Do third world immigrants impose a cost on Canadian public treasury?
Akbari, Ather H.
INTRODUCTION
The recent rise in Third World immigrant flows into the U.S. and
Canada has raised interest in the analysis of immigrant's impact on
host nations. Among the various economic issues addressed in the
literature are the immigrant's impact on the public treasury, the
employment and income distribution effects, and the performance of
immigrants in the labour market. The purpose of the present paper is to
provide some evidence of the impact on Canadian public finances from
immigrant flows from various world sources.
In Canada, a popular view argues that immigration should be
encouraged from countries with similar cultural values as Canada. It is
held that such immigrants have greater assimilative capacity and are
likely to possess skills required in the Canadian labour market. (1)
Despite this concern over the immigrants' country of origin, no
study to date has been conducted in Canada to provide an economic
justification for giving any country preference. The present study is an
attempt to fill this gap. To this end, a life-cycle model 'for the
consumption of public services and payment of taxes is estimated for
immigrant households from various source countries. The public services
consumption and tax payments of immigrant groups are then compared to
those of non-immigrants. Finally, the net transfer balances of each of
the immigrant groups with the non-immigrant population are provided.
IMMIGRANT SUB-GROUPS
Four major source areas of the immigrant population are identified.
These are: (1) the United States, (2)the United Kingdom, (3)Western
Europe, (2) and (4) Asia, Africa, South and Central America including
the Caribbean.
The above classification of immigrants focuses on some factors
which may differentially affect immigrant performance in Canada. Chief
among these factors is language. Our data indicate that, for nearly all
U.S. and U.K. immigrant groups, household heads reported English as
their mother tongue. The comparable figure for households from Asia,
Africa, South and Central America is 40 percent and for those from
western Europe is less than five percent.
Another comparable factor between individual immigrant groups is
the state of technology in their place of origin. Whereas the United
States has a similar or more advanced technology, the United Kingdom and
Western Europe have a similar or slightly inferior technology when
compared to Canada. Asia, Africa, and South and Central America
(including the Caribbean) usually have a less sophisticated technology
to work with.
ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
The life-cycle net benefits hypothesis has been tested for the U.S.
immigrants by Simon (1984) and for Canadian immigrants by Akbari (1989).
The present study is based upon a similar analysis using data for
immigrants of various world origins residing in Canada. The impact of an
immigrant household on the non-immigrant household is assessed by
obtaining estimates of public services consumption and tax payments by
immigrant households of different duration of stay in Canada. Due to
space limitations, we will not provide details of our estimation technique and the assumptions involved as these can be referred to by
the interested reader in Akbari (1989) or Simon (1984). In sum, the
transfer balance between immigrants and non-immigrants has been obtained
with and without allowance for the public goods contribution by
immigrants and are summarised in Equations 1 and 2 presented below:
[NB.sub.in] = ([R.sub.n] - [R.sub.i]) + ([T.sub.i] - [T.sub.n]) (1)
[NB.sub.in] = ([R.sub.n] - [R.sub.i]) + ([T.sub.i] - [T.sub.n]) +
[aT.sub.n] (2)
Where [NB.sub.in] is the net balance of public funds transfer from
an immigrant household to a non-immigrant household, [R.sub.i] and
[R.sub.n] represent the amount of public services consumed by an
immigrant and a non-immigrant household respectively, [T.sub.i] and
[T.sub.n] represent the amount of taxes paid by an immigrant and a
non-immigrant household respectively, and a is the percentage of
expenditures on a pure public good out of total public expenditures.
Thus Equation 2 calculates the transfer balance by accounting for public
goods financing by immigrants.
DATA
The study is based on microdata obtained from the household/family
file of the one percent public use sample drawn from the 1981 Canadian
Census of Population. (3) This data file permits a detailed demographic
breakdown of both the immigrant and non-immigrant groups. In addition,
some secondary data had to be employed to compute values for certain
variables. The units of analysis are a census family or a non-family
person aged 15 years or above.
The analysis pertains to the calendar year 1980 since the 1981
Census collected information on earnings, consumption of government
transfer payments and labour force activity for 1980. The immigrant
cohorts that arrived in Canada upto the year 1979 are considered.
Immigrant families where only the wife is an immigrant are excluded from
the analysis in order to partially avoid double-counting. (4)
DISCUSSION OF RESULTS
The results of our computations using both Equations 1 and 2 are
summarised in Table 2. Table 1 presents an overview of those
calculations by summarising estimated results of public services
consumption and tax payment by immigrant households of different years
of entry.
The components of public services considered in this study include
government transfer payments, educational services and health care
services. These three items comprised around half of total government
expenditure in 1980 (5) and are expected to be affected by
characteristics (especially age) that differentiate immigrants from
non-immigrants. (6)
The tax estimates have been obtained by using the average 1980
earnings for each cohort from the census microdata and obtaining
estimates of tax incidence by various income levels.
Computations of public services consumption and tax payment by each
cohort are discussed in Akbari (1988, 1989).
For statistical conciseness, we summarise estimated results for
public services consumption in Table 1 by computing the ratio of public
services consumed by each immigrant cohort to the amount consumed by the
non-immigrant population. (7) For convenience, the ratio is termed the
consumption ratio. A greater than unity consumption ratio implies that
an immigrant household's average consumption of public services is
higher than that of a non-immigrant household. Conversely, a less than
unity consumption ratio implies that the average consumption by an
immigrant household is less than that of a non-immigrant household.
The estimated tax payment results for each cohort are summarised
likewise by computing a tax ratio with implications similar to the
consumption ratio for values above and below unity.
In each case it is important to compare the length of stay in
Canada after which the public services consumption and tax payment by a
particular immigrant cohort begins to exceed that by non-immigrants.
THE NET EFFECT: TAXES AND SERVICES
Table 2 presents estimates of overall transfer balance obtained by
employing Equations 1 and 2 and the results of Table 2. A positive
balance implies that non-immigrants are net recipients of public funds
from the immigrants. A negative balance implies that immigrants are net
recipients of public funds from non-immigrants. (8) Again, in each case
it is important to note when the transfer balance becomes positive.
The Table 2 results have been utilized in Table 3, to report the
net present values to the non-immigrant population of an average
immigrant household entering Canada in 1980 with characteristics similar
to the present immigrant stock. This is done under the assumption that
immigrant cohorts by various dates of entry represent different ages in
the life-cycle. The Canadian relevant real discount rate for the year
1980 was 2.5 percent and the risk-adjusted real discount rate was 5
percent. The present values can be compared with the 1980 non-immigrant
household employment earnings of $17,311.
As shown in Table 3, with the exception of West Europeans, all
immigrant households are profitable investment for native-born
Canadians. The West Europeans are profitable investment only when the
stream of transfers resulting from them is discounted at a lower rate
and their public goods contribution is also counted. Households from the
United Kingdom provide the highest net benefits; followed by the U.S.
immigrants. Immigrants from the "Third World" countries of
Asia, Africa, and South and Central America, initially impose a cost on
Canadians; however, when analysed over their life-cycle, the performance
of these immigrants is comparable to those from the United States and
the United Kingdom.
In sum, the present study has demonstrated some evidence to suggest
that concerns over rising immigrant flows from the Third World countries
may not be justified on economic grounds.
Comments on "Do Third World Immigrants Impose a Cost on
Canadian Public Treasury?" *
The author has selected an important topic for analysis which has
lately been the main focus of attention for American and Canadian
policy-makers. Although, the cost-benefit analyses of population
movements play a crucial role in formulating the host countries'
immigration policies yet little research has so far been done on the
topic. This very fact makes the author's attempt worth
appreciating.
My comments about the paper are general in nature and are mostly
for the purposes of clarification. Two points may be made. First, the
author uses the average consumption ratio and the average tax ratio to
arrive at net transfers to nonimmigrants. The analytical framework used
by the author is similar to Simon (1984) who has tested the hypothesis
for US immigrants. But Simon (1984) has used actual values of services
used and taxes paid by immigrants which is a more comprehensive and
straightforward approach to get the net effect of migration. The use of
consumption and tax ratios does not change the conclusions, I agree, but
creates a lot of confusion when the explanations of the ratios in the
text are compared with their numerical values in the tables. For
instance, while discussing Table 2, the author's conclusions for
Western Europe are not compatible with the estimates of the average
consumption ratio. Immigrants from Western Europe transfer funds to
non-immigrants after 1970 i.e., after spending 14-15 years in Canada and
not during their first ten years as the discussion of the ratio shows.
Table 3 is more confusing when a comparison is made with the discussions
given in the text especially in the case of the U.K. Here, tax payments
by U.K. immigrants exceed payments by non-immigrants till 1977.
Thereafter, it becomes equal to that of the natives. The author's
explanations in the case of the U.K. are confusing and are the opposite
of what Table 3 reveals. Furthermore, contrary to the explanations
given, the estimates in Table 3 show that West European immigrants pay
more taxes than the natives right from the beginning and it is only in
1978 and 1979 that the tax ratio in their case becomes less than unity.
Similarly, immigrants from Asia, Africa and South and Central America
pay more taxes till 1975, pay less in 1976, pay more in 1977 and
thereafter they pay less than the non-immigrants. The confusion further
compounds when suddenly Table 4 brings forward the actual values of the
net transfer from immigrants to the non-immigrants without any
discussions as to how and where have these values been derived from.
Furthermore, the negative balance in 1978 and 1979 in respect of Asia,
Africa and South and Central America is not compatible with their
corresponding consumption and tax ratios. For instance, in 1978 their
average tax ratio (ATR) had decreased to .74 from 1.02 in 1977 and their
average consumption ratio (ACR) had declined to 0.57 from 0.73 in the
preceding year thus registering a decline of 27 percent and 22 percent
respectively. In 1979, the ATR is reduced to 0.69 from 0.74 in the
previous year and the ACR reducing to 0.53 from 0.57 in 1978 thus
positing a decline of 7 percent for both the ratios. If the two ratios
decline at more or less the same rate, how then can the negative values
of the net transfer in 1978 and 1979 be explained? The paper would
improve substantially if these inconsistencies are removed. One way of
removing them would be to construct separate tables showing the total
transfer payments and services used by various groups of immigrants in
various years after entry and by natives before arriving at Table 4. But
then it seems from the reference list of the paper that Akbari (1988)
discusses the same subject and has followed the same theoretical
framework under a slightly different title. It is possible that more
elaborate statistical analysis is undertaken in the paper under
reference which is not available here to read.
My second comment is about the net present value calculations which
have been dealt with very inadequately. Table 5 presents this showing
that immigrants contribute more to the public treasury than they take
from it assuming a 2.5 percent real discount rate. My queries, here, are
(a) how is the real discount rate defined? If it reflects, simply, the
opportunity cost of capital to the economy, then it ignores the
distributional considerations which are important when cost-benefit
analysis of population movements is undertaken. (b) In a similar type of
study for the US, Simon (1984) has shown that immigrants in the USA are
worth more to the natives at a much higher rate, 9 percent. How would
the author compare his findings with those of Simon's regarding the
economic performance of immigrants in Canada vis-a-vis those in America,
in general, and, in particular, for the West European group which is not
worth investing in if the net transfers are discounted at 5 percent.
Presumably, the immigrant groups in both countries come from almost the
same sources of origin.
Shamim A. Sahibzada
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
REFERENCE
Simon, J. L. (1984) Immigrants, Taxes and Welfare in the United
States. Population Development Review 10 : 1 55-69.
* These comments were prepared on the original paper as presented
in the Sixth Annual General Meeting of the Pakistan Society of
Development Economists.
REFERENCES
Akbari, Ather H. (1988) Immigrants' Net Benefits to Canadians:
Evidence for Various Immigrant Groups. Employment and Immigration
Working Paper.
Akbari, Ather H. (1989) The Benefits of Immigrants to Canada:
Evidence on Tax and Public Services. Canadian Public Policy 15:4
424-435.
Blau, F. D. (1984) The Use of Transfer Payments by Immigrants.
Industrial and Labour Relations Review 37 : 2 222-239.
Simon, J. L. (1984) Immigrants, Taxes and Welfare in the United
States. Population Development Review 10 : 1 55-69.
Statistics Canada (1983) Household/Family File (1981 Census of
Canada).Machine Readable Data Files Number of Logical Records: 18:750.
(1) Recently, the Immigration Association of Canada has expressed
such a view. In addition, a survey conducted by the association showed
that 52.7 percent of those questioned held that immigrants should be
selected from countries with cultures similar to Canada's.
(2) The sub-sample of immigrant households denoted by Western
Europe consists of those whose heads reported their country of birth to
be Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, Netherlands,
Switzerland and "other Western Europe".
(3) The data are available on the Public Use Sample Tapes (PUST)
produced by Statistics Canada.
(4) Such exclusion is consistent with literature. For example,
Simon (1984) and Blau (1984).
(5) Statistics Canada (1983).
(6) The remaining half of government expenditures, for example,
conservation of natural resources and environment, recreation and
culture, etc., are not likely to be influenced by the characteristics
that differentiate immigrants from non-immigrants. Hence, for an average
household in each group, the difference between the consumption of all
other public services is expected to be negligible.
(7) Estimated results for consumption of public services by
individual components can be found in Akbari (1988).
(8) The items from the Canadian federal government expenditures,
which best represent pure public goods include national defence
($4761m), science and technology ($2000m) and, foreign affairs and
international assistance ($1076m). These federal expenditure items
together comprised 5.9 percent of consolidated government expenditures
in 1980 ($132535m) after elimination of intergovernmental transfers.
Thus 5.9 percent of taxes paid in 1980 were for pure public goods. By
virtue of their presence, immigrants reduce by 5.9 percent the taxes
paid by the original set of residents through pure public goods
financing as this financing is not offset by an increase in consumption.
ATHER H. AKBARI *
* The author is Assistant Professor at the Department of Economics,
Sant Mary's University, Halifax, Canada.
Table 1
Average Consumption of Public Services and Payment of Taxes by
Immigrant Households Relative to Non-immigrants, Canada, 1980 (1)
Years since Immigration
Birth Place of
Household Heads 1 2 3 4 5-9
United States
Consumption Ratio (2) 0.48 0.80 0.62 0.71 0.73
Tax Ratio (3) 1.13 1.37 1.16 1.29 1.08
No. of Households 26 17 25 25 167
United Kingdom
Consumption Ratio 0.68 0.79 0.76 0.70 0.96
Tax Ratio 1.00 1.00 1.29 1.29 1.26
No. of Households 54 35 48 52 350
West Europe
Consumption Ratio 0.85 0.88 0.72 0.73 0.87
Tax Ratio 0.88 0.79 1.02 1.02 1.02
No. of Households 49 36 53 64 513
Asia, Africa, South & Central
America
Consumption Ratio 0.53 0.57 0.73 0.77 0.83
Tax Ratio 0.69 0.74 1.02 0.96 1.02
No. of Households 268 160 175 263 1319
Years since Immigration
Birth Place of 25 or
Household Heads 10-14 15-19 20-24 More
United States
Consumption Ratio (2) 0.76 0.63 0.69 1.58
Tax Ratio (3) 1.24 1.16 1.29 0.79
No. of Households 190 79 74 768
United Kingdom
Consumption Ratio 0.89 0.88 0.89 1.60
Tax Ratio 1.53 1.43 1.37 0.86
No. of Households 565 328 640 2858
West Europe
Consumption Ratio 1.14 1.22 1.13 1.31
Tax Ratio 1.16 1.16 1.21 1.08
No. of Households 909 746 1309 2443
Asia, Africa, South & Central
America
Consumption Ratio 0.98 0.98 0.99 1.42
Tax Ratio 1.32 1.40 1.29 1.16
No. of Households 824 268 183 309
(1) The average 1980 public services consumption by a non-immigrant
household in Canada is estimated at $3,651, while tax payments by
non-immigrants is estimated at $8,896.
(2) Ratio of public services consumption by immigrants to that by
non-immigrants.
(3) Ratio of tax payments by immigrants to that by non-immigrants.
Table 2
Balance of Transfers between Immigrant and Non-immigrant Households,
Canada, 1980
Years since Immigration
Birth Place of
Household Heads 1 2 3 4 5-9
United States
Balance (1) 3,579 4,560 3,335 4,164 2,222
Alternate Balance (2) 3,054 4,035 2,810 3,639 1,697
United Kingdom
Balance 1,689 1,288 4,000 4,197 3,006
Alternate Balance 1,164 763 3,475 3,672 2,481
West Europe
Balance 6 -884 831 1,672 1,191
Alternate Balance -519 -1,409 306 1,152 666
Asia, Africa, South & Central
America
Balance -521 -157 448 994 1,319
Alternate Balance -1,046 -682 -77 469 794
Years since Immigration
Birth Place of 25 or
Household Heads 10-14 15-19 20-24 More
United States
Balance (1) 3,512 3,268 4,244 -2,652
Alternate Balance (2) 2,987 2,743 3,719 -3,957
United Kingdom
Balance 5,689 4,784 4,197 -2,937
Alternate Balance 5,164 4,259 3,672 -3,462
West Europe
Balance 1,416 1,133 1,916 104
Alternate Balance 891 608 1,391 -421
Asia, Africa, South & Central
America
Balance 3,434 4,124 3,141 394
Alternate Balance 2,909 3,599 2,616 -131
(1) With provision for public goods financing - conforms to
Equation 1.
(2) Without provision for public goods financing - conforms to
Equation 2 (with a 0.059).
Table 3
Present Net Worth' of an Immigrant Household for the Non-immigrant
Population, Canada, 1980
Discount Rate 2.5 % Discount Rate 2.5%
Birth Place of Alternate Alternate
Household Head Result (2) Result (3) Result (2) Result (3)
($) ($) ($) ($)
United States 42,886 31,198 36,628 28,442
United Kingdom 56,763 45,075 45,118 36,933
West Europe 21,044 9,356 14,829 7,065
Asia, Africa,
South & Central
America 42,535 30,846 28,779 20,595
(1) Evaluated over 45 years in Canada.
(2) With provision for pure public goods financing.
(3) Without provision for pure public goods financing.