major source of employment and income for a
vast majority of the poor in Pakistan. Its performance has been uneven,
in terms of both the rates of growth and commodity balances. Aggregate
growth rates of agriculture show that the stagnation of the 1950s was
followed by a robust growth in the 1960s. The growth process slowed down
considerably in the early to the mid-1970s. A somewhat impressive
revival has been an important aspect of economic change in Pakistan in
the last seven to eight years [22].
The state of agriculture in recent years has improved particularly
with respect to its terms of trade with other sectors in the economy.
Government policies of price support, subsidies and taxes seem to have
played an important role in helping the agricultural sector to receive a
"fair" deal in the process of growth in the national economy
[5]. This aspect will be explored further when we analyse the relevant
policy instruments.
These optimistic indicators of the improved health of agriculture
conceal several serious deficiencies.
1. The growth performance has not been shared equally even by the
four major crops, viz. wheat, rice, cotton and sugar-cane. Wheat and
rice have continued to show a stable growth in the yield levels, but
cotton and sugar-cane have been subject to wide fluctuations. In fact,
the sugar-cane yields have been stagnant or even falling. The yield
levels of fodders and pulses have shown little change. The crisis of oil
crops has yet to be resolved to save the foreign exchange used for
importing edible oils.
2. The livestock sector is still highly fragmented and inefficient.
The exception is the emergence of a somewhat well-organized poultry
industry around major urban centres. A similar development is perhaps
now under way in the dairy Industry.
3. Regional disparity between irrigated and rain-fed areas is not
only high but perhaps even increasing. Development of land-saving
technology for increased yield levels has not been observed in the
rain-fed areas simply because of lack of assured supply of water and
adequate research funding.
4. Finally, and perhaps most importantly, the impact of growth on
the various classes engaged in agriculture has been highly uneven. This
aspect will be analysed in considerable detail because of the existing
differentiation and asymmetrical relations observed in the countryside.
Poverty afflicts millions in Pakistan. Most of the poor live in
rural areas, working on or around land. The rural poor are mostly in
households of sharecroppers and landless (casual) labourers.
Landlessness is perhaps the most important indicator of rural poverty.
Of course, there is considerable poverty even among the small
owner-operators in the Punjab and the NWFP, particularly in the rain-fed
regions.
There were about 10 million rural households, representing 60
million people, in Pakistan at the last agricultural census in 1980
[20]. Rural households do not now all depend on agriculture for their
incomes. Over 6.5 million of them are "agricultural"
households and the rest can be called "non-agricultural"
households. Among the agricultural households, about two-thirds are
attached to land as either owners or tenants, and the remaining
one-third live as labourers with or without some heads of livestock. The
land-owning households consist mostly of owner-operators; and the tenant
households are mainly share-croppers. Small owner-operators--owning less
than 2 hectares in the rain-fed regions--do not, however, own a large
proportion of the area. Share-croppers cultivate land mainly for large
landowners or landlords. Of the nearly 3.3 million non-agricultural
households, about two million are working in agriculture-related
activities as artisans, petty traders, etc. The remainder work outside
agriculture as professionals, transporters, skilled workers, state
employees, etc.
There are no consistent sets of data on rural poverty in Pakistan.
As in many other countries, in Pakistan, too, there have been serious
problems in defining poverty itself: should it be expressed in
"relative" or "absolute" terms? Which of the various
measures of absolute poverty should be used? Even if an aggregate
measure of poverty has been estimated, can the poor be identified as
distinct groups? A few estimates of poverty at the aggregate level seem
to indicate that about 30 to 40 percent of the rural households can be
regarded as poor. These studies also show that these magnitudes of rural
poverty have changed by little in the 1970s [8; 13; 17]. (1) There is
also now some evidence on who the rural poor are. The most prominent and
numerous among these groups are the landless agricultural workers and
share-croppers, followed by small owner-operators. Share-croppers are
the single largest group among the rural poor in Sind and in several
regions of the Punjab as well. It is generally agreed that the poor
households in rural Pakistan are mainly those of landless agricultural
workers (including those who own a few heads of livestock), landless
share-croppers and the land-owning small owner-operators [7].
Changes in the distribution of landownership and rural income are
the two most important indicators of the level of, and changes in, rural
poverty. In Table 1, the household data on land and income show that (a)
landownership is far more concentrated than rural income and (b) the
inequalities in both increased during the 1970s. The share of the bottom
40 percent of the rural households has fallen--from 11 to 10 percent in
land and 22 to 21 percent in income--and the share of the top 20 percent
has increased in both--from 55 to 57 percent in land and 40 to 41
percent in income. The middle 40 percent of the households have lost in
land but gained slightly in income during the same period.
Policy Instruments in Agriculture
The question here is not whether governments should or should not
play a role in the economy of Pakistan, particularly in its agricultural
sector. The question rather is: How well have they used the various
policy instruments to promote efficiency and equity? The analysis will
focus on the following instruments of public policy.
1. Land reforms, including land redistribution and tenancy reforms;
2. Agricultural taxation, including land and income taxes;
3. Price support for major crops and subsidies for major farm
inputs;
4. Agricultural credit institutions; and
5. Agricultural research and extension services.
All of these instruments have been used in varying degrees by
governments in Pakistan in the name of efficiency and equity. However,
they have relied mainly on policies that have not forced structural
changes in either the dichotomous and asymmetrical relations on land or
distribution of income through extraction of surplus by direct taxation.
Reliance on "softer" options have tended to reinforce income
inequalities and rural poverty.
1. Land Reform Policies
There is little disagreement that at the time of creation of
Pakistan in 1947 its agrarian structure was characterized by (i) a
quasi-feudal landlord tenant nexus in most areas of Sind and the Punjab
and (ii) a peasant system with fragmented (individual and joint) family
farms in parts of the Punjab and the NWFP. Landownership was highly
concentrated, particularly in Sind. However, the more numerous family
farm owners in the Punjab and the NWFP did not own more than 55 percent
of the total farm area. There is also some evidence that most of the
land in Pakistan was then cultivated by share-croppers: about 50 percent
of the area in the Punjab and the NWFP and over 70 percent in Sind. It
should also be noted that while occupancy tenants--who had some legal
rights on land--were predominant in the first two provinces,
tenants-at-will (haris)--who had no legally recognized
rights--cultivated most of the land in Sind. Family farms--which were
highly fragmented--did not occupy a significant proportion of the
cultivated area.
The tenancy reforms of the 1950s, enacted in the three provinces,
were nominal in that they had apparently no impact on contractual
arrangements between landlords and share-croppers. The first visible
pressure on landlords, particularly with large landholdings, came with
the Land Reform Act of 1959. However, there is considerable evidence
that it did not significantly alter the concentration of landownership,
as there were substantial intrafamily land transfers and even evasion of
the ceiling requirements on individual holding. The landless and
near-landless peasants received little land. The Act of 1959 did not
include changes in the traditional tenancy laws of the provinces.
The second land reform act was promulgated in 1972. It was
seemingly mote radical than the first one. While its impact on land
redistribution has been fat more limited in terms of the resumed area,
its tenancy legislation has apparently had a favourable effect on the
legal position of the share-croppers.
The third land reform act was announced in 1977, just before the
imposition of Martial Law in the July of that year. There has been
little or no redistribution of land in accordance with the Act of 1977.
In fact, the federal government has made several amendments to the act
since 1982 to encourage large-scale farming in Pakistan.
The three land reform acts have redistributed less than 1.5 million
hectares of land to less than 290,000 beneficiaries. It should be
remembered that a substantial part of the distributed land area was not
of high quality. Secondly, not all beneficiaries have been the landless
share-croppers; a high proportion of the beneficiaries in the Land
Reform Act of 1959 were small owners. Landless agricultural workers have
not been included in any list of beneficiaries. A more important aspect
of these reforms has been the absence of a follow-up support system,
including distribution of credit, inputs and establishment of either new
or encouragement of the existing peasant organizations. There is ample
evidence that a deliberate and systematic policy has been followed
against organizations supporting small landowners, share-cropping
tenants and landless workers.
In most regions of Sind and several areas of the Punjab and the
NWFP, where large landowners (landlords) have a high share of the land
area, a sharecropping (batai) system has evolved according to the
political and economic conditions. The tenancy laws incorporated in the
1972 land reform act were meant to alleviate the subservient position of
the tenant. Among other things, occupancy rights were expanded,
arrangements of expense-sharing were clearly defined, and provisions
were made for increased security to tenants on the lands they occupy.
There are, however, several problems with the sharecropping system.
1. The conventional formula of equal shares in the gross produce
under normal circumstances has not only been more favourable to the
landowner, but the additional items of costs which the tenant must now
share with landowners have imposed a new burden. This is particularly
striking as some inputs, of which the cost must be equally shared,
increase the capitalized (equity) value of land for the landowner--in
which the labour of the tenant has been subsumed--and some inputs may
even displace the tenant's own labour and that of his animals and
further weaken his bargaining position. Use of fertilizers and tractors
is an example.
2. While the risk is shared between the landowner and his tenant,
all decisions about crops, use of inputs, etc., are entirely in the
hands of the owner or his agent.
3. In several areas, at least of Sind, landlords rotate their
tenants on different parcels of land, which keeps the tenant insecure and provides little or no incentive for him to improve land management.
Also, the legal provision for the right of landowners to expand
"self-cultivated" area can lead to the eviction of tenant or
at least to a reduced land parcel and increased insecurity.
4. Notwithstanding the legal provisions for the tenant's
rights, his bargaining position remains weak because of the high degree
of land concentration among some individuals or households in a village,
in which the dependence of cultivators is almost total on the amount of
land made available for sharecropping by owners of large landed estates.
A sharecropping system can thus prolong the subservient position of
direct producers if land concentration remains high.
A fixed-rent tenancy would not suffer from these weaknesses.
However, the lease system can only work to the benefit of both the
parties if the lessee has access to the required resources to take all
the risk himself and pay a fixed amount to the landowner at the end of
each season or year. Most share-croppers or small land-owning tenants
have no support system of credit and farm inputs to enter into a
fixed-rent tenancy. Therefore, this tenancy in Pakistan is increasing
only among the medium to large landowners who lease land parcels from
those small or marginal landowners who cannot make a living by land
alone and must supplement their income by securing employment elsewhere.
Agriculture in Pakistan has been undergoing a process of rapid
structural changes with respect to farm size and tenancy relations, Some
of these changes reflect the effects of the land reforms acts, but most
of them are being brought about mainly by (a) population growth, (b)
laws of inheritance, (c) forces of the market, and (d) government
policies of support prices, subsidies, taxes and credit. Recent changes
in land concentration, shown in Table 2, indicate several interesting
features.
1. Concentration of landownership reduced only marginally in the
1970s, and the highest concentration is still in Sind. Small landowners
(with less than 2 hectares) are preponderant in the Punjab (80 percent)
and the NWFP (93 percent), but they own, respectively, only 36 and 55
percent of the area in the two provinces. They comprise only two-thirds
of all the landowners in Sind with less than one-quarter of the area.
The large landowners (with more than 20 hectares) still own 38 percent
of the area in Sind, 20 percent in the Punjab and 14 percent in the
NWFP.
2. Access to land, as reflected in the distribution of operational
holdings (farms), has become somewhat more restricted in the Punjab and
Sind, but has increased slightly in the NWFP. However, it should be
noted that access to land is less concentrated than landownership only
in Sind, reflecting the dominance of a sharecropping system based on a
landlord-tenant nexus. Owner-operated farms are most dominant in the
NWFP which is followed by the Punjab in this respect. Changes in the
distribution of farms and farm area in the 1970s show that (a) the share
of large farms has remained unchanged in the Punjab and Sind but has
somewhat decreased in the NWFP, and (b) the share of small farms has
increased in all the provinces. It should also be pointed out that the
average size of farms has increased only among the very large farms; the
other sizes have remained almost unchanged.
3. Of course, not all landowners cultivate land, either their own
or anyone else's, and not all cultivators own land. There are
several kinds of tenancy arrangements on land for cultivation purposes,
ranging from owner-operatorship (with family or hired labour) to
sharecropping and leasing of land. Small farms are largely
owner-operated and they have been increasing in numbers and area.
Sharecropped farms are mainly in the range of 2-5 hectares, but they
have declined sharply in number and area. Large farms, particularly the
ones that are owner-operated, have been increasing impressively. The
tendency away from sharecropping is also reflected in a significant
reduction of the proportion of the tenant-operated area on farms of all
sizes. A high percentage (nearly 75 percent) of the ownership holdings
are operating all of their owned area. Even the large holdings dependent
on tenants sharply reduced their tenant-operated area in the 1970s [18;
20].
In predominantly agrarian societies, the structure of landownership
determines the manner in which land and labour are combined for
production. It has in turn implications for the absolute and relative
well-being of the rural population. Control of land confers upon the
owners considerable economic and political power, particularly if
landownership is highly concentrated. The inequity embedded in a
dualistic agrarian structure not only reproduces rural poverty but is
also highly inefficient in producing food and raw material for
industrialization. Land reforms can be used to alter the existing and
highly asymmetrical relations on land and alleviate the condition of the
rural poor.
Land reforms can have serious impact on the processes that
reproduce poverty. They are often expected to reverse or at least slow
down these processes. On the other hand, these reforms can contribute
significantly to a process of agricultural growth that creates affluence
and poverty simultaneously. There is considerable evidence indicating
these contradictory effects of land reforms in underdeveloped countries.
It should be emphasized that the long-term effects of reforms may not
necessarily be the same as their immediate impact on the agrarian
structure. The effects of a land reform programme depend on a host of
factors. What specific objectives does it aim at achieving? How is it
implemented? What are the follow-up policies that have been used? It is
in exploring answers to these questions that links between land reforms,
landlessness and rural poverty in a specific country may be discovered.
It is significant that no interest seems to have been shown by
either governments or researchers in Pakistan in analysing the impact of
the various land reform acts on new and old landowners and on
sharecropping tenants with respect to production levels, incomes,
employment structure, etc. There is not one micro-level study exploring
these issues. Similarly, there are no studies, even anecdotal, of the
impact of tenancy laws on contracts between tenants and landlords.
It is fair to say that the agrarian structure in Pakistan is highly
differentiated, with asymmetrical relations between the landlord and his
tenant, on the one hand, and between the large (capitalist) farmer and
the contending marginal and small owner-operator, on the other. This
biformity affects the outcomes of almost all interactions between the
contending groups, be they in the market-place or in the public sector.
Inequities in the economy and society, reflected in distributions of
rural income and land, tend to persist mainly because of these
asymmetries. There is also evidence that this land system is not
conducive to efficiency in agriculture: large farms are not more
efficient users of society's resources than small farms, and
sharecropped (small) farms are not better performers than owner-operated
(small) farms [3; 11 ; 15].
The basic agrarian problem for public policy in Pakistan is still
to radically alter the existing land tenure system. The case is argued
with substantial evidence on
(i) high concentration of ownership and use of land;
(ii) landlessness and near-landlessness of a large and increasing
proportion of peasants;
(iii) wide differences in productivity and income between farms by
size and tenancy;
(iv) biformity in the input and-output markets because of the rigid
structure of accessibility based on landholding, thus neutralizing the
positive effects of public policies on taxes, price support, subsidies,
credit and agricultural research and extension; and
(v) cumulative tendency towards increasing income disparities and
exclusive participation in the development process.
The argument for a radical restructuring of the land system in
Pakistan is then based on efficiency and equity. The disequilibrating
effects of new technology, increasing specialization and division of
labour are becoming quite evident on the weakened position of small
landowners, landless share-croppers and wage workers.
2. Agricultural Taxation
The structure of direct taxes in agriculture can not only affect
the ownership and use of land and the distribution of rural incomes, but
also provide investible surplus to the government for the development of
agriculture and improvement in rural life. There is at present only one
form of direct tax on agriculture in Pakistan. It is called the land
revenue. There is no tax on agricultural incomes. The land revenue
system is ancient and rigid. Its tax base has not expanded with changes
in agricultural production and income. Since the introduction of ushr on
agricultural output in 1983, land revenue collections have contracted
and the ushr revenue is not available to the public sector for
developmental work.
Governments have resorted to taxing agriculture indirectly as a
soft option to the restructuring of the land tax. Several forms of
explicit and implicit indirect taxes, which have had few if any positive
effects on efficiency and equity, have been imposed on agriculture. The
dependence on a variety of indirect taxes is a sad reflection of the
failure of governments to make taxes flexible and progressive.
Governments have allowed transfer of agricultural surplus to other
sectors without at the same time returning to agriculture and rural
community the benefits of investible resources for their own development
and well-being. Furthermore, public policy in the agricultural sector
has helped only certain groups to appropriate the benefits of growth
without using the fiscal instruments to redistribute these gains.
The rigid tax structure of the land revenue system is reflected in
the several indicators shown in Table 3. It has been producing largely
an unchanging amount of revenue in the provinces, except in two to three
years in the late 1970s when the collections rose because of ad hoc increases in the rates of land tax. The reduced collections in 1983-84
reflect the introduction of ushr from the Rabi of 1982-83. Then, again,
since the total provincial taxes and the national value added in
agriculture have been rising, the share of direct agricultural tax has
fallen quite sharply over time: the ratio of land tax to provincial tax
revenues fell from about 7 percent in 1974-75 to 1.0 percent in 1983-84
and the ratio of land revenue to gross value added in agriculture fell
from 0.8 percent to 0.2 percent in the same period. Finally, provincial
governments have been collecting only Rs. 8-12 per cropped hectare. In
other words, a landowner pays a tax not exceeding 0.5 percent of the
gross value per hectare! Of course, there are wide differences in the
incidence of land revenue per cropped hectare between the provinces: the
highest is still in Sind which is followed by the Punjab and the NWFP.
Another serious aspect of the land revenue system, at least until
1977, was that the revenue collected per unit of cropped land did not
vary with the size of an owner's landholding. However, the basic
exemption of revenue for holdings of less than 5 hectare since then has
induced landowners to alter land records to reduce the size of the
individual holding. A surcharge, called "agricultural income
tax", brings Rs 3-5 million per year with the land revenue. The
small amount of collections is due to the fact that the surcharge is not
imposed on those landowners who pay land revenue of less than Rs 250 in
the Punjab and Rs 450 in Sind. Since there are not too many landowners
who pay more than Rs 500, the total amount of surcharge has remained
largely insignificant.
The exclusion of agricultural income from tax poses three serious
problems: (a) it limits opportunities for the mobilization of domestic
resources for development expenditure; (b) it maintains inequities
between the agricultural and nonagricultural sectors and within the
agricultural sector; and (c) it introduces inefficiency in the tax
system of the country. The welfare cost of not taxing agricultural
income would be reflected in capital not moving to activities where it
is more productive because taxpayers are concerned with the after-tax
returns rather than with gross returns [9]. Exemption of agricultural
income from tax, subsidies for credit and farm inputs, and tax holiday
on investment in agriculture are attracting capital from urban areas
into land. Given a lower marginal productivity of capital in agriculture
than in industry, the cost to the society is in the form of lost output.
The land revenue system is a tragic anachronism, maintained by the
tenacity of the landed interests and supported by the existing revenue
administration. The interest of landlords in maintaining a largely
regressive tax structure, in which their lands and incomes enjoy special
treatment, needs no demonstration. These interests have been expressed
with force in almost all official committees and they have so far been
guarded by governments. The civil service associated with the
administration of land revenue, almost without exception, has on every
occasion supported the position of the landed interests. The revenue
officials have helped these interests by pleading that the agricultural
sector deserves a "special treatment" for direct taxation.
They appear to be pleading for all groups in agriculture as if the
present tax structure is efficient and equitable. In reality, they are
successfully defending the wealth and income positions of a minority of
landowners and farmers who are not necessarily the most efficient agents
of agricultural production. However, their influence on public policy is
reflected in the fact that the Finance Act of 1977, replacing land
revenue by a tax on agricultural income, was aborted after the
imposition of Martial Law in 1977.
There is now considerable evidence that the burden of indirect
taxes on agriculture has been falling, thanks to the abolition of export
taxes and increased support prices for major crops, and the terms of
trade have moved in favour of agricultural producers [5]. Secondly, how
long can the society bear the welfare costs of a policy based on the
"infant industry" argument that is no longer valid for
increasing agricultural productivity. Finally, there are the persistent,
if not increasing, inequalities of landownership and rural income.
Therefore, the present land tax should be replaced by an efficient and
equitable direct tax on agricultural income [11; 13]. The new tax system
should take into account at least the following considerations:
(i) it should be a rational instrument with which the State may be
able to mobilize investible resources from agriculture to help develop
the much needed infrastructure in rural and urban areas;
(ii) it should be based on the principle of the ability to pay,
maintaining a measure of equity within agriculture;
(iii) it should be responsive to changes in incomes, prices and
output; and
(iv) it should be administered without imposing unbearable economic
and political costs.
Introduction of direct and progressive tax on agricultural incomes
will not only introduce the much-needed elements of efficiency and
equity, but will also significantly increase government revenues without
the government having to resort to explicit and implicit taxes that are
both unfair and socially inefficient. There is an additional argument
for direct taxation in agriculture, for it also provides a politically
feasible alternative to a radical redistribution of land.
3. Price Support and Subsidies
Government intervention in the pricing of major crops and farm
inputs has been one of the most important instruments of taxing and
subsidizing agriculture in Pakistan since at least the early 1960s. The
policy of support prices for major crops (wheat, rice, cotton and
sugar-cane) and subsidies on prices of farm inputs, particularly
fertilizer and water, has been premised on the argument of incentives to
farmers to raise farm productivity. There are several interesting
aspects of this policy that need examining here.
Firstly, it is significant that the terms of trade for agriculture
have improved in the last seven to eight years. This is indicated by
increased purchasing power of farmers, whether measured in terms of the
quantity of output or in those of productive effect. It can thus be
argued that the farmers' ability to pay for farm inputs has not
been eroded even with the recent reduction in subsidies. This is also
reflected in the evidence on increased net returns per hectare in the
1970s. One of the major reasons for this has been the increases in the
procurement prices of the principal crops [5].
Secondly, support prices for major crops have been rising
significantly, particularly since the late 1970s. The procurement price
of wheat has almost doubled, the price of rice has been raised by 50
percent, the cotton price has gone up by about 40 percent, and the
sugar-cane price has risen by over 50 percent. What is even more
important is that the ratios of the procurement prices of major crops to
the prices of farm inputs have not moved adversely, and the ratio of
domestic prices to international prices of these crops has improved. In
fact, cotton prices are now very closely alligned; and the domestic
price of sugar far exceeds its international price [5].
Thirdly, as shown in Table 4, the total amount of subsidy on farm
inputs has increased significantly after 1977, maintaining a level of
Rs. 2.5 billion to Rs. 3.0 billion. It has absorbed about 8-16 percent
of the total development expenditure of the federal and provincial
governments. The lion's share, nearly three-quarters, of the
subsidy on farm inputs has gone to fertilizer, followed by irrigation water and pesticides. Subsidy on pesticides was eliminated in 1981 and
the fertilizer subsidy is expected to be removed this year. The subsidy
on irrigation water has been rising, even though the water rates have
increased in recent years.
The issue of price support and subsidies has engendered a number of
controversies. One thing can be said in the context of Pakistan. A price
support policy, with sensitivity to changes in domestic resource cost
and international prices of major crops, should be the only instrument
to enable farmers to get a "fair" return for their effort.
Subsidies on farm inputs, even if they had a credible case in the past,
should be eliminated completely, particularly on canal water, fertilizer
and machinery (tubewells and tractors). This argument will be developed
following a discussion of the price support policy.
Price support for major crops can give farmers a fair deal through
its effect on their incomes and provide stability to the prices in the
market-place. A major advantage of reliance on a price support system
will be the likely distribution of benefits between large and small
farmers. Small farms, as shown in Table 5, account for about two-thirds
to three-quarters of the cropped area of the major crops and their
cropping intensity is 30-40 percent higher than that of large farms.
Consequently, a price incentive would tend to affect the small farmers
more favourably. The only problem here is the observed difference in the
marketable surplus of grains between large and small farms. The evidence
of lower marketable surplus on small farms, given in Table 6, reflects
partly the subsistence requirements of these households. It also
indicates the problems the small farmers usually face in marketing their
grain crops even through the government procurement centres [6]. The
emphasis of the government policy should be on alleviating the marketing
and storage problems of the small farmers in order to encourage them to
sell higher proportions of their output of grains. This policy ties in
well with the gains in terms of the larger output that the small farmers
would be able to provide to consumers at reduced unit cost.
A price support system can work only if governments are aware of
and sensitive to changes in the factors that affect prices in markets
both at home and abroad. Among these factors, the most important are (a)
domestic resource costs or crop parity ratios, (b) border or
international prices, (c) relative prices of major farm inputs and
manufactured goods, (d) domestic demand conditions, and (e) marginal
cost of crop production under various farming systems and areas. It is a
long agenda, but without taking these factors into account, government
intervention may tend to distort the incentives for efficiency and
equity. The research needs are equally great, as little has so far been
done in Pakistan. It is encouraging that the Agricultural Prices
Commission has undertaken some studies either directly or through other
institutions. Results of well-conducted studies can present reasonable
options to policy-makers to use in the political process by which
support prices are in the end determined.
The other area of concern for an effective price support system is
that of institutional support to facilitate the disposal of agricultural
surplus, particularly that of small farmers. Governments should pay
attention to the development of a decentralized storage system which is
accessible to the farmers with small amounts of surplus. While the
public sector may develop large-scale and strategically located storage
facilities, it is necessary to encourage private groups (traders and the
like) to construct small-scale storage that is available to small
farmers at reasonable cost. Finally, the marketing intelligence services
should be expanded and more closely integrated with the market
committees at all levels. Participation of direct producers needs far
more attention than it now receives.
One of the arguments often presented against reliance on a price
support policy as a substitute for subsidies on inputs has been that the
former is likely to raise directly the prices of food and raw material
paid by urban consumers and the growing industrial sector. The
experience in Pakistan shows that support prices of almost all major
crops have been below their domestic resource cost or border prices.
Urban consumers of grains, particularly of wheat, have been protected
through a rationing system. In fact, it can be argued that all poor
consumers, rural and urban, can be subsidized through some kind of a
rationing system, implying a subsidy considerably smaller than the
amount of subsidy being given to farmers on inputs. A wheat rationing
system for the poor households may be one of the few ways to protect
their real incomes [6; 24]. What is perhaps more significant is that
increased agricultural production through price incentive may allow
termination of consumer subsidy and release state revenues for transfer
to the poor through improved services in urban and rural areas. The
industrial sector, as user of raw material, needs no protection as long
as the prices of raw material do not exceed their opportunity cost or
the border price. It is unreasonable to tax raw material producers
through low prices, when the industrial producers have been protected so
well through taxes, subsidies and exchange rates.
The case against subsidies on farm inputs is based on several
arguments. For one thing, there is considerable evidence that since
access to major farm inputs is dependent on the size of landholding,
there has been a definite discrimination between small and large farmers
in the distribution of subsidies on inputs and the consequent incomes
they help to produce. Also, there is evidence that the use of many of
the so-called modern inputs is higher on large farms than on small
farms, although there is no equally credible evidence that large farms
are more efficient users of these inputs. This has been certainly true
of fertilizer, pesticides and farm machinery [20].
Secondly, there is evidence that the price elasticity of demand for
some inputs (water and fertilizer) is quite low. Thus, their negative
price effect is more than offset by the positive income effect. The
positive income effect of fertilizer and water has been demonstrated by
the continued profitability of the use of these inputs [5].
Thirdly, subsidy on certain inputs not only encourages waste of a
scarce factor (water), but also leads to substitution of other inputs
that may have a negative impact on income and employment, offsetting the
private profitability of the subsidized input. This argument is clearly
relevant and strong in the observed substitution of labour by machines.
Fourthly, the cost of certain inputs, like water and fertilizer,
even without a price subsidy, may be a very small proportion of the
total cost of production of crops per hectare. Removal of subsidy would
put little additional burden on the total cost. What is even more
important is that the cost of fertilizer and water and some other inputs
is demonstrably lower than the value added by them per unit with support
prices for crops [5].
Finally, reduced subsidies in the economy would release substantial
financial resources to be used for improving services to farmers, e.g.
maintenance and operation of watercourses, provision of research and
extension services, and expansion of institutional credit.
The principle of charging user cost of major inputs from farmers
can thus be defended on the following grounds:
(i) distributional impact of subsidies is highly skewed;
(ii) farmers are fully aware of the benefits of water and
fertilizer, and increased charges are not likely to affect aggregate
production;
(iii) some subsidized inputs misallocate resources, with negative
effects on aggregate production and employment; and
(iv) subsidies tend to lead to wastage of scarce resources,
particularly by the less efficient users.
4. Agricultural Credit
Public provision of farm credit can be an important instrument for
improving production and income of the small farmers and the landless.
However, it rarely works this way in most countries, and Pakistan is no
exception. While the indebtedness of the rural poor is proverbial, there
is usually underreporting of debt by most households, and it is
particularly noticed amongst share-croppers whose relationship with
their landlords almost always involves significant borrowing. Most
households borrow from relatives and friends and are often unwilling to
reveal their debt to those sources. There is evidence that small farmers
and the landless borrow from non-institutional sources, including
relatives and friends, money-lenders, landlords, commission agents and
traders [20]. Also, there is evidence that the interest rates paid on
loans from these sources are considerably higher than those paid on
loans from institutional sources. The low-income rural households borrow
mostly for current cash requirements of production and consumption. In
fact, small farms (less than 5 hectares) make few investments: their
share is less than one-quarter of all agricultural investments. Their
limited investments are from their own resources, because they
reportedly borrow no more than 35 percent of their investments. (2)
This, of course, reflects the limitation of their demand for credit by
their ability to pay for it.
Institutional credit in Pakistan is not demand-oriented: like most
other inputs and services it is constrained or rationed by supply. There
are no estimates of demand for farm credit, based on rate of return,
level of technology, Financial constraints, etc. Since the cost of
institutional credit is relatively low, there is excess demand for it. A
bias in favour of large farms is built into the institutional credit
system because of considerations of (a) risk minimization through
collateral requirement, (b) low administrative cost and convenience and
(c) the power and influence of large landowners. A close examination of
the lending policies and disbursements of credit by institutions shows
that these problems militate against small farmers in general and the
landless in particular. Share-croppers have no direct access to
institutional credit. Their major source is their landlord, and he also
works as a conduit for seasonal loans from institutional sources. The
other landless groups must depend entirely on non-institutional credit
sources. The high cost of and limited access to credit thus prevent the
rural poor from expanding their income-earning capacity.
The growth of institutional credit in Pakistan has been impressive
in the last decade, rising from about Rs. 1 billion to Rs. 9 billion
[22]. However, most of the loan money still flows to those who own
substantial land or can give similar collateral as personal security.
Institutional credit is not directed to meeting the consumption needs of
rural households, although some of it gets chanelled into consumption.
This was observed particularly in the early to mid-1970s, when
commercial banks began to extend loans to "farmers".
Production requirements of farmers are the major focus of the public
credit system. However, it excludes borrowing for purchase or mortgage
of land.
Development or investment lending is done almost exclusively by the
Agricultural Development Bank of Pakistan (or ADBP). It is allocated
nearly one-third of the total public lending. The lending programme of
the ADBP is dominated by loans for tractors, tubewells, and minor
irrigation and agro-industrial ventures in the private sector. As shown
in Table 7, small farmers get less than one-fifth of its loans. The
number of beneficiaries is limited to a few thousands. Landless workers
and share-croppers without collateral are not eligible for credit. The
mobile credit scheme of the ADBP has apparently increased the lending
for new and even innovative enterprises. It has also helped somewhat in
increasing the recovery rates, from 75 percent to over 80 percent. It is
significant that small farmers are better borrowers than large
landowners in this respect.
Public sector lending for the purchase of current or seasonal
inputs, like seeds, fertilizer, pesticides, etc., is done through the
co-operative and commercial banks. The co-operative banking system is
still very weak in Pakistan in terms of its ability to extend loans to
small farmers, to recover these loans and to manage its affairs
efficiently. The absence of multi-level societies and the dominance of
public (provincial) bureaucracy do not allow participation of small
farmers in the system. Consequently, large farmers tend to dominate at
the apex level of the co-operative organization.
Commercial banks were inducted into the farming sector-in 1973, and
they now account for about 45 percent of the total farm loans. Lending
by these banks is also apparently mainly to large farmers. It works in
their favour in several ways. The required quotas of loans for farmers
by the size of the landholding are circumvented by considerable
"proxy" lending, particularly through sharecropping tenants to
landlords. This has become perhaps more significant after the
introduction of interest-free seasonal loans intended for small farm
operators. Similarly, the transaction costs of obtaining the "pass
book", introduced in 1973, are quite different, depending on
one's holding or degree of influence on the local bureaucracy. The
result is that a very low proportion of small farmers have obtained the
pass books, whereas most of the large landowners possess them.
The observed duality in the rural money market of Pakistan is a
reflection of its dualistic agrarian structure. A substantial subsidy
implied in public loans for agricultural production is transferred to a
small number of large landowners or operators. There are several policy
options necessary to reduce the imbalance and increase the flow of
credit to small farmers, including the landless tenants and farm
workers.
Firstly, the ADBP should lower its land ceiling requirement to
define a small farmer. It should also shift its emphasis from tractors
to small loans with a large portfolio:
(i) loans to purchase farm implements and improve farm structures;
(ii) loans for tractor hiring services for land levelling;
(iii) loans for additional heads of livestock for dairy products and meat;
(iv) loans to the landless for livestock and similar ventures in
rural areas.
Secondly, the mobile credit scheme of the ADBP and the supervised
credit programmes of commercial banks should be integrated with the
research and extension services to introduce and expand well-tested
packages of technology.
Thirdly, it is necessary to strengthen effective monitoring and
evaluation programmes in the banking system to reduce wastage and avoid
misallocation of resources. The banking system has so far resisted these
programmes or allowed their nominal existence.
Finally, and perhaps most importantly, the intended beneficiaries
should be helped and not discouraged to form somewhat homogeneous and
formal groupings or associations for activity planning, loan appraisal,
credit delivery and even group saving schemes. These associations can be
used for a group security system to help individual members in obtaining
loans for production, livestock, etc. They can also act as watchdogs and
help to improve the effectiveness of public lending institutions.
The links between credit and rural welfare are strong but complex.
There are many questions that Pakistani researchers need to explore in
order to understand the impact of public policy on credit. For example,
what is the nature of the linkage between borrowers and
non-institutional lenders, particularly the links between the tenant and
his landlord and between the small farmer and the money-lender or
trader? What are the factors that play a dominant role in determining
the demand for credit by the rural poor? How does farm credit affect
adoption and use of various packages of technology? And so on. The
Pakistani literature on farm credit is woefully inadequate and cannot
yield meaningful responses to these questions.
5. Agricultural Research and Extension
The share of agriculture in the development plans of Pakistan has
fallen from about 10 percent in the first five-year plan to 4 percent in
the sixth plan (Table 8). The share of agricultural research and
extension in the development budget of agriculture has risen from about
8 percent to 20 percent in the same period. The significant fact is that
Pakistan spends for research and extension only one-quarter of one
percent of its Gross Domestic Product and only one percent of the Gross
Value of Agricultural Output. Put differently, in the early 1980s the
average spending on these activities was Rs. 100 per farm (Rs. 30 for
research and Rs. 70 for extension) and Rs. 20 per cultivated hectare
(Rs. 6 for research and Rs. 14 for extension). These expenditures make
Pakistan amongst the lowest spenders in the Third World. Several studies
have shown that most countries, irrespective of their state of
development, have high returns on expenditures on agricultural research
and extension. The real rate of return in Pakistan varies from 15 to 60
percent.
Traditionally, agricultural education, research and extension
services have been funded through and administered by provincial
governments. The federal government has played its role mainly in
distributing resources and co-ordinating these activities at the
national level. However, the rapid expansion of funding for agricultural
research since the late 1970s has created serious contradictions in the
national research effort. The Pakistan Agricultural Research Council PARC--which was established only as a federal co-ordinating agency for
research in the provinces has acquired increasing resources for and
control of agricultural research to which the provincial institutes have
little access to improve their own research activities. In fact, a
distinct duality has developed in the working conditions, rewards, etc.,
leading to a drain of researchers from provinces to the PARC. The
increasing centralization of agricultural research at the PARC and its
emerging elitism are not sensible or economic solutions of the acute
regional problems of quality research in provincial institutions.
The other problem of agricultural research is that the emphasis is
still on traditional questions about major crops. There is apparently
little appreciation of "adaptive" research, emphasizing the
development of technology packages that respond to the specific needs of
various farming regions and the sizes and tenures of landholdings. What
is equally important is that agronomic research has not been integrated
with the economics of potential demanders of new technology. There is
serious deficiency in the study of economic aspects of agriculture under
different soil and water conditions, crop mixes, farm sizes and tenures.
The present approach to fill this gap is again premised on increased
centralization of resources and personnel at the PARC. The provincial
research institutes do not have even a nominal existence of agricultural
economists on their staff. Most of the research in agricultural
economics rests with individuals outside these institutions, either in
universities or other autonomous institutes.
The impact of research on agricultural production and rural welfare
depends on how well farmers, as prospective demanders, benefit from it.
This in turn would depend on the integration of agricultural research
with the extension system. The concept of adaptive research requires a
high degree of integration between these services in carrying to farmers
profitable packages of technology etc. The extension system has to act
not only as a conveyer belt between researchers and farmers, but also as
a catalyst for adoption of new techniques by the farmers with small
means and low incomes. A targeted extension network with strong links
with research institutes has to be developed to achieve these
objectives.
Agricultural extension services in Pakistan are still based on the
notion that a cadre of agents with some general knowledge about
agricultural sciences can help the farmers to improve their production.
There are at least two serious problems with this approach. One, it has
allowed a proliferation of frontline workers (called field assistants)
with poor training, limited mobility and low reward for good work. The
provincial agricultural extension departments seem to have become a
refuge for a large number of young high school graduates with little
prospect for growth in their careers or service to the farming
community. Two, these workers and their supervisors (called agricultural
assistants) must often concentrate their best efforts on reaching the
influential and well-off farmers. This is partly the duality problem
that for economy and convenience every public sector service
accommodates at the expense of the small or poor farmers.
The training and visit (T and V) method introduced in some
districts of the Punjab and Sind in the early 1980s has so far produced
no evidence of its alleged superiority over the conventional extension
methods. Perhaps one of the important factors constraining its work has
been a lack of commitment to resources and training of personnel. The
adaptive research technique integrated with the T and V extension system
seems quite attractive, but its impact on farmers will depend on two
major factors.
Firstly, there should be a shift from a reliance on a large number
of poorly trained frontline workers (field assistants), with little
motivation, to a core of well-trained extension agents (agricultural
assistants) formed in teams and linked closely to the research system.
Here, the role of subject specialists is central to the success of the
research-extension nexus, because these specialists can provide a
constant and stable flow of the relevant research to extension agents
and farmers. The emphasis on competent and specialized knowledge, of
course, would be equally helpful in improving the low standards of
teaching and training observed today.
Secondly, it is imperative that farmers, particularly those who
need good quality service and do not at present get it, should be
organized into formal groups or associations to take advantage of the
specialized and integrated approach to technology transfer. The
formation of these groups will not only yield economies of scale, and
hence save considerable resources, but will also encourage participation
of small operators. At present, sharecropping tenants and small
owner-operators have little, if any, direct access to quality extension
service. As individuals, they are dependent on a system which reinforces
duality. As members of relatively homogeneous groups, they can exercise
far greater influence on the system that now excludes them as
individuals.
CONCLUDING REMARKS
The process of development is not about marginal adjustments; it
usually involves deep structural changes. These changes, at least
initially, rarely come from reliance on markets. Public policy plays a
dominant role in creating new structures and organization that may help
or hinder development. In societies with highly differentiated agrarian
structures, low levels of productivity and high income inequalities,
State intervention can exacerbate these conditions without major
readjustments in agrarian relations, taxes and the like. These
adjustments are the necessary conditions for realizing the positive
impact of policies about support prices, input subsidies, credit, etc.
Pakistani governments do not seem to agree with this proposition. They
have relied instead on policies which have largely excluded the option
of structural change. This paper has attempted to demonstrate some of
the serious consequences of their policies on agriculture in Pakistan.
Concluding Remarks
SYED FAKHAR IMAM
(Speaker, National Assembly of Pakistan)
Chairperson
I should like to commend Professor Mahmood Hasan Khan for his very
learned discourse in which, in some ways, he has touched upon the most
sensitive issues that may confront any policy-maker in a developing
country, especially in a country which may be undergoing the phase of
economic, social and political development that we are passing through
today. He has looked at the social, economic and political constraints
of an academician. The policy-formulator has to look at those very
options from the vantage point where the art of compromise has to be
arrived at. Some individual may say that, of course, the social power
structure is primarily based on our land tenure systems and land
ownership systems but the policy-makers have their own limitations. Of
course, this is so in all the systems of governments in the world. But
in Pakistan the issue of land reforms in the pre-partition and
post-partition era has been an issue looked at primarily from the
land-ceiling angle; but I think it should also be examined from other
angles. As Mr Shafi Niaz has said, when we consider land reforms in
Pakistan we perhaps only look at one dimension, which is land ceiling,
and the other three or four factors which go along with it are often not
considered in depth. Normatively Prof. Mahmood Hasan Khan may have come
up with this highly differentiated and asymmetrical analysis; but,
again, how many micro analyses have been done pertaining to cropping
pattern options, given our factors of land, labour, technology and
capital? To what extent has there been investment in terms of training
persons in modern agriculture techniques and to what degree have
research and extension been spread to the farmers? What has been the
flow of the terms of trade in Pakistan's economy? Have they been
flowing from the rural areas to the urban areas from 1947 to 1985, or
have they been flowing in the reverse direction from the urban areas to
the rural areas? And what are the rural and urban social indices of
rates of literacy in the urban and rural areas, rates of educational
levels, rates of potable water availability and rates of energy
consumption in the urban and rural areas? Many articulate men and women
have talked about policy-making but there has been no comparison drawn,
on the per capita basis, of these essential factors of our urban and
rural people. When an election is held, it is the rural people who get
elected--naturally, as the rural people form 70 percent of the
population and naturally those people will come within the rural areas
who have had a greater opportunity for acquiring positions of influence
and power within the political arena. But the same also goes within the
urban areas in Pakistan: only those people, whether it is in the
commerce, industrial or trade sector, come forth who have had more
opportunities and who are also likely to be in the political arena. But
when we try and compare it on an urban-rural basis, then we do not
sometimes analyze it along these lines because the rural areas being
less literate and articulate, their influence in policy-formulation is
not commensurate with their representation. For instance, how may major
newspapers reflect the role of the rural areas? Does any one major
newspaper dwell at length at the issues facing rural people as outlined
in the theoretical framework put up by Professor Mahmood Hasan Khan?
Overall, it has been the urban factor which has been the dominant
factor. And how many times have we had the rural people coming out and
playing the role of power and influence in 37 years? About 17 years,
perhaps? Even in these 17 years, can it be said that total dominance was
only of the rural people? Were the other power elites, viz. the armed
forces, bureaucracy and urban elites, not having any say? Even in the
National Assembly today the number of agriculturists and the extent of
their land holding are not yet determined. I think we would have to make
an analytical study of that. Then, how can we differentiate the classes
of people according to their holdings? And if we look at the social
structure, the power structure, I am not so sure that we may come out
with the kind of power structure that is commonly understood by the
people as the one which actually influences decisions. Maybe they do,
maybe they do not; I am not sure because I have yet to see a study, a
micro-analysis study. But, more than that, I think the agricultural
economists of Pakistan should address themselves to these questions,
namely croping patterns, where the price differentials and the
comparative advantages should accrue to Pakistan. I know, for instance,
that of the four major crops over a 35-year time-span, sugar has been
supported at the cost of other crops. I do not think this is true of the
other three major crops, namely rice, wheat and cotton. There it has
always been the middleman, whether it has been the government
procurement agencies since 1977 or the private procurement sector before
1977, who have been the beneficiaries, not the producer, whether it is
small, big or middle-size producer. Today we are importing edible oil
for Rs 700 crores, milk and milk products for 40-50 crores, and timber
for Rs 70-78 crores. Pakistan has less than four percent of its total
land area under forest and we have not even touched on that subject
today. About livestock, which contribute 28 percent to our agriculture,
not one person has spoken today except in the brief introduction by
Professor Mahmood Hasan Khan. So, I think the concepts of agroeconomics
in Pakistan needs many more micro studies and I think our universities,
our research centres, our extension people and the farmers need to
explore these areas because ultimately it is the small producer who must
be made capable of producing at optimum levels of production.
The 50-acre farm in Pakistan is supposed to be a large-size
holding. Now what are the optimum levels of efficiencies of production
and the economies of scale as far as land holding is concerned in
Pakistan? Can this size of holding, given the levels of inputs of
fertilizer, pesticide, extension, research and education; be considered
'large' on a comparative economy of scale? Anyway, these are
value judgements. Of course, we have to go back and see the levels of
development at which Pakistan stands today in industry, in commerce and
in agriculture. Agriculture was our base where we could have been having
surpluses of production. But where are we today? Last year 2.9 million
bales of cotton, this year 5.9 million bales of cotton. Look at the
extreme variation, the drop, it is a 100-percent drop due to weather and
lack of pesticide application this year. A yield of 10 to 11 million
tonnes is what we are hearing can be expected this year. Nobody knows
the last figure. 13 million tonnes was predicted, but last year it was
only 11 million tonnes. For two years successively we had surpluses. We
did not know where to put them; it was put under the canvas. So, there
are variations in Pakistan's agriculture and still the major factor
which affects our fanning strategies is weather, followed by all these
other strategies in which, of course, I think pricing mechanisms have
played a very essential part. But I would still say that the
policy-maker still has to look at these differentials, at these policy
implications in a manner, perhaps, where the academician, the
theoretician, the philosopher may have to look at it from a different
vantage point. But, of course, without the philosopher, the theoretician
and the person who can always point his finger at the policy, the person
who has to compromise (which is the policy-maker), I think we would not
have progressed. Preparation of such dissertations, the holding such for
a which provide us this opportunity for arriving at decision make it
better for us. Without having full-fledged debate and discussion,
policy-making can never be meaningful.
REFERENCES
[1.] Agricultural Development Bank of Pakistan. Annual Report
1982-83. Islamabad.
[2.] Berry, R. A., and W. R. Cline. Agrarian Structure and
Productivity in Developing Countries. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins
University Press. 1979.
[3.] Chaudhry, M. G. "Green Revolution and Redistribution of
Rural Incomes: Pakistan's Experience". Pakistan Development
Review. Vol. XXI, No. 3. Autumn 1982.
[4.] Cheema, A. A., and M. H. Malik. "Consumption and
Employment Effects of Income Redistribution in Pakistan". Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. XXIII, Nos. 2&3. Summer-Autumn 1984.
[5.] Cheong, Kee-Cheok, and E. H. D'Silva. Prices, Terms of
Trade, and the Role of Government in Pakistan's Agriculture.
Washington, D.C. April 1984. (World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 643)
[6.] Cornelisse, P. A., and Syed Nawab Haider Naqvi. The Anatomy of
the Wheat Market in Pakistan. Rotterdam: Erasmus University, Islamabad:
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics. October 1984.
[7.] Ercelawn, A. "Income Inequality in Rural Pakistan: A
Study of Sample Villages". Pakistan Journal of Applied Economics.
Vol. XXIII, No. 1. Spring 1984.
[8.] Irfan, M., and R. Amjad. "Poverty in Rural
Pakistan". In A. R. Khan and E. Lee (eds.), Poverty in Rural Asia.
Bangkok: ILO/ARTEP. 1984.
[9.] Jetha, N., S. Akhtar and G. Rao. Domestic Resource
Mobilization in Pakistan: Selected Issues. Washington, D.C. February
1984. (World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 632)
[10.] Khan, M. H. "The Political Economy of Agricultural
Research in Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XX, No. 2.
Summer 1981.
[11.] Khan, M. H. Underdevelopment and Agrarian Structure in
Pakistan. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press. 1981.
[12.] Khan, M. H. "Green Revolution and Redistribution of
Rural Incomes: Pakistan's Experience--A Comment". Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. XXII, No. 1. Spring 1983.
[13.] Khan, M. H. "Policy Options on Rural Poverty in
Pakistan". A Report to Pakistan Planning Commission, June 1983.
(Mimeographed)
[14.] Khan, M. H. "Classes and Agrarian Transition in
Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXII, No. 3. Autumn
1983.
[15.] Mahmood, M., and Nadeem-ul-Haque. "Farm Size and
Productivity Revisited". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XX, No.
2. Summer 1981.
[16.] Mahmood, Zafar. "Income Inequality in Pakistan: An
Analysis of Existing Evidence". Pakistan Development Review. Vol.
XXIII, Nos. 2&3. Summer-Autumn 1984.
[17.] Mujahid, G. B. S. "A Note on Measurement of Poverty and
Income Inequalities in Pakistan: Some Observations on Methodology".
Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XVII, No. 3. Autumn 1978.
[18.] Pakistan. Agricultural Census Organisation. Pakistan Census
of Agriculture 1972. Vol. 1. Lahore. 1976.
[19.] Pakistan. Agricultural Census Organization. Pakistan Census
of Agriculture 1980. Vol. 1. Lahore. 1983.
[20.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Household Income and
Expenditure Survey 1971-72 [and 1979]. Karachi.
[21.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. 10 Years of Pakistan
in Statistics 1972-80. Karachi. 1984.
[22.] Pakistan. Ministry of Finance. Economic Adviser's Wing.
Pakistan Economic Survey 1984-85. Islamabad. May 1985.
[23.] Pakistan. Planning Commission. The Sixth Five Year Plan
1983-88. Islamabad. June 1983.
[24.] Thobani, M. "The Effects of a Change in Wheat Prices on
Incomes". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XVIII, No. 4. Winter
1979.
[25.] United Consulting Group Ltd. Report on Agricultural Marketing
in Pakistan. Lahore. 1984.
[26.] Zahid, S. N. "Differences Between Sharecropped and
Owner-Operated Farms in Sindh, Pakistan: Some Theoretical and Empirical
Observations". Pakistan Journal of Applied Economics. Vol. 2, No.
2. 1983.
(1) Estimates of rural poverty in Pakistan are: 35 percent of rural
households in 1969-70 [17], 42 percent in 1971-72 [13], 28 percent in
1977 [8], and 31 percent in 1979 [8]. Khan [131 has classified the rural
poor as (a) small landowning cultivators, (b)small landowner-tenants,
(c) share-croppers, (d) landless farm workers, and (e) landless non-farm
workers.
(2) Small farmers' share in all farm investments is less than
one-quarter. Most of their investment is in conventional implements and
tools, animals and related equipment [20].
MAHMOOD HASAN KHAN, Dr Khan is Professor of Economics at Simon
Fraser University, Burnaby, B.C. (Canada).
Table 1
Household Distribution of Landownership and Rural Income in Pakistan,
1972 and 1980
Decile of Rural Percent of Land Owned Percent of Rural Income
Households 1972 1980 1972 1980
First 0.98 0.72 3.56 3.56
Second 2.24 1.66 5.36 4.95
Third 3.05 2.94 5.67 5.60
Fourth 4.53 4.36 7.43 6.50
Fifth 5.49 5.29 7.33 8.27
Sixth 8.32 7.81 9.04 8.32
Seventh 8.34 8.08 9.75 9.99
Eighth 12.13 12.02 11.61 11.64
Ninth 14.06 14.64 14.49 14.31
Tenth 40.86 42.48 25.76 26.86
Note: Data are compiled from [18 and 20] for land and [19] for income.
Land records show that in 1976 one-quarter of the land area was held
by about three-quarters of landowners with a holding of less than 2
hectares.
Table 2
Distribution of Landownership and Operational Holdings in Provinces
of Pakistan, 1971-72 and 1980-81
Size of Farm/ Landownership Holdings
Holdings Year Percent Percent
(hectares) of Owners of Area
Punjab
Less than 2.0 1971-72 80.0 33.4
1980-81 79.9 36.2
2.0--less than 20.0 1971-72 17.3 43.2
1980-81 18.3 43.7
20.0 and over 1971-72 2.7 23.4
1980-81 1.8 20.1
Sind
Less than 2.0 1971-72 59.9 16.1
1980-81 66.2 22.0
2.0--less than 20.0 1971-72 31.3 39.7
1980-81 28.6 39.9
20.0 and over 1971-72 8.8 44.2
1980-81 5.2 38.1
NWFP
Less than 2.0 1971-72 90.7 51.4
1980-81 92.5 55.2
2.0--less than 20.0 1971-72 8.3 30.5
1980-81 6.8 30.4
20.0 and over 1971-72 1.0 18.1
1980-81 0.7 14.3
Size of Farm/ Operational Holdings
Holdings Percent Percent
(hectares) of Farms of Area
Punjab
Less than 2.0 65.1 29.4
70.8 33.4
2.0--less than 20.0 31.9 50.1
26.6 46.1
20.0 and over 3.0 20.5
2.6 20.5
Sind
Less than 2.0 70.7 39.0
75.9 41.7
2.0--less than 20.0 27.3 42.4
21.9 39.6
20.0 and over 2.0 18.6
2.2 18.7
NWFP
Less than 2.0 83.7 36.3
87.1 41.6
2.0--less than 20.0 13.5 31.2
11.2 30.6
20.0 and over 2.8 32.5
1.7 27.8
Note: Landownership data are from records of Boards of Revenue of the
provincial governments [13]. Data for operational holdings are
compiled from [18 and 20]. The land concentration ratios (Gini
coefficients) are as follows:
Landownership Holdings Operational Holdings
Province
1971-72 1980-81 1971-72 1980-81
Punjab 0.50 0.47 0.48 0.50
Sind 0.57 0.53 0.44 0.46
NWFP 0.41 0.38 0.60 0.57
Table 3
Land Revenue Collections in Pakistan, 1975 and 1984
Gross
Value
Year Land Provincial of all
Revenue Tax Revenue Crops
(.... In Million Rupees ....)
(1) (2) (3) (4)
1974-75 183 2,705 23,271
1975-76 187 4,075 26,602
1976-77 141 4,442 29,447
1977-78 178 4,973 34,516
1978-79 231 5,764 39,322
1979-80 169 7,386 44,765
1980-81 241 10,982 49,408
1981-82 230 11,869 57,601
1982-83 189 12,531 62,422
1983-84 143 14,082 61,202
Ratio of
Land Revenue
Year Ratio of Ratio of to Cropped
2 and 3 2 and 4 Area
(Percent) (Percent) (Rs /Hectare)
(1) (5) (6) (7)
1974-75 6.8 0.8 10.54
1975-76 4.6 0.7 10.38
1976-77 3.2 0.5 7.74
1977-78 3.6 0.5 9.63
1978-79 4.0 0.6 11.97
1979-80 2.3 0.4 8.79
1980-81 2.2 0.5 12.47
1981-82 1.9 0.4 11.63
1982-83 1.0 0.3 9.40
1983-84 1.0 0.2 7.04
Note: Data are compiled from [21] and [22].
Table 4
Agricultural Subsidies in Pakistan, 1975 and 1984
Year Plant
Ferti- Protec- Wheat Tube-
lizer tion Seeds wells
(.... in Million Rupees....)
197475 326 112 6 16
1975-76 607 381 6 24
1976-77 381 485 6 48
1977-78 617 523 25 20
1978-79 1,692 267 8 24
1979-80 2,454 218 29 22
1980-81 2,457 -- 2 20
1981-82 1,794 -- 8 24
1982-83 1,948 -- 8 24
1983-84 1,720 -- -- 16
Ratio of
Net Develop- Subsidies
Year Irri- ment to Ex-
gation Total Expendi- pendi-
Cost Subsidies ture ture
(.... in Million Rupees....) (Percent)
197475 61 521 10,734 4.9
1975-76 146 1,164 12,366 9.4
1976-77 166 1,086 15,038 7.2
1977-78 121 1,306 15,353 8.5
1978-79 231 2,222 18,494 12.0
1979-80 361 3,084 19,082 16.2
1980-81 578 3,057 23,321 13.1
1981-82 750 2,576 24,643 10.5
1982-83 727 2,707 29,833 9.1
1983-84 700 2,436 29,264 8.3
Note: Net Irrigation Cost is the difference between the
operation and maintenance cost of the irrigation system and
revenue collected from water users. Development expenditure
is of both federal and provincial governments. Figures for
1983-84 are estimates. Data are compiled from [22,
Table 8.4, pp. 102-3 and 5, Table 11, p. 25] .
Table 5
Distribution of Cultivated and Copped Area by
Farm Size in Pakistan, 1980
Farm Size Percent of Percent of
(hectares) Cultivated Cropped
Area Area
Less than 2.0 8 9
2.0 to less than 10.0 56 58
10.0 to less than 60.0 30 28
60.0 and over 6 5
Percent of
Farm Size of Major Cropping
(hectares) Crops in Intensity
Cropped Area
Less than 2.0 63 147
2.0 to less than 10.0 66 130
10.0 to less than 60.0 57 111
60.0 and over 59 100
Note: Data are compiled from [20].
Table 6
Distribution of Marketable Surplus by
Farm Size in Pakistan, 1983
Percentage of Total Output in Markets
Farm Size Sugar-
(hectares) Wheat Rice Maize Cotton cane
Less than 5.0 28 50 20 91 99
5.0 to less than 10.0 60 88 35 98 99
10.0 and over 78 98 59 98 95
Note: Data are compiled from [25, Table 111-2].
Table 7
Distribution of Loans by Agricultural Development Bank
of Pakistan by Farm Size in Pakistan, 1982-83
Amount
Ownership in Percentage
Status Million Rs Share
1. Landowners:
up to 5.0 hectares 463.74 20.1
over 5.0 to 10.0 800.48 34.6
over 10.0 to 20.0 512.30 22.2
over 20.0 342.52 14.8
2. Non-Landowners 191.40 8.3
Note: The loans to non-landowners are to corporate bodies
or individuals for agro-industries, poultry, etc.
Data are compiled from [1].
Table 8
Allocation of Public Investment to Agriculture in
the Five Year Plans of Pakistan
Percentage Allocation
Sector First Second Third
Plan Plan Plan
1955-60 1960-65 1965-70
1. Agriculture 9.5 6.6 6.2
2. Fertilizer -- 1.9 4.2
Subsidy
3. Total (1+2) 9.5 8.5 10.4
4. Water 19.9 43.3 34.2
5. Agriculture 29.4 51.8 44.6
and Water
Percentage Allocation
Sector Non-Plan Fifth Sixth
Period Plan Plan
1970-77 1978-83 1983-88
1. Agriculture 5.5 4.2 4.2
2. Fertilizer 3.1 5.6 0.6
Subsidy
3. Total (1+2) 8.6 9.8 4.8
4. Water 17.0 10.1 10.8
5. Agriculture 25.6 19.9 15.6
and Water
Note: Data are compiled from [231.