Modeling industrial growth and agglomeration economies in the manufacturing sector of Pakistan.
Chaudhary, M. Aslam
The uneven distribution of production and consumption is one of the
several problems being faced by the less developed countries (LDCs). The
governments of these countries are pursuing multidimentional policies to
develop the backward areas and to put a check on overcrowded cities. For
example, in Pakistan National Development Finance Corporation (NDFC) has
been established to promote industries in backward areas. Moreover, tax
holidays, import facilities and loans on easy terms are some of the
devices which are being used to promote the backward regions. Besides,
Lahore and Karachi are facing serious economic problems due to rapid
urbanization. Their population is growing I percent to 2 percent above
the national growth rate of population. (1) On the other hand, several
geographical locations are still backward, despite policy measures taken
by the public sector. (2) It is important that, if these policies fail
to improve the situation, a better rationale should be explored in this
respect.
The purpose of this study is to identify the sources of industrial
concentration in Pakistan. Besides, we will be looking at reasons for
the concentration of industries at certain locations. One way to explain
this phenomena is through agglomeration economies. We will develop a
model to study this event. If our model can explain the increasing
returns to scale, which is a way to measure agglomeration economies, (3)
then, we may be able to utilize this knowledge to provide a base for
policy formulation to develop the backward areas, as well as, for
efficient use of public finance.
Agglomeration economies (AE) relate to those factors which produce
"centralizing effects". It is the economies of size and
concentration. Of course, there are several other factors like markets,
urbanization, inputs and infrastructure facilities which do lead to the
clustering of manufacturing units at particular locations. However, (AE)
may be one of the major sources for this event. In brief, (AE) may be
decomposed as follows:
(i) Urbanization economies (market size and inputs);
(ii) Internal scale economies;
(iii) Localization economies; and
(iv) Infrastructure economies.
It is only recently that some serious attempts have been made to
quantify the concentration of industrialization. Shefer (1973),
classified it into internal and external economies. Positive internal
economies will be realized when expansion in the scale of an enterprize
leads to decreasing average cost. The external economies result from the
scale of urban areas, decreasing input cost, concentration of
industries, urbanization and infrastructure facilities.
The study of the above events is important for several reasons.
Most LDCs industries are concentrated in a few areas, while other areas
remain underdeveloped. The policies introduced to achieve balanced
growth, by providing incentives like tax holidays, infrastructure
facilities etc., have been unsuccessful. (4) Since one of the goals of
public policies in LDCs is to promote 'even' geographical
development, it requires government intervention for the removal of
bottlenecks, (5) These objectives may be achieved by direct government
intervention, regulation or through competition. Therefore, we want to
study the hypothesis whether there agglomeration economies exist in the
manufacturing sector which may be a source of industrial concentration.
Thus, if we are able to identify the existence of agglomeration
economies, the government could introduce policies to increase the
peoples' welfare.
This study has been organized as follows. Section II of this paper
provides a theoretical background and description of the model. The
results and empirical outcomes have been discussed in Section III.
Section IV conclude with a discussion on policy implications, derived
from the theoretical and empirical findings.
II. THEORETICAL BACKGROUND AND THE MODEL Most location theories are
explained by using data of the developed countrie which have rarely been
applied to less developed countries (LDCs). Shefer (1973) and Carlino
(1980) have attempted to utilize the production function approach to
explain such events. Dhrymes (1965) provided empirical rationale for
these events.
In applying the CES production function to identify AE in the
developing countries we face the problem of restricted economies. (6)
The economies of LDCs may differ from developed economies in market
competition, rigidities in the system and other bottlenecks for free
growth. They may also not fulfil the conditions that the factors of
production are paid according to their marginal productivities. However,
we may assume these conditions for the LDCs as long as a country has an
unrestricted investment environment and an open economy. Furthermore,
the public sector participates in business as a competitor. Moreover,
factors of production enjoy free mobility. We believe that given free
mobility of the factors of production, a mixed economic system, a
dominant private sector, significant size of its foreign trade, and an
unrestricted investment environment in Pakistan, the neoclassical type
framework may be utilized to study the above stated hypothesis.
A pioneering article by Solow, Minhas, Arrow and Chenery
(SMAC)(1961), examined the invariant returns to scale. To study
Agglomeration Economies (AE), we need to study increasing returns to
scale which may be derived from the CES type production function.
Assume that the relationship between wages and output per
worker/hour is as given below:
W = A [(Q/L).sup.[beta] ... ... ... ... (1)
and that:
Q = F (K, L) ... ... ... ... (2)
Where
W = Wages;
Q = Output;
L = Labour; and
K = Capital.
If we assume constant returns to scale and perfect competition in
the market, then Equation (2) can generate a functional form.
Q = F (K, L) = A [[[alpha][K.sup.-e] + (1-[alpha]) [L.sup.-e]]-1/e]
... (3)
Where 'A' is efficiency parameter '[alpha]' is,
(0 [less than or equal to] [alpha] [less than or equal to] 1),
distribution parameter, 'e' is substitution parameter.
Assuming profit maximization and production function of homogenous degree 'h', Dhrymes (1965) showed that Equation (2)can be
rewritten as given below:
w = [AQ.sup.[beta]] [L.sup.[alpha]] ... ... ... ... (4)
When [alpha] = -[beta], it includes Equation (1). Now with some
modification we can generate CES type production function.
Q = F(K, L) = [L.sup.h] F(K/L) = A(t)[[[THETA].sub.1] (t)
[K.sup.hg] + [[THETA].sub.2] (t), [L.sup.hg].sup.1/g] ... (5)
In this equation '[[THETA].sub.i]' is distribution
parameter, 'h' stands for homogeneity and 'g' is the
substitution parameter. Given this, Equation (4) can be rewritten as:
W = A [(Q/h).sup.[beta]] - ([alpha] + [beta]h) ... ... ... (6)
Equation (6) can be rearranged as:
W = A [Q.sup.[beta]] x [L.sup.([alpha] + [beta]h - [beta]h]) ...
... ... (6.1)
Let:
S (h) = [alpha] + [beta]h ... ... ... (7)
Now if we define S(h) = [alpha] + [beta]h then the Dhryme's
model reduces to the SMAC, CES type production function, when h = 1 [xi]
S(h) = 0. Let 'S' take a simple function form:
S (h) = h - 1 ... ... ... ... (8)
Now setting Equation (7) equal to Equation (8) and solving for (h).
We have:
h - 1 = [alpha] + [beta]h ... ... ... ... (9)
Thus:
h = 1 + [alpha]/1 - [beta] ... ... ... ... (9.1)
We can estimate 'h', increasing returns to scale or (AE)
from Equation (4). Thus, for estimation, we transform Equation (4) into
log form.
Log [W.sub.ij] = log A + [beta] log [Q.sub.ij] + [L.sub.ij] +
[U.sub.ij] ... ... (10)
Where subscripts refer to ith manufacturing industry at jth
location.
For further verification we may also adopt another model based on
Solow's technological change (1957) and Arrow (1962), as follows.
Q/L = [AW.sup.[alpha]] [Q.sup.[beta]] ... ... ... ... (11)
Where
[beta] = Z (1 - [alpha])
In this model ([alpha]) is the elasticity of substitution and Q is
the proxy for cumulated experience. In this model (AE) is (1 + z).
For estimation purposes, we apply OLSQ to the logarithmic form of
Equation (11). Let us call it model 2.
Log (Q/L) = log A + [alpha] log [W.sub.ij] + [beta] log [Q.sub.ij]
+ [U.sub.ij] ... ... ... (12)
To estimate Equations (10) and (12), cross-sectional data may be
used for a specific year. We test the hypothesis that in Equation (9.1),
h > 1. If so, then, there exist AE, which will provide a base for
government policy for industrialization of backward areas by providing
AE incentives. In Equation (12) AE is (1 + z), which may also be
estimated from cross-sectional data. (7)
III. EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
The Equations (10) and (12) are estimated for major industries in
the main industrial districts in Pakistan. (8) The cross-sectional data
for the year 1984-85, taken Government of Pakistan (1989). For
estimation, ordinary least squares is applied to the logarithmic forms
of the models. The results of the regressions are presented in Table 1.
The empirical results indicate that all the coefficients are
significant at better than ninety-five percent level of confidence, for
all industries, except for food manufacturing. The '[beta]'
coefficient for food manufacturing was also significant at the
ninety-five percent level of confidence. However, '[alpha]'
coefficient was significant at ninety percent level of confidence. All
these coefficients provide an explanation of the event and the models
performed well.
Table 1 indicates that for model 1, all the industries axe enjoying
increasing returns to scale. The values of "h' are greater
than one, which implies that there exist agglomeration economies in all
the industries. The values of [R.sup.2] are also better than 0.90 for
all the industries, except for food manufacturing. The value of
[R.sup.2] for food manufacturing is 0.60, which means that the variables
utilized explain the event by 60 percent. However, the value of
'h' is the highest among all the industries. (9)
The results of model 2, show that the values of 'h' are
also greater than one, which indicates that there exist agglomeration
economies in all the industries and they are enjoying increasing returns
to scale. It confirms our findings of the model one that there exist AE
in the manufacturing industries in Pakistan.
We have also identified urbanization economies, by applying both
the models, based upon the entire manufacturing sector as a unit of
observation. The coefficients of the regression equations are valid at
better than ninety-five percent level of significance. Thus, it seems to
indicate that agglomeration, as well as, urbanization economies are
sources for concentration of manufacturing units at certain locations in
Pakistan. It may be noted that we have not attempted to decompose different economies which are part of AE. However, our models did
identify well the AE and urbanization economies.
IV. CONCLUSION
Most of the studies have explained that AE is a phenomena of
developed countries. However, our study has revealed that AE also exists
in developing countries, like Pakistan. Our study seems to indicate that
the increasing returns to scale is a phenomena for concentration of
industries in Pakistan. There exist agglomeration, as well as,
urbanization economies.
As far as policy implications for LDCs are concerned, we may
suggest that public policies may be amended according to the local
environment. Our findings have indicated that industrial zones may be
established by providing proper industrial environment. In other words,
if tax holidays, tax free zones etc., fail to develop a certain region,
it may be possible to develop backward areas by industrializing that
region. It could be done by generating AE at a specific location. The
government may introduce public goods industrial units at a specific
location and thus it may generate AE to attract other industries from
the private sector. By doing so, backward areas may be brought forward
into the mainstream. Besides, it could be extended for balanced growth.
By similar policy actions, the public sector may also generate a
competitive environment for development. Further research in these areas
may strengthen these findings, which may provide further support for
such public policies to develop backward areas.
Comments on "Modeling Industrial Growth and Agglomeration
Economies in the Manufacturing Sector of Pakistan"
The study addresses the important issue of industrial concentration
in Pakistan. It is a well-known fact that industrialization in Pakistan
has led to the emergence of a few enclaves in which industrialization
has taken place while the world outside these enclaves has not changed
much. This phenomenon entails a number of socioeconomic problems.
Given this background the title and introduction of this paper
catch the eyes of the reader as they give the impression that the study
would present and estimate a model which would relate industrial
concentration to industrial growth and also to some policy variables.
But actually the paper does not meet all these expectations because it
is primarily concerned with statistically verifying and quantifying the
phenomenon of industrial concentration.
For this purpose, the author estimates two equations. From the
estimated Equation (11) he calculates the value of parameter h. This
parameter measures the degree of homogeneity of an extended version of
the CES production function which is modified to take care of market
imperfections. If we look at Equation (11), we can see that after
estimation it cannot be differentiated from the standard Equation which
is commonly sued for indirectly estimating the elasticity of
substitution of an ordinary CES production function. So I wonder how can
one be definite about whether the estimated coefficients are the
parameters of an ordinary CES production function or those of a
Dhrymes-type extended CES production function. As far as Equation (13)
is concerned, I have to take it for granted since the author has not
given much explanation of its theoretical underpinnings.
On the basis of his results, the author reaches three main
conclusions. One, increasing returns to scale prevail in the industries
he has studied, two, he has identified urbanization economies and,
three, his estimated coefficients according to him provide
"strong" explanation of the phenomenon of industrial
concentration. Now, even if increasing returns to scale prevail in
certain industries, it is not clear how does it necessary imply the
presence of industrial concentration because other factors also
influence returns to scale. It would also have added to our knowledge if
the author had clarified how one could identify urbanization economies
from other types of economies in such an aggregative framework. I also
feel it difficult to agree with the claim that the estimated
coefficients provide "strong" explanation of industrial
concentration. In my opinion they, at the most, statistically verify and
quantify the presence of this phenomenon.
The last section of the paper presents some recommendations for
government policy. While these recommendations may be very useful, one
wonders how do they directly follow from the findings of this study.
Overall, this is a commendable paper because it draws our attention to
an important problem of our country.
Najam us Saqib
Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics, Islamabad.
Appendix Table 1
Industry/Coefficient [alpha] [beta] [R.sup.2] DW
1. Textile Manufacturing 1.12 1.203 0.88 1.20
(8.47) (10.06)
2. Food/Beverages and Tobacco 0.21 0.89 0.85 2.30
Manufacturing (2.11) (5.99)
3. Metal Products and Machinery 0.96 1.07 0.76 2.50
Equipment Manufacturing (10.81) (13.01)
4. Food Manufacturing 0.14 0.46 0.53 1.40
(1.50) (4.80)
Model : 2 Log [(Q/L).sub.ij] = Log A + [alpha] Log [W.sub.ij] + [beta]
Log [Q.sub.ij + [u.sub.ij
Appendix Table 2
Industry [beta] [alpha] [R.sup.2] DW
1. Textile Manufacturing 0.32 0.74 0.98 1.30
(4.19) (8.47)
2. Food/Beverages and Tobacco 0.21 0.89 0.89 2.30
(2.11) (5.91)
3. Metal Products and 0.57 0.497 0.95 1.70
Machinery Equipment (3.65) (2.89)
4. Food Manufacturing 0.42 0.54 0.55 2.21
(1.62) (1.52)
5. Chemical/Rubber and Plastic 0.26 0.75 0.92 2.30
Manufacturing (2.40) (4.91)
Model : 1 Log [W.sub.ij] = log A + [beta] Log [Q.sub.ij] + [alpha] Log
[L.sub.ij] + [U.sub.ij]
Appendix Table 3
All Industries
[alpha] [beta] [R.sup.2] DW
1. Model : 1 1.03 1.18 0.89 1.80
(10.81) (13.01)
2. Model : 2 0.30 0.81 0.98 1.70
(4.66) (10.60)
Author's Note: I am indebted to Dr Ashfaque H. Khan and Mr
Khurram Azad Khan for the IR valuable Comments on the first draft of
this paper. The views expressed entirely belong to me, not in any case
to the organization I am affiliated with.
REFERENCES
Arrow, K. J. (1962) The Economic Implication of Learning by Doing.
Review of Economic Studies.
Carlino, G. A. (1980) Economies of Scale in Manufacturing
Locations..... Urban Studies.
Dhrymes, P. T. (1965) Some Extensions and Tests for CES Class of
Production Function. Review of Economics and Statistics 67 : 357-366.
Pakistan, Government of (1988) Census of Manufacturing Industries,
(1984-85) Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Pakistan, Government of (1988) Economic Survey, 1983-84 to 1985-86.
Ministry of Finance, Economic Advisor's Wing.
Pakistan, Government of (1989) Census of Manufacturing Industries.
Islamabad: Federal Bureau of Statistics.
Shefer, D. (1973) Localization Economies in the SMSAs, A Production
Foundation Analysis. Journal of Regional Science.
Solow, R. M. (1957) Technical Change and the Aggregate Production
Function. Review of Economics and Statistics 39 : 312-332.
Solow R. M., H. B. Minhas, K. Arrow and H. B. Chenery (1961)
Capital Labour Substitution and Economic Efficiency. Review of Economics
and Statistics 43 : 228-232
Tylant, R. (1977) Agglomeration of Manufacturing in Detroit.
Journal of Regional Science 17 : 1.
(1) The overall population growth in Pakistan is 3.1 percent.
However, the largest cities are growing at a rate of 4 percent to 4.5
percent per annum.
(2) The public sector has introduced several economic polities to
develop the backward areas by providing incentives for
industrialization. These incentives include, tax holiday, tax free
zones, concession in import of inputs etc. The province of Baluchistan
is lagging behind other provinces. See also by the same author (1989).
(3) For details see Tylant (1977), Shefer (1973).
(4) In Pakistan, industrial units are concentrated at few locations
in the each province. Most of the districts and interior of the
provinces are underdeveloped. Even, the regional production activities
are concentrated at few points.
(5) There are several bottlenecks for balanced economic growth. The
income inquality, monopolies in production, privileged loans, black
marketing and tax evasion are some of the diseases which require public
sector's interference. Stiff, Pakistan's economy is somewhat
open.
(6) For developed countries it could be assumed that their markets
are close to perfect competition. However, it is relatively less logical
to assume the same for developing countries.
(7) Also refer to SMAC (1961). Capital and Labour Substitution and
Economic Efficiency. (1961) Review of Economics and Statistics.
(8) Sample size varies for each industry from 31 to 15
observations, based on heavily industrialized districts/cities.
(9) The Durban Watson (DW) statistics is also satisfactory.
However, we may not pay much attention to DW, since we are not focusing
on forecasting.
M. ASLAM CHAUDHARY, The author is Assistant Chief, Planning and
Development Division, Islamabad.
Table 1
Agglomeration Economies in the Manufacturing Industries
in Pakistan (1984-85)
Model: 1 h = 1 +
Industry [alpha]/1 - [beta] [R.sup.2] DW
1. Textile Manufacturing 2.49 0.98 1.30
2. Chemical, Rubber and
Plastic 2.40 0.92 2.30
3. Food, Beverages and
Tobacco 2.40 0.89 2.30
4. Metal Products and
Machinery 3.48 0.95 1.70
5. Food Manufacturing 3.66 0.60 2.30
Model: Model: 2 h = 1 + z [R.sup.2] DW
1. Textile Manufacturing 1.56 0.88 1.20
2. Food, Beverages and
Tobacco 3.80 0.85 2.30
3. Metal Products and
Machinery 1.55 0.76 2.50
4. Food Manufacturing 1.40 0.53 1.40
Urbanization Economies
Al Industries
1. Model: 1 2.59 0.98 1.80
2. Model: 2 1.57 0.89 1.80