Changes in consumption patterns and employment under alternative income distributions in Pakistan.
Cheema, Aftab Ahmad ; Malik, Muhammad Hussain
The demand and employment effects of alternative distributions of
the existing as well as the additional income generated through growth
of the economy have been analysed in this paper. The results show that
income redistribution in favour of the low-income households would
increase the demand for basic necessities like wheat, pulses, edible
oils, etc., while the demand for certain other commodities would
decrease. The results also show that the consumption levels of the poor
households can be significantly increased with income redistribution
without much adverse effects on the rich. The employment effects axe
found to be positive and substantial.
INTRODUCTION
Not satisfied with the working of the 'trickle down'
theory, economists in recent years have started stressing the need for
'direct attack' on poverty [7, pp. 42-44] and for specific
policies with growth implications for different groups in the society
[3, p. xiii]. Redistribution of income is therefore emerging as an
important policy objective in many developing countries, including
Pakistan. There are a number of ways by which the objective of a more
equitable distribution of income could be attained. One such policy
could be a direct transfer of money income from the rich to the poor. In
Pakistan, income redistribution of this kind is already taking place
through the policy of zakat and ushr. (1) Whatever policy tools are used
by the government, if the final outcome is an increased disposable
income of the poor and a lowered disposable income Of the rich, then
changes in such relative income shares are bound to affect a number of
economic variables. The objective of this study is to see the effects of
changes in relative income shares of different income groups on the
composition and level of consumption demand and also on the level of
employment in Pakistan.
Expenditure patterns of the poor and rich households are usually
not the same. While the former spend a major portion of their incomes on
food, the latter spend relatively more on non-food items. Income
transfers from the rich to the poor, therefore, tend to increase the
demand for those commodities which are consumed mainly by the poor.
Again, if different commodities are produced with different labour
intensities, changes in demand also affect the level of employment.
Some of the studies done in this area are by Cline [4], Nigris et
al. [14], Paukert et al. [20], Ho [7], Soligo [22], and Cheema [2].
Results of most of these studies show that the effects of income
redistribution would be positive on employment and that the composition
of demand would change in favour of food items. Only Soligo's and
Cheema's studies are on Pakistan. Soligo used income distribution
data for the year 1963-64 and measured capital and labour intensities of
consumption expenditures of different income groups. His results show
that the upper-income groups consume more capital-intensive goods and
services than are consumed by the lower-income groups, whose consumption
basket is more labour-intensive. He also looked at the effects on
employment of alternative distributions of additional income generated
in a growing economy. Cheema's work is on the lines being pursued
in the present study but is based on more aggregated data for 1971-72,
and on somewhat different analytical techniques. The present study is
based on data for 1979. It examines the redistributional effects of the
existing as well as additional income not only on the aggregate
consumption demand but also on the demand for different commodities. It
also examines the changes in the consumption levels of households in
different income groups, as well as those in employment level in the
economy after income redistribution.
METHODOLOGY AND DATA
In order to see the consumption effects of inter-group income
transfers, we divided total consumption expenditure into seven groups,
viz. food and drinks, clothing and footwear, personal effects, house
rent and housing, furniture and fixtures, fuel and lighting, and
miscellaneous commodities. Expenditure on food and drinks was subdivided
into twelve groups. We thus had a total of eighteen categories of
commodities. For each of those eighteen categories, five different
functional forms of consumption functions were specified: linear,
semi-log, log-log, log-log inverse and ratio semi-log inverse. (2) These
functions are given, in order, in equations 1-5 below.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (1)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (2)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (3)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (4)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (5)
where
[C.sub.ij] = Average expenditure on commodity i by the households
in the jth income group;
[y.sub.j] = Average income of the households in the jth income
group;
[S.sub.j] = Average size of the household in the jth income group;
and
u,v,n,[member of], and e are the random disturbance terms.
Household size variable, in addition to income variable, has been
introduced in the equations because it is an important determinant of
the consumption expenditure of a household. Furthermore, it allows
flexibility with respect to economies of scale. Relative prices have not
been included in the equations because we are using cross-sectional data
for only one year.
The following other relationships were used to compute the
consumption effects. For illustrative purposes, we give here the linear
consumption function only.
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (6)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (7)
[MATHEMATICAL EXPRESSION NOT REPRODUCIBLE IN ASCII] (8)
where [N.sub.j] and [S.sub.j] are the number and the size of
households in the jth income group. Equation (6) expresses aggregate
expenditure on commodity i by all groups, while equation (7) denotes
aggregate expenditure on all goods by the jth group. Total expenditure
on all commodities by all groups is given by equation (8).
To find consumption expenditure corresponding to a new income
distribution we changed [y.sub.j] to [y.sup.*.sub.j] where
[y.sup.*.sub.j] denotes the new income level. The [y.sup.*.sub.j]s were
calculated corresponding to the following alternatives: (3)
1. Transfer of income from the richest 10 percent to the poorest 10
percent households;
2. Transfer of income from the richest 20 percent to the poorest 20
percent households;
3. Transfer of income from the richest 30 percent to the poorest 20
percent households; and
4. Income growing at a rate of 6.5 percent, with government taxing
away all the additional income and then redistributing it in any of the
following ways:
A. Equal rate of increase in income for all groups;
B. Additional income going relatively more towards the poor;
C. Additional income going relatively more towards the rich; and
D. All households getting equal absolute amounts of the additional
income.
For the first three cases, the incomes of the households in
upper-income brackets were taxed at the rates of 1 percent, 2.5 percent,
5 percent, and 10 percent, and the money thus collected was then equally
distributed among the households in the lower-income brackets. For (B)
and (C) in case (4), the distribution of additional income was based on
weights given in Appendix Table 6. Using the estimated parameters, we
computed the values of equations (6) to (8), corresponding to the
initial and the new income levels. Changes in consumption expenditures
were then obtained from the differences between the initial and new
expenditure levels, [C.sub.ij] and [C.sup.*sub.ij], corresponding to the
initial and the new income levels, [y.sub.j] and [y.sup.*.sub.j].
Constant labour/value-added ratios were used to find the number of
persons required for output corresponding to the new level of
consumption.
The implicit assumptions of this analysis are that the relative
prices of different commodities do not change significantly, that people
do not reduce their work efforts as a result of income transfers, and
that there exists enough under-utilized capital stock, with no other
supply constraints.
The data used in this study were taken from the Household Income
and Expenditure Survey, 1979 [15]. The total number of households
covered in that Survey was 19,847, of which 12,210 households were from
rural areas and the remaining 7,637 households were from urban areas.
Income and expenditure values for the entire country, as given in the
Survey report, were not used as they were unweighted averages of the
urban and rural values. We recalculated those values after assigning appropriate weights to the urban and rural values, the weights being the
proportions of households in the two areas.
Besides the problem of unweighted average of urban and rural
values, another limitation of the Survey data was its coverage. The
Survey did not cover Federally Administered Tribal Areas, Military
Restricted Areas, and Tribal Areas of Peshawar, D. I. Khan and Malakand
Divisions. The population of these areas, according to the 1972
Population Census, constituted about 6.7 percent of the total population
of Pakistan [15, p. xxi]. These areas are relatively economically
backward and their exclusion causes some under-representation of the
poor in the Survey. Despite this limitation, these are the only data
available for recent years and they have been used in a number of other
studies. (4)
The basic sampling unit in the Survey was a "household"
which was defined as "a single person living alone or a group of
persons who normally live and eat together". Common cooking
arrangement was taken as the basic feature of a household. Thus, if two
or more families lived together but did not eat together, they were
treated as separate households.
The concept of income used in this study is that of
"disposable income", i.e. the income left after the payment of
all personal taxes. The income data were converted into deciles which
made it easier to analyse the effects of income transfers from the
richest x percent to the poorest y percent households. The first and the
last deciles were again subdivided into two parts to find the average
incomes of the poorest 5 percent and the richest 5 percent households.
The transformations were done with linear interpolation.
CONSUMPTION EFFECTS
We estimated consumption functions for different commodities, using
the specifications given in equations (1) to (5). Since these
estimations were based on grouped data, we used the Weighted Least
Squares method to solve the problem of heteroscedasticity. (5) All the
functional forms performed well in terms of [bar.R.sup.2] and the
statistical significance of the coefficients. However, the ratio
semi-log inverse specification (equation 5) was chosen on the basis of
Box-Cox test. (6) On theoretical side, this specification is more
flexible and has certain desirable properties. It allows both MPC and
the income elasticity to vary, in all directions, with the level of
income. (7)
The estimates of parameters in equation 5 for different commodities
are given in Table 1. The explanatory powers of all the equations, as
shown by [[bar.R].sup.2], is very high, even though in a few cases some
of the coefficients are not statistically significant. One of the
reasons for these very high [[bar.R].sup.2] is that the equations have
been estimated with cross-sectional grouped data with 12 observations.
The MPCs based on these results were found to decline consistently with
an increase in the level of income for all commodities except personal
effects, fuel and lighting, and miscellaneous items. The MPCs for these
three categories are higher for the rich households and lower for the
poor households. Income elasticities of demand for different commodities
also vary considerably for the rich and the poor households. There are a
number of commodities which, in strict economic sense, are found to be
"luxuries" (income elasticity > 1) for the poor, but
"necessities" (income elasticity < 1) for the rich. These
commodities include milk and milk products, edible oils, cereals other
than wheat and rice, 'meat, fish, and poultry', fruits and
vegetables, 'gur, sugar, honey, and sugar preparations',
tobacco and chewing products, and other food items. (8)
The results show that income transfers from the rich to the poor
households would increase the demand for commodities like wheat and
wheat flour, rice and rice flour, 'meat, fish and poultry',
cereals, edible otis, housing, sugar and sugar preparations, tobacco and
chewing products, etc., and decrease the demand for fuel and lighting,
personal effects, and miscellaneous commodities. Similar results have
been found in other studies. In a study of eleven Latin American
countries by Nigris et al. [14], for example, it was found that income
redistribution in favour of the poor would increase the demand for food
items significantly. Similarly, the results of Iyengar's study on
India, cited in [14, p. 3], also show that the redistribution of the
existing income would increase the consumption of essential commodities.
Percentage changes in consumption expenditures on different commodities
after income redistribution are given in Appendix Tables 1-4. For the
first three income policies, the results are very similar. The
directions of changes in the demand for various commodities are the
same. The only differences are in numerical magnitudes. These results
can briefly be stated as follows.
1. For a given income-transfer policy, the expenditure on
commodities in all except three categories, viz. fuel and lighting,
personal effects and miscellaneous commodities, varies directly with the
rate of income transfer. In Appendix Table 1, for example, expenditure
on meat, fish and poultry increases by 0.58 percent with a 1-percent
income transfer from the top 10 percent to the bottom 10 percent
households while it increases by 4.81 percent when the rate of transfer
is taken as 10 percent.
2. For a given rate of income transfer, increases in expenditures
on various commodities are higher when transfers are made from the
richest 30 percent to the poorest 20 percent households than when
transfers are made from the richest 10 percent (or 20 percent) to the
poorest 10 percent (or 20 percent) households. For example, the increase
in expenditure on edible oils, with 10-percent income transfers as shown
in Appendix Table 3, is 4.47 percent while the corresponding figures in
Appendix Tables 1 and 2 are 3.38 percent and 4.05 percent respectively.
3. The increase in expenditure is greater in cases where income is
allowed to grow. This is quite obvious. Out of the four cases discussed
under this category, consumption expenditure on food and clothing, as
compared to the corresponding expenditure on other items, increases most
under policy 4-B where the distribution of additional income is more in
favour of the poor. These results are given in Appendix Table 4. The
results also show that the demand for items other than food and clothing
would increase relatively more under policy 4-A where incomes of all
households are allowed to increase at the same rate.
The overall effect in the level of consumption under different
policies is shown in Table 2. The pattern of results is almost the same
as discussed above. For given income transfer policies, aggregate
consumption expenditure increases directly with the rate of income
transfer, and out of the first three policies the maximum increase in
consumption takes place when income transfer is from the top 30 percent
to the bottom 20 percent households, in which case it is 1.59 percent
corresponding to the 10-percent rate of income transfer. Also, in cases
in which income is allowed to grow, aggregate consumption increases by
6.78 percent when the distribution of additional income is in favour of
the poor, and by 5.92 percent when the distribution of additional income
is the same as the existing distribution.
The effects of income redistribution on the consumption levels of
households in different income groups are given in Tables 3 and 4. The
results of this exercise show that a 1-percent income transfer from the
top 10 percent to the bottom 10 percent households would decrease the
consumption of the richest 5 percent households by only 0.81 percent,
whereas the consumption of the poorest 5 percent households would
increase by 11.52 percent. At the 10-percent rate of transfer, the
consumption level of the latter group increases by 107.96 percent with
only an 8.2-percent decrease in the consumption of the former. Results
for other policies are also very similar and show that the positive
effects of income redistribution on the poor are stronger than the
negative effects on the rich, thus resulting in a significant increase
in the consumption levels of the former. This is so mainly because of
the fact that the initial consumption level of the poor is very low. In
the case of the distribution of additional income when income is also
allowed to grow, figures in Table 4 show that the poor households would
benefit most under policy B when the consumption of the poorest 5
percent households would increase by 38.36 percent and of the next 5
percent households by 26.05 percent. Increases in consumption levels of
these groups corresponding to equal distribution of additional income
(Case D) are 24.23 percent and 17.49 percent respectively.
Increasing the consumption levels of the poor may be desirable not
only on social but also on economic grounds. There is no dearth of
evidence that the poor in many developing countries are undernourished.
An increase in the consumption levels may well improve the general
health of the workers and hence raise their physical productivity [13,
p. 269]. Galenson and Pyatt's study [5] provides empirical evidence
in support of this argument. While studying the effects of various
determinants of labour productivity they found that of all the variables
included in their model, level of nutrition, as measured by the daily
calories available per head, had the greatest impact on the growth of
output. We can therefore expect that increased consumption by the poor
will have positive effects on labour productivity in Pakistan.
It may be noted that the above results are based on the assumption
of constant relative prices. While there is no reason to believe that
the relative prices will not change after income redistribution, for
small amounts of income transfers changes in the composition of demand
may be so small that their effect on the relative prices may be
negligible. It is only in those cases where substantial amounts are
involved in inter-group income transfers that there may be some
significant change in the relative prices. In the above analysis it is
only when 5 percent or 10 percent of the incomes of the rich are
transferred to the poor that there may be a noticeable change in the
relative prices. The implications of such changes for the present
analysis may be that the numerical magnitudes of the increase in the
demand for certain food items, and the decrease in the demand for
certain non-food items, may be somewhat smaller than the ones reported
in this study. Except for those small differences in the numerical
values, the general results of this study would still be quite valid.
EMPLOYMENT EFFECTS
Since different commodities are produced with different factor
intensities, changes in the composition and level of demand also affect
the level of employment. The employment effects under different income
policies are given in Table 5. These results were computed on the basis
of constant labour/value added ratios which are reported in Appendix
Table 5. We used labour/value added ratios rather than labour/output
ratios as we wanted to capture the effect of changes in demand on the
direct as well as indirect labour requirements. The implicit assumption
in using labour/value added ratio to capture indirect labour
requirements as well is that labour is being employed in the same fixed
proportion at different stages of production of a commodity.
The ratios for wheat and wheat flour, rice and rice flour, other
cereals, pulses, milk and milk products, 'meat, fish, and
poultry', and fruits, and vegetables are based on figures for
employment and the value added in the agriculture sector for the year
1978-79, taken from the Pakistan Economic Survey [16]. The major portion
of miscellaneous items comprises different kinds of services. Therefore,
the labour/value added ratio for the service sector was used for
miscellaneous items. The ratio pertaining to the service sector was also
used for house rent and housing. These ratios are also for the year
1978-79 and are based on the data contained in the Pakistan Economic
Survey [16]. For the remaining commodities, we computed the ratios by
taking the relevant categories from the Census of Manufacturing
Industries 1977-78 [18].
The results in Table 5 show that the level of employment would
increase considerably in all cases of income redistribution. The level
of new employment varies directly with the rate of income transfer. In
the case of redistribution of the existing income, maximum increase in
employment would take place if income is transferred from the richest 30
percent to the poorest 20 percent households, the increase amounting to
31,923 jobs and 259,501 jobs corresponding to 1-percent and 10-percent
rates of transfers, respectively. These results are similar to the
results of other studies for developing countries. Paukert et al. [20]
and Ho [7] in their studies for the Philippines and Taiwan respectively
found that the redistribution of the existing income would have positive
and significant effects on the level of employment.
Labour requirement increases even more when income is allowed to
grow with or without any redistribution taking place. Under policy 4-A,
for example, the demand for almost 793 ,000 new workers is created when
incomes of all households grow at a rate of 6.5 percent, with absolutely
no change in the relative income shares of different groups. If the
distribution of the additional income is in favour of the poor (policy
4-D), under the assumptions of this model approximately 943,000 new jobs
could be expected to arise. These results are in line with Soligo's
findings that the 'direct and indirect' employment effects of
an income distribution policy are stronger in the case where the
redistribution of the additional income is in favour of the poor.
In short, in a country like Pakistan where unemployment, both open
and disguised, is alarmingly high, redistribution of income in favour of
the poor may be expected to have a positive and significant effect on
the level of employment.
SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
In this paper, an attempt has been made to analyse the effects of
changes in the relative shares of disposable income of households in
different income groups on the level and composition of consumption
expenditure, and also on labour utilization in Pakistan. The results of
this study show that the redistribution of the existing income in favour
of the poor will increase the demand for food, clothing and footwear,
and housing, while the demand for personal effects, fuel and lighting,
and miscellaneous goods and services would decrease. Commodities for
which demand would increase most include 'meat, fish, and
poultry', cereals, and edible oils. The positive effects on
consumption are also stronger than the negative effects in all cases,
thus resulting in an increase in aggregate consumption expenditure. The
maximum increase in consumption takes place when income is transferred
from the richest 30 percent to the poorest 20 percent households at a
rate of 10 percent, in the case of redistribution of the existing
income; and when the distribution of the additional income is in favour
of the poor (policy 4-B), in case where income is allowed to grow.
An important feature of the study is the estimation of the impact
of various income redistribution policies on the consumption levels of
households in different income groups. In the case of a 10-percent
income transfer from the top 10 percent to the bottom 10 percent
households, the results of this study show that the consumption
expenditure of the former group would decrease by less than 9 percent,
while of tile latter group it would increase by more than 90 percent.
The cost of increasing the consumption level of the poorest groups in
the society would therefore not be very high compared to the benefits in
terms of welfare improvements and increased productivity.
The results also show that income redistribution, by increasing the
demand for relatively more labour-intensive commodities, would increase
the demand for labour substantially. A 5-percent income transfer from
the top 10 percent to the bottom 10 percent households is expected to
increase the labour demand by 106,259 jobs and if the income transfer is
from the top 30 percent to the bottom 20 percent households the demand
may go up by as many as 145,287 workers. In a developing country like
Pakistan, where unemployment is a serious problem, income redistribution
policies would have the added advantage of easing this problem by
absorbing some of the surplus labour.
In this study we have looked only at the bright side of the
picture. Income redistribution also has a negative aspect. An increase
in total consumption expenditure with constant level of total income
also implies a corresponding decrease in the level of savings. Our
results show that income redistribution may not have a very significant
effect on total consumption expenditure. This means that the
corresponding reduction in personal savings would therefore also be very
small. If there are no changes in business and government savings, we
can say, on the basis of the results of this study, that the economic
costs of increased consumption and employment levels in terms of reduced
savings will not be very high.
The tentative nature of the results of this study would call for a
rather cautious interpretation. There is a need for more work in this
field and the results can be further improved if the analysis is done in
a dynamic framework which takes into account the growth in income over
time and also the consumption and employment effects in the second,
third, and all subsequent rounds. Through the working of the multiplier,
the final increase in both consumption and employment levels would be
much larger than the values reported in this study. The results may also
be improved if we allow the relative prices to vary with changes in the
demand for different commodities after redistribution of income.
Appendix Table 1
Percentage Change in Consumption Expenditure on Different
Commodities after Income Transfer from the Richest 10 percent
to the Poorest 10 percent Households
Rate of Income Transfer
Commodity 1% 2.5% 5% 10%
Wheat and Wheat Flour 0.05 0.11 0.21 0.39
Rice and Rice Flour 0.17 0.41 0.77 1.41
Other Cereals 0.43 1.04 1.98 3.60
Pulses 0.05 0.12 0.23 0.42
Milk and Milk Products 0.28 0.68 1.29 2.34
Edible Oils 0.41 0.98 1.86 3.38
Meat, Fish, and Poultry 0.58 1.40 2.65 4.81
Fruits and Vegetables 0.38 0.92 1.74 3.16
Gur, Sugar, Honey, and Sugar
Preparations 0.34 0.82 1.56 2.84
Tea and Coffee 0.05 0.11 0.21 0.38
Tobacco and Chewing Products 0.34 0.82 1.55 2.82
Other Food Items 0.25 0.59 1.13 2.05
Clothing and Footwear 0.22 0.54 1.02 1.85
Personal Effects -0.03 -0.08 -0.15 -0.28
House Rent and Housing 0.36 0.86 1.64 2.98
Furniture and Fixtures 0.06 0.14 0.27 0.49
Fuel and Lighting -0.59 -1.44 -2.73 -4.96
Miscellaneous -0.21 -0.52 -0.98 -1.78
Appendix Table 2
Percentage Change in Consumption Expenditure after Income Transfer
from the Richest 20 percent to the Poorest 20 percent Households
Commodity Rate of Income Transfer
1% 2.5% 5% 10%
Wheat and Wheat Flour 0.05 0.13 0.25 0.46
Rice and Rice Flour 0.20 0.48 0.91 1.68
Other Cereals 0.50 1.22 2.34 4.31
Pulses 0.06 0.14 0.28 0.51
Milk and Milk Products 0.33 0.80 1.52 2.80
Edible Oils 0.47 1.15 2.21 4.05
Meat, Fish, and Poultry 0.67 1.64 3.14 5.76
Fruits and Vegetables 0.44 1.08 2.06 3.78
Gur, Sugar, Honey, and Sugar
Preparations 0.40 0.97 1.85 3.40
Tea and Coffee 0.05 0.13 0.25 0.45
Tobacco and Chewing Products 0.39 0.96 1.84 3.37
Other Food Items 0.29 0.70 1.34 2.46
Clothing and Footwear 0.26 0.63 1.20 2.21
Personal Effects -0.04 -0.1 -0.18 -0.33
House Rent and Housing 0.42 1.02 1.95 3.57
Furniture and Fixtures 0.07 0.17 0.32 0.59
Fuel and Lighting -0.69 -1.69 -3.24 -5.94
Miscellaneous -0.25 -0.61 -1.16 -2.13
Appendix Table 3
Percentage Change in Consumption Expenditure After Income Transfer
from the Richest 30 percent to the Poorest 20 percent Households
Rate of Income Transfer
Commodity 1% 2.5% 5% 10%
Wheat and Wheat Flour 0.06 0.15 0.29 0.51
Rice and Rice Flour 0.23 0.55 1.04 1.86
Other Cereals 0.58 1.41 2.66 4.75
Pulses 0.07 0.17 0.31 0.56
Milk and Milk Products 0.38 0.92 1.73 3.09
Edible Oils 0.55 1.33 2.50 4.47
Meat, Fish, and Poultry 0.78 1.89 3.56 6.35
Fruits and Vegetables 0.51 1.24 2.33 4.17
Gur, Sugar, Honey, and Sugar
Preparations 0.46 1.11 2.10 3.75
Tea and Coffee 0.06 0.15 0.28 0.50
Tobacco and Chewing Products 0.46 1.10 2.08 3.72
Other Food Items 0.33 0.80 1.52 2.71
Clothing and Footwear 0.30 0.72 1.36 2.44
Personal Effects -0.05 -0.11 -0.21 -0.37
House Rent and Housing 0.48 1.17 2.21 3.94
Furniture and Fixtures 0.08 0.19 0.37 0.65
Fuel and Lighting -0.81 -1.94 -3.67 -6.55
Miscellaneous -0.29 -0.70 -1.31 -2.35
Appendix Table 4
Percentage Change in Consumption Expenditure
with Income Growth
Policies for the Distribution
of Additional Income
Commodity A B C D
Wheat and Wheat Flour 0.74 1.01 0.85 0.93
Rice and Rice Flour 3.40 4.39 3.82 4.09
Other Cereals 4.17 6.66 5.23 5.94
Pulses 1.29 1.59 1.41 1.50
Milk and Milk Products 4.29 5.92 4.98 5.44
Edible Oils 5.78 8.13 6.78 7.45
Meat, Fish, and Poultry 11.13 14.49 12.55 13.50
Fruits and Vegetables 7.21 9.42 8.14 8.77
Gur, Sugar, Honey, and Sugar
Preparations 5.66 7.64 6.50 7.06
Tea and Coffee 2.49 2.76 2.60 2.68
Tobacco and Chewing Products 6.45 8.42 7.28 7.84
Other Food Items 9.00 10.45 9.60 10.01
Clothing and Footwear 5.27 6.56 5.81 6.18
Personal Effects 9.17 9.03 9.09 9.03
House Rent and Housing 12.35 14.47 13.23 13.82
Furniture and Fixtures 2.20 2.56 2.35 2.45
Fuel and Lighting 5.07 1.70 3.61 2.63
Miscellaneous 6.59 5.41 6.06 5.71
Appendix Table 5
Labour/Value Added Ratios for Different Commodities
Commodity Average Daily Employment/
Value Added per Year in
Thousand Rupees
Wheat and Wheat Flour 0.2075
Rice and Rice Flour 0.2075
Other Cereals 0.2075
Pulses 0.2075
Milk and Milk Products 0.2075
Edible Oils 0.0089
Meat, Fish, and Poultry 0.2075
Fruits and Vegetable- 0.2075
Gur, Sugar, Honey, and Sugar Preparations 0.0154
Tea and Coffee 0.0149
Tobacco and Chewing Products 0.0040
Other Food Items 0.0246
Clothing and Footwear 0.0227
Personal Effects 0.0196
House Rent and Housing 0.0391
Furniture and Fixtures 0.0642
Fuel and Lighting 0.0693
Miscellaneous 0.0391
Note: The ratios for wheat and wheat flour, rice and rice flour,
other cereals, pulses, milk and milk products, 'meat, fish and
poultry', and fruits and vegetables are based on figures for
employment and value added in the agriculture sector for the
year 1978-79, taken from the Pakistan Economic Survey [16].
Ratios for the service sector are used for house rent and
housing, and miscellaneous items. These ratios are also for
the year 1978-79 and are based on the data contained in the
Pakistan Economic Survey [16]. For remaining commodities,
the ratios are computed by taking relevant categories from
the Census of Manufacturing Industries 1977-78 [18].
Appendix Table 6
Weights used for the Distribution of Additional Income
Households Distribution in Favour Distribution in Favour
of the Poor of the Rich
(Policy 4-B) (Policy 4-C)
Poorest 5 Percent 0.080 0.020
6-10 Percent 0.075 0.025
11-20 Percent 0.135 0.065
21-30 Percent 0.125 0.075
31-40 Percent 0.115 0.085
41-50 Percent 0.105 0.095
51-60 Percent 0.095 0.105
61-70 Percent 0.085 0.115
71-80 Percent 0.075 0.125
81-90 Percent 0.065 0.135
91-95 Percent 0.025 0.075
Richest 5 Percent 0.020 0.080
REFERENCES
[1.] Box, G. E. P., and D. R. Cox. "An Analysis of
Transformations". Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series
B. 1964. pp. 211-243.
[2.] Cheema, Aftab Abroad. "An Analysis of Income Inequality and Some Macroeconomic Implications of Income Redistribution: A Case
Study of Pakistan". Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of
Cincinnati, Ohio (USA). 1983.
[3.] Chenery, Hollis B., et al. Redistribution with Growth. London:
Oxford University Press. 1974.
[4.] Cline, William R. Potential Effects of Income Redistribution
on Economic Growth--Latin American Cases. New York: Praeger Publishers.
1972.
[5.] Galenson, Walter, and Graham Pyatt. The Quality of Labour and
Economic Development in Certain Countries. Geneva: ILO. 1964.
[6.] Haq, Mahbub ul. The Poverty Curtain. New York: Columbia
University Press. 1976.
[7.] Ho, Yhi-Min. Income Redistribution and its Effect on Factor
and Import Demand in Taiwan: A Simulation Approach. Houston, Texas (USA): Rice University. 1975. (Paper No. 68, Programme of Development
Studies)
[8.] Irfan, M., and Rashid Amjad. "Poverty in Rural
Pakistan". In Azizur Rahman Khan and Eddy Lee (eds.), Poverty in
Asia. Bangkok: International Labour Organization. 1983.
[9.] King, Robert P., and Derek Byerlee. Income Distribution,
Consumption Patterns and Consumption Linkages in Rural Sierra Leone.
East Lansing, Mich. (USA): Michigan State University, Department of
Agriculture Economics. 1977. (African Rural Economy Paper No. 16)
[10.] Koutsoyiannis, A. Theory of Econometrics. 2nd ed. London:
McMillan. 1977.
[11.] Leser, C. E. "Forms of Engel Functions".
Econometrica. October 1963. pp. 694-703.
[12.] Mahmood, Zafar. "Income Inequality in Pakistan: An
Analysis of Existing Evidence". Pakistan Development Review. Vol.
XXIII, Nos. 2&3. Summer-Autumn 1984. pp. 365-376.
[13.] Meier, Gerald M. Leading Issues in Development Economics. New
York: Oxford University Press. 1964.
[14.] Nigris, M. de, A. Coccia and O. Tampieri. "The Impact on
Demand of Changes in Income Distribution". Monthly Bulletin of
Agricultural Economics and Statistics. Vol. 21, No. 3. March 1972.
[15.] Pakistan. Federal Bureau of Statistics. Household Income and
Expenditure Survey, 1979. Karachi. 1983.
[16.] Pakistan. Finance Division. Economic Adviser's Wing.
Pakistan Economic Survey 1980-81. Islamabad. 1981.
[17.] Pakistan. Ministry of Law and Parliamentary Affairs. Zakat
and Ushr Ordinance, 1980. Islamabad. June 1980.
[18.] Pakistan. Ministry of Planning and Development. Statistical
Division. Census of Manufacturing Industries 1977-78. Karachi.
[19.] Pasha, Hafiz A. "Consumption Planning: A Suggested New
Approach". Pakistan Journal of Applied Economics. Vol. 1, No. 1.
Summer 1982. pp. 93-111.
[20.] Paukert, F., et al. "Redistribution of Income, Pattern
of Consumption and Employment--A Case of Philippines". In Karen R.
Polenske and Jiri V. Skolka (eds.), Advances in Input Output Analysis.
Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Publishing Company. 1976.
[21.] Rao, P., and R. Miller. Applied Econometrics. Belmont, Ca.:
Wadsworth. 1971.
[22.] Soligo, Ronald. Factor Intensity of Consumption Patterns,
Income Distribution and Employment Growth in Pakistan. Houston, Texas
(USA): Rice University. 1973. (Paper No. 44, Programme of Development
Studies)
(1) Zakat is a kind of wealth tax paid annually by the
'rich' to the 'poor' at a rate of 2.5 percent. Ushr
is a kind of zakat which is levied on land produce. For details, see
Zakat and Ushr Ordinance, 1980, [17].
(2) See Leser [11], and King and Byerlee [9] for a detailed
discussion of the properties of these functional forms.
(3) A large number of income redistribution alternatives were
possible in this kind of analysis but we intentionally confined ourselves to somewhat extreme cases where transfers take place from the
rich to the poor households. In Pakistan, income transfers of this kind
are already taking place through the policy of zakat and ushr. What is
not known is the actual amount being transferred, and the percentages of
the households involved in those transfers. We therefore decided to use
not only different percentages of households but also different rates of
income transfers. This was also expected to give us some idea about the
sensitivity of our results. We may add here that the objective of this
exercise is not to identify a policy which gives best results in terms
of raising the levels of consumption and employment, but to see the
implications of some policies concerning income transfers from the rich
to the poor.
(4) See, for example, Irfan and Amjad [8] and Mahmood [12].
(5) See Koutsoyiannis [10, pp. 285-292].
(6) In this test, the Sums of Squared Residuals (SSRs) are compared
and the functional form which gives the minimum value is chosen. The
Sums of Squared Residuals are not directly comparable when the
measurement units of the dependent variable are not the same. To remove
this problem of measurement unit, some transformation of the SSR is
required. For a detailed description of the test, see Box and Cox [1].
The test is also discussed in Rao and Miller [21, pp. 107-111].
(7) The significance of variable income elasticity has been
recognized by other authors. Pasha [19], for example, argues that it is
not appropriate to use a functional form which makes income elasticity
constant for all income levels or constrains the change in income
elasticity in one direction as income rises. He specifies a functional
form which allows income elasticity to vary, in any direction, across
income levels. The functional form used in our study also has this
property.
(8) Pasha [19] chooses a particular functional form for a commodity
on the basis of the criteria not explicitly stated in the paper. He uses
three functional forms: (i) in which income elasticity is constant; (ii)
in which elasticity varies linearly with income; and (iii) in which the
relationship between the elasticity and income is quadratic. He
estimates these functions by pooling cross-sectional and time-series
grouped data for the years 1969-70, 1970-71, and 1971-72. Most of the
commodities in his study are not directly comparable with the
commodities in our classification. However, patterns of elasticities
across income groups for some of the similar commodities, like rice and
rice flour, milk and milk products, sugar, and furniture and fixtures,
are the same in the two studies.
AFTAB AHMAD CHEEMA AND MUHAMMAD HUSSAIN MALIK *
* The authors are Research Economists at the Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad. This paper extends and improves their
earlier work on the same subject presented at the First Annual General
Meeting of the Pakistan Society of Development Economists, held at
Islamabad in March 1984 and subsequently published in the Papers and
Proceedings issue (i.e. the Summer-Autumn 1984 issue) of this Review.
The authors are thankful to Anjum Nasim, Sayyid Tahir, Faiz Mohammad, M.
Fahim Khan, and anonymous referees for their helpful comments and
suggestions. They also gratefully acknowledge computational assistance
by Attiya Yasmeen, Azra Alauddin, and Masood Ishfaq Ahmad. The errors of
omission and commission are the sole responsibility of the authors.
Table 1
Parameter Estimates of Consumption Functions based on Ratio
Semi-Log Inverse Functional Form
Independent
Variables
Commodity Intercept Y
Wheat and Wheat Flour 6.5481 0.0613
(1.7130) (1.1738)
Rice and Rice Flour -5.7438 0.0507
(-2.4542) (1.5858)
Other Cereals -2.9349 0.0359
(-3.0761) (2.7544)
Pulses 1.5534 0.0142
(1.3758) (0.9188)
Milk and Milk Products -37.4783 0.4427
(-6.3794) (5.5161)
Edible Oils 5.6365 0.1960
(2.7894) (7.0987)
Meat, Fish, and Poultry -3.4033 0.3700
(-0.9479) (7.5431)
Fruits and Vegetables 5.5827 0.2382
(1.6646) (5.1993)
Gur, Sugar, Honey and Sugar 0.4016 0.2021
Preparations (0.2920) (10.7052)
Tea and Coffee -2.2352 0.0113
(-2.3820) (0.8815)
Tobacco and Chewing -2.3415 0.1166
Products (-1.8273) (6.6585)
Other Food Items 7.6629 0.1467
(4.1192) (5.7737)
Clothing and Footwear -0.6022 0.3114
(-0.2102) (7.9580)
Personal Effects -0.4438 0.0043
(-0.9825) (0.6929)
House Rent and Housing 35.4229 0.5511
(3.4432) (3.9210)
Furniture and Fixtures 6.1596 0.0512
(4.7998) (2.9189)
Fuel and Lighting 0.8083 -0.0817
(0.3203) (-2.3706)
Miscellaneous -6.9387 -0.2910
(-0.3359) (-1.0312)
Independent Variables
[[bar.R]
Commodity Y Ln Y S .sup.2]
Wheat and Wheat Flour -0.0062 11.2881 .9946
(-1.0946) (4.6386)
Rice and Rice Flour -0.0049 1.7006 .9879
(-1.4170) (1.1414)
Other Cereals -0.0039 0.2060 .9732
(-2.7778) (0.3392)
Pulses -0.0013 1.8536 .9896
(-0.7907) (2.5787)
Milk and Milk Products -0.0451 4.9037 .9975
(5.2160) (1.3111)
Edible Oils -0.0202 -3.6429 .9953
(6.8118) (2.8318)
Meat, Fish, and Poultry -0.0361 -10.4346 .9979
(-6.8285) (-4.5609)
Fruits and Vegetables -0.0233 -5.5248 .9959
(-4.7267) (-2.5876)
Gur, Sugar, Honey and Sugar -0.0202 -2.5366 .9990
Preparations (-9.9870) (-2.8965)
Tea and Coffee -0.0008 1.4655 .9936
(-0.6101) (2.4530)
Tobacco and Chewing -0.0114 -1.4659 .9981
Products (6.0368) (-1.7970)
Other Food Items -0.0121 -5.3884 .9991
(4.4402) (-4.5498)
Clothing and Footwear -0.0290 -1.8812 .9993
(-6.8894) (-1.0215)
Personal Effects 0.0002 -1.1699 .9982
(0.2659) (-0.5907)
House Rent and Housing -0.0463 -26.6179 .9976
(-3.0611) (-4.0641)
Furniture and Fixtures -0.0042 3.5721 .9989
(-2.2226) (4.3723)
Fuel and Lighting 0.0113 2.2021 .9956
(3.0461) (1.3707)
Miscellaneous 0.0606 10.7101 .9981
(1.9965) (0.8145)
Note: Values in parentheses are t-ratios of the coefficients
under which they appear.
Table 2
Percentage Change in Aggregate Consumption Expenditure
Rate of Income Transfer
Income Transfer 1% 2.5% 5% 10%
From the Richest 10% to the Poorest
10% Households 0.14 0.35 0.66 1.21
From the Richest 20% to the Poorest
20% Households 0.17 0.41 0.79 1.45
From the Richest 30% to the Poorest
20% Households 0.20 0.47 0.89 1.59
Policies for the Distribution
of Additional Income
A B C D
Percentage Change in Aggregate
Consumption Expenditure with
Income Growth 5.92 6.78 6.28 6.52
Note: For definitions of A, B, C, and D, see page 4.
Table 3
Percentage Changes in Total Consumption Expenditures of Different
Income Groups after Income Transfer from the Rich to the Poor
Income Transfer Policy Households Rate of Income Transfer
1% 2.5% 5% 10%
Poorest 5% 11.52 28.43 55.77 107.96
Transfer of Income from 6-10% 8.30 20.53 40.43 78.69
the Richest 10% to the
Poorest 10% households 91-95% -0.88 -2.21 -4.44 -8.94
Richest 5% -0.81 -2.03 -4.07 -8.21
Poorest 5% 8.32 20.61 40.63 79.19
6-10% 5.99 14.87 29.40 57.57
Transfer of Income from 11-20% 4.84 12.01 23.79 46.70
the Richest 20% to the
Poorest 20% households 81-90% -0.91 -2.28 -4.58 -9.21
91-95% -0.88 -2.21 -4.44 -8.94
Richest 5% -0.81 -2.03 -4.07 -8.21
Poorest 5% 10.58 26.14 51.34 99.57
6-10% 7.62 18.87 37.20 72.53
Transfer of Income from 11-20% 6.15 15.25 30.13 58.91
the Richest 30% to the
Poorest 20% households 71-80% -0.92 -2.31 -4.62 -9.30
81-90% -0.91 -2.28 -4.58 -9.21
91-95% -0.88 -2.21 -4.44 -8.94
Richest 5% -0.81 -2.03 -4.07 -8.21
Table 4
Percentage Changes in Total Consumption Expenditure of Households
in Different Income Groups with Income Growth
Households Policies for the Distribution
of Additional Income
A B C D
Poorest 5 percent 6.54 38.36 9.80 24.03
6-10 percent 6.48 26.05 8.81 17.49
11-20 percent 6.40 19.79 9.23 14.13
21-30 percent 6.32 14.48 8.73 11.61
31-40 percent 6.25 11.19 8.30 9.75
41-50 percent 6.21 9.03 8.18 8.61
51-60 percent 6.17 7.40 8.18 7.79
61-70 percent 6.10 5.61 7.57 6.59
71-80 percent 5.94 3.70 6.15 4.93
81-90 percent 5.87 2.83 5.87 4.35
91-95 percent 5.69 1.51 4.53 3.02
Richest 5 percent 5.20 0.50 1.98 1.24
Table 5
Additional Employment Created under Different Income Policies
Rate of Income Transfer
Income Transfer 1% 2.5% 5% 10%
From the Richest 10% to the 23,140 55,951 106,259 193,028
Poorest 10% Households
From the Richest 20% to the 27,009 63,900 125,600 231,157
Poorest 20% Households
From the Richest 30% to the 31,923 77,015 145,287 259,501
Poorest 20% Households
Policies for the Distribution
of Additional Income
A B C D
Additional Employment 792,817 943,163 859,465 89,881
with Income Growth