The economic rate of return in small and household manufacturing industries.
Mahmood, Mir Annice ; Sahibzada, Shamim A.
I. INTRODUCTION
Small-scale and Household Manufacturing Industry can contribute to
economic development by providing employment; creating jobs with low
capital costs; building up a reservoir of skilled and semi-skilled
labour; reducing income disparities as small-scale manufacturing is
widespread and not concentrated in any specific area or region;
developing indigenous technology" and raising saving and investment
within the country rather than being dependent on external sources.
Small-scale manufacturing is also a potential breeding ground for the
development of entrepreneurial talent which is of great importance in
accelerating the developmental process.
In Pakistan, the importance of the small-scale manufacturing
industry has not been given its due recognition. The various five-year
plans mention small-scale industry but focus their main attention in
other areas. For example, to quote from the First Five-Year Plan (1955-60):
"Small industries have specific contributions to make to
economic development. In the first place it can contribute to the output
of needed goods without requiring the organization of large new
enterprises or the use of much foreign exchange to finance the import of
new equipment. Secondly, it can provide opportunities for employment
beyond the narrow boundaries of urban centres. Finally, as history
shows, it can perform an important function in promoting growth,
providing a training ground for management and labour and spreading
industrial knowledge over wide areas". (Government of Pakistan,
First Five-Year Plan p. 473).
Statements in a similar vein relating to small-scale manufacturing
were repeated in the successive five-year plans.
Notwithstanding the fact that small-scale industry has not been
given a significant role to play in the country's economic
development, this sector does contribute greatly to value added in the
manufacturing sector (26 percent)to GNP (5.3 percent) and to total
exports (18 percent)(Government of Pakistan, Economic Survey 1987-88).
Tables 1 and 2 are self-explanatory dealing with growth rates between
large-scale manufacturing and small-scale manufacturing. It is clear
that for the last four years, small-scale manufacturing has been growing
steadily and at a greater rate than large-scale manufacturing. Table 2
gives the share of different manufacturing industries in value added and
employment.
Given the contribution that small-scale industry makes to the
national economy, the objective of this paper is to assess the economic
profitability of small and household manufacturing units. For this
purpose, data from the survey of Small and Household Manufacturing
Industries 1983-84 are used to calculate the economic profitability of
these units. The paper is divided into four sections. After an
Introduction, Section II looks at Data and Methodology, Section III
presents the results and discusses matters of policy relevance to the
small-scale manufacturing industry.
II. METHODOLOGY AND DATA
In this paper, we have calculated our estimates of the economic
rates of return for 1983-84 for small-scale industries from the data
provided by the Survey of Small and Household Manufacturing Industries
for urban areas only. Data were collected on the following items of
small and household manufacturing units separately: plant and
manchinery; land and building and other fixed assets. Data on employment
cost, industrial cost, fuel costs and on miscellaneous costs were also
collected. The amount of indirect taxes paid by these small and
household manufacturing units is also given. It should, however, be
noted that no asset figures in the form of land and building are
available for household units and no figures are available for the fuel
costs borne by the household units. Also no data were provided for
working capital requirements. For our analysis we therefore assumed
these to be 10 percent of the total production cost. Data are also
provided on the total value of output from which the relevant costs can
be deducted to arrive at value added. It should be emphasized that all
prices given in the survey are market prices which have to be adjusted
by various conversion factors to arrive at economic prices.
The following industries were covered in the survey: Food,
Beverages and Tobacco, Textile, Wearing Aparrel and Leather, Wood and
Wood Products, Paper and Paper Products, Printing Publishing, Chemicals
and Chemical Petroleum, Coal Rubber and Plastic Products Drugs and
Pharmaceuticals, other chemical products such as Varnishes, Cosmetics,
Soap and Detergent, Non-metallic Mineral Products, Pottery, China and
Earthenware, Glass and Glass Products, Iron and Steel Basic Industries,
Non-ferrous Metal Basic Industries, Electrical Machinery, Apparatus,
Appliances and Supplies, Scientific Instruments, Optical Instruments
Handicrafts, Sports and Athletic Goods, and Other Manufacturing
Industries.
However, repair and service establishments which dealt in shoes,
cycles, watches and clocks, radio and television, motor cars, and
domestic electric appliances were not covered in this survey. These
activities are mainly directed to the domestic consumer market. Only
activities that had industrial applications such as repair of industrial
plant and machinery were defined as manufacturing activity and included
in the survey.
Sufficient data are available in the survey from which we can
calculate the net profit after subtracting production and wage costs
from total output, net of indirect taxation. This net profit, when
divided by the capital stock, gives the rate of return, (1) which is an
average figure and is based on market prices.
Conversion Factors
The major items whose market prices are to be adjusted into border
prices are given below in three separate categories. These are traded
items; non-traded items and skilled and unskilled labour. In the first
category items such as fuel and gross output are included for adjustment
purposes. In the category items such as land and buildings, electricity
and depreciation are included. The third category adjusts the market
prices of wages/salaries paid to unskilled and skilled labour. The
numeraine in our exercise to determine the economic rate of return is
border prices which are expressed in domestic currency at the official
exchange rate.
The following three conversion factors have been, used to adjust
for market price distortions:
1. Standard Conversion Factor;
2. Shadow Wage Rates;and
3. A ratio of value added at world prices to value added at market
prices.
If the numeraire is border prices expressed in domestic currency at
the official exchange rate, then all inputs and outputs have to be
valued in terms of world prices. For estimating the costs of producing
non-traded goods at world prices we need a specific conversion factor
which is the ratio of the shadow price of a good to its domestic price.
In practice, due to the lack of appropriate data, an average conversion
factor i.e., the Standard Conversion Factor is made use of.
Standard Conversion Factor
The Standard Conversion Factor (SCF), which is an average
relationship, (2) is the ratio of the sum of imports and exports at
border prices to the sum of imports at border prices plus import taxes
and exports at border prices minus export taxes. In algebraic terms it
is expressed as follows:
SCF = (T + M)/(M + Tm) + (X - Tx) where
M is the c.i.f, value of visible imports;
X is the f.o.b, value of visible exports;
Tm is the value of total import duties; and
Tx is the value of total export taxes minus export subsidies.
It has been estimated to be 0.85 (Weiss 1979) and .909 (Squire,
Little and Durdag 1979). In the absence of specific conversion factors
for various non-trading items, the SCF has been made use of frequently.
It should be stressed that such frequent use of conversion factors based
on average relationships like the SCF is not recommended in the
literature; it is suggested that the SCF be used only for minor
non-traded goods, and items for which detailed information is lacking.
However, many published case studies have had to rely significantly upon
a SCF (Stewart 1978) and this was the experience of the Pakistan Study
(Weiss 1979).
Shadow Wage Rates
Market labour costs have been adjusted by a shadow wage rate of
0.75. This rate has been based on the World Bank's revised
estimates of the economic value of labour in the uncontrolled sector
which consists of mostly small and household manufacturing. It is also
to be noted that in our study a large proportion of the labour force is
unpaid, mainly household workers helping out. A labour cost has thus
been imputed to these workers by multiplying the average monthly wage by
the number of workers in both household and small-scale manufacturing.
These costs are then added to the actual wage costs already given in the
survey to arrive at the total wage cost, admittedly a rough and ready
procedure.
A ratio of value added at world prices to value added at market
prices has been used in order to allow for domestic price distortions.
This ratio is .55, based on an unpublished study done at PIDE.
III. RESULTS
Table 3 presents the economic rate of return for Small-scale
Manufacturing. Table 4 does the same for Household Manufacturing. In
both the tables market prices have been adjusted by the use of the
relevant conversion factor to their economic values. For example,
tradeable and traded goods have been adjusted by the average tariff rate
(.63): plant and machinery and raw materials fall in this category.
Gross output, net of indirect taxation has been adjusted by the ratio of
value added at world prices to value added at domestic prices (.55).
Fuel and electricity charges, where available, have been adjusted by
doubling the market prices, to arrive at their economic price, a rough
rule of thumb employed by the Planning and Development Division,
Government of Pakistan. The Standard Conversion Factor (SCF) was used
against those items that are considered to be nontraded, e.g. Land and
Building, Other Costs etc. The shadow wage rate used was .75.
For small-scale manufacturing the rate of return was 16.9 percent.
For household manufacturing, the economic rate of return was 19.7
percent. We should like to point out that these rates are just
approximations--given that the data on which these estimates are based
were of low quality.
One of the major factors affecting data quality was the level of
education, given that a large proportion of those surveyed were
uneducated and hence would not have responded appropriately to the
questionnaire. They would not have appreciated the significance for
which the data were being collected. Also, small and household
manufacturing units do not maintain accounts of their transactions over
the year. Again, data on fixed assets is based on oral estimates
supplied by the respondents themselves rather than on any documentary
evidence. Finally, figures on employment cost, industrial cost, other
costs and the value of production were collected mainly on the costs
etc. that prevailed in the previous month. These figures were then
multiplied by twelve to arrive at annual figures for costs incurred and
the value of production produced. Thus, given these shortcomings of the
data base, the economic rates of return estimated should be treated with
some caution. Much more work remains to be done, in particular in
improving the data base, before more meaningful analysis can be
conducted.
Comments on "The Economic Rate of Return in Small and
Household Manufacturing Industries"
The authors begin by underlining the importance of small-scale (SS)
and household (H) manufacturing industries (MI) and point out that,
beside being paid lip service, these industries have generally been
neglected by the policy-makers. They then try to substantiate their
point by estimating the social--which, contrary to their usage in a
previous paper, they now opt to call economic--rates of return for those
industries. Since their estimated rates of return turn out to be fairly
high (in the 30 to 36 percent range) therefore their conclusion is that
SS, and HMI need more attention of the policy-makers. While it may be
true that SS, and HMI deserve more encouragement the present paper does
not support such a conclusion when subjected to a closer scrutiny.
First and foremost the authors do not compare and contrast the
present rates of return with those obtained in the other sectors of the
economy, not even with their own estimates for large-scale manufacturing
industries (LSMI) (Sahibzada and Mahmood 1986). Since we do not have any
idea of the alternative rates of return (the opportunity cost of funds),
no meaningful conclusions could be derived by looking at the estimated
rates of return per se. (1)
It seems appropriate to compare their current estimates with those
that they obtained for LSMI (which are in the 16 to 19 percent range).
When we attempt to do this we quickly discover that these two estimates
are not readily comparable. This is because in the present estimation,
unlike the previous ones, 'working capital' has not been
accounted for. We are not offered any explanation for such an omission.
My own exercise with their previous work shows that if the working
capital, which accounts for almost 45 percent of the total capital stock
is excluded, the rates of return estimates (in the neighbourhood of 33
percent) turn out to be more or less identical to the present estimates,
and it becomes difficult to support the hypothesis that SS, and HMI have
been neglected.
Should we then draw the conclusion, assuming working capital to
constitute the same proportion of total capital stock in both the SS,
and HMI, and the LSMI, that the competitive capital market has tended to
equalize the rates of return across these industries? Such a conclusion
is far from warranted. Actually, the present estimates do not seem to be
very reliable, primarily due to the data base being used. Though the
authors have warned about the unreliability of the data yet they have
not carefully analysed the data to provide an idea of the margin of
unreliability. For example, their data yield capital-output ratios of
1.61 and HMI respectively without the working capital (the latter does
not even include land and building assets. The comparable figure for
LSMI from their earlier study turns out to be 1.79 without the working
capital (with working capital it is 3.18). This means, that even if we
make the generous assumption that value added per worker is the same in
both the LSMI and the SS and HMI (which clearly is unrealistic), the
small-scale manufacturing industry is roughly as capital-intensive as
the LSMI, while the household manufacturing is even more
capital-intensive than that.
Another indication of the unreliability of data is provided by the
estimates of private rates of return (which the authors fail to
provide). These estimates are 127 percent and 67 percent for SS and HMI
respectively. These are, of course, without including working capital.
Even when we make a liberal adjustment for working capital (allowing it
to be 45 percent of the total capital stock), we get an estimate of more
than 87 percent for small-scale manufacturing industry. But then we do
not observe much rush of investment into this industry.
Rauf A. Azhar
International Islamic University, Islamabad
REFERENCE
Sahibzada, Shamim A., and M. Annice Mahmood (1986). Social Rates of
Return in Pakistan's Large-scale Manufacturing Sector. Pakistan
Development Review. Vol. XXV, No. 4. pp. 891-904.
(1) Since the authors have adopted the same methodology as in their
previous work (ibid), comments on their methodology by K. Sarmad are
relevant to the present paper. See Khwaja Sarmad, (1986), "Comments
on Social Rates of Return in Pakistan's Large-scale Manufacturing
Sector". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXV, No. 4. pp. 905-6.
REFERENCES
Bruce, C. (1976). "Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: A Guide for
Country and Project Economists to the Derivation and Application of
Economic and Social Accounting Prices". Washington, D.C.: The World
Bank. (World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 239)
Lal, D. (1972). Wells and Welfare. Paris: Development Centre for
the OECD.
Pakistan, Government of (1957). First Five Five-Year Plan,
1955-1960. Karachi: National Planning Board.
Pakistan, Government of (1987). Survey of Small and Household
Manufacturing Activities. Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (1988). Pakistan Economic Survey.
Islamabad: Finance Division.
Sahibzada, Shamim A., and Mir Annice Mahmood (1986). "Social
Rates of Return in Pakistan's Large-scale Manufacturing
Sector". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XXV, No. 4.
Squire, Lyn, and G. Herman van der Tak (1975). Economic Analysis of
Projects. Baltimore, Maryland : The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Squire, L., I. M. D. Little and M. Durdag (1979). "Shadow
Pricing and Macroeconomic Analysis: Some Illustrations from
Pakistan". Pakistan Development Review. Vol. XVIII, No. 2.
Stewart, F. (1978). "Social Cost-Benefit Analysis in Practice:
Some Reflections in the Light of Case Studies Using Little-Mirrlees
Techniques". World Development. Vol. 6, No. 1.
Weiss, John (1979). "Project Selection and Equity Objective:
The Use of Social Analysis". Pakistan Development Review. Vol.
XVIII, No. 2.
(1) The calculation of the rate of return in this paper is based on
the methodology followed in our earlier paper by the authors (1986).
(2) See Squire and van der Tak [(1975) and Bruce (1976)].
MIR ANNICE MAHMOOD and SHAMIM k. SAHIBZADA *
* The authors are respectively, Senior Faculty Member and Chief,
Training Programme at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics,
Islamabad.
Table 1
Growth of Manufacturing Sector
Period Annual Compound Growth Rate (%)
Total Large Scale Small Scale
1949-50--1959-60 7.7 15.4 2.3
1959-60--1969-70 9.9 13.3 2.9
1969-70--1979-80 5.4 4.7 7.6
1979-80--1984-85 9.4 9.8 8.4
1985-86 7.5 7.2 8.4
1986-87 7.5 7.2 8.4
1987-88 7.6 7.3 8.4
1983-88 (6th Plan) 7.7 7.5 8.4
Source: Government of Pakistan (1987; 1988. p. 109)
Table 2
Share of Different Manufacturing Industries in Value Added and
Employment (1983-84)
Large Scale Small Scale
Value Value
Added Employment Added Employment
Food, Beverages & Tobacco
Industry 21.8 15.9 28.8 17.1
Textiles 18.6 37.6 20.1 23.4
Leather & Rubber Products 5.0 3.0 1.3 1.1
Chemicals & Chemical Products 17.8 7.8 1.8 1.6
Non-metallic Mineral Products 0.9 3.4 4.9 1.2
Basic Metal, Machinery &
Transport Equipment 28.2 20.6 12.9 17.3
Others 6.5 10.7 23.6 27.7
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: Government of Pakistan (1987; 1988, p. 112)
Table 3
Economic Rate of Return in Small-scale Manufacturing
Market Values Conversion
(1) (000 Rs) Factor
(I) (II)
(A) Capital Account
(a) Fixed Assets
(i) Plant and Machinery 1,936,695 .63 (2)
(ii) Land and Buildings 2,514,620 .91 (3)
(iii) Other Assets 127,416 .91 (3)
(b) Depreciation 330,809 .91 (3)
Total A (a + b) 4,909,540
(B) Production Cost
(a) Employment Cost
(i) Paid Labour 1,307,515
(ii) Imputed to Unpaid
Labour 165,145
Total (a) 1,472,660 .75 (4) (.91) (3)
(b) Fuel Costs
(i) Electricity 494,505 2 (5)
(ii) Gas 39,531 2 (5)
(iii) Other Fuel 103,792 2 (5)
Total (b) 637,828 2 (5)
(C) Other Costs 225,701 .91 (3)
(D) Raw Materials 9,869,879 .63 (2)
(E) Working Capital
(10 Percent of Product Cost) 1,220,607 .63
(F) Indirect Taxation (Rs) 9,046,520
(G) Gross Output
(i) Exported (18%) 3,318,148
(ii) Domestic Consumption 15,116,007
Total (D) 18,434,155 .55 (6)
(H) Value Added 7,709,793
Economic Value
(000 Rs)
(III)
(A) Capital Account
(a) Fixed Assets
(i) Plant and Machinery 1,220,118.00
(ii) Land and Buildings 2,228,304.00
(iii) Other Assets 115,949.00
(b) Depreciation 301,036.00
Total A (a + b) 3,925,407.00
(B) Production Cost
(a) Employment Cost
(i) Paid Labour
(ii) Imputed to Unpaid
Labour
Total (a) 1,005,094.00
(b) Fuel Costs
(i) Electricity 989,010.00
(ii) Gas 79,062.00
(iii) Other Fuel 207,584.00
Total (b) 1,275,656.00
(C) Other Costs 205,388.00
(D) Raw Materials 6,218,024.00
(E) Working Capital
(10 Percent of Product Cost) 768,982.00
(F) Indirect Taxation (Rs)
(G) Gross Output
(i) Exported (18%)
(ii) Domestic Consumption
Total (D) 10,138,785.00
(H) Value Added 2,439,717.00
Economic Rate of Return Value = Added - Wage Cost/Capital Cost =
768,982/3,925,407 = 16.9%
Notes: (1) All values under column 1 have been taken from the
Survey of Small and Household Manufacturing Industry (Urban)
1983-84.
(2) The overall average tariff rate.
(3) The standard conversion factor estimated by the World Bank.
(4) The shadow wage rate.
(5) Doubling of fuel prices as per rough rule of thumb by the
Planning and Development Division, Government of Pakistan.
(6) The ratio of value added at world prices to value added at
domestic prices.
Table 4
Economic Rate of Return in Household Manufacturing
Market Values Conversion
(1) (000 Rs) Factor
(I) (II)
(A) Capital Account
(a) Fixed Assets
(i) Plant and Machinery 494,143 .63 (2)
(ii) Land and Buildings --
(iii) Other Assets 508,545 .91 (3)
(b) Depreciation 99,226 .91 (3)
Total (a +b) 1,101,914
(B) Production Cost
(a) Employment Cost
(i) Paid Labour 83,608
(ii) Imputed to Unpaid
Labour 58,879
Total (a) 142,487 .75 (4) (.91) (3)
(b) Fuel Costs
(i) Electricity
(ii) Gas
(iii) Other Fuel
Total (b)
(C) Other Costs 29,046 .91 (3)
(D) Industrial Costs 1,356,839 .63 (2)
(E) Working Capital
(10 Percent of Production
cost) 128,837 .63
(F) Indirect Taxation (Rs) 571,179
(G) Gross Output
(i) Exported (18%)
(ii) Domestic Consumption
Total (D) 2,264,846 .55 (5)
(H) Value Added 879,552
Economic Value
(000 Rs)
(III)
(A) Capital Account
(a) Fixed Assets
(i) Plant and Machinery 311,310.00
(ii) Land and Buildings
(iii) Other Assets 462,776.00
(b) Depreciation 90,296.00
Total (a +b) 864,382.00
(B) Production Cost
(a) Employment Cost
(i) Paid Labour
(ii) Imputed to Unpaid
Labour
Total (a) 97,247.00
(b) Fuel Costs
(i) Electricity
(ii) Gas
(iii) Other Fuel
Total (b)
(C) Other Costs 26,432.00
(D) Industrial Costs 854,809.00
(E) Working Capital
(10 Percent of Production
cost) 96,287.00
(F) Indirect Taxation (Rs)
(G) Gross Output
(i) Exported (18%)
(ii) Domestic Consumption
Total (D) 1,245,665.00
(H) Value Added 170,890.00
Economic Rate of Return = Value Added - Wage Costs/Capital Stock =
92,287/846,382 = 19.7%
Notes: (1) All values under column 1 have been taken from the
Survey of Small and Household Manufacturing Industry (Urban)
1983-84.
(2) The overall average tariff rate.
(3) The standard conversion factor.
(4) The shadow wage rate.
(5) The ratio of value added at world prices to value added at
domestic prices.