Analysis of inter-industry relations in Pakistan for 1975-76.
Syed, Aftab Ali
INTRODUCTION
Input-Output tables provide a detailed accounting of the goods and
services that individual industries buy from and sell to each other,
and, therefore, constitute a useful medium for an analysis of the
interdependent nature of the various sectors of an economy. The
PIDE's release of input-output (I-O) tables of Pakistan's
economy for the year 1975-76 [9] is an important contribution in this
respect. An 'open' output determination of model of the
Leontief type (1) is applied to the said data base to delineate the
structural interdependence of Pakistan's economy. Some salient
features of the economy such as sectoral distribution of the value
added, cost composition of the value of sectoral outputs, output and
income multipliers are discussed in Section I. The notion of
interdependence arising through technological interconnections between
various sectors implies structural linkages--both 'backward'
and 'forward'. Quantification of these linkages provides an
effective way of identifying "key sectors" of the economy.
Section II discusses the methodology used and the empirical results
obtained pertaining to key sectors of the Pakistan's economy. Some
concluding remarks are offered in Section III.
I. SOME ASPECTS OF THE STRUCTURAL CHARACTERISTICS OF
PAKISTAN'S ECONOMY, 1975-76
Some structural indicators of the economy of Pakistan derived from
the I-O tables for the year 1975-76 are presented in Table 1. During the
year in question goods and services worth Rs. 243 3 billion were
producted. This resulted in generating of about Rs. 117 billion worth of
gross domestic product (at factor cost)--48 percent of the total output.
The direct import content of goods and services embodied in production
amounted to Rs. 21 billion. Almost similar amount was spent on the
imports of goods and services for final consumption. The total import
bill accounted for some 34.4 percent of the gross domestic product at
market prices.
An economy's sectoral interdependence is characterized by the
amount of goods and services it delivers to various sectors of the
economy for further processing. Pakistan's economy delivered about
42 percent of the output (Rs. 102 billion) for intermediate use. This
proportion rises to about 51 percent if imports are taken into account.
This compares favourably with the situation that existed in 1954 when
the intermediate use of the output stood at 36 percent [8].
Primary production activities contributed 35 percent of the gross
value added at factor cost and 33.9 percent of the gross value added at
market prices. Manufacturing activities accounted for 11.7 percent and
14.4 percent of the gross value added at factor cost and market prices,
respectively. Tertiary activities explain shares of 53.3 percent and
51.7 percent of the gross value added at factor cost and market prices
respectively.
The maximum contribution is made by "agriculture" (crop
sector) alone--22.1 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) at factor
cost and 21.4 percent at market prices. The second largest contribution
of 15.2 percent and 14.7 percent is made by wholesale and retail sector
respectively. This is followed by livestock sector which accounts for
10.8 percent of GDP at factor cost and 10.4 percent in market prices.
Although maufacturing industries as a group contribute about 12 percent
of GDP at factor cost, it is important to note that of the 81
manufacturing industries there are only seven industries whose
contribution is of any significance--five-tenths of one percent or
slightly more.
The disaggregation of the value added by 118 sectors has provided
an improvement, for analytical purposes, over the traditional 11-sector
National Accounts presentation. This improvement is, however, restricted
by the fact that various components of the value added--wages and
salaries, income of unincorporated business, operating surplus--have not
been spelled out. This additional information is essentially required in
its own right but is also crucial to link income (of the households) to
consumption expenditures--an element required to derive the
'closed' I-O model for the economy.
The cost of material inputs and services (both domestic and
imported) for the economy as a whole accounted for 50.4 percent of
output with taxes, while the gross value added at factor cost comes to
48 percent. Taxes (less subsidies) account for 1.6 percent of the
output.
The taxes are maximum for cigarettes and other tobacco products
(sector 026), explaining about 50 percent of the value of output. On
sugar refining they account for 25 percent of the value of output,
whereas perfumes and cosmetics (sector 045) and paints and varnishes
(sector 046) explain about 24 percent and 20 percent taxes,
respectively.
The cost of material inputs expressed as the percentage value of
output with taxes is highest for cotton ginning (sector 063), rice
husking (sector 069), gut and khandsari (sector 070), and edible oils
(sector 071), explaining more than 90 percent of the value of output.
Rice milling (sector 018) and steel furniture (sector 082) account for
84 percent or more of the cost of the materials used.
For sectors in which indirect taxes on outputs as well as cost of
materials and services are low, the share of the value added at factor
cost is high and vice versa. Mostly, primary activities like fishing
(sector 014), forestry (sector 015), and mining and quarrying (sector
016) fall in this category. Similarly, in public services like water
transportation (sector 112), radio (sector 114), and telephones,
telegraphs and post (sector 115) the cost of materials accounts for only
18 to 20 percent with correspondingly very high value added.
Impact Analysis
The relationship between the initial expenditure and the total
effect triggered by the expenditure is known as the impact of the sector
on the economy as a whole--the multiplier effect. As such, the study of
multipliers has come to be called impact analysis. The modern concept of
income multipliers is usually associated with Keynes [2]. Since Keynes
dealt with broad aggregates, his income and employment multipliers were
also highly aggregated. Although these aggregative multipliers are
useful analytical tools, they do not show the details of how multiplier
effects are worked out throughout the economy.
Analysts are most often interested in sectoral details rather than
in overall impact. Assume, for example, that one wishes to measure the
disaggregated effects of the initial stimulus to the agriculture sector
of the economy. There will be undoubtedly an immediate (direct) impact
on this sector, but how will these effects of stepped up activity in
agriculture ramify throughout the economy? Given the interdependent
nature of economic activities, it is apparent that the total impact will
not be limited to those industries that are directly affected. Sectoral
multipliers, derived from an I-O model, provide this important and
useful information.
The impact matrix for the industries under study captures both the
direct and indirect requirements of domestically produced commodities
and services per rupee of delivery to final demand. (2) The direct
inputs are those used by the industry under consideration, whereas
indirect input requirements refer to the inputs purchased by all other
industries in which production is required to enable them to supply
inputs to the first industry, and so on. Thus, an impact matrix traces
the total impact of an initial stimulus throughout the economy.
In a fashion analogous to output multipliers, one can also compute value-added (or income) multipliers. These relate to the sectoral income
arising as a result of a unit increase in final demand. (3)
Income and Output multipliers calculated for 118 sectors of
Pakistan's economy for 1975-76 are presented in Table 2. Column (1)
of this table shows observed direct value added coefficients, whereas in
Column (2) total value added in each of the sectors is shown. If we
divide the values reported in Column (2) by their corresponding values
in Column (1), we would obtain what is described as income or value
added multipliers. (4) In Column (4) the output multipliers for the
sectors in question are reported. These are the diagonal elements of the
impact matrix and, therefore, do not indicate the impact on the economy
as a whole.
A unit increase in the bill of final demand, for example, for wheat
growing on small farms (sector 001) leads to an increase of Rs 1.06 in
output in this sector. This results in an increase of Rs 1.27 in income
in this sector. The largest output multiplier value of 2.54 is recorded
for tea blending (sector 021) which is followed by basic metals (sector
055) and edible oils (sector 020) having multiplier values of 1.95 and
1.82, respectively. The largest income increases are reported by basic
metals (sector 055), petroleum products (sector 051), and cotton ginning
(sector 063) with values of 23.60, 17.14, and 10.16, respectively.
The above sectoral summary measures, based as they are on an I-O
model of Pakistan's economy, can serve as a useful guide to an
analyst in choosing between competing alternatives of income generation
versus output stimulation.
II. STRUCTURAL LINKAGES AND KEY SECTORS IN PAKISTAN'S ECONOMY
Hirschman [4] has been instrumental in defining operationally the
linkage effects and also in describing the causal link between linkages
and economic development. The structural linkages can be analysed in two
ways. An activity absorbs inputs from others and, as such, whenever it
operates at a positive level, it provides stimulus for the expansion (or
initiation) of production in the input--providing industries--the
backward linkage effect. Secondly, an activity provides inputs to other
industries and, in so doing, either through the cheapening of its
products or through greater availabilities, stimulates increases in the
output levels of the absorbing industries--the forward linkage effect.
The potential importance of a particular sector in generating growth
depends upon the strength of these stimuli, and it is argued that the
backward linkage effects, which are more powerful in their operation
than the forward linkage effects, could be used as a basis for
development planning.
Following earlier studies, (5) we have used the I-O table of
Pakistan's economy for 1975-76 to empirically determine these
linkages. A measure of backward linkage for any industry may be defined
as the ratio of its intermediate consumption to its total output [1].
Correspondingly, the forward linkage for any industry may be estimated
as the ratio of intermediate demand for the output of that industry to
the total availability of the output of that industry. These are,
however, average measures and do not give the distribution of inputs or
deliveries among the various industries. Thus, these estimates of
linkages do not distinguish between industries which have highly skewed inputs or deliveries pattern and those whose structural relations might
be more even.
A more refined way of computing these linkages has been suggested
by Ramaussen [7] who makes use of the inverse matrix for this purpose.
We have utilized his formulation in this paper. (6)
Concept of a Key Industry
Having operationally defined backward and forward linkages, we may
define a 'key' industry as one for which (a) both [K.sub.*j]
and [K.sub.i*]. are greater than unity; and (b) both [L.sub.*j] and
[L.sub.i*] are relatively low. This designation of a key industry can be
defended on the ground that if [K.sub.*j] is relatively large and
[L.sub.*j] is relatively low, an increase in the final demand for the
products of industry j would cause a relatively greater share of the
increase in final demand to be returned to the system of industries in
general. And it can be argued that large effects on other industries are
the most significant characteristics of a key industry. This formulation
also follows Hirschman's characterization of a key industry in that
he defines a key industry as one which has a high backward as well as
forward linkage.
Industries with high backward and forward linkages as well as key
industries determined on the basis of the formulation discussed above
are shown in Table 3. An examination of this table reveals that of the
118 industries examined there are only 26 industries that show high
backward linkages. The number of industries with high forward linkages
is 34. Of the high backward-linkage industries road transportation
(sector 109), petroleum products (sector 051), and other chemicals
(sector 149) show relatively strong backward linkages, whereas
agricultural machinery (sector 057), cotton fabrics (sector 043), and
soaps and detergents (sector 047) are among the industries showing
strong forward linkages.
Based on the chosen criterion, only 6 industries--out of a total of
118 industries--can be designated as key industries. These are cotton
yarn (sector 027), silk and synthetic textiles (sector 029), metal
products (sector 056), other non-electrical machinery (sector 058),
electrical machinery (sector 059), and other textiles (sector 078).
It should be borne in mind that characterization of key industries,
as has been reported in this study, is by no means unique. Another
criterion, such as employment generation or final demand propogation,
may result in the choice of a quite different set of key industries from
the one identified here. Our choice is dependent entirely on
technological considerations--that is, an analysis of the inverse matrix
of the economy of Pakistan.
III. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The PIDE's release of I-O table of Pakistan's economy for
1975-76 has provided a rich data-base for analysing the interdependent
nature of the various sectors of the economy. Applying the traditional
Leontief type open I-O model to this database, this paper has
highlighted some aspects of the structural characteristics of the
economy. Sectoral income and output multipliers, based on the impact
matrix, have been estimated. Relatively large income multipliers have
been obtained for basic metals, petroleum products, and cotton ginning,
whereas tea-blending, and edible oils report high output multipliers.
Analysis of the impact matrix has been extended further to quantify backward and forward linkages. Based on these indices, key industries
for the economy have been identified. They include cotton yarn, metal
products, and silk and synthetic textiles, among others.
Comments on "Analysis of Inter-Industry Relations in Pakistan
for 1975-76"
Let me begin by saying that any work on input-output analysis of
the economy of Pakistan is most welcome as this has been my hobby horse throughout my professional career. The technique of input-output
analysis was formally introduced in Pakistan's planning in the
early Sixties. But I must say that over the last quarter of a century we
have not made as much progress in this regard as others have made in
similar situations. I take this opportunity to congratulate the Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics (PIDE) on reactivating research in
this area and, specifically, on their contribution in the form of the
input-output table of Pakistan's economy released in 1983, on which
the paper under discussion is based.
Before discussing the paper, I must also pay my compliments to
Aftab Ali Syed, the author of the paper, who must have put in a
tremendous effort in carrying out a number of applications of the
input-output technique to the input-output table of the economy of
Pakistan. For discussion purposes the entire paper can be divided into
three parts.
In the first part of the paper, the author analyses the cost
structure of 118 different sectors into which the economy is divided, by
looking at the columns of the table. The analysis shows that
intermediate inputs account for 90 percent of the gross value of output
in the agricultural processing industries, like cotton ginning, edible
oils, etc. On the other hand, the value added as a ratio of output is
highest for those sectors in which indirect taxes on inputs and outputs
are lowest. Examples are fishing, forestry, mining and quarrying, etc.
In the second part, the paper presents the usual exercise of
analysing the effect of change in one segment of the economy on the rest
of the economy by using the I eontief-type inverse of direct input
coefficient matrix. The matrix of 'direct' and
"indirect" input coefficients so derived helps the author to
quantify the total impact of an initial stimulus throughout the economy,
sector by sector.
The last part of the paper is devoted to an analysis of the
structural linkages in the inter-industry relationships of the economy.
This is done by studying the 'backward' and
'forward' linkage effects with a view to guiding investment
policy decisions. Basically, the criterion applied here lays emphasis on
interdependence among industries and hence the need for striking a
balance in the relative rates of growth of such interlinked industries
as support each other. The idea is to underline the importance of
simultaneous creation of effective demand. The second aspect is to
explore the technological interdependence among certain industries.
Investment decisions would thus be guided by the so-called
'key' sectors of the economy which have the highest
technological linkages.
Input-output technique in this case is used to explore such
linkages on the following presumptions.
(a) Expansion of a sector obviously provides direct stimulus to its
input-delivering sectors. This may be known as the 'backward'
linkage effect.
(b) Increase in the level of output of a sector is again usually
meant for delivery of its output to another sector, thereby stimulating
that sector. This may be called the 'forward' linkage effect.
The potential strength of a particular sector is thus proportional to the above two linkage effects, and, according to the author of the
paper, should therefore be used as a basis for investment decisions.
I have two main comments to offer on the paper. My first comment
pertains to the third part of the paper, where the input-output
technique is used to identify 'backward' and
'forward' linkage effects with the objective of using the same
as a guide for investment policy decisions. I believe such an approach
is extremely inadequate for the following reason. Whereas an application
of such an approach may be appropriate for a technologically advanced
economy in which practically all processes of production are already in
operation, it would not suit a developing economy, especially when an
important element in its development strategy is to pursue a policy of
economic diversification. This would mean that it has yet to introduce
many new processes. Under such circumstances, making the existing
inter-industry relations a basis for new investment decisions would be
utterly inadequate. As an illustration, one may look at that stage of
Pakistan's economic development in the Sixties when cotton--textile
manufacturing was predominant in our industries. Such a framework would
hardly provide a clue to introduction of new processes like the Steel
Mills and even synthetic fibre plants which are more recent
introductions into the system. Obviously, applications of the
input-output framework as developed in the third part of the paper would
be completely inadequate as a guide for investment decisions under such
circumstances.
My second point relates to the weaknesses in basic statistics:
while discussing the cost structure in the first part of the paper, the
author mentions that manufacturing constitutes 12 percent of the total
GDP. If one looks up the latest Statistical Bulletin, published by the
Federal Bureau of Statistics, Government of Pakistan, the contribution
of the manufacturing sector amounts to 20 percent of the total GDP in
Pakistan. In absolute terms, the difference comes to some Rs. 30
billion. I do not blame the author for such a gap, for he could hardly
do much while in Canada. But I do believe that such a discrepancy is
typical of our statistical gaps which call for an urgent attention to
this aspect of the problem before sophisticated applications are made
which are essentially dependent on these data.
By the way, my second comment may get higher ranking than the
first.
Dr Ghulam Rasul
Joint Chief Economist, Planning and Development Division,
Government of Pakistan, Islamabad
Appendix
AN OUTPUT DETERMINATION MODEL OF PAKISTAN'S ECONOMY
The formal structure of the I-O accounts for the economy can be
expressed as
[g.sub.i] = [M.sub.i] + [X.sub.i] = [summation over (j)][X.sub.ij]
+ [F.sub.i] = [W.sub.i] + [F.sub.i] ... ... (1)
[X.sub.j] = [summation over (i)][X.sub.ij] + [V.sub.j] = [U.sub.j]
+ [V.sub.j] ... ... (2)
(1 = 1,...,n)
(j = 1,...,n)
where
[g.sub.i] = total supply of commodity i;
[X.sub.i] = total production of commodity i;
[M.sub.i] = imports of commodity i;
[X.sub.ij] = amount of commodity i used in sector j;
[F.sub.i] = total final demand for commodity i;
[W.sub.i] = total intermediate use of commodity i ([summation over
(j)][X.sub.ij]);
[U.sub.j] = total use by sector j of inputs purchased from other
industries ([summation over (i)][X.sub.ij]); and
[V.sub.j] = total use of primary inputs (value added) in sector j.
Equation (1) states that for each commodity total supply is equal
to demand, which is composed of intermediate demand plus final demand,
whereas equation (2) implies that total production in each sector is
equal to the value of inputs purchased from other sectors plus the value
added in that sector.
Assuming that a given product is supplied only by one sector, that
there are no joint products, and that the amount of each input used in
production by any sector is determined by the level of the output of
that sector, we can write
[X.sub.ij] = [a.sub.ij] [X.sub.j] ... ... ... (3)
Substituting (3) into (1) yields
[X.sub.i] - [summation over (j)][a.sub.ij][X.sub.j] = [F.sub.i] -
[M.sub.i] ... ... (4)
or, more generally,
X - AX = F
X = [(I - A).sup.-1] F ... ... (5)
SECTORAL INCOME MULTIPLIERS
Sectoral value added (or income) multipliers can be calculated as
[K.sub.i] [v.sub.i] ([c.sub.il][F.sub.1] + [C.sub.i2][F.sub.2] +
...... + [c.sub.in][F.sub.n]) ... ... (6)
where
[K.sub.i] = value added (total) in sector i;
[v.sub.i] = ratio of value added (direct) to the value of sectoral
output;
[F.sub.i] = final demand of outputs of sector]; and
[c.sub.ij] = elements of the inverse matrix [(I-A).sup.-1].
STRUCTURAL LINKAGES : BACKWARD AND FORWARD
Rewriting equation (5) as
X = CF ... ... ... (7)
where C = [(I-A).sup.-1], let us denote the sum of the column and
row elements, respectively, as
[n.summation over (i=1)] [c.sub.ij] = [C.sub.*j] ... ... ... (8)
[n.summation over (j=1)] [c.sub.ij] = [C.sub.i*] ... ... ... (9)
For making suitable inter-industry comparisons, we use the
following indices as suggested by Rasmussen [7] :
[K.sub.*j] = 1/n [C.sub.*j]/ 1/[n.sup.2] [n.summation over (j=1)]
[C.sub.*j] ... ... (10)
[K.sub.i*] = 1/n [C.sub.i*]/ 1/[n.sup.2] [n.summation over (i=1)]
[C.sub.i*] ... ... (11)
Indices [K.sub.*j] and [K.sub.i*] are termed as "index of
power of dispersion" and "index of sensitivity of
dispersion", respectively. These indices can also be interpreted as
measures of Hirschman's backward and forward linkages,
respectively.
To avoid the bias created by the averaging principle, Coefficients
of Variation of the above indices are constructed and used :
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... (12)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] ... (13)
REFERENCES
[1.] Chenery, H. B., and T. Watanabe. "International
Comparisons of the Structure of Production". Econometrica. Vol. 26,
No. 4. October 1958. pp. 487-521. pp. 487-521.
[2.] Dillard, D. The Economics of J. M. Keynes. Englewood Cliffs,
N.J.: Prentice-Hall Inc. 1948.
[3.] Hazari, B. R. "Empirical Identification of Key Sectors in
the Indian Economy". Review of Economics and Statistics. Vol. LII,
No. 3. August 1970.
[4.] Hirschman, A. O. The Strategy of Economic Development. New
Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press. 1958.
[5.] Laumas, P. S. "Key Sectors in Some Underdeveloped Countries". Kyklos. Vol. 28, Fase-1. 1975.
[6.] Moore, F. T., and J. W. Peterson "Regional Analysis: An
Inter-industry Model of Utah". Review of Economics and Statistics.
Vol. XXXVII, No. 4. November. 1955.
[7.] Rasmussen, P. N. Studies in Intersectoral Relations.
Amsterdam: North-Holland. 1957.
[8.] Rasul, G. Input-Output Relationships in Pakistan, 1954.
Rotterdam: Rotterdam University Press. 1964.
[9.] Saleem, Mohammad, et al. "Revised P.I.D.E. Input-Output
Table of Pakistan's Economy: 1975-76". Islamabad: Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics. November 1983. (Research Report
Series, No. 139)
[10.] Syed, Aftab A. "Structural Change, Key Sectors and
Linkage-balanced Growth: An Input-Output Analysis of the Canadian Economy". Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Simon Fraser University,
Vancouver. 1975.
(1) The formal structure of the model is given in the appendix to
this paper.
(2) The impact matrix of the economy of Pakistan is not being
reproduced in this paper. It is, however, available on request, from the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
(3) The formulation of income multipliers is given in the appendix
to this paper.
(4) The reported multipliers, it should be pointed out, are
"partial multipliers" as these refer to an open I-O model used
in this study. "Complete multipliers are obtained when the model is
closed to the households. Consult Moore [6] for a detailed explanation
of the distinction.
(5) Some relevant studies are by Hazari [3], Hirschman [4],
Rasmussen [7], Laumas [5], and Syed [10].
(6) See appendix to this paper for the exact formulation used in
this study.
AFTAB ALI SYED, The author is Senior Analyst in the Input-Output
Division of Statistics Canada, Ottawa (Canada). The views expressed in
this paper are those of the author alone and should in no way be
ascribed to the agency he is associated with.
Table 1
Some Structural Indicators Derived from Input-output
Tables of Pakistan's Economy: 1975-76
(Million
Structural Indicators Rupees)
1. Gross value of total output 243,340
2. Gross Domestic Product (factor cost) 116,816
3. Indirect taxes less subsidies 3,754
4. Gross Domestic Product (market prices) 120,570
5. Value of total imports 41,548
6. Total imports as a proportion of GDP
(market prices) 0.344
7. GDP (factor cost) as a proportion of total output 0.480
8. Total intermediate demand for goods and
services produced 122,770
[From domestic sources 101,877]
[From imports 20,893]
9. Total final demand of goods and services produced 161,997
[From domestic sources 141,342]
[From imports 20,655]
10. Domestic intermediate use as a proportion of
total output 0.42
Source: [9).
Table 2
Sectoral Multipliers
Income
Direct Total
VA Coeff. VA Coeff.
001 Wheat Growing on Small Farms 0.5956 0.7582
002 Wheat Growing on Large Farms 0.5438 0.8380
003 Rice Growing on Small Farms 0.5721 0.6833
004 Rice Growing on Large Farms 0.2954 0.4392
005 Cotton Growing on Small Farms 0.6002 0.9156
006 Cotton Growing on Large Farms 0.5609 0.9878
007 Sugar-cane Growing on Small Farms 0.6625 0.7782
008 Sugar-cane Growing on Large Farms 0.6611 0.8236
009 Tobacco Growing 0.7391 0.8825
010 Oilseeds other than Cotton Seeds 0.6012 0.6426
011 Pulses 0.2357 0.2709
012 Other Crops 0.6228 1.5164
013 Livestock 0.5684 2.2975
014 Fishing 0.8609 0.9484
015 Forestry 0.7904 1.6197
016 Mining and Quarrying 0.6378 3.3272
017 Grain Milling 0.1511 0.1653
018 Rice Milling 0.1524 0.1524
019 Sugar Refining 0.1575 0.2802
020 Edible Oils 0.0729 0.2835
021 Tea Blending 0.1738 0.4415
022 Fish and Fish Preparations 0.1460 0.1460
023 Confectionery and Bakery 0.1804 0.1804
024 Other Food Industries 0.2639 0.3030
025 Beverages 0.3414 0.3605
026 Cigarettes and other Tobacco
Products 0.1380 0.1380
027 Cotton Yarn 0.2503 1.0643
028 Cotton Fabrics 0.2097 0.4973
029 Silk and Synthetic Textiles 0.1382 0.4672
030 Woollen Textiles 0.2592 0.3557
031 Hosiery 0.0522 0.0523
032 Thread Ball Making 0.1898 0.1982
033 Carpets and Rugs 0.3074 0.3074
034 Other Textiles 0.2756 0.5320
035 Footwear other than Rubber
Footwear 0.1092 0.1092
036 Wearing Apparel 0.3763 0.3763
037 Wood, Cork and Furniture 0.2604 0.3584
038 Paper, Paper Board and Paper
Product 0.2858 1.1381
039 Printing and Publishing 0.2790 0.4603
040 Leather and Leather Products 0.1956 0.6780
041 Rubber Footwear 0.1009 0.1009
042 Other Rubber Products 0.1610 0.4311
043 Pharmaceutical and Medicinal Prep-
aration 0.1055 0.1177
044 Fertilizer 0.3263 0.6368
045 Perfumes and Cosmetics 0.1470 0.1470
046 Paints and Varnishes 0.0411 0.1102
047 Soaps and Detergents 0.1305 0.1306
048 Matches 0.1234 0.1234
049 Other Chemicals 0.3355 1.5182
050 Plastic Products 0.3572 0.4953
051 Petroleum Products 0.1506 2.5824
052 Cement 0.2089 0.6750
053 Glass and Glass Products 0.1164 0.3419
054 Other Non-Metallic Mineral Products 0.3104 0.4431
055 Basic Metals 0.1794 4.2345
056 Metal Products 0.1927 1.2542
057 Agricultural Machinery 0.0761 0.1533
058 Other Non-Electrical Machinery 0.3381 1.4393
059 Electrical Machinery 0.1495 0.6200
060 Bicycles 0.1989 0.1989
061 Auto-Assembly and Parts 0.2324 0.5559
062 Ship Building 0.4575 0.5762
063 Cotton Ginning 0.0876 0.8907
064 Office Equipment 0.0503 0.1191
065 Sports Goods 0.3783 0.3783
066 Surgical Instruments 0.5335 0.5345
067 Other Large-scale Manufacturing 0.5629 0.9035
068 Grain Milling 0.0693 0.0960
069 Rice Husking 0.0983 0.1634
070 Gur and Khandsari 0.0871 0.0917
071 Edible Oils 0.0909 0.1022
072 Other Food Industries 0.3914 0.3966
073 Beverages 0.4434 0.4434
074 Tobacco 0.3297 0.5022
075 Cotton Textiles 0.2275 0.3680
076 Silk and Artsilk Textiles 0.1697 0.1697
077 Carpets 0.4563 0.4608
078 Other Textiles 0.0747 0.6271
079 Shoe Making 0.4330 0.4330
080 Wood 0.3954 0.5826
081 Furniture 0.4866 0.4890
082 Steel Furniture 0.1602 0.1602
083 Printing and Publishing 0.1856 0.1940
084 Leather Goods 0.3769 0.5572
085 Rubber Products 0.1669 0.1936
086 Chemicals 0.2218 0.4087
087 Plastic Products 0.4058 0.7481
088 Non-Metallic Mineral Products 0.2680 1.0096
089 Iron and Steel Remoulding 0.5425 0.8699
090 Metal Products 0.7695 0.9397
091 Agricultural Machinery 0.5284 0.5284
092 Non-Electrical Machinery 0.4747 0.4799
093 Electrical Machinery 0.2935 0.3181
094 Transport Equipment 0.3925 0.3925
095 Sports Goods 0.3583 0.3583
096 Surgical Instruments 0.0814 0.0814
097 Other Small-scale Manufacturing 0.3459 0.3459
098 Low-cost Residential Buildings 0.4366 0.4610
099 Luxurious Residential Buildings 0.3997 0.4078
100 Rural Buildings 0.5000 0.5345
101 Factory Buildings 0.4036 0.4550
102 Public Buildings 0.4258 0.4258
103 Roads 0.5549 0.5549
104 Infrastructure 0.4165 0.4165
105 Ownership of Dwellings 0.8997 0.8997
106 Electricity 0.7671 1.3193
107 Gas 0.8159 1.3756
108 Wholesale and Retail Trade 0.9449 6.0205
109 Road Transportation 0.3157 2.9445
110 Rail Transportation 0.5510 0.9730
111 Air Transportation 0.4092 0.4372
112 Water Transportation 0.8198 0.8232
113 Television 0.5354 0.5534
114 Radio 0.7669 0.7760
115 Telephone, Telegraph and Post 0.8055 1.0267
116 Banking and Insurance Services 0.7285 1.7674
117 Government Services 0.5342 1.5582
118 Services, N.E.S. 0.9581 2.6976
Total 42.8801 85.4257
Income
Output
Multiplier Multiplier
001 Wheat Growing on Small Farms 1.2730 1.0658
002 Wheat Growing on Large Farms 1.5411 1.0598
003 Rice Growing on Small Farms 1.1945 1.0268
004 Rice Growing on Large Farms 1.4867 1.0368
005 Cotton Growing on Small Farms 1.5255 1.0210
006 Cotton Growing on Large Farms 1.7609 1.0223
007 Sugar-cane Growing on Small Farms 1.1747 1.0384
008 Sugar-cane Growing on Large Farms 1.2459 1.0307
009 Tobacco Growing 1.1940 1.0463
010 Oilseeds other than Cotton Seeds 1.0689 1.0130
011 Pulses 1.1493 1.0757
012 Other Crops 2.4349 1.1104
013 Livestock 4.0422 1.0635
014 Fishing 1.1016 1.0000
015 Forestry 2.0491 1.0003
016 Mining and Quarrying 5.2168 1.0378
017 Grain Milling 1.0943 1.0000
018 Rice Milling 1.0000 1.0000
019 Sugar Refining 1.7787 1.0000
020 Edible Oils 3.8917 1.8222
021 Tea Blending 2.5401 2.5401
022 Fish and Fish Preparations 1.0000 1.0000
023 Confectionery and Bakery 1.0000 1.0000
024 Other Food Industries 1.1481 1.0189
025 Beverages 1.0558 1.0525
026 Cigarettes and other Tobacco
Products 1.0000 1.0000
027 Cotton Yarn 4.2529 1.0139
028 Cotton Fabrics 2.3720 1.0050
029 Silk and Synthetic Textiles 3.3803 1.2075
030 Woollen Textiles 1.3723 1.0153
031 Hosiery 1.0014 1.0014
032 Thread Ball Making 1.0438 1.0000
033 Carpets and Rugs 1.0000 1.0000
034 Other Textiles 1.9304 1.1518
035 Footwear other than Rubber
Footwear 1.0000 1.0000
036 Wearing Apparel 1.0000 1.0000
037 Wood, Cork and Furniture 1.3764 1.2118
038 Paper, Paper Board and Paper
Product 3.9815 1.3273
039 Printing and Publishing 1.6497 1.0449
040 Leather and Leather Products 3.4670 1.0403
041 Rubber Footwear 1.0000 1.0000
042 Other Rubber Products 2.6779 1.0292
043 Pharmaceutical and Medicinal Prep-
aration 1.1164 1.0641
044 Fertilizer 1.9516 1.0001
045 Perfumes and Cosmetics 1.0000 1.0000
046 Paints and Varnishes 2.6779 1.1685
047 Soaps and Detergents 1.0005 1.0000
048 Matches 1.0000 1.0000
049 Other Chemicals 4.5251 1.1765
050 Plastic Products 1.3867 1.0178
051 Petroleum Products 17.1451 1.0719
052 Cement 3.2319 1.0001
053 Glass and Glass Products 2.9378 1.2202
054 Other Non-Metallic Mineral Products 1.4276 1.0004
055 Basic Metals 23.6068 1.9543
056 Metal Products 6.5079 1.0172
057 Agricultural Machinery 2.0147 1.0001
058 Other Non-Electrical Machinery 4.2570 1.0710
059 Electrical Machinery 4.1473 1.5466
060 Bicycles 1.0000 1.0000
061 Auto-Assembly and Parts 2.3921 1.1085
062 Ship Building 1.2594 1.0000
063 Cotton Ginning 10.1658 1.0051
064 Office Equipment 2.3684 1.0178
065 Sports Goods 1.0000 1.0000
066 Surgical Instruments 1.0019 1.0000
067 Other Large-scale Manufacturing 1.6053 1.0056
068 Grain Milling 1.3845 1.0000
069 Rice Husking 1.6627 1.0000
070 Gur and Khandsari 1.0538 1.0000
071 Edible Oils 1.1245 1.0000
072 Other Food Industries 1.0133 1.0000
073 Beverages 1.0000 1.0000
074 Tobacco 1.5231 1.5231
075 Cotton Textiles 1.6174 1.1646
076 Silk and Artsilk Textiles 1.0000 1.0000
077 Carpets 1.0098 1.0000
078 Other Textiles 8.3963 1.6605
079 Shoe Making 1.0000 1.0000
080 Wood 1.4736 1.0004
081 Furniture 1.0048 1.0000
082 Steel Furniture 1.0000 1.0000
083 Printing and Publishing 1.0451 1.0002
084 Leather Goods 1.4784 1.0003
085 Rubber Products 1.1601 1.1026
086 Chemicals 1.8424 1.8135
087 Plastic Products 1.8436 1.4121
088 Non-Metallic Mineral Products 3.7669 1.7033
089 Iron and Steel Remoulding 1.6036 1.1819
090 Metal Products 1.2211 1.0045
091 Agricultural Machinery 1.0000 1.0000
092 Non-Electrical Machinery 1.0109 1.0033
093 Electrical Machinery 1.0838 1.0485
094 Transport Equipment 1.0000 1.0000
095 Sports Goods 1.0000 1.0000
096 Surgical Instruments 1.0000 1.0000
097 Other Small-scale Manufacturing 1.0000 1.0000
098 Low-cost Residential Buildings 1.0558 1.0000
099 Luxurious Residential Buildings 1.0204 1.0000
100 Rural Buildings 1.0689 1.0000
101 Factory Buildings 1.1274 1.0001
102 Public Buildings 1.0000 1.0000
103 Roads 1.0000 1.0000
104 Infrastructure 1.0000 1.0000
105 Ownership of Dwellings 1.0000 1.0000
106 Electricity 1.7199 1.0012
107 Gas 1.6860 1.0059
108 Wholesale and Retail Trade 6.3714 1.0026
109 Road Transportation 9.3270 1.0430
110 Rail Transportation 1.7658 1.0056
111 Air Transportation 1.0685 1.0001
112 Water Transportation 1.0041 1.0000
113 Television 1.0335 1.0003
114 Radio 1.0118 1.0001
115 Telephone, Telegraph and Post 1.2747 1.0159
116 Banking and Insurance Services 2.4259 1.0275
117 Government Services 2.9169 1.1704
118 Services, N.E.S. 2.8155 1.0052
Total 267.2137 128.4732
Table 3
Structural Linkages and Key Industries: Pakistan, 1975-76
High Backward
Linkage & Low
Industry Coeff. of Varia- Industry
tion
[K.sub.*j] [L.sub.*j]
005 1.17 4.27 018
006 1.44 3.51 023
012 1.58 3.45 027
013 2.76 2.04 028
015 1.61 3.08 029
016 4.09 1.48 031
020 1.28 6.89 032
027 2.07 2.79 034
029 1.22 4.95 035
038 2.02 3.24 036
040 1.10 5.36 041
049 3.07 1.99 042
051 3.67 1.84 043
056 1.95 3.32 046
058 2.42 2.65 047
059 1.09 6.92 056
063 2.12 2.67 057
078 1.30 6.41 058
088 1.27 6.60 059
106 1.28 3.86 060
107 1.29 3.80 061
108 8.19 1.11 062
109 4.21 1.51 064
116 2.14 2.40 068
117 1.67 3.44 069
118 2.73 1.94 071
075
076
078
083
085
093
096
097
High Forward
Linkage & Low
Industry Coeff. of Varia- Industry
tion
[K.sub.i*] [L.sub.i*]
005 1.22 3.91
006 1.22 3.91
012 1.22 5.53 027
013 1.24 4.23
015 1.19 5.70 029
016 1.39 3.44
020 1.25 3.81 056
027 1.16 4.76
029 1.33 3.59 058
038 1.13 4.25
040 1.15 4.16 059
049 1.19 4.26
051 1.22 4.18 078
056 1.12 5.03
058 1.28 3.73
059 1.28 4.68
063 1.50 3.18
078 1.19 5.62
088 1.29 5.79
106 1.33 3.59
107 1.13 4.68
108 1.33 3.63
109 1.11 4.43
116 1.18 4.05
117 1.29 3.74
118 1.29 3.70
1.30 4.27
1.31 3.65
1.55 5.33
1.21 3.95
1.14 4.63
1.19 4.23
1.16 4.14
1.15 4.18
Industry Key Industries
[K.sub.*j] [L.sub.*j] [K.sub.i*] [L.sub.i*]
005
006
012 2.07 2.79 1.22 5.53
013
015 1.22 4.95 1.19 5.70
016
020 1.95 3.32 1.28 4.68
027
029 2.42 2.65 1.19 5.62
038
040 1.09 6.92 1.29 5.79
049
051 1.30 6.41 1.55 5.33
056
058
059
063
078
088
106
107
108
109
116 Average [L.sub.*j] = 8.64
117
118 Average [L.sub.i*] = 5.88