Taxes and subsidies on agricultural producers as elements of intersectoral transfer of resources: magnitude of the transfer and search for policy options.
Qureshi, Sarfraz Khan ; Ghani, Ejaz ; Mushtaq, Muhammad 等
INTRODUCTION
Public policies in many diverse fields have implications for the
transfer of resources between sectors. Administered agricultural prices,
taxes, subsidies, an overvalued currency and protection provided to
producers are examples of some of the policies that have been used by
many governments in mobilizing resources for development. From the
vantage point of assessing the past performance and development
prospects of the agricultural sector, it is useful to have an idea about
the direction and extent of the resource transfer from this sector. The
knowledge of the policy instruments used to bring about the transfer is
also important. While the size of the transfer is a measure of the
overall incentives being provided, the tools used for the transfer have
unique implications for efficiency, equity and growth outcomes. The
purpose of the paper is confined to: (i) an estimation of the magnitude
of the transfer for the period 1972-73 to 1986-87; and (ii)
identification, in broad terms, of the direction that the restructured
public policies may take.
II. NET FISCAL BURDEN
The fiscal burden on agricultural producers takes into account open
and concealed taxes and subsidies affecting agricultural producers in
both output and input markets. Open taxation of the agricultural sector
comprises of two broad categories of taxes. Land tax, agricultural
income tax and Ushr (an Islamic levy) are three taxes in the first
category that affect farmers directly as their disposable income is
reduced as a result of the imposition of these taxes. A number of
indirect taxes on agricultural commodities form the second category that
adversely affect prices received by agriculture. These comprise cesses
on different crops--mainly sugarcane and cotton, export duties on rice
and cotton and profits and/or losses of the Rice and Cotton Export
Corporations. The revenue from such taxes is, by far, more important in
magnitude than the direct taxes on farmers.
The agricultural producers in Pakistan have always been subject to
concealed taxes. (1) During the 1950s and 1960s, agricultural exporters
suffered an income loss through an overvalued exchange rate. After
devaluation in 1972, this source of concealed taxation was replaced to a
great extent by open taxes in the form of export duties on agricultural
exports and profits from government monopoly trading corporations. In
addition to the open taxes, farmers are forced to pay taxes (or receive
subsidy) if the prices of products sold by them are kept lower (higher)
than those that prevail in the international market. The size of the tax
(subsidy) to producers is measured by the difference between the value
of output at domestic prices and the value of output at world prices.
The rate of tax or subsidy for different crops can be measured by the
divergence of the Nominal Protection Coefficients (NPCs) from a value of
1. An NPC with a value greater than 1 implies a subsidy while an NPC of
value less than 1 implies a tax.
In the plethora of subsidies to the agricultural sector several
important direct (producer) development subsidies and concealed
subsidies on inputs have had a considerable impact on the overall
resource transfer between sectors. The important subsidies covered are
subsidies on: (1) fertilizer, (2)tube-wells, (3)plant protection, (4)
seeds, (5) electricity, (6)water, and (7) credit. The subsidies on
electricity, water and credit do not appear in government budgets. The
subsidies on other items are budgeted and paid through the development
budgets. It is for their inclusion in the development budget that they
are labelled as development subsidies in Pakistan.
A consolidated picture of taxes and subsidies shown in Table 1
throws up a number of conclusions which are briefly listed.
First, an unsatisfactory performance regarding resource
mobilization from agriculture is indicated. Net taxes on
farmer-producers record negative values in three out of fifteen years.
Net taxes as percent of value added from the crop sub-sector is
generally low excepting for a few years when the levels of concealed
taxation sharply increased due to increases in world prices of some
crops.
Second, although the yield from direct taxes on land and/or
agricultural produce has not declined in absolute terms yet it shows a
declining trend when measured as a proportion of agricultural value
added. The expectations of some observers that Ushr may in due course
become a significant source of revenue for poverty alleviation projects
in rural areas may not be realized in the light of experience of the
past five years. The assessments of, and collections from Ushr, have
been much lower than the estimated potential of this tax. The
inelasticity of the direct taxes on agriculture is a major structural
weakness in the tax structure.
Third, the revenue from taxes on agricultural commodities from
export duties and/or from the profits of state trading corporations has
been large in some years. However, this source of revenue exhibits a
large measure of instability and cannot be relied on to finance
development programmes on a continuing sustained basis.
Fourth, concealed taxation on agricultural commodities due
primarily to trade and exchange rate policies has been heavy. Like
export duties, it is also an unstable source of revenue. In fact, in
some years, the level of concealed taxation transforms itself into
subsidies to farmers. At the disaggregated commodity levels, this source
of revenue provides distorted incentives for farmers. Nominal Protection
Coefficients for different commodities imply widely divergent rates of
taxation or subsidization for crops. These coefficients for given crops
also change over time.
Fifth, open subsidies on inputs have grown in magnitude over time.
The government has eliminated subsidies on plant protection, seeds and
some other minor items. There is also a stated government policy goals
regarding the elimination of fertilizer subsidies. Despite this goal,
subsidies on fertilizers in the terminal year are high. There was a
restraint on the growth of fertilizer subsidies during 1981-82 to
1984-85 but this restraint seemed to have been relaxed in the last two
years of the study.
Sixth, concealed subsidies on irrigation, credit and electrified
tube-wells have increased significantly over the period of the study.
Water and Power Development Authority (WAPDA), through fuel adjustment
charges, has been successful in eliminating the subsidy on electricity
for the agricultural sector in some years. In the budget for 1988-89,
some steps in restraining the credit subsidy on production loans have
been announced. However, the singular policy failure has been in the
area of the subsidy on irrigation. The sharp increase in operation and
maintenance expenses for the upkeep of the vast canal system is
warranted. The subsidies on account of irrigation sub-head can be
restrained only if the water rates are increased.
III. BROAD DIRECTIONS FOR POLICY REFORMS
Our discussion on policy options for the taxation of the
agricultural sector would remain on the general level of broad
principles as it is difficult to suggest concrete reforms when the bulk
of the existing taxes and subsidies are concealed. However, our finding
that there has been an increasing trend of resource flow into
agriculture resulting in increased agricultural incomes suggested a need
for a more intensive taxation of agriculture in Pakistan. The burden of
direct taxes has shown a sharp declining trend despite the introduction
of Ushr since 1982-83. The indirect taxes on agricultural exports
through export taxes and the profits of government export corporations
have been used for the stabilization of prices and incomes rather than a
device for raising revenue for the government treasury. The yield from
these revenue heads has shown a large measure of instability and no
rising trend. The subsidies on agricultural inputs have also increased
both in absolute terms and relative to the value added in the
agricultural sector. Despite a floating exchange rate, the Rupee has
remained overvalued by about 20 percent. However, the extent of the
overvaluation is much less than was the case prior to the massive
devaluation of the Rupee in 1972. The extent of concealed taxation
through artificially low domestic prices for farm produce has also been
reduced and/or turned into subsidization by a closer alignment of
domestic prices to world prices.
While the case for a more intensive taxation of agriculture can
easily be made in view of the increased taxable capacity of the sector,
the question arises as to the appropriate method of taxing the
agricultural sector. There is a need to review and reduce the level of
both open and concealed subsidies on most agricultural inputs. The
subsidies on inputs which require to be popularized among the farming
community may, however, continue for a limited time only. An overvalued
currency and export duties are simple to administer but have large
adverse effects on resource use efficiency. Taxes of this type should be
discontinued. A tax on the value of land, an old favourite of
economists, needs to be made use of on a much larger scale than has been
the case in the past. The land tax is generally not shiftable. It
encourages owners of unused land to either use the land productively or
sell it to other people who will make productive use of the newly
acquired land. The administrative and political feasibility of the
proposal needs to be established by a detailed and in-depth study,
however.
Comments on "Taxes and Subsidies on Agricultural Producers as
Elements of Intersectoral Transfer of Resources: Magnitude of the
Transfer and Search for Policy Options"
I would like to thank the organizers of the meeting for inviting me
to discuss an interesting paper. Taxes and subsidies on agriculture,
which is the subject of the paper, have increasingly engaged the
attention of economists, lately as the budget deficit has assumed
alarming proportions and the search for new options for resource
mobilization has become quite intense.
I compliment the authors for having collected the vast amount of
data relating to various types of taxes and subsidies, from various
scattered sources, and analysing their incidence.
Open Taxation of the Agriculture Sector
The authors have identified the following instruments of direct
taxation of agriculture in Pakistan: (i) Land Tax (ii) Agricultural
Income Tax: and (iii) Ushr, which directly affect the farmers'
incomes.
In their discussion of direct taxes on agriculture, the authors
have rightly pointed out that agricultural income tax, as currently in
vogue in Pakistan, is misnamed and confusing as it is not a tax on
agricultural incomes but a graduated surcharge on land revenue collected
from the farmers.
The authors have correctly argued that yield from the land tax have
declined over time as with the introduction of Ushr in 1982, farmers
paying Ushr were exempted from the payment of land revenue.
Nevertheless, it may be noted that inspite of the exemption from land
revenue payments, granted to those paying Ushr, the revenue from land
tax did not fall that rapidly as was expected initially. It has been
pointed out that the Ushr collection during the last five years has been
about 86 percent of the assessment and only 20 percent of the reported
potential yield from this levy. However, the most relevant issue
relating to Ushr in the context of resource mobilization and development
financing is can the revenues collected from the Ushr levy be used for
financing general Government expenditure and development programmes.
This issue merits serious thought by those who are well versed with the
subject. To my understanding the uses of Ushr money have been prescribed
and may not be changed.
Taxes on Agricultural Crops
While discussing taxes on agricultural crops the authors have
discussed various commodity cesses such as sugar-cane and cotton cesses,
export duties on cotton and rice. In addition, they have included the
profits or losses of the Cotton Export Corporation (CEC) and Rice Export
Corporation of Pakistan (RECP) in their discussion on the subject. This
inclusion of profits and losses of the RECP and CEC along with various
commodity cesses needs reconsideration. The authors mention the
instability of the revenues from the commodity cesses and the profit and
loss of CEC and RECP. This instability stems partly from the
fluctuations in commodity production and partly from the prices
prevailing in international markets. The falling international prices of
rice and cotton besides the high incidentals of the CEC and RECP were
also responsible for the losses incurred by these corporations.
Indirect Taxes Paid by Agricultural Consumers
While apportioning the share of agriculture from the indirect taxes
representing import duties, sales taxes, etc. the distinction between
farm population and rural population needs to be kept in view as the
farm population is only a subset of the rural population. It is
significant to note that the incidence of indirect taxes paid both in
terms of per capita and as a percentage of value added in agriculture
has increased considerably over time.
Concealed Taxation of Agriculture
Concealed taxation of agriculture has been generally practised through an overvalued exchange rate and paying domestic producers prices
less than that providing in the international market. To provide the
evidence for such taxation, the authors have relied mainly in
calculating the Nominal Protection Coefficients (NPCs) for wheat,
basmati rice, IRRI rice, cotton and sugar-cane.
It may be emphasised here that NPCs, although relatively simple to
comprehend and calculate, nevertheless need to be interpreted rather
carefully. An NPC greater than one in the case of farm commodities does
not necessarily imply protection or subsidy to the producers for the
following reasons as the domestic border prices comprise at least 3
major components i.e. (i) cost of the produce, (ii) marketing and
processing expenses and (iii) transport and handling expenses. Thus,
higher NPCs could very well result from the high expenses entailed in
marketing, processing, etc.
The institutional arrangements for the exports, of farm produce
etc. in Pakistan are not very efficient involving very high expenses and
have frequently resulted in higher values of the resulting NPCs.
Open and Concealed Subsidies to Farmers
The authors point out that the size of the subsidy to the producer
is measured by the difference between the value of output at domestic
prices and the value of output at world prices. The economic subsidy on
various inputs, at least on those that are tradeable such as fertilizers
and pesticides and seed need to be worked out by following the above
definition. The economic subsidies need to be differentiated from the
budgetary subsidies as well and need to be treated separately. The
authors have mainly relied on the budgetary subsidies and ignored the
concept of economic subsidy.
Following the definition of economic subsidies, it would be really
interesting to find out that in case of fertilizers, pesticides etc. (i)
what part of the subsidy has been meant for the farmers? (ii) what
proportion has gone to the industry? and, (iii) what percentage was due
to the tied aid by the donors? These are, I think, important questions
and have not been touched upon in the paper.
The authors mention that the subsidy involved in irrigation water
charges could be calculated by comparing the prices of water charged by
the Government with either the marginal cost of tube-well water or the
market prices of tubewell water. I have some reservations to the use of
this approach for the following reasons:
(i) There is no single cost of tube-well water as it is likely to
vary across various regions. The flexibility in the use of tube-well
water is much greater while canal water use is characterized by
institutional rigidities.
(ii) As regards the operation and maintenance (O & M) charges,
it needs to be borne in mind that most of the water development projects
are multi-purpose and what really are the O & M charges for
irrigation is a question of judgement.
(iii) The irrigation network is a part of the socio-economic
infrastructure and are we charging the users of other infrastructure
accordingly?
(iv) To what extent are O & M charges a real and to what extent
are they padded?
(v) Should the farm sector be charged and penalized for the
inefficiencies and dubious practices of the irrigation and power
departments?
At the end, I would like to point out that the proposal of
instituting tax on the value of land, by the authors, needs to be
spelled out and carefully looked into.
I believe there is an urgent need for investment of time and
resources to find out further avenues of mobilising resources.
Abdul Salam
Agricultural Prices Commission, Islamabad
REFERENCES
Appleyard, Dennis R. (1987). "Report on Comparative
Advantage". Islamabad: Agricultural Prices Commission. (APCOM
Series No. 61)
Cheong, Kee Cheok, and Emmanuel H. D'Silva (1984).
"Prices, Terms of Trade and the Role of Government in
Pakistan's Agriculture". Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
(World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 643).
Gotsch, Carl, and Gilbert Brown (1980). "Prices, Taxes and
Subsidies in Pakistan Agriculture, 1960-76". Washington, D.C.: The
World Bank. (World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 387)
SARFRAZ KHAN QURESHI, EJAZ GHANI and MUHAMMAD MUSHTAQ *
* The authors are respectively, Joint Director and Staff Economists
at the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad. They are
grateful to Professor Syed Nawab Haider Naqvi, Director, Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics for continued inspiration and
stimulating discussions. The authors are also grateful to Dr Abdul
Salam, Division Chief, Agricultural Prices Commission and Dr Muhammad
Hussain Malik, Senior Research Economist, PIDE, for their useful
suggestions and comments. The paper is an abridged version of the paper
presented in the Fifth Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of
Development Economists. The reader is referred to the original paper for
a complete description of the nature of open and concealed taxes and
subsidies affecting the agriculture sector and for the estimation
procedures used in the computation of the value of resource transfers.
Table 1
Taxes and Subsidies in Agriculture Sector: A Consolidated Picture
(Million Rupees)
Taxesand Subsidies 1972-73 1973-74 1974-75
A. TAXES 879.30 905.40 810.80
A1. Open Taxes on Agricultural
Producers Direct Taxes 167.30 201.40 231.80
Land Revenue 167.00 196.00 228.00
Agriculture Income Tax 0.30 5.40 3.80
Ushr -- -- --
Indirect Taxes 712.00 704.00 579.00
Export Duty on Rice 128.00 464.00 333.00
Export Duty on Cotton 442.00 179.00 335.00
Profits of Rice Export
Corporation -- -- --
Profits of Cotton Export
Corporation -- -76.00 -228.00
Cotton Cess 120.00 110.00 115.00
Sugar-cane Cess 22.00 27.00 24.00
A2. Concealed Taxes on Agri.
Producers (SER) 1119.51 9533.06 7869.00
Wheat 462.56 1796.83 2254.56
Rice--Basmati 145.14 762.09 1725.08
Rice--Irri 160.48 4112.36 1920.28
Cotton 657.26 3371.55 869.86
Sugar-cane -305.93 -509.77 1099.22
A3. Taxes Paid by Agricultural
Producers (A1+A2) 1998.81 10438.46 8679.80
B. SUBSIDIES 481.00 224.00 793.00
B1. Open Subsidies 441.00 203.00 454.00
Fertiliter 288.00 118.00 326.00
Tube-wells 22.00 10.00 16.00
Plant Protection 128.00 63.00 112.00
Seeds 3.00 12.00 --
B2. Concealed Subsidies 40.00 21.00 339.00
Irrigation -25.00 -75.00 150.00
Agriculture Credit 23.00 37.00 34.00
Electricity 42.00 59.00 155.00
C. NET TAXES ON AGRICULTURAL
PRODUCERS (A3-B) 1517.81 10214.46 7886.80
Net Taxes on Agricultural
Producers as % Value-
added in Agriculture 6.93 36.37 23.52
Taxesand Subsidies 1975-76 1976-77 1977-78
A. TAXES 1258.00 508.00 596.00
A1. Open Taxes on Agricultural
Producers Direct Taxes 266.00 136.00 125.00
Land Revenue 260.00 136.00 125.00
Agriculture Income Tax 6.00 -- --
Ushr -- -- --
Indirect Taxes 992.00 372.00 471.00
Export Duty on Rice 241.00 58.00 --
Export Duty on Cotton 340.00 1.00 --
Profits of Rice Export
Corporation 353.00 57.00 114.00
Profits of Cotton Export
Corporation -61.00 142.00 220.00
Cotton Cess 90.00 80.00 101.00
Sugar-cane Cess 29.00 34.00 36.00
A2. Concealed Taxes on Agri.
Producers (SER) 5178.15 3054.67 10753.35
Wheat 1168.83 60.84 979.36
Rice--Basmati 754.80 -26.50 1650.53
Rice--Irri 318.57 -376.92 2503.76
Cotton 1266.51 4598.10 6979.35
Sugar-cane 1669.44 -1200.85 -1359.66
A3. Taxes Paid by Agricultural
Producers (A1+A2) 6436.15 3562.67 11349.35
B. SUBSIDIES 1271.00 956.00 1390.00
B1. Open Subsidies 897.00 562.00 1026.00
Fertiliter 607.00 87.00 617.00
Tube-wells 43.00 48.00 37.00
Plant Protection 241.00 424.00 347.00
Seeds 6.00 6.00 25.00
B2. Concealed Subsidies 374.00 394.00 364.00
Irrigation 189.00 169.00 113.00
Agriculture Credit 45.00 54.00 44.00
Electricity 140.00 171.00 207.00
C. NET TAXES ON AGRICULTURAL
PRODUCERS (A3-B) 5165.15 2606.67 9959.35
Net Taxes on Agricultural
Producers as % Value-
added in Agriculture 13.47 5.93 19.70
Taxesand Subsidies 1978-79 1979-80 1980-81
A. TAXES 538.00 1189.60 2087.30
A1. Open Taxes on Agricultural
Producers Direct Taxes 291.00 174.60 227.30
Land Revenue 291.00 172.00 226.00
Agriculture Income Tax -- 2.60 1.30
Ushr -- -- --
Indirect Taxes 247.00 1015.00 1860.00
Export Duty on Rice -- -- --
Export Duty on Cotton -- -- 500.00
Profits of Rice Export
Corporation 289.00 711.00 454.00
Profits of Cotton Export
Corporation -152.00 151.00 724.00
Cotton Cess 85.00 130.00 135.00
Sugar-cane Cess 25.00 23.00 37.00
A2. Concealed Taxes on Agri.
Producers (SER) 1001.64 2720.15 8241.80
Wheat 184.45 651.69 2521.84
Rice--Basmati 1844.50 1859.13 1675.04
Rice--Irri 1042.44 2200.77 1472.04
Cotton -22.69 691.47 1666.92
Sugar-cane -2047.06 -2682.91 905.96
A3. Taxes Paid by Agricultural
Producers (A1+A2) 1539.64 3909.75 10329.10
B. SUBSIDIES 2380.00 3047.00 3159.00
B1. Open Subsidies 1991.00 2703.00 2479.00
Fertiliter 1692.00 2454.00 2457.00
Tube-wells 24.00 2.00 20.00
Plant Protection 267.00 218.00 --
Seeds 8.00 29.00 2.00
B2. Concealed Subsidies 389.00 344.00 680.00
Irrigation 274.00 244.00 588.00
Agriculture Credit 48.00 116.00 180.00
Electricity 67.00 -16.00 -88.00
C. NET TAXES ON AGRICULTURAL
PRODUCERS (A3-B) -840.36 862.75 7170.10
Net Taxes on Agricultural
Producers as % Value-
added in Agriculture -1.55 1.39 10.00
Taxesand Subsidies 1981-82 1982-83 1983-84
A. TAXES 635.40 1837.40 1471.10
A1. Open Taxes on Agricultural
Producers Direct Taxes 287.40 427.40 435.10
Land Revenue 286.00 249.00 209.00
Agriculture Income Tax 1.40 1.40 1.10
Ushr -- 177.00 225.00
Indirect Taxes 348.00 1410.00 1036.00
Export Duty on Rice -- -- --
Export Duty on Cotton 150.00 462.00 265.00
Profits of Rice Export
Corporation 234.00 667.00 576.00
Profits of Cotton Export
Corporation -237.00 77.00 46.00
Cotton Cess 142.00 154.00 95.00
Sugar-cane Cess 59.00 50.00 54.00
A2. Concealed Taxes on Agri.
Producers (SER) 2963.25 6294.23 7626.36
Wheat 1963.52 2331.68 6123.74
Rice--Basmati 2004.82 2017.80 2269.33
Rice--Irri 932.20 -508.47 -555.46
Cotton -1253.39 1391.22 1686.23
Sugar-cane -683.90 1062.00 1897.48
A3. Taxes Paid by Agricultural
Producers (A1+A2) 3598.65 8131.63 9097.46
B. SUBSIDIES 2762.00 2912.00 2937.00
B1. Open Subsidies 1826.00 1980.00 1482.00
Fertiliter 1794.00 1948.00 1466.00
Tube-wells 24.00 24.00 16.00
Plant Protection -- -- --
Seeds 8.00 8.00 --
B2. Concealed Subsidies 936.00 932.00 1455.00
Irrigation 682.00 683.00 1084.00
Agriculture Credit 265.00 349.00 524.00
Electricity -11.00 -100.00 -153.00
C. NET TAXES ON AGRICULTURAL
PRODUCERS (A3-B) 836.65 5219.63 6160.46
Net Taxes on Agricultural
Producers as % Value-
added in Agriculture 100.00 5.56 644.00
Taxesand Subsidies 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87
A. TAXES 1377.10 -542.50 -1160.60
A1. Open Taxes on Agricultural
Producers Direct Taxes 505.10 459.50 365.40
Land Revenue 251.00 236.00 225.00
Agriculture Income Tax 1.10 0.50 0.40
Ushr 253.00 223.00 140.00
Indirect Taxes 872.00 -1002.00 -1526.00
Export Duty on Rice -- -- --
Export Duty on Cotton 300.00 834.00 84.00
Profits of Rice Export
Corporation 406.00 343.00 89.00
Profits of Cotton Export
Corporation -72.00 -2456.00 -1994.00
Cotton Cess 185.00 229.00 240.00
Sugar-cane Cess 59.00 48.00 55.00
A2. Concealed Taxes on Agri.
Producers (SER) 6046.77 -2066.33 3658.80
Wheat 4278.56 1782.00 8872.80
Rice--Basmati 3516.26 3960.00 5556.00
Rice--Irri -9.09 -1082.50 -1433.33
Cotton 4437.07 -1467.50 -2984.17
Sugar-cane -6176.03 -5258.33 -6352.50
A3. Taxes Paid by Agricultural
Producers (A1+A2) 7423.87 -2608.83 2498.20
B. SUBSIDIES 3737.00 4790.00 5294.00
B1. Open Subsidies 1517.00 2424.00 2044.00
Fertiliter 1501.00 2408.00 2026.00
Tube-wells 16.00 16.00 18.00
Plant Protection -- -- --
Seeds -- -- --
B2. Concealed Subsidies 2220.00 2366.00 3250.00
Irrigation 1456.00 1428.00 1811.00
Agriculture Credit 661.00 923.00 1064.00
Electricity 103.00 15.00 375.00
C. NET TAXES ON AGRICULTURAL
PRODUCERS (A3-B) 3686.87 -7398.83 -2795.80
Net Taxes on Agricultural
Producers as % Value-
added in Agriculture 3.15 -6.34 -2.29