Technological change and distribution of agricultural land: the case of Pakistan.
Chaudhry, M. Ghaffar
1. INTRODUCTION
It has been claimed in the literature that the Green Revolution
technology by its very nature tended to increase the concentration of
agricultural land in Pakistan [Alavi (1976); Falcon (1970); Gotsch
(1973) and Khan (1985)]. The view has very important implications for
the development of Pakistan's agriculture. Agricultural land being
the chief source of income in rural areas, a growing land concentration
implies a continuous deterioration in the distribution of rural income.
Empirical research has shown that productivity and labour input per acre
are inversely related to farm size [Naqvi, Khan and Chaudhry (1989) and
Chaudhry, Gill and Chaudhry (1985)]. As such, any increase in the size
of agricultural holdings would be conducive to a slower growth of
agricultural output and employment than would otherwise be the case. An
increasing control of a productive resource like land by large and
well-to-do farmers would endow them with sufficient economic, social and
political powers to frustrate any measures for the improvement of social
welfare of the rural masses.
The purpose of the present paper is to examine the trend of land
distribution in Pakistan and to assess the validity of the conclusion
that land distribution has deteriorated under the Green Revolution.
Accordingly the paper is divided into five Sections. In Section 2, a
brief review is presented of the literature which favours the conclusion
that under Green Revolution the concentration of agricultural land has
been on the increase. Section 3 empirically determines the trend of land
distribution on the basis of ownership, and operational holdings. Given
the improvement of land distribution as verified by statistical data,
Section 4 points to the fallacies of the arguments in the literature on
the subject and identifies the factors that have led to a greater
equality of land distribution in Pakistan with the progressive
advancement of the Green Revolution technologies over time. Section 5
summarises the conclusions of the present study.
2. AN OVERVIEW OF THE LITERATURE
The thesis that concentration of agricultural land has increased
instead of relying on any direct empirical evidence, is based on a
number of assumptions regarding the adoption pattern of Green Revolution
technology and its impact on the profitability of agriculture. Following
the initial adoption pattern, it was assumed, that large farmers, (1)
mainly because of their financial superiority, were in a better position
to adopt innovative methods and technologies and would, for the same
reason, continue to maintain the lead in this respect over their smaller
counterparts [Falcon (1970)]. As argued by Gotsch (1973), since the
potential for utilizing a more advanced technology is greater on large
holdings, it is only natural that adoption of advanced technology will
produce further land agglomeration. Another reason cited for the growing
land concentration is that technological concentration on large farms
has enabled the large farmers to gain substantial increases in
productivity and their reluctance to share these increases with their
tenants has often led to large-scale tenant evictions so that the lands
previously cultivated by tenants are now cultivated by the owners
themselves [Gotsch (19731, Alavi (1976), Falcon (1970) and Khan (1985)].
There is also the likelihood that large farmers, encouraged by the rapid
increase in their incomes and constrained by paucity of avenues for
productive investment outside agriculture purchased land on a fairly
large scale [Falcon (1970)]. Land purchases by large farmers may not
have been very difficult as large landowners are always in a position to
force small farmers to sell their land to them; and, of course, large
landowners are always eager to buy the land of poorer neighbours [Alavi
(1976) and Khan (1985)]. It has also been forcefully asserted by Khan
(1985) that the concentration of tubewells and tractors has provided
added incentives to large landowners to lease their neighbours'
land. Although the impact of all these factors on land distribution may
understandably have been significant, the studies reviewed above give no
quantitative estimates of the land that may have been redistributed under that impact.
Reference, however, may be made to two more studies that have tried
to quantify the impact of tractor introduction on farm size [McInerney
and Donaldson (1975) and Lockwood and Munir (1981)]. The two studies
have estimated that the average farm size more than doubled following
the purchase of tractors by large farmers. Of the more than 100 percent
increase in farm size, nearly 42 percent was attributed by McInerney and
Donaldson (1975) to self-cultivation of the land previously rented out,
24 percent to the land newly rented in, 12 percent to the land purchased
from others and the rest to the land newly brought under cultivation.
According to Lockwood and Munir (1981), the area previously rented out
(62 percent) and the area newly rented in (30 percent) were the major
contributions to the total increase in average farm size following
tractor purchases by large farmers.
If we accept the arguments and data presented by the studies
referred to above and also keep in mind the rapid progress made by
technological innovations in Pakistan, we may well agree with the
conclusion that, following the inception of Green Revolution in the
early Sixties, land distribution has deteriorated considerably (or land
concentration has increased notably) in Pakistan. But has this actually
happened? This is the question which we address in the next Section.
3. TREND OF LAND DISTRIBUTION
The trend in land distribution connotes changes in the ownership
and operational status of agricultural land by size. Since land
purchases are an addition to the size of ownership units and changes in
tenanted land are reflected in the size of operational holdings, a
comprehensive study of land distribution must be based on size
distribution of both ownership and operational holdings. Although land
shares and land-concentration ratios have often been used as alternative
measures of land distribution, a precise measurement of inequality and
its trend may not be permitted by the former approach, especially under
fluctuating and conflicting trends of land shares for various
percentiles of households and population. On the other hand, land
concentration ratios or Gini-coefficients may be helpful in measuring
inequalities fairly accurately and have therefore, been used for the
purpose of analysis in this study. Based on data from agricultural
censuses, Table 1 reports the trend of land distribution in Pakistan and
provinces since 1960.
Three major conclusions follow from Table 1. Firstly, operational
holdings are less skewed than ownership holdings. This is as expected,
because an overwhelming majority of the owners of large estates tend to
cultivate land with the help of tenants, breaking up a single ownership
unit into as many operational units as the number of tenants. Secondly,
land concentration, though high, improved markedly in the Green
Revolution period from 1960 to 1980. As Table 1 shows, there was a
definite and marked reduction in the land concentration of operational
holdings between 1960 and 1972. Although data about ownership of
household holdings for the Sixties are not available, empirical data on
individual ownership holdings show the same trend as mentioned above
[Naqvi, Khan and Chaudhry (1989)]. By contrast, the period from 1972 to
1980 was marked by insignificant changes in the distribution of
operational or ownership holdings. It may be noted that whatever
improvement or deterioration in the concentration is revealed by Table 1
between 1972 and 1980 may be attributed to intersecting (although not in
the relevant range) Lorenz curves [Naqvi, Khan and Chaudhry (1989)].
Finally, the trend of land distribution at the national level was
closely followed by the provinces despite large variations in provincial
concentration ratios. However, the distribution of land ownership
improved considerably in the province of Sind between 1972 and 1980.
It may be interesting to note that the above conclusions imply that
the Green Revolution has made some positive contributions to the nature
or quality of land distribution in Pakistan. For example, although
technological concentration during the initial years of the Green
Revolution was high because of the leadership role of large farmers,
land concentration improved considerably. Despite varying trends in the
adoption of Green Revolution among the provinces from time to time,
there are no significant variations in the trend of land distribution
across the provinces. Likewise a consistent trend of land distribution
of ownership and operational holdings suggests uniformity of changes in
land purchases and rented land from time to time and does not support
the arguments advanced in favour of a deteriorating land distribution.
It however, remains to be seen as to what is wrong with those arguments
and what other forces were responsible for shaping the trend in land
distribution in Pakistan.
4. FACTORS IN LAND DISTRIBUTION
The divergence between the empirically determined trend in land
distribution and the trend predicted by some of the studies, is
indicative of some fault in the arguments and reasoning of those
studies. One of the major defects in the arguments based on land lease
and land purchases by large farmers is that they begin with a wrong
premise. They unrealistically assume that the large farmers were the
sole beneficiaries of the Green Revolution and that land lease and land
purchases by large farmers were essential for deriving benefits from the
new technology. As a large body of evidence showing the widespread
impact of Green Revolution has been produced in a number of recent
studies [Chaudhry (1982), Naqvi, Khan and Chaudhry (1989) and
Pinstrup-Anderson and Hazell (1985)], there is no need to discuss the
above-mentioned, unsubstantiated premise here. Is there any need for the
large farmers to enter into land leases and land purchases to maximize
benefits? And do they really enter into such bargains? These are the
questions needing direct investigation.
It is a known fact that large farmers maintain vast reserves of
uncultivated land and they cultivate land only extensively. According to
the Pakistan Census of Agriculture 1980 [Government of Pakistan (1983)],
only about 67 percent of the farm area of large holdings was under
cultivation and only 86 percent of the actually cultivated area was sown to crops. Given this scenario, it would be far more rational for the
large farmers to cultivate their own land more effectively than to
engage in costly land purchases and land leasing from their small
neighbours. The invalidity of the "land purchase" argument may
also be obvious from the growing pressure of land reforms on large
farmers. In spite of the relative ineffectiveness of land reforms in
Pakistan, the fear of an effective land reforms and land confiscation constitutes a powerful factor in directing the large farmers'
emphasis away from land purchases. The argument that increased incomes
of large farmers under the Green Revolution are most likely to be
channelled into land purchases is equally untenable as there can be no
dearth of productive investment opportunities in a rapidly growing
economy like that of Pakistan, In view of the growing scarcities of
labour in Pakistan's agriculture despite mechanization [Chaudhry
(1986)], it will be highly uneconomical on the part of the large
farmers, who lack family labour to rent more land, evict tenants and
undertake self-cultivation.
In the case of Pakistan, the logic of "land lease" and
"land purchase" arguments can be challenged not only on
theoretical grounds but also on empirical grounds. The data on the area
under ownership and operational holdings by farm size, presented in
Table 2, enable us to verify the validity of some of the issues
discussed above.
The data in Table 2 point to several obvious conclusions. Firstly,
the movement in the ownership of agricultural land between 1972 and 1980
was inversely related to farm size and thus negates the possibility of
large-scale land purchases by large farmers. (2) Assuming that some of
the small farmers entered into distress sales, the ownership data
indicate that the buyers of the land offered for sale were in all
probability also the small farmers. It may, however, be pointed out that
redistribution of the area of ownership holdings from large to small
farmers may also be induced by land reforms and inheritance laws. All
else remaining constant, inheritance laws tend to subdivide large
holdings into smaller pieces with the passage of time. In view of the
increase in ownership area between 1972 and 1980, and assuming that the
census data are correct, it is reasonable to conclude that land
allotment to or purchases by small farmers of government land would be
another factor in the redistribution of area of ownership holdings.
Secondly, the operational farm area swells or contracts in relation
to the ownership farm area in various farm-size categories, depending
upon the amount of land rented in or rented out in the categories
concerned. As a general rule, rented out land is positive for the
category of large farmers and negative for small farmers. Between 1972
and 1980, the land rented out by large farmers fell only slightly
precluding the possibility of large-scale tenant displacements. Small
farmers continued to rent in land, although at a decreasing rate, to
supplement their small ownership holdings. These tendencies of large and
small farms seem to have been the result of the growing scarcities of
labour in the case of large farms and the alleviation of land constraint
by intensive cultivation under the Green Revolution in the case of small
farmers. Since large farmers are characterized by scarcities of family
labour and hired-labour wages have risen enormously over the period
under consideration [Chaudhry (1981)], the dependence of the large
farmers on the tenants as a cheap and assured source of labour supply is
only natural and inevitable [Majid and Nadvi (1987)]. In addition to
this economic necessity, large farmers are likely to retain their
tenants for political support in local and national elections.
Finally, self-cultivated land belonging to large owners either
decreased or increased only marginally while that belonging to small
owners increased rapidly. Although the total tenant-cultivated area fell
between 1972 and 1980, the fall was induced not by increased
self-cultivation of land on large farms but by that on farms of other
size categories. Assuming that the rise in the profitability of
agriculture under the Green Revolution was a factor in the cultivation
of land by owners themselves the pattern of self-cultivation seems to
suggest that it appealed more to small owners than to large ones.
Increased cultivation of land by owners themselves may also be the
result of normal process of economic development. As development
proceeds, owners of land may be forced to take up land cultivation
themselves because of the migration of rural labour to urban areas,
particularly the industrial ones. In the case of Pakistan, the labour
market in the rural areas doubly suffered from labour shortages during
the Seventies because of labour migration to domestic urban centres and
to international labour markets.
5. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
The purpose of this paper was to study the pattern of land
distribution with a view to checking the legitimacy of the thesis that
land distribution deteriorated under the Green Revolution in Pakistan as
well as of the arguments given in support of this thesis. The empirical
evidence cited in this study indicates that land distribution in
Pakistan either improved (as was the case from 1960 to 1972) or remained
unchanged (as was the case between 1972 and 1980). This trend in land
distribution serves to show that technological changes were accompanied
by significant improvements in land distribution between 1960 and 1980.
Large increases in the ownership area of small farmers between 1972 and
1980 vis-a-vis decreases in the ownership area of large farmers during
the same period render untenable the view that under the Green
Revolution land distribution had worsened because of land purchases by
large farmers. Substantial gains in the operational area of large
farmers due either to large areas of land rented in or to increased
self-cultivation appear to be unlikely in view of the continued and
rising dependence of those farmers on tenants. Favourable changes in the
distribution of ownership and operational holdings seem to be the result
of the widespread impact of Green Revolution on the profitability of
agriculture, growing labour scarcities, land reforms, inheritance laws
and the general trends in the economic development of Pakistan. The
Green Revolution accomplished the desirable redistribution of land from
large to small farmers which politically motivated and thus necessarily
ineffective programmes of land reforms failed to achieve. Whether the
Green Revolution has had the same redistributive impact as is expected
from an effective land-reform programme is a moot question which can be
adequately answered only when a large body of more reliable data is
available.
Comments on "Technological Change and Distribution of
Agricultural Land: The Case of Pakistan"
Dr Chaudhry has written a provocative paper. He has vigorously
attacked the well-known hypothesis which stipulates that the Green
Revolution has tended to increase the concentration of agricultural land
in Pakistan. Various arguments in support of the hypothesis have been
refuted by Dr Chaudhry. However, two additional arguments not considered
by Dr Chaudhry need also to be mentioned. First, that with heavy
investment in machinery and equipment by large farmers, an increase in
the size of holdings became an economic necessity to spread out the
heavy fixed costs. Secondly, that big landowners in Pakistan
deliberately chose to purchase rather big (45-55 h.p.) tractors at
subsidized prices which put a premium on increasing the farm size.
Using aggregate agricultural census data, Dr Chaudhry has attempted
to dismantle the said hypothesis. His empirical findings can be stated
briefly: During the Green Revolution period (1960-80), the concentration
of both ownership and operational holdings decreased instead of
increasing as stipulated in the hypothesis. Operational holdings were
found to be less skewed than the ownership holdings.
Having challenged the hypothesis, Dr Chaudhry makes the most
controversial statement that "the Green Revolution has accomplished
the desirable redistribution of land from large to small farmers".
In other words, according to him, the Green Revolution has accomplished
what the land reform was supposed to do. Not much evidence, however, has
been provided in support of the new hypothesis.
Relying on calculations in Table 2 of his paper, he has arrived at
two rather unusual conclusions: First, that between 1972 and 1980, the
land area leased out by the big landowners to tenants increased
substantially which would indicate an increased dependence of the large
farmers on tenants. This contradicts the earlier studies which
discovered that increased self-cultivation by big landowners had
resulted in the large-scale eviction of tenants. Secondly, that there
was a decrease in the area self-cultivated by large farmers between 1972
and 1980. This again runs counter to the earlier findings which showed
that widespread tractor cultivation had increased the area under
self-cultivation of the large farmers. In actual fact, however, both of
Dr Chaudhry's findings fail to be substantiated by the data in his
paper. This is due to an unfortunate data error in the table which has
distorted the Findings. The figure of total farm area in Table 7, column
2 for the size category 150 acres and above, in the Pakistan Census of
Agriculture, 1972, was erroneously picked up by Dr Chaudhry as 6482
(thousand) acres, instead of the real 4482 (thousand) acres. This
depressed the area leased out to tenants in 1972.
The rectified figures would show that the land area leased out by
large landowners to tenants actually decreased between 1972 and 1980,
which is in line with the earlier findings.
The next conclusion of Dr Chaudhry that there was a decline in the
area under self-cultivation of large farmers between 1972-1980 is also
open to question. The table on which this conclusion is based fails to
take notice of the cautionary statement in the 1980 Agricultural
Census--All Pakistan Report that the area resumed by the Government
under the Land Reforms of 1972 and 1977 is not accounted for in the 1972
census figures. If the census figures of land ownership of large farmers
were adjusted to reflect the resumption of 3.6 million acres by the
Government and then compared with the 1980 census figures, it would show
a significant increase in the owner-operated area of the large
landowners during the period 1972-1980.
Notwithstanding these weaknesses, Dr Chaudhry's paper stands
out as an important contribution to the current debate on the economic
and social consequences of the Green Revolution. Hopefully, it will lead
to a great deal of further research. In that sense it is a provocative
paper.
B. A. Azhar
Faculty of Agricultural Economics and Rural Sociology
University of Agriculture, Faisalabad.
REFERENCES
Alavi, Hamza (1976) The Rural Elite and Rural Development in
Pakistan. In Robert D. Steven et al. (eds) Rural Development in
Bangladesh and Pakistan. Honolulu: University Press of Hawaii.
Chaudhry, M. Ghaffar (1981) Rural Employment in Pakistan; Magnitude
and some Relevant Strategies. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics. (Research Report Series No. 131)
Chaudhry, M. Ghaffar (1982) Green Revolution and Redistribution of
Rural Incomes: Pakistan's Experience. The Pakistan Development
Review 21 : 3 173-205.
Chaudhry, M. Ghaffar (1986) Mechanization and Agricultural
Development in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 25 : 4 431-450.
Chaudhry, M. Ghaffar, Manzoor A. Gill and Ghulam Mustafa Chaudhry
(1985) Size-productivity Relationship in Pakistan's Agriculture in
the Seventies. The Pakistan Development Review 24 : 3 & 4 349-360.
Falcon, W. P. (1970) The Green Revolution: Second Generation
Problems. American Journal of Agricultural Economics December 52 :
698-710.
Gotsch, Carl H. (1973) Tractor Mechanization and Rural Development
in Pakistan. International Labour Review 107 : 2 133-166.
Khan, Mahmood Hasan (1985) Lectures on Agrarian Transformation in
Pakistan. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
(Lectures in Development Economics, No. 4)
Lockwood, B., and M. Munir (1981) Farm Mechanization in Punjab:
Development in Faisalabad District. Lahore: Pakistan Society of
Agricultural Engineering.
Majid, Nomaan, and Khalid M. Nadvi (1987) Agrarian Transition in
Sind: An Analysis of Interlinked Rural Factor Markets. The Pakistan
Development Review 26 : 4 433-444.
McInerney, J. P., and G. F. Donaldson (1975) The Consequences of
Farm Tractors in Pakistan. Washington, D. C.: The World Bank. (World
Bank Staff Working Paper No. 210)
Naqvi, Syed Nawab Haider, Mahmood Hasan Khan and M. Ghaffar
Chaudhry (1989) Structural Change in Pakistan's Agriculture.
Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
Pakistan, Government of (1975) Pakistan Census of Agriculture 1972:
All-Pakistan Report, Lahore: Agricultural Census Organization.
Pakistan, Government of (1983) Pakistan Census of Agriculture 1980:
All-Pakistan Report. Lahore: Agricultural Census Organization.
Pinstrup-Anderson, P., and B. A. Hazell (1985) The Impact of the
Green Revolution and Prospects for the Future. Food Reviews
International 1 : 1 1-25.
(1) Following the general literature, a large farm, estate or
holding in this study is defined as a unit of 50.0 acres or more. A
small farm or holding, on the other hand, has an area of less than 12.5
acres.
(2) Due to lack of data on ownership holdings for 1960, it is not
possible to consider changes in land ownership or those in land leases
between 1960 and 1972. The analysis is, therefore, restricted to changes
between 1972 and 1980.
M. GHAFFAR CHAUDHRY, Dr Chaudhry is Chief of Research at the
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
Table 1
Land Concentration Ratios for Operational and
Ownership Holdings of Households
Land Concentration Ratios
Type of Holdings/
Pakistan and Provinces 1960 1972 1980
A. Operational Holdings
1. Pakistan 0.62 0.52 0.53
2. Punjab 0.59 0.49 0.51
3. Sind 0.51 0.43 0.47
4. NWFP 0.73 0.64 0.64
5. Balochistan 0.71 0.64 0.62
B. Ownership Holdings
1. Pakistan -- 0.66 0.65
2. Punjab -- 0.63 0.62
3. Sind -- 0.69 0.63
4. NWFP -- 0.68 0.69
5. Balochistan -- 0.69 0.68
Source: Nagvi, Khan and Chaudhry (1989).
Table 2
Area of Ownership and Operational Holdings,
Area Leased * and Self-cultivated Area by
Farm Size for 1972 and 1980
Farm Area
Farm Size Holdings of Ownership
Categories Holdings
1972 1980
Under 1.0 Acres 135 150
1.0 - 5.0 Acres 3064 3721
5.0 - 12.5 Acres 6967 8726
12.5 - 25.0 Acres 6945 8276
25.0 - 50.0 Acres 6948 7333
50.0 - 150.0 Acres 8590 8723
150.0 Acres and
Above 8870 7484
Farm Area
Farm Size Holdings of Operational
Categories Holdings
1972 1980
Under 1.0 Acres 77 89
1.0 - 5.0 Acres 2485 3230
5.0 - 12.5 Acres 13338 12855
12.5 - 25.0 Acres 13061 11617
25.0 - 50.0 Acres 9215 8386
50.0 - 150.0 Acres 7402 6913
150.0 Acres and
Above 4482 4004
Area
Farm Size Holdings Leased-out
Categories by Owners
1972 1980
Under 1.0 Acres 58 61
1.0 - 5.0 Acres 579 491
5.0 - 12.5 Acres -6371 -4129
12.5 - 25.0 Acres -6116 -3341
25.0 - 50.0 Acres -2267 -1053
50.0 - 150.0 Acres 1188 1810
150.0 Acres and
Above 4388 3480
Area
Farm Size Holdings Self-cultivated
Categories by Owners
1972 1980
Under 1.0 Acres 60 78
1.0 - 5.0 Acres 1556 2267
5.0 - 12.5 Acres 5288 6908
12.5 - 25.0 Acres 5904 6823
25.0 - 50.0 Acres 5024 5444
50.0 - 150.0 Acres 5000 5319
150.0 Acres and
Above 3556 3434
Source: Calculations based on data in Government of Pakistan (1975)
and (1983). * As a matter of principle area leased-in and
leased-out must be identically the same. The equality does not hold
in the present case as some of the land could also be leased from
government departments.