Rural Poverty in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan: profiles and policies.
Khan, Mahmood Hasan
I. INTRODUCTION
The Bangladesh--India--Pakistan subcontinent has about one billion
people or one-fifth of the world's population. A majority of the
subcontinent's people live in rural areas and depend directly or
indirectly on agriculture and related pursuits. The highly
differentiated rural population includes a large proportion of the poor
in the throe countries. Their differentiated structure is based on (a)
control of land through right of ownership and usufruct, and (b)
employment opportunities for the labour power and its wages. Absolute
poverty afflicts nearly 60 percent of the rural population in
Bangladesh, 40 percent in India and 35 percent in Pakistan. The major
causes of rural poverty are (a) landlessness and (b) lack of adequate
employment (including low real wages) in or outside agriculture. Both
these factors are responsible for keeping the poor consigned to low
"entitlements" to income and commodities. The growth of the
economy in general, and of agriculture in particular, has not produced
the "trickle-down" effects large enough to counter the basic
causes of persistent and high levels of rural poverty.
One of the serious problems in comparing the three countries is
that generalizations or statements about each of them do not have the
same meaning. There is regional diversity in rural India, and the same
is true, but to a lesser extent, of Pakistan. Bangladesh has far less
disparity between its rural areas. The major economic indicators for the
three countries are given in Table 1. India's economy is the
largest, the most diversified and industrially advanced. Pakistan has,
however, the highest income per capita. As compared with Bangladesh,
Pakistan is more urbanized and less dependent on agriculture. Bangladesh
is most heavily dependent on agriculture; and is the least urbanized of
the three countries. Pakistan's economic growth has been the most
impressive, including the growth of its agriculture. All three economies
have done better in the mid-1970s to mid-1980s than they did during the
60s. Bangladesh has not kept pace with the other two in expanding per
capita output of agriculture in general and of food in particular. But
all three countries have apparently become "self-sufficient"
in staple grains of wheat and rice. A word of warning is in order here.
The state of agriculture in all three of them remains fragile. Technical
advance has not fully overcome the major constraints on agricultural
growth imposed by Nature. What is even more important is that higher
supplies of food, does not mean that it gets distributed proportionately across regions and income groups or classes. Distribution of food
depends on "entitlements", which in turn are determined by the
endowments of income earning assets, wage employment, and prices.
External economic relations, given in Table 2, have been less
important to India's growth than to either Bangladesh or Pakistan.
Pakistan's economy is the most "open" of the three to
trade, and its current account deficit has also been the largest. The
exports of the three countries have grown more rapidly in the second
decade than in the first; and imports have also grown faster in the same
period. Capital inflow through workers remittances has been as high as
the export earnings in Pakistan, but it accounts for less than one-half
in Bangladesh and just over one-quarter in India. India has the lowest
burden of external debt. Bangladesh has the highest burden of total debt
which constitutes nearly 40 percent of its GNP. Pakistan's external
debt liability is also very large: its total debt is 30 percent of the
GNP and its service payments take up over 27 percent of its export
earnings.
The differences in per capita income and growth of the economy are
not altogether consistent with the differences in the "quality of
life" in the three countries (see Table 3). An average Pakistani is
better off than his counterparts in India and Bangladesh: his income is
higher and he consumes more calories and proteins every day. However, an
average Indian, male or female, expects to live a little longer. Fewer
infants and children die in India than in Pakistan. India also has a
greater supply of physicians and nurses per person. Bangladesh is not
far behind Pakistan on life expectancy, infant and child death rates. It
has, however, fewer physicians and nurses per person than Pakistan. It
is interesting to note that Pakistan has the highest population growth
rate than India and Bangladesh, mainly due to higher birth rates. The
latter countries have shown a distinct slowdown in birth rates, which is
not as clearly seen in Pakistan. Pakistan's performance on literacy
and education has been the least impressive while both India and
Bangladesh have higher literacy rates as well as enrolments in primary
and secondary schools.
II. RURAL POVERTY PROFILES
Poverty may not always be transparent, but it blights the lives of
millions in most underdeveloped countries. No matter how poverty is
defined, it always implies a state of deprivation and dispossession. The
individual's judgement on poverty depends on (a) how deprived or
dispossessed he feels in some absolute measure and (b) his own
predicament relative to others in the society. From a society's
point of view, the concept of absolute poverty implies existence of some
socially acceptable norm for subsistence or survival. But most societies
have also made commitments to alleviate relative poverty by focusing on
income'(or asset) redistribution. The alleviation of poverty is the
dominant rhetoric in the Third World.
While normative judgement of individuals and households may differ
widely, poverty is best described in terms of the following interrelated aspects:
(a) lack of income-earning assets and flow of income;
(b) vulnerability to contingencies of sickness, debt, crop
failures, etc.; and
(c) powerlessness to influence the economic and social environment.
Viewed in this way, a large proportion of rural households and
individuals in most underdeveloped countries are indeed poor.
A comparative study of rural poverty in Bangladesh, India and
Pakistan raises many issues of what is meant by poverty and how it can
(or should) be measured. At one level the concept of poverty is simple
enough: it is a state of deprivation and dispossession. However, it does
not fully answer the main questions. For one thing, the relative and
absolute concepts are different measures of poverty, even though they
are closely associated with inequality of-income distribution. Relative
poverty arises directly from the inequality in income distribution,
irrespective of the level of income or the state of deprivation of those
at the bottom end of the income scale. Absolute poverty, on the other
hand, represents a societal view of deprivation through some physical
manifestation of consumption, nutrition, etc. Absolute poverty, however
measured, will decline if, and only if, income inequality falls in a way
in which (a) the value of the Gini coefficient is lower and (b) the new
distribution (Lorenz) curve lies entirely above the old one. If the mean
income of distribution rises, without any change in the inequality
measure, absolute poverty falls; which means there is an inverse
relationship between the two. However, as the measure of inequality
(Gini coefficient) is independent of the mean income, a change in the
latter does not necessarily reflect a change in relative poverty. It is,
therefore, possible that changes in relative poverty may not have a
significant impact on absolute poverty. But it is also possible that
absolute poverty may be greatly alleviated by adjustments in the
existing inequalities. The focus of this paper is on absolute poverty in
rural areas of Bangladesh, India and Pakistan.
What is the best measure of absolute poverty? There is none known
so far. Most of the measures are related to the level of income
(purchasing power) necessary to provide a "minimum"
consumption of (a) calories from a basket of food commodities, or (b)
"basic needs", including food, shelter and clothing. The first
measure has been used more extensively than the second in establishing a
"poverty line" by carrying out a headcount of the poor in
rural and urban areas. Social scientists, particularly the economists,
have developed a substantial body of literature on both the methodology
and measurement of absolute poverty in underdeveloped countries. Most
studies of absolute poverty in India, as in other underdeveloped
countries, have so far used the method of headcount below the poverty
line which is based on consumption of calories or, in other words nutritional intake.
The headcount approach has serious limitations for the comparative
study of poverty between countries and over time in the same country.
For one thing, nutritional intake on the average means little in light
of the variations required for different age and working groups. Also,
various baskets, each perhaps requiring a different purchasing power,
can produce the same level of nutrition. For this reason alone, poverty
lines within the same country can vary at the same time and over time.
It makes comparisons very difficult. Then there is the problem of
distribution of the poor below the poverty line. How close are they on
each side will determine the impact of incremental incomes or
consumption on the alleviation of poverty. These distributions are not
easy to estimate even in cross-section studies; they are even more
difficult to study through time-series data. In the end what matters is
the identification of the poor and the severity of their poverty for
designing public policy. As long as these limitations are kept in mind
in interpreting the measured variables, the poverty line studies can
yield meaningful results for research and policy making.
The headcount (given in Table 4) of the rural poor in Bangladesh,
India and Pakistan shows that (a) a greater proportion of the rural
population is poor m Bangladesh than in India and Pakistan, and that
this proportion has been rising; (b) the proportion of the rural poor in
India remained around 45 to 50 percent during the 1960s and 1970s, but
this proportion has fallen to around 40 percent in the early 1980s; and
(c) rural poverty first rose in Pakistan in the 1960s, but had fallen
since to less than 40 percent in 1979. Assuming that the proportion of
the poor in the rural populations of Bangladesh, India and Pakistan have
fallen to 50, 35 and 30 percent, and using population estimates of 1985,
there were 255 million absolutely poor people in the rural areas of the
three countries, making up 36 percent of their rural populations and 27
percent of their total populations. It is still more difficult to
identify who these poor are. But the rural poor in these countries may
be identified better by looking closely at the agrarian structures in
Bangladesh, India and Pakistan.
As the data in Table 5 show, small owners--hose owning 1 hectare in
Bangladesh and 2 hectare in India and Pakistan--form the overwhelming
majority (three-quarters in Bangladesh and India and two-thirds in
Pakistan), but they own one-third in Bangladesh, one-quarter in India
and one-fifth in Pakistan. Their numbers and areas have both increased.
The very large owners (4 hectare for Bangladesh, 6 hectare for India and
10 hectare for Pakistan) are 3 to 6 percent of all owners, but claim
one-quarter in Bangladesh, 40 percent in India and 44 percent in
Pakistan. Their proportion has fallen in numbers and area. Most of the
farms operated are also small in the three countries (Table 6): one-half
are less than 1 hectare in Bangladesh, three-quarters in India, but
one-third in Pakistan. They have one-fifth area in Bangladesh,
one-quarter in India, but just over one-twentieth in Pakistan. Large
farms-owning 3 hectare in Bangladesh, 10 hectare in India and
Pakistan--are less than one-tenth in Bangladesh, 2 percent in India and
one-tenth in Pakistan. They possess one-third area in Bangladesh,
one-quarter in India, and nearly one-half in Pakistan.
Landownership is far more concentrated than access to land through
use. Landownership is highly concentrated in both India and Pakistan,
but not as much in Bangladesh. Land use concentration (shown in Table 7)
is also the lowest in Bangladesh, but it is the highest in India. It has
gone down substantially in Bangladesh, slightly in India, and has
somewhat gone up in Pakistan. Rural income is the least concentrated in
Pakistan; it went down in the 1960s, but went up in the 1970s. The
reverse seems to have happened in India. In Bangladesh, it did not
change much in the 1960s, but went up in the 1970s. It appears that
income concentration goes down in the period of high growth and remains
stationary or goes up in the stagnant or slow growth period!
Landlessness is difficult to define because of conceptual and data
problems. Three alternative definitions of landlessness are given below:
(a) who own no land,
(b) who operate no land, and
(c) whose major source of income is wage employment, even when they
own or operate some land.
There is considerable overlapping between these categories, which
creates confusion about the incidence of landlessness. The best way
would be to construct the following four-way classification:
Owning Land Not Owning Land
Operating Land A: O-O C: Pure Tenants
Not Operating Land B: Landlords D: Pure Landless
There are some estimates of the landless, based on landownership
and land use (Table 8). In terms of land ownership, landless households
constitute 62 percent in Bangladesh, 45 percent in India, and 58 percent
in Pakistan. They include even those households which have less than 0.4
hectare of land. The pure landless households were 29 percent in
Bangladesh and 26 percent each in India and Pakistan. By land use, or on
the basis of access to the use of land, landless households constituted
29 percent in Bangladesh, 31 percent in India, and 22 percent in
Pakistan. The pure landless (with no access to land) were 21 percent in
Bangladesh, 16 percent in India and 20 percent in Pakistan. There is a
large number of the marginal and small cultivators which has less than
2.0 hectare to cultivate; they are 30 percent in Bangladesh, 35 percent
in India, and only 12 percent in Pakistan. Pakistan has a much higher
percentage (66 percent) of households with access to land of over 2
hectare.
Poverty in rural areas may not be affected much by ensuring access
to land if (a) land is plentiful or distributed equitably through
communal or tribal rights, and (b) reliance on non-farming occupations
is high and rising. Poverty is also not reduced by holding bad quality
land, for instance in semi-arid regions. A little land can avoid poverty
if and only if land has a high return per hectare. Land reduces the risk
of poverty because it can be mortgaged in emergency. However,
landlessness alone is not important for analysing poverty. It should be
seen together with (a) the conditions of cultivation of land by those
who operate it (size of holding, productivity of land, and tenure), and
(b) condition of wage employment for those who depend on wages alone for
household incomes. A majority of the rural poor come from households
which are completely landless (agricultural labourers) and which have
some access to land as small owner-operators and tenants. They all have
to sell a part of the household labour to earn their incomes.
Labour-force data are even scarce and of poor quality, particularly
in Pakistan. But they show (Table 9) that the proportion and absolute
number of households dependent primarily on wages are increasing, or of
those dependent mainly on income from land are declining in numbers.
Nearly one-quarter of the rural populations of Bangladesh and Pakistan
are in the labour force. Mainly because of the higher female
participation rate, a much higher proportion of India's rural
population participates in work than in Pakistan or Bangladesh. This is
shown below.
Bangladesh India Pakistan
(%) (%) (%)
working on their own farms 50 25 33
helping on farms 25 23 33
agricultural labourers 25 39 10
outside agriculture - 13 25
Wage employment is becoming important in all three countries. But
the total dependence on wages is not increasing. One-tied of the rural
households in India depend on wage employment (of which 50 percent are
agricultural labourers and 50 percent are marginal and small farmers).
Around 40 percent of the rural households in Bangladesh are labourers,
of which three-quarters depend mainly on wage labour. Pakistani data do
not permit this breakdown.
Rural (real) wages are an indicator of the incomes of the poor
rural households. They depend on (a) agricultural growth, (b) employment
prospects within and outside agriculture, (c) rural-urban migration, and
(d) public-sector policy on minimum wages, technology, etc. The real
rural (agricultural) wage has remained stationary and has even fallen in
Bangladesh, has risen somewhat in India, and has increased impressively
in Pakistan (Table 10). The condition of the rural poor households also
depend on (a) period of gainful employment, and (b) demographic
composition of the household.
Rural poverty is persistent among certain groups--namely, among the
landless agricultural labourers (including the low-caste and tribals),
and the marginal (small) owner-operators and tenants. They depend
increasingly on wages and employment. Rural populations are still
increasing in absolute numbers, but cultivated areas are not likely to
increase. Agricultural growth has not been stable or evenly distributed
by regions or income groups. The prospects of finding jobs outside
agriculture have not become brighter either.
III. POLICIES FOR ALLEVIATION OF RURAL POVERTY
Poverty alleviation means raising the entitlements of the rural
poor. A weak asset base, with increasing or even stationary state of
landlessness (high concentration of land, population growth, and limited
area), makes the poor vulnerable in the labour and commodity market,
Landlessness can be countered by:
(a) improving terms of trade;
(b) increasing land productivity;
(c) increasing employment opportunities and high real wage rates;
and
(d) the growth of non-farm activities in the rural and urban areas.
However, these forces, left to themselves, do not work well. In
none of these countries has there been a long and sustained period of
rapid economic growth, particularly in agriculture. There is also
evidence that the rural poor have not been the major beneficiaries of
agricultural growth, because they were unable to participate in this
process. Growth policies have not necessarily been consistent with the
goal of alleviating poverty. National resources given to the development
of agriculture and social sectors in the five-year plans have not been
focused on the target groups (Table 11). The growth experience in
Bangladesh, India and Pakistan shows that poverty has to be attacked
directly by (a) distributing more equally the income generating assets
(land and non-land assets) and (b) expanding wage employment and
creating human capital.
These strategies for alleviating rural poverty can be classified as
follows:
Group I Group II
Income Generation Through Creation Income Generation Through Guarantee
or Redistribution of Assets of Employment, Wages, Consumption
1. Land Reform Measures 1. Employment Guarantee
(a) land redistribution (a) food for work
(b) new tenancy contracts (b) minimum wage/work guarantee
(c) land consolidation
2. Non-land Assets: Capital 2. Food Distribution
(a) livestock/other enterprises (a) rationing system
(b) labour training for skills (b) school/farm meals
3. Public Infrastructure for Small 3. Rural Industrialization
Farmers/Poor Regions (a) non-farm employment
(a) water/irrigation system (b) labour-intensive technology
(b) subsidy on credit/inputs
(c) research/extension
(d) price support/procurement.
Land Reform Measures
The land reforms in all three countries have been generally
disappointing. Two basic reasons stand out for this; one is the
inadequate political support for land redistribution and new tenancy contracts, and the second is the poor implementation through the
existing bureaucracy without the participation of the prospective
beneficiaries. The states of Kerala and West Bengal in India have been
the only exceptions, because the rural poor there were allowed to
organize themselves. In addition, political and infrastructural support
was provided to help them to gain their claims.
Land redistribution in Bangladesh has been the least impressive,
although the first tenancy laws were enacted in the early 1950s. In
fact, land ceilings have been changed twice since then: they were raised
in 1961, and lowered again in 1972. The total amount of land resumed in
35 years is 300,000 hectare, of which only 137,000 hectare have been
distributed. The government toyed with the idea of redistributing land
again in 1983, but nothing has been done so far. However, it has
legislated long-term tenancy rights to sharecroppers after 5 years of
tenancy and has introduced a minimum rural wage. The two most important
impediments to land redistribution in Bangladesh are; first, there is
not enough land, and second the data on rights of landownership and
tenancy are very poor. No serious attempt has been made to register the
legal claims. This has added to the problems of tenant eviction and
costly litigation.
In India, the land ceiling laws were first enacted in the 1950s,
and revised in the early 1970s. A majority of the Indian states now have
laws about ceilings on agricultural land holdings. However, the surplus
area declared to date amounts to 2.97 million hectares or less than 2
percent of the total cultivated area. Of this area, only 1.8 million
hectares have been redistributed. The total number of beneficiaries are
reported to be 3.3 million. It has been estimated that even with the
present land ceilings, there should be nearly 6 million hectares
available for redistribution. Tenancy contracts have not been revised in
most states, with the consequence that tenants remain at the mercy of
the landlords. The states of Kerala and West Bengal have pursued better
the goals of land redistribution and revision of tenancy contracts. The
land reform measures there have made a considerable impact on the lives
of millions of the landless and near-landless. The follow-up support
system to new landowners has been an important part of the land reform
programme there.
The land reform measures in Pakistan have so far resulted in the
redistribution of about 1.4 million hectare to about 256,000
beneficiaries. The land ceilings in Pakistan are the most generous.
Hence the potential for land redistribution to the landless. A 25
hectare ceiling on land holdings can release 3 million hectare for
redistribution. While the tenancy laws have removed the most blatant
excesses against the sharecroppers, their enforcement is greatly
hampered by the lack of political support given to the tenants.
There are several common features of the existing policies on land
redistribution and revision of tenancy contracts in the three countries:
(a) The data base for titles of ownership and tenancy rights is at
best inadequate to establish individual claims.
(b) Land ceilings have remained high because of poor legislative
action and evasion, with the exception of Bangladesh where there is
perhaps little land to redistribute.
(c) The poorest quality of land has often been surrendered and
transferred.
(d) The beneficiaries, especially the marginal owners and tenants
have been small and the landless labourers have been excluded.
(e) Tenancy rights have not been enforced and evictions of tenants
remains a serious problem.
(f) Minimum wage laws exist only in name, except in the Food for
Work Programme (FFWP) in some states of India and in Bangladesh.
(g) The follow-up or support for the new landowners in terms of
specific inputs and credit remains weak and uncertain.
(h) Political support for peasant organizations is not forthcoming,
and the existing bureaucracy is not suited to deliver the needed
support.
Distribution of Non-land Assets and Creation of Skills
The idea of extending loans to the landless poor for non-land
assets to generate new income was first experimented in the state of
Rajasthan in India. The purpose of the antyodaya programme in Rajasthan
was to lift the poor above the poverty line by providing them loans to
buy income-generating assets other than land. This programme had been
preceded by various rural-development programmes in the sub-continent,
starting from the community development and village-aid programmes in
the 1950s. However, they did not aim at alleviating the problem of
poverty for specific groups or regions. The Integrated Rural Development
Programme (IRDP) in the early to mid-1970s was in the tradition of
providing social and physical infrastructure to rural areas with
emphasis on agricultural development through new technology, etc. The
experience in India and Pakistan was that the IRDPs there strengthened
the economic and social positions of the rural elite and transferred
public resources to a bureaucracy which was not capable of delivering
inputs and services to the majority of the rural population. Inadequate
accountability and low participation of the poor in IRDP made the
programme further wasteful through mismanagement and corruption.
The IRDP in India was remodelled in 1979 in the light of the
antyodaya experiment of Rajasthan. It was initiated in less than
one-half of the blocks, and was then extended to the entire country. The
IRDP is funded by the central and state governments on a 50:50 basis. It
uses a mixture of subsidy (25 to 50 percent) from the state and
low-interest loans from the banking system. The aim of the programme is
to raise the income of the rural poor above the poverty line on a
permanent basis. It is basically a scheme to provide incremental income
through selfemployment. The Training of Youth for Self-Employment
(TRYSEM), which is an integral part of IRDP, is designed to give
specific training to the youths (18 to 35 years) from the landless poor
households to be used for self-employment in or around the village. The
village panchayats, Block Development Officers (BDOs), and the District
Rural Development Agency (DRDA) are expected to play an important role
in formulating and executing each IRDP project.
The IRDP experience in India has several interesting features. The
programme was allocated Rs 45 billion during the Sixth Plan. Several
studies have been done on its impact and the lessons learnt about its
implementation. The estimates are that 16.5 million families benefited
from the programme; investment per household went up from Rs 1,642 to Rs
3,344 per household; 17 percent of the target families crossed the
poverty line and 51 percent improved their income levels. The TRYSEM
programme trained about 1 million youth. These studies have also
revealed some of the major weaknesses of the programme: only about 3
percent of the poor rural households were able to cross the poverty line
and that too temporarily, because a long-term impact on their income
would have required at least Rs 9,000 per household; there were
significant "leakages" from the system: about 20 percent of
the beneficiaries were wrongly identified as poor; projects and
activities were not always well chosen and the infrastructural support
to make them viable was poor, etc. Funds were equally distributed to the
blocks but without any concern about their actual needs. The TRYSEM
programme has also been criticised because a high percentage of the
trained youth did not go for self-employment; but looked for jobs in or
out of their villages. One of the most serious problems has been the
implementation of these programmes within the existing bureaucracy,
particularly in those areas in which the representative panchayats are
either non-existent or weak.
The IRDP in Bangladesh is focused on the development of village
infrastructure for agricultural development, based on a rural works
programme within the existing two-tier system of cooperatives in the
Thanas. Its foundation dates back to the Rural Works Programme of the
1960s. The size of the programme has shrunk significantly since the
mid-1970s due to inadequate resources. Some of these resources have been
chanelled into the Food for Work Programme (FWP) to generate employment
for the landless agricultural workers. As an anti-poverty programme, the
Grameen (rural) bank scheme was introduced in 1979 in a small number of
Thanas to extend low-interest loans to the landless poor for buying
non-land assets (livestock, etc.). The borrowers are required to repay
these loans in weekly instalments and contribute to a common fund to be
used in emergency for the poor in the village. The landless are defined
as those with less than 0.25 hectare. Over 50 percent of the borrowers
are females. The average size of loan was Tk. 3,300. The total number of
beneficiaries in 1980-85 was 100,000, and the project covered less than
3 percent of the villages. It has been estimated that the incomes of
beneficiaries increased by 30 percent and their saving levels rose to 10
percent.
The experience of the Grameen banks has already brought to light
some of their weaknesses and strengths. For example, the landless
agricultural workers were excluded from this project, with benefits
flowing to those with some land. Many of the activities or products
could disappear without replacement. A cow or a flock of poultry could
die or be sold in emergency. Similarly, a sewing machine could be sold.
In view of the small numbers and limited investment, it is not clear if
the impact on the individual household income was significant or
lasting. Serious doubts have also been expressed about the impact of
these ventures on labour productivity. One of the advantages of the
project has been its ability to attract the poor at the village level
and introduce them to the idea of self-employment. This is particularly
important for females in many households. The problem of leakages has
not been very severe because the project relies on decentralized decision-making, in which villagers can play an important role in the
local setting.
In Pakistan, there has been virtually no such programme to enable
the landless poor in rural areas to own non-land assets for generating
new or supplemental incomes. As part of its "Islamization"
policy, the government has introduced two levies on Muslims: zakat (since 1980) as 2.5 percent of the wealth during a year, and ushr (since
1983) as 5 to 10 percent of the value of output of agriculture (crops
and livestock products) during each season. The revenue from zakat and
ushr has been transferred to the "eligible" poor. (It cannot
be spent for any activity other than the welfare of the poor.) Zakat
councils have been set up at each administrative level, with
representation from the elected council members at the local level in
rural and urban areas, to distribute the revenues from zakat and ushr
levies. The decisions about the amounts to be transferred to individual
families or to welfare institutions are usually left to the local
councils in each province and district.
Zakat collections during 1980-86 were Rs 6.2 billion, out of which
Rs 3.9 billion were distributed to 7.9 million persons, representing a
transfer of Rs 498 per beneficiary. These payments have been given as
cash grants to the destitute families; as educational scholarships to
the children of poor families; as grants to religious schools and to
welfare trusts for the health care of the poor. There are no details
given about the breakdown of the beneficiaries by the urban and rural
poor. A rough estimate is that about 50 percent of the rural poor have
benefited at least once from one of these grants. In view of the nature
and size of the transfer payment, it is doubtful if it can make a big
impact on the resource availability of the rural poor, except in those
families in which a scholarship grant is provided for the education or
training of a number of family members or over a number of years. The
subsistence grants on a regular basis can only alleviate the problem of
destitution for a large number of families. The structure of zakat
councils is reasonably decentralized, which helps in reaching the poor
without excessive bureaucratic red-tape and corruption. However, the
Central and Provincial Zakat Councils retain a significant portion of
the total revenue from zakat and ushr.
A "Five Point" programme was launched in Pakistan for
four years from 1986. One of the major goals of this programme is to
improve the conditions of life for the poor in rural areas. Under it,
nearly Rs 118 billion have been allocated to activities ranging from
rural social and physical infrastructure (electrification, health
centres, schools, adult literacy, water supply, and roads) to land for
housing (a 7 marla plot for each family without shelter). In the first
year, 1986-87, it has spent Rs 23 billion or nearly one-half of the
annual development plan. One of the problems in assessing the impact of
this programme is that there is no independent evaluation of its
achievements so far. The only source of information is the Planning
Commission. Given the existing administrative and political structure in
the country, it is hard to say that the Five Point Programme would
achieve most or any of its lofty goals by 1990. Similar programmes in
other countries have brought great disappointments.
Income Generation through Employment/Food Guarantee Programmes
The landless poor have become increasingly dependent on wage
income, derived from work in or outside agriculture. This has also
become an important source of income for sharecropping tenants and
marginal owners, because of their low income levels and the available
slack time during the crop season. In all three countries, a rural works
programme was used in the 1960s to create employment for agricultural
labourers and poor cultivators and build rural infrastructure at the
village level. Wages were paid in cash or kind under the PL-480 food aid
programme from the U.S. The experience in some Thanas of what East
Pakistan (now Bangladesh) was particularly impressive, although it did
not extend to many parts of the country.
In both Bangladesh and India the rural works programme was
converted into a Food-for-Work Programme (FFWP) in the mid-1970s. The
rural-works programme in Pakistan was part of the IRDP in the early
1970s, but it was abandoned in the late 1970s. The FFWP in Bangladesh
has been a major source of using the food aid (particularly wheat) for
providing jobs to the landless poor in rural areas. However, this is not
an employment guarantee programme. It provides only part-time
employment. It created employment for 110 million mandays. Not more than
3 percent of the unemployed labour time was used in 1984-1985. Almost
three-quarters of the labourers were from the landless or near-landless
households. The minimum wage, paid mostly in kind, was 3 kgs. of wheat
per day.
Several issues have been raised about the impact of FFWP in
Bangladesh. First, it does not guarantee job or food to anyone who is
landless and poor. Second, the minimum wage has not always been paid to
workers. Third, a large proportion of the workers have sold their food
for cash, so their consumption of food may not have gone up by much. A
fourth problem is the disproportionate representation of workers from
the landowning households, who give up their own farm work to earn the
minimum wage in kind and then convert it into cash. Finally, the quality
of infrastructure such as water channels, culverts, roads, etc., built
by these workers has not been well controlled both in terms of design
and life.
India's FFWP was restructured in 1980 as National Rural
Employment Programme (NREP). The central and state governments pool
their resources (Rs 18 billion during 1980-1985) to provide employment
to landless workers. Wages are paid in cash and kind (grain). Workers
build rural infrastructure, e.g. social forestry, village tanks, roads,
schools, land reclamation, and watercourse improvement. The NREP was
supplemented in 1983 by a new rural employment programme, called the
Rural Landless Employment Guarantee Programme (RLEGP). It was designed
to guarantee work for 100 days in the year to at least one member in
each household of the landless labourers. The RLEGP was started along
the lines of the Employment Guarantee Scheme (EGS), which had been
functioning in the state of Maharashtra since 1974.
The estimates are that the NREP and RLEGP in India created 2,035
million mandays of employment during 1980-1985; they provided an average
daily employment of 1.1 million mandays or 7 percent of the estimated
unemployed mandays in rural areas. The planners had estimated that there
were 15.36 million daily workers looking for work in 1980. The daily
wage rate increased from Rs 5.63 to Rs 8.92 during 1981-1985. The NREP
has provided short-term employment to landless workers, on average 50-55
days in the year. The RLEGP did not get the required resources--it was
given Rs 4 billion for two years--to fulfil its mandate. The Seventh
Five-Year Plan proposed to increase funding to reach the goals of the
NREP and the RLEGP. One of the serious problems in designing and
implementing these programmes has been the lack of an effective
political and bureaucratic framework which would guarantee the
participation of the prospective beneficiaries and ensure the delivery
of quality infrastructure to rural areas.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
The problem of rural poverty in the three countries remains
intractable mainly because it has not been confronted by policies with
the biggest impact on the target groups; and because they have relied on
"soft" policy options. The agricultural sectors in these
countries have not been dynamic enough to sustain the growth process.
What is even more disturbing is that agricultural growth has not
provided new jobs and incomes to the landless poor. This sorry state of
affairs is partly reflection of the institutional impediments and partly
a result of policies that have been contradictory. Industrial growth has
not touched many of the rural communities; and the relative abundance of
labour in these countries has not been used to advantage in selecting
the industries which have the biggest impact on growth in both rural and
urban areas. A direct attack on poverty requires that income earning
opportunities are provided to the rural poor, by making available assets
like land and human capital and through providing productive employment
in and out of agriculture. The efforts made so far in the three
countries do not represent an effective strategy to alleviate rural
poverty.
Comments on "Rural Poverty in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan:
Profiles and Policies"
Professor Mahmood Hasan Khan has conditioned us through the years
to expect from his writings penetrating and statistically
well-documented analyses of rural poverty. He has once again delivered
on our expectations--and he has delivered his lecture with great verve
and least statistical indiscretion. In an area where Professor Khan has
not ventured before, the comparative analysis of the three countries of
the sub-continent, he has collected a huge amount of data in comparing
poverty, landlessness, external economic relations, the openness of the
economy, the quality of life and so on. A number of stories emerge from
studying the differences among the three countries on various
performance indicators. These have been discussed by the author and some
are quite convincing. It is the feeling of this reviewer, however, that
the big story is not in the differences in individual performance
indicators but in the similarities of the basic development outcomes. If
this is correct, it becomes a puzzle which is left unanswered by the
paper.
Absolute poverty is difficult to define and to measure on a
comparable basis. Professor Khan makes a valiant effort by putting
disparate sources together. He finds poverty as a percent of rural
population at 60, 40 and 35--or alternatively 50, 35 and 30--for
Bangladesh, India and Pakistan, respectively. This represents about 255
million people, or 27 percent of the total population. With the possible
exception Of Bangladesh, the outcome is rather close for the two
countries. In a paper, that I presented in another session of this
meeting, I have found poverty levels even closer together, at 22, 27 and
23 percent of the total population, for Bangladesh, India and Pakistan.
The real difference on the poverty score is somewhere else: there has
been no famine in Pakistan. Still, when it comes to broader guages of
the quality of life, Pakistan is behind India (e.g., life expectency,
child mortality, number of physicians and nurses) and occasionally
behind Bangladesh (education, both male and especially female).
Landlessness and near-landlessness (less than 0.4 hectares),
whether defined in terms of ownership or operational holding, is roughly
comparable in the three countries--between 25 and 30 percent for
operation and double that for ownership. Where the three contestants
seem to differentiate themselves is the rate of increase in rural real
wages. With an index of 100 in 1975, real agricultural wages increased
by 0, 33 and 86 percent by 1984, respectively, for Bangladesh, India and
Pakistan. The substantial wage increase in Pakistan may be misleading as
the market wage rate applies to members of the labour force, that is,
those employed or looking for work. The labour force in Pakistan is a
highly selective concept. According to the Labour Force Survey
(1985-86), the participation rate for males is 50 percent but that of
females is 6 percent (as opposed to about 30 percent for other LDCs).
That women do not participate in the labour force does not necessarily
mean that they do not work. The Agricultural Census (1980), for example,
reported that women were 42 percent of the 22.8 million economically
active persons in agriculture. This implies a female participation rate
of 74 percent. Women are omitted from the labour force reporting simply
because most of them (96 percent) work on their own holdings. Moreover,
since these working women could not accept paid employment outside their
own farms, they have hardly benefited from the real wages increase. In
such a tightly segmented labour market, the only way to increase the
real incomes of those in hidden unemployment is to increase the
productivity of smallholders in agriculture.
In my opinion, the big story of the tripartite comparison lies in
the similarity of development outcomes which, if normalized by initial
conditions, indicate vastly dissimilar economic performances. Initial
endowments, especially in agricultural infrastructure, since the time of
the Partition and more recently, have been unequal in the three
countries. Population pressure on resources and ecological systems have
been quite different. Economic orientation and socio-political systems
have also differed. The similarity of development outcomes in the light
of these differences in initial conditions is counterintuitive.
Moreover, it brings into question the economic performance of Pakistan
first, and of India next, in comparison to that of Bangladesh.
It seems to me that this is the real story which is hidden in
Professor Khan's comparisons.
Pan A. Yotopoulos
Stanford University, U.S.A.
Comments on "Rural Poverty in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan:
Profiles and Policies"
Professor Mahmood Hasan Khan is well aware of the methodological
issues involved in the measurement of poverty and in the comparison of
such estimates across regions and overtime. However, at the expense of
incurring his wrath, I would like to reiterate a note of caution. The
problem that Professor Khan has tackled is indeed extremely complex and
difficult. It is as difficult to conceptualize as it is to measure. The
concept is multi-dimensional. It depends in part on the absolute level
of income and consumption and in part on the relative distribution of
income, wealth, power and social status. It depends, in part, on the
ease with which it is possible to move from one occupation or social
category to another. The concept has stock and flow elements, absolute
and relative dimensions and static and dynamic characteristics. Not only
is the concept difficult to capture in terms of simple indicators but it
is almost impossible to expect the conditions that affect it to be
similar across regions or across time. The sensitivity of the estimates
of rural poverty especially in Pakistan's case, has been well
documented.
Many studies have found poverty increases even where there have
been quite rapid increases in incomes. When the poor starve it is not
mainly because there is no food but because they do not have the
wherewithall to acquire food. It is widely recognized that the problem
of world hunger cannot be solved merely by attempting to increase
production. The solution requires better distribution and more
productive employment both to increase incentives to expand output and
to create effective demand for greater food output. In most countries
where poverty is widespread the resources needed for development are
available. They are, however, unutilized or poorly utilized.
Underutilization of labour and land is often accompanied by the
underutilization of capital as well. Factor prices are generally
distorted --either as direct conscious policy or as a spill-off of other
policies. This leads to a sub-optimal choice of techniques and
distortions in the distribution of the product.
A lot of work has been done on the measurement of rural poverty and
on the policies of rural development designed to alleviate it. The main
issue still remains: what can be done to. help alleviate this poverty?
In particular, the question that should concern us directly is; what is
the role that the research community can and should play in alleviating
this scourge?
I have recently reviewed some work done by the International
Agricultural Research Centres supported by the consultative group on
International Agricultural Research. Their work, which incorporates the
objective of improved human nutrition in agriculture research, is a
great step forward in maximizing the contribution of the research
community to the alleviation of absolute poverty and related ills such
as insufficient food intake and malnutrition. These centres have set up
commodity priorities that reflect nutritional considerations. The
desirability of changing the nutritional characteristics of certain
commodities is, however, considered in relation to the effects of
changes in the composition of the diet. In some instances, dietary
deficiencies can best be alleviated through changes in individual
commodities. In others, diversifying a diet and increasing consumption
of commodities already available offer the best solution.
Research is being done on improving the nutritional characteristics
of a given commodity, without in any way jeopardising other
characteristics such as yield, consumer acceptance as reflected in
prices and resistance to pests etc., which are important considerations
in the farmer's adoption of these commodities. This research is
taking explicit consideration of the technology characteristics of new
and existing commodities and of the production systems prevailing in the
areas for which this research is being conducted.
This is the type of work designed to alleviate some of the
associated ills of poverty to which we as professional researchers can
contribute.
Sohail J. Malik
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad
Appendix I
ANTI-POVERTY PROGRAMMES IN BANGLADESH
1. In the 1950s: Land Reforms were undertaken to abolish
intermediary rights of landlords and other rentiers; land ceilings were
lowered and land was redistributed; tenancy laws were passed to secure
rights for the sharecropping tenants.
2. In the 1950s: Village-Aid Programmes were introduced for
community development at the village level through the existing
government line departments which involved the locally constituted or
elected village councils.
3. In the 1960s: Rural Works Programmes (RWP) were undertaken to
create employment for agricultural labourers and poor cultivators and to
build rural infrastructure at the village level. They involved the
"Basic Democracy" councils at the Thana (sub-district) level.
Wages were paid both in cash and kind under the food-aid programmes.
4. From 1971 to-date: Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP)
was initiated in order to deliver inputs and give advice to small
farmers (owners and sharecroppers) to increase productivity. The
programme excludes the landless.
5. From 1974 to-date: Food-for-Work Programme (FFWP), replaced RWP.
The FFWP implies a minimum wage, paid mainly in grains, but it does not
guarantee employment to poor landless workers or farmers.
6. From 1979 to-date: Grameen (Rural) Banks were established as a
pilot programme in a small number of Thanas to extend low-interest loans
to the landless poor to buy non-land assets (livestock, etc.) for new
incomes. The borrowers are required to repay these loans in weekly
instalments and contribute to a common fund to be used in emergency for
the poor in a village.
7. In 1982-83: Land Reform measures were debated and acts were
passed to lower land ceiling and rearrange the tenancy contracts, but
they have not been undertaken so far.
Appendix II
ANTI-POVERTY PROGRAMMES IN INDIA
1. In 1948-1950: Land Reforms were introduced in several states to
(a) abolish the intermediary fights in land, (b) lower the land ceiling,
and (c) change the tenancy laws to give more secure rights to tenants
and sharecroppers.
2. In the 1950s: Community Development Programme (CDP) was
undertaken in every state. The country was divided into Blocks (with 80
to 100 villages) and the focus was on (a) building local infrastructure,
(b) providing agricultural extension, (c) encouraging rural/cottage
industry, and (d) establishing community centres. At the village level,
the village Panchayats (elected assemblies) were to work with government
departments. CDP was premised on the idea of building a harmonious and
undifferentiated community in rural areas.
3. In the 1960s: Intensive Agricultural District Programme (IADP)
was launched mainly to promote rapid agricultural growth. Its focus was
on the distribution of seeds, particularly of high-yielding varieties,
fertilizer and the extension of other services to farmers. It was
"technocratic" in its approach to rural development without
involving the landless.
4. In the 1970s: The realization, that agricultural growth was not
adequate, and it was creating inter-personal and inter-regional
disparities without making a dent in the level of absolute poverty, led
to several new (but some ad hoc) programmes targeted at small farmers
and the landless in rural areas:
(a) 1971-1980: Small Farm Development Agency (SFDA); Marginal
Farmers and Agricultural Labourers Programme (MFALP).
(b) 1971-1974: Crash Scheme for Rural Employment (CSRE); Pilot
Intensive Rural Employment Programme (PIREP).
(c) 1977-1980: Food-for-Work Programme (FFWP). It was restructured
in 1980 as National Rural Employment Programme (NREP). The central and
state governments pool resources on a 50:50 basis to provide employment
to landless workers, and wages are paid in cash and kind (grain).
Workers build rural infrastructure, e.g. social forestry, village tanks,
rural roads, school buildings, land reclamation, and watercourse
improvement.
(d) 1983 to-date: Rural Landless Employment Guarantee Programme
(RLEGP) was started based on the model of Employment Guarantee Scheme
(EGS) which was functioning in Maharashtra state since 1974. The RLEGP
is funded entirely by the central government to guarantee employment for
100 days in a year to at least one member of a landless household or
family. This labour is used to build the rural infrastructure as in
NREP. There is provision for a minimum wage in cash or kind.
(e) 1979 to-date: The Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP)
was started in 2,300 Blocks initially and then expanded to over 5,000
Blocks (almost the entire country). It is funded by the central and
state governments on a 50:50 basis. IRDP included the idea of Antyodaya,
which had been used since 1977 in Rajasthan to lift the poor above the
poverty line by providing them loans to buy income-generating assets
other than land. IRDP also merged the SFDA and MFALP for small and
marginal farmers to focus on their problems through subsidies and loans.
IRDP uses a mixture of subsidy (25 to 50 percent) from the state and
low-interest loans from the banking system. The aim of IRDP for those
below the poverty line is to raise their income above the line on a
permanent basis: it is basically a scheme that can provide incremental
income through self-employment. The village Panchayats, Block
Development Officers (BDOs) and the District Rural Development Agency
(DRDA) are expected to play their roles in formulating and executing
each programme.
(f) 1979 t0-date: The Training of Youth for Self-Employment
(TRYSEM) is an integral part of IRDP, but it focuses on the youth (18 to
35 years old) from the landless poor households. The aim is to create
new skills through specific training programmes to be used for
self-employment in or around the village.
(g) 1983 to-date: The Development of Women and Children in Rural
Areas (DWCRA) was added to IRDP as a sub-programme to let more poor
rural women and their children participate in IRDP. The initial
experience of IRDP was that no more than 6 percent of its beneficiaries
were women, although they constituted 50 percent of the rural labour
force.
(h) 1971 to-date: The Minimum Needs Programme (MNP) is simply a
name given to allocations in the public sector for education, health
care, electrification, water supply, housing assistance, and nutrition
in rural areas.
(i) The Drought Prone Area Programme (DPAP) since 1971 and the
Desert Development Programme (DDP) since 1978 focus on regional
handicaps that rural populations, both cultivators and the landless,
face due to deserts and droughts in arid and semi-arid regions of
several northern states.
5. In the late 1960s and early 1970s: Land reform measures were
introduced in some states (e.g. West Bengal and Kerala) to readjust land
ceilings and tenancy contracts. However, in many states no measures have
been undertaken despite the recurring rhetoric in the Sixth and Seventh
Five Year Plan documents.
Appendix III
ANTI-POVERTY PROGRAMMES IN PAKISTAN
1. In the early 1950s: Tenancy Laws were enacted in the provinces
(except Baluchistan) to give security to tenants and redefine tenancy
contracts.
2. In the late 1950s: Land reform measures were undertaken to
redistribute land and lower the land ceiling on individual holdings;
revenue-free estates were resumed by the state.
3. In the 1950s: Village AID programmes were undertaken for
community development at the village level through the existing line
departments which involved the locally constituted, but not elected,
village councils.
4. In the 1960s: Rural Works Programme (RWP) was introduced in 1962
after the pilot programmes in the then East Pakistan were implemented.
The "Basic Democracy" provided the support of Union Councils
to government departments for the employment of rural labour to build
infrastructure.
5. In the early 1970s: Land reforms were introduced to lower land
ceiling, redistribute land, and readjust the tenancy contracts. However,
the land reforms announced in March 1977 were shelved after the Martial
Law in July was imposed.
6. 1972-77: Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) was
undertaken to build markaz (centre) around which villages were to be
strengthened by using public departments and village representatives
through either the cooperative societies or the unelected constituted
councils. The aim here was to "develop" rural areas by taking
a holistic approach in providing inputs and infrastructure through the
public sector, but without adequate representation of the target groups.
7. 1972-77: Peoples Works Programme (PWP) was a new name given to
RWP, which was used to provide some employment in rural areas to the
landless labour and build physical infrastructure.
8. In the 1980s: Since 1978, the elected (rural Union Councils have
been given some resources to continue the RWP, but IRDP has been
dismantled. The provincial line departments are engaged as before in
providing services and inputs to rural areas without focus on the
landless or the rural poor.
9. As part of its "Islamization" policy, the government
has introduced two levies on Muslims: zakat (since 1980) as 2.5 percent
of wealth during a year, and ushr (since 1983) as 5 to 10 percent of the
vlaue of output of agriculture (crops and livestock products) during
each season. Zakat is collected on a voluntary basis from those whose
wealth position is above a specified level. Ushr is likewise collected
from agriculturists whose production level is above a specified value in
the year. Non-Muslims and Muslims belonging to the Shia sect are
exempted from the payment of zakat and ushr to the state. The revenue
from zakat has to be spent as transfer payment to the
"eligible" poor and for no other purpose. The zakat councils
have been set up at each administrative level, with representation from
the elected council members at the local level in rural and urban areas,
to distribute the revenue from zakat. The ushr revenue can be spent on
transfer payments and welfare projects for the rural poor. These
decisions are left to local councils in each province and district. It
is important to note that payment of zakat does not reduce one's
tax liability, although an agriculturist is exempted from land tax if he
is paying the ushr levy.
10. A "Five Point" Programme was launched by the Prime
Minister in mid-1986 for four years. One of its major aims is to improve
the conditions of life for the poor in rural areas by focusing resources
on building physical and social infrastructure to which the poor would
have direct access and on distribution of small plots for those without
shelter. This programme was given one-half of the budget in the annual
development plan for 1986-87. It is expected to get a higher share in
the next three years.
REFERENCES
Ahluwalia, M. S. (1985). "Rural Poverty, Agricultural
Production and Prices: A Reexamination". In J. W. Mellor and G. M.
Desai (eds.), Agricultural Change and Rural Poverty. Baltimore: The
Johns Hopkins University Press.
Abroad, Q. K., and Mahabub Hossain (1984). "An Evaluation of
Selected Policies and Programmes for the Alleviation of Rural Poverty in
Bangladesh". In Rizwanul Islam (ed.), Strategies for Alleviating
Poverty in Rural Asia. Bangkok: I.L.O./A.R.T.E.P.
Bandyopadhyay, D. (1986). A Study of Poverty Alleviation in Rural
India through Special Employment Creation Programmes. Asian Employment
Programme Working Paper. New Delhi: ILO/ARTEP.
Bardhan, P. K. (1984). The Political Economy of Development in
India. Oxford: Basil and Blackwell.
Bhatty, I. Z. (1974). "Inequality and Poverty in Rural
India". In T. N. Srinivasan and P. K. Bardhan (eds.), Poverty and
Income Distribution in India. Calcutta: Statistical Publishing Society.
Cain, Mead (1983). "Landlessness in India and Bangladesh: A
Critical Review of National Data Sources". Economic Development and
Cultural Change. Vol. 32, No. 1.
Dandekar, V. M. (1986). "Agriculture, Employment and
Poverty". Economic and Political Weekly. Vol. 21, Nos. 38/39. pp.
A90-A100.
Food and Agricultural Organization (1985). Production Year Book.
Rome.
International Labour Organisation (1985). Yearbook of Labour
Statistics. Geneva.
Irfan, Mohammad, and Rashid Amjad (1984). "Poverty in Rural
Pakistan". In A. R. Khan and Eddy Lee (eds.), Poverty in Asia.
Bangkok: ILO/ARTEP.
Islam, Rizwanul (ed.) (1985). Strategies for Alleviating Rural
Poverty in Rural Asia. Bangkok: ILO/ARTEP'
Khan, Mahmood H. (1987). "Pakistan's Agriculture Sector:
Performance and Policies, 1971-1985". Research Paper for the World
Bank. (Unpublished)
Mohammad, Faiz, and Ghulam Badar (1985). "Structure of Rural
Income in Pakistan: Some Preliminary Estimates". Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. XXIV, Nos. 3&4. Autumn-Winter.
Osmani, S. R., and R. Rahman (1981). A Study of Income Distribution
in Bangladesh. Dhaka: Institute of Development Studies.
Singh, Inderjit (1983). "The Landless Poor in South
Asia". In Growth and Equity in Agricultural Development.
Proceedings of the 18th International Conference of Agricultural
Economists. London: Gower.
UNESCAP (1984). Statistical Year Book for Asia and the Pacific.
Bangkok: ESCAP.
World Bank (1986). World Development Report. New York: Oxford
University Press.
MAHMOOD HASAN KHAN, Dr Khan is Professor of Economics at Simon
Fraser University, Burnaby, B. C. (Canada). His participation in the
PSDE meeting was financed by the Friedrich Ebert Foundation of West
Germany.
Table 1
Basic Data on Economies of Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Economic Indicator Years Bangladesh
1. GNP per Person (US$) 1985 140
2. Population 1965 58
1985 101
3. Percent Rural Population 1965 94
1984 82
4. Percent Agricultural Population 1965 84
1984 71
5. Percent Growth of Population 1965-73 2.6
(Annual Rate) 1973-84 2.5
6. Percent Growth of GDP 1965-73 --
(Annual Rate) 1973-84 5.0
7. Percent Growth of Agricultural 1965-73 0.4
Output (Annual Rate) 1973-84 3.1
8. Percent Share of Agriculture 1965 53
in GDP 1984 48
9. Percent of Labour Working in 1965 84
Agriculture 1984 75
10 Index of Agricultural Output 1974 98
per Person (1979-81 = 100) 1985 96
11. Index of Food Production 1974 98
per Person (1979-81 = 100) 1985 96
12. Cultivated Area per Person 1985 0.13
in Agriculture (Hectare)
Economic Indicator India Pakistan
1. GNP per Person (US$) 280 400
2. Population 495 57
759 95
3. Percent Rural Population 81 76
75 71
4. Percent Agricultural Population 73 60
69 52
5. Percent Growth of Population 2.3 3.1
(Annual Rate) 2.3 2.9
6. Percent Growth of GDP 3.9 5.4
(Annual Rate) 4.1 5.6
7. Percent Growth of Agricultural 3.7 4.7
Output (Annual Rate) 2.3 3.0
8. Percent Share of Agriculture 47 40
in GDP 35 24
9. Percent of Labour Working in 73 60
Agriculture 70 55
10 Index of Agricultural Output 91 98
per Person (1979-81 = 100) 109 102
11. Index of Food Production 90 97
per Person (1979-81 = 100) 109 100
12. Cultivated Area per Person 0.32 0.39
in Agriculture (Hectare)
Note: Data are compiled from World Bank (1986); F.A.0. (1985) and
I.L.O. (1985).
Table 2
Basic Data on External Economic Conditions of Bangladesh, India and
Pakistan
Economic Indicator Years Bangladesh
1. Exports as Percent of GDP 1984 7.6
2. Imports as Percent of GDP 1984 16.6
3. Exports as Percent of Imports 1984 45.7
4. Current Account Deficit as
Percent of GDP 1984 4.2
5. Terms of Trade (1980 = 100) 1984 106.0
6. Percent Growth of Exports 1965-73 -6.6
(Annual Rate) 1973-84 2.9
7. Percent Growth of Imports 1965-73 -8.3
(Annual Rate) 1973-84 4.2
8. Workers Remittances:
As Percent of GDP 1984 3.5
As Percent of Exports 1984 46.7
9. Total External Liability
As Percent of GDP 1984 45.8
10. Total Long-term Debt
As Percent of GNP 1984 40.0
11. Debt Service Payments:
As Percent of GNP 1984 1.3
As Percent of Exports 1984 14.2
Economic Indicator India Pakistan
1. Exports as Percent of GDP 5.8 9.3
2. Imports as Percent of GDP 9.2 21.1
3. Exports as Percent of Imports 62.9 44.1
4. Current Account Deficit as
Percent of GDP 1.5 4.0
5. Terms of Trade (1980 = 100) 107.0 88.0
6. Percent Growth of Exports 2.4 3.7
(Annual Rate) 3.3 7.4
7. Percent Growth of Imports -5.7 -2.9
(Annual Rate) 5.4 7.5
8. Workers Remittances:
As Percent of GDP 1.6 9.3
As Percent of Exports 28.2 99.0
9. Total External Liability
As Percent of GDP 18.9 42.0
10. Total Long-term Debt
As Percent of GNP 13.6 29.7
11. Debt Service Payments:
As Percent of GNP 1.1 2.8
As Percent of Exports 13.8 27.1
Note: Data are compiled from World Bank (1986).
Table 3
Social Indicators for Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Social Indicator Years Bangladesh India Pakistan
1. Life Expectancy Male 1965 45 46 46
at Birth Female 1965 44 44 44
Male 1984 50 56 52
Female 1984 51 55 50
2. Infant Mortality 1965 153 151 150
Rate 1984 124 90 116
3. Child Death Rate 1965 24 23 23
1984 18 11 16
4. Population per 9010 4860 3160
Physician 1965 1984 6000 2610 2320
5. Population per Nurse 1965 -- 6500 9900
1984 19400 4670 5870
6. Adult Literacy Rate Male 1970 36 47 30
Female 1970 12 20 11
Male 1983 40 55 36
Female 1983 18 26 15
7. Primary School Male 1965 67 89 59
Enrolment Female 1965 31 57 20
Male 1983 67 100 63
Female 1983 55 68 33
8. Secondary School 1965 13 27 12
Enrolment 1983 19 34 16
9. Daily Calorie Intake 1964-66 2001 1967 1757
per Person 1981-83 1878 2088 2236
10. Daily Protein Intake 1964-66 43.6 49.1 49.8
per Person 1981-83 40.3 50.8 58.6
(in Grams)
Note: Data are compiled from F.A.O. (1985); World Bank (1986) and
UNESCAP (1984).
Table 4
Rural Poverty in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Countries Percent of Rural Population Below Poverty Line
1963-64 1972-73 1977-78 1978-79 1983-84
Bangladesh 52.0 55.7 67.9 -- --
India
a. 53.8 50.5 51.2 53.3 40.4
b. 44.5 43.1 39.1 -- --
c. -- 46.0 51.9 -- 48.9
Pakistan 40.5 51.5 -- 39.8 --
Notes: (1.) Data for Bangladesh are from Q.K. Ahmad and Mahabub
Hossain (1984) and Rizwanul Islam (1985).
(2.) Data for India are from (a) D. Bandyopadhyay (1986), (b) M. S.
Ahluwalia (1985) and (c) V. M. Dandekar (1986).
(3.) Data for Pakistan are from M. Irfan and R. Amjad (1984).
Table 5
Distribution of Landownership in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Size of Landholdings Percent of
(in hectare)
Households Population Area
1. Bangladesh: 1978.
Up to 0.4 46.6 39.6 8.4
Over 0.4 to 1.2 31.3 31.2 25.2
Over 1.2 to 2.0 11.1 13.1 18.6
Over 2.0 to 4.0 7.7 10.3 22.7
Over 4.0 to 6.0 1.7 3.1 10.1
Over 6.0 1.6 2.7 15.0
2. India: 1961-62, 1971-72
Percent of Households Percent of Area
1961-62 1971-72 1961-62 1971-72
Less than 0.4 36.8 44.0 1.6 1.6
0.4 to Less than 2.0 35.1 33.8 18.4 22.9
2.0 to Less than 6.0 20.3 16.7 34.5 36.1
6.0 to Less than 20.0 7.1 5.0 34.4 31.1
20.0 and Over 0.7 0.4 11.1 8.3
3. Pakistan: 1976
Percent of Population Percent of Area
Up to 0.4 30.3 3.3
Over 0.4 to 2.0 36.2 14.3
Over 2.0 to 5.0 17.9 17.9
Over 5.0 to 10.0 10.1 21.1
Over 10.0 to 20.0 3.2 14.5
Over 20.0 2.3 28.9
Notes: (1.) Bangladesh: The data exclude the landless. Their
proportion was (a) 28.8 percent in the households and (b) 23.4
percent in the population. The data are from Bangladesh Land
Occupancy Survey, 1978.
(2.) India: The data exclude the landless. Their proportion in the
households was (a) 27.5 percent in 1961-62 and (b) 25.6 percent in
1971-72. The data are from National Sample Surveys, Rounds 17 and 26.
(3.) Pakistan: These data exclude the landless. The data for
landowners and their area are from Federal Land Commission of
Pakistan. They are based on land records of 1976.
Table 6
Distribution of Farms and Farm Area in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Size of Farm (in hectare) Percent of Farms Percent of Farm Area
1. Bangladesh 1960 1977 1960 1977
Up to 0.4 24.3 15.9 3.2 2.7
Over 0.4 to 1.0 27.3 33.8 12.9 16.3
Over 1.0 to 3.0 37.7 40.9 45.7 49.4
Over 3.0 10.7 9.4 38.1 32.7
2. India 1971 1981 1971 1981
Less than 1.0 50.0 56.5 9.0 12.2
1.0 to Less than 2.0 18.9 18.0 11.9 14.1
2.0 to Less than 4.0 15.0 14.0 18.5 21.2
4.0 to Less than 10.0 11.2 9.1 29.7 29.7
10.0 and Over 3.9 2.4 30.9 22.8
3. Pakistan 1972 1980 1972 1980
Less than 1.0 14.0 17.0 1.0 1.0
1.0 to Less than 2.0 14.0 17.0 4.0 5.0
2.0 to Less than 5.0 39.0 40.0 25.0 28.0
5.0 to Less than 10.0 21.0 17.0 27.0 25.0
10.0 and Over 11.0 8.0 43.0 42.0
Notes: (1.) Bangladesh: Average size of farm (a) 1.43 hectare in
1960 and (b) 1.42 hectare in 1977. Data are from Census of
Agriculture 1960 and 1977.
(2.) India: Average size of farm (a) 2.28 hectare in 1971 and (b)
1.82 hectare in 1981. Data are from Census of Agriculture 1971 and 1981.
(3.) Pakistan: Average size of farm (a) 5.3 hectare in 1972 and (b)
4.7 hectare in 1980. Data are from Census of Agriculture 1972 and 1980.
Table 7
Land and Rural Income Concentration in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Concentration of Land use
Countries 1960 1971 1972 1977 1980 1981
1. Land Concentration
Bangladesh 0.47 -- -- 0.41 -- --
India -- 0.62 -- -- -- 0.60
Pakistan -- -- 0.50 -- 0.54 --
2. Rural Income
Concentration
1960 1962 1964 1969 1972 1974
Bangladesh -- -- 0.34 -- -- 0.34
India -- 0.41 -- 0.43 -- --
Pakistan 0.35 -- -- -- 0.29 --
Concentration of
Ownership
Countries 1972 1976 1978
1. Land Concentration
Bangladesh -- -- 0.58
India 0.68 -- --
Pakistan -- 0.68 --
2. Rural Income
Concentration
1976 1977 1980
Bangladesh -- 0.40 --
India 0.39 -- --
Pakistan -- -- 0.36
Notes: (1.) Land concentration ratios are the Gini coefficients
estimated from data on land distribution by ownership and use given
in earlier tables.
(2.) Data on rural income concentration ratios (Gini coefficients)
are from: (a) S.R. Osmani and A. Rahman (1981), (b) I. Z. Bhatty
(1974), (c) P. K. Bardhan (1984), and (d) Faiz Mohammad and Ghulam
Badar (1985).
Table 8
Distribution of Landless Households in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Percent of Rural Households
Landlessness Based on Ownership/
Operation or use Bangladesh India Pakistan
1. Ownership Status 1978 1972 1980
No Land Owned 28.8 25.6 26.2
Owned Less than 0.4 Hectare 33.2 19.2 32.0
Total Landless 62.0 44.8 58.2
2. Operational Status 1980 1980 1980
Landless Rural Labour 20.9 16.0 19.8
Operating 0.4 Hectare (NL) 7.7 15.0 2.0
Operating 0.4 to 1.0 Hectare (MF) 16.1 18.1 5.0
Operating 1.0 to 2.0 Hectare (SF) 14.0 17.0 6.9
Other Rural Households 42.3 33.9 66.3
All Rural Households 100.0 100.0 100.0
(14.3) (93.6) (10.1)
Notes: (1.) Data on landlessness based on landownership are from Mead
Cain (1983) and Mahmood Hasan Khan (1987).
(2.) Data on landlessness based on operation or use of land are from
Inderjit Singh (1983).
(3.) Figures in parentheses are numbers of rural households in
millions.
Table 9
Rural Labour Force in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
(in millions)
Bangladesh India
1972 1978 1972 1978
Rural Population 65.0 78.0 455.0 493.0
Rural Labour Force 16.0 24.0 200.0 218.0
Proportion of Rural Labour:
a. Working on Own Farm 7.7 11.5 50.0 54.5
b. Working as Helpers 4.3 6.5 46.0 50.1
c. Working as Labourers 4.0 6.0 78.0 85.0
d. Working outside Farms -- 26.0 28.4
Pakistan
1972 1978
Rural Population 48.0 59.0
Rural Labour Force 11.5 16.0
Proportion of Rural Labour:
a. Working on Own Farm 3.8 5.3
b. Working as Helpers 3.5 4.8
c. Working as Labourers 1.0 1.4
d. Working outside Farms 3.2 4.5
Notes: (1.) Data for labour working outside agriculture in Bangladesh
were not available.
(2.) All data are compiled from Inderjit Singh, op. cit., (Table 8).
Table 10
Index Numbers of Real Agricultural Wage in Bangladesh, India and
Pakistan
Years Bangladesh India Pakistan
1973 115.1 118.1 138.5
1974 123.2 99.2 144.3
1975 100.0 100.0 108.8
1976 108.1 128.1 100.0
1977 110.1 118.9 105.2
1978 119.5 123.1 108.3
1979 130.7 126.9 115.0
1980 122.5 131.1 121.8
1981 125.1 119.7 158.8
1982 124.0 126.7 147.7
1983 112.0 127.5 176.7
1984 100.3 133.1 186.2
Note: The indices of real wage rates have been constructed by
deflating the average daily wage rates for agricultural labourers
by the consumer price indices. Data on nominal wage rates and
consumer price indices are from I.L.O. (1985), UNESCAP (1984).
Table 11
Sectoral Shares of Plan Allocations in Bangladesh, India and Pakistan
Percent Share of Sector
in the Plan
India
Bangladesh
Second Sixth Seventh
Sector Plan Plan Plan
1980-85 1980-85 1985-90
1. Agriculture, Irrigation
and Rural Devel-
opment 35 24 22
2. Industry and
Mining 13 16 13
3. Energy (Power and
Fuels) 19 28 30
4. Transport and
Communications 13 13 13
5. Social Services 17 14 16
6. Others 4 5 6
Percent Share of Sector in the Plan
Pakistan
Fifth Sixth
Sector Plan Plan
1978-83 1983-88
1. Agriculture, Irrigation
and Rural Devel-
opment 20 16
2. Industry and
Mining 17 9
3. Energy (Power and
Fuels) 25 38
4. Transport and
Communications 23 19
5. Social Services 13 17
6. Others 2 2
Notes: (1.) Social Services include physical planning and housing,
health care, education, manpower, population planning, and social
welfare.
(2.) Data are from the Five Year Plan documents of the three
countries.