The demand for inputs and the supply of output in Pakistan: estimating a fixed-effects, distributed-lag model for wheat farmers.
Deolalikar, Anil B. ; Vosti, Stephen A.
INTRODUCTION
Agricultural growth in Pakistan over the past 3 decades has been
very impressive, averaging 3.3 percent annually over the period 1965-80,
and accelerating to 413 percent per year over the period 1980-90, But as
impressive as these numbers are, questions arise regarding the success
of the agricultural sector in terms of meeting food and employment
needs, the potential for continuing or increasing growth rates in the
future, the likely sources of future agricultural growth, and the
technologies, policies, and institutional arrangements necessary to
achieve that growth.
The truth is that agriculture in general, and food production in
particular, have been working hard to just to keep pace with other
sectors and with the food needs of the domestic population. Agriculture
was the slowest growing sector in Pakistan over the past 30 years, with
general economic expansion moving along at an average of 5.2 percent
annually over the 1965-80 period, and of 6.3 percent per year over the
decade of the 1980s. In addition, in spite of very substantial
production and productivity gains for most major crops, the average
index of food production per capita remained constant over the 1980-90
period, while the total volume of cereal imports nearly doubled to over
2,048,000 metric tons [World Development Report (1992)].
And the future could be worse. Growth rates in agricultural
productivity may not continue at historical levels, and the population
growth rate is likely to continue at (or around) 3.0 percent annually
for some time, thereby almost guaranteeing a population of over 150
million by the end of the century, and perhaps 250 million by the year
2025. Frighteningly, some estimates of the hypothetical size of a
stationary Pakistani population are as high as 400 million people by the
middle of the next century [World Development Report (1992)].
That is a lot of mouths to feed and able-bodied individuals to
employ, and agriculture will clearly have to do its share in meeting
both needs, though rural-to-urban migration and intersectoral shifts in
employment and growth emphases towards non-agricultural sectors suggest
that a disproportionately large share of the burden will be borne by
these sectors. But agriculture must grow, and the challenges for the
1990s (and indeed the next 25 years) is to identify potential sources of
growth, and select and implement policies that promote it.
Historically, promoters of agricultural growth have focused their
attention on bringing more area under plow, principally via the
extension of large-scale irrigation projects, and on generating and
disseminating higher-yielding varieties of basic cereal crops. As we
look to the future, it is not clear whether these will continue to be
the principal sources of growth over the next quarter-century. Indeed,
the absolute amount of net cropped area (currently about 27 percent of
total surface area in Pakistan, after an increase of 0.4 percent per
year over the 1965-89 period) may even fall in the future due to urban
encroachment and environmental degradation (principally soil salinity and waterlogging). Irrigated area (which stands at an astonishing 63
percent of total agricultural area) will be difficult and very expensive
to increase broadly. In addition, yields among Pakistan's most
productive farmers may not increase very much at all [Government of
Pakistan (1991); World Development Report (1992)]. Therefore, we must
look for different sources of productivity increases to fuel
agricultural growth, and help meet poverty and environmental management
goals as well. Potential sources of future growth are- increases in
gross cropped area via reduction in fallow periods, with proper care
taken not to degrade the natural resource base; increases in labour
productivity; increases in the application of traditional and chemical
fertilizers, in both rainfed and irrigated areas; improvements in the
quality of existing large-scale irrigation systems; increases in area
serviced by small-scale irrigation projects, with particular focus on
tubewell irrigation; and, generally improving farm management practices
[Nag-Chowdhury and Vosti (1992)]. The sources of future agricultural
growth will certainly differ across regions, as will the policies needed
to promote growth. It is noteworthy that much of Pakistan's future
agricultural growth may have to come from its currently poorest and
least productive farmers [Raza and Vosti (1992)].
Perhaps our best indicator of likely sources of future agricultural
growth is the set of factors that influenced very recent agricultural
change. The more we know about how farmers make resource (including
human resource) allocation decisions; the more likely we are to identify
the technological and policy "hooks" on which to hang our
hopes for the future of Pakistani agriculture [Reardon and Vosti
(1992)].
This paper uses a 1986-89 panel of farm-level data from several
regions in Pakistan to examine the factors influencing the supply of
wheat, and the demand for the various purchased and farm-produced inputs
that go into wheat production. An analytical framework capable of
capturing farm-level fixed effects and allowing for inter-farm
differences in responses to changes in the agroeconomic environment is
introduced. A fixed-effects, distributed-lag model derived from this
framework is estimated, and the results interpreted. Conclusions and
policy implications derived from the empirical results are presented,
and avenues for future research are suggested.
ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK
A Static Model of Input Demand and Output Supply
The starting point for analysing farm input and output decisions is
the set of crop production functions
[Y.sub.ij] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [f.sub.j] ([X.sub.ij], [A.sub.ij]),
... ... ... (1)
where i indexes a farm, j indexes a crop, Y is the output
harvested, X is the vector of variable inputs (such as tractor and
bullock services, fertilizer, labour, etc.), and A is cropped area. The
individual crop production functions represent the agricultural
technology in use, and indicate the maximum physical output that can be
obtained from the applied inputs. Of special interest here is the
unobserved, farm-specific intercept, [[alpha].sub.i] that may represent
the managerial ability of the farmer or the unobserved attributes of the
farm, such as soil quality.
The restricted farm profit function can then be derived under the
assumption that farmers maximise total farm profits, for a given season,
[PI] = [[summation].sub.j]][p.sub.j][Y.sub.j] - [[summation].sub.j]
q [X.sub.j], ... ... ... (2)
where [p.sub.j] is the price of crop j and q is the vector of input
prices, subject to their total land constraint, viz.,
[[summation].sub.j] [A.sub.j] = A, ... ... ... ... (3)
where A is the total amount of land (size of operational holding)
available.
While the crop production functions assume technical efficiency on
the part of farmers, the restricted farm profit function assumes price
(or allocative) efficiency. (1) It is possible to derive the profit
function from the individual crop production functions, and vice versa.
(2) The profit function is:
[[PI}.sub.i] = [PI]([p.sub.1], [p.sub.2] ... , [p.sub.n], q,
[A.sub.i,] [[alpha].sub.i]). ... ... (40
The demand functions for variable inputs X are given by the
relation:
X([p.sub.1], [p.sub.2], ... , [p.sub.n], q [A.sub.i],
[[alpha].sub.i]) = - [partial derivative][PI](*)/[partial derivative] q,
... ... (5)
while the output supply function (not to be confused with the
production function) for crop j is given by:
[Y.sub.j]([p.sub.1], [p.sub.2], ... , [p.sub.n], q, [A.sub.i],
[[alpha].sub.i]) = - [partial derivative][PI](*)/[partial
derivative][p.sub.j]. (3) ... ... (6)
Equations (5) and (6) represent the reduced-form system of input
demand and output supply equations. There are several points worth
noting about this demand system. First, since the farmer is assumed to
maximise total profits and since there may opportunities for
substituting across various inputs and across crops, all input and
output prices enter the demand relation for each input and the supply
relation for each crop. Thus, not only will the rental price of bullocks
influence the demand for bullock services and that for tractor services
(which may be close substitutes), but they may also affect the demand
for fertilizer. Likewise, the prices of all possible crops that can be
cultivated will influence the demand for each factor and the supply of
every crop. This realistic approach to demand interrelationships is
consistent with theory and common sense, but differs greatly from
standard single-equation, single product estimation production [see, for
example, Government of Pakistan (1991a), p. 3].
Second, within the above model, total cropped area as well as the
area under individual crops are choice variables for the farmer;
therefore, these do not enter the system of input demand and output
supply equations. Instead, what enters the system is the variable A-the
size of operational holding--which is treated as a fixed factor of
production in the short term. Of course, to the extent that farmers can
lease in and lease out land for cultivation, even the size of
operational holding is not a fixed factor in the medium or long term.
However, since tenancy contracts may be difficult to adjust in the short
run, the assumption that the size of the operational holding is not a
variable factor in the short run is not unrealistic.
Third, the unobserved, farm- (or farmer-) specific effect,
[[alpha].sub.i], enters the system of input demand and output supply
equations. Indeed, this is an important reason why ordinary least
squares estimates of the crop production functions in (1) are likely to
be biased. In OLS estimates of a production function, any fixed effects,
such as [alpha], are included in the disturbance term. Since the demand
for all inputs will necessarily depend on these unobserved endowments
(e.g., managerial ability, soil quality, locational advantage, etc.),
the disturbance term in the production function is correlated with the
included independent variables. As a result, OLS estimates of the
production function will be biased.
Fourth, the effects of prices and fixed factors obtained in the
input demand and output supply system are mutatis mutandis (as opposed
to ceteris paribus) effects. This means that the estimated effect of
wages on, say, the demand for tractor services reflects the (total)
effect on tractor use of a change in wage rates after allowing all other
inputs and outputs to also adjust to the wage rate change. Thus, even
though labour and tractor services may be complementary inputs, an
increase in wage rates could reduce output and thereby the demand for
tractor services. If this (negative) output effect is larger than the
(positive) substitution effect, the demand for tractor services could
fall with an increase in wages.
The estimated parameters of the reduced-form demand model can be
used to analyse the impact of policy changes on a number of behavioural variables. For instance, the estimated model can be used to simulate the
effects of, say, a higher procurement price for wheat (holding other
prices and policy variables constant) on the demands for labour (hired
and family, male and female), bullock and tractor services, fertilizer,
and other inputs. The model also allows us to trace the simultaneous
impact of several different policy changes--say, a reduction in
fertilizer and tractor subsidies--on input use.
It is possible to control for the unobserved fixed effects,
[[alpha].sub.i], in estimating the reduced-form input demand and output
supply equations with panel data. Assuming a linear functional form for
the demand/supply equations, (4) Equations (5) and (6) can be written
as:
[X.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.i] + a [p.sub.it] + c [q.sub.it] + d
[A.sub.it], ... ... (7)
and [Y.sub.it] = [[alpha]'.sub.i] + a' [p.sub.it] +
c' [q.sub.it] + d' [A.sub.it]. ... ... (8)
First-differencing the two equations yields:
[DELTA] [X.sub.i] = a [DELTA] [p.sub.i] + c [DELTA] qi + d [DELTA]
[A.sub.i], ... ... (9)
and [DELTA] [Y.sub.i] = a' [DELTA] [p.sub.i] + c' [DELTA]
[q.sub.i] + d' [DELTA] [A.sub.i], ... ... (10)
where [DELTA]Z is the first-difference operator (viz., [DELTA]Z =
[Z.sub.it] - [Z.sub.i,t-1]). Estimation of the first-differenced
Equations (9) and (10) by the ordinary least squares method provides
unbiased and consistent estimates of parameters in Equations (7) and
(8).
A Dynamic Model of Demand Adjustment
So far we have assumed a static framework in which farmers can
respond to price and other policy changes instantaneously. In fact,
adjustment may be slow and spread out over several years. If this is the
case, the current demand for inputs should be a function not merely of
current prices but of past prices as well. Rewriting the input demand
and output supply Equations in (7) and (8), we would have:
[X.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [[beta].sub.0][Z.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.1][Z.sub.i,t-1] + ... + [[beta].sub.k][Z.sub.i,t- k], ...
(11)
[Y.sub.it] = [[alpha]'.sub.i] + [[beta]'.sub.0]
[Z.sub.it] + [[beta]'.sub.1][X.sub.i,t-1] + ... +
[[beta]'.sub.k][X.sub.i,t-k], ... (12)
where the vector Z includes all the independent variables,
[p.sub.1], [p.sub.2] ... , [p.sub.n], q, and A. Estimation of (11) and
(12) would require an infinite time series of data; however, if one
makes the assumption that the [[beta].sub.j]'s decline
geometrically, i.e., [[beta].sub.1] = [lambda] [[beta].sub.0],
[[beta].sub.2] = [[lambda].sup.2] [[beta].sub.0], [[beta].sub.3] =
[[lambda].sup.3] [[beta].sub.0], ... , [[beta].sub.k] = [[lambda].sup.k]
[[beta].sub.0], and 0 < [lambda] < 1, Equations (11) and (12)
reduce to:
[X.sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [[beta].sub.0][Z.sub.it] +
[[beta].sub.0][lambda][Z.sub.i,t-1] + ... +
[[beta].sub.0][lambda][Z.sub.i,t-k], (11a)
[Y.sub.it] = [[alpha]'.sub.i] + [[beta]'.sub.0]
[Z.sub.it] + [[beta]'.sub.0][lambda]'[Z.sub.i,t-1] + ... +
[[beta]'.sub.0][[lambda]'[Z.sub.i,t-k]. (12a)
For the time period t -1, we have:
[lambda] [X.sub.it-1] = [[alpha].sub.i] + [[beta].sub.0] [lambda]
[Z.sub.i,t-1] + ... + [[beta].sub.0] [lambda] [Z.sub.i,t-k-1], ... (11b)
[lambda] [Y.sub.it-1] = [[alpha]'.sub.i] +
[[beta]'.sub.0][lambda]'[Z.sub.i,t-1] + ... +
[[beta]'.sub.0][lambda]'[Z.sub.i,t-k-1].
Subtracting (11b) from (11a) and (12b) from (12a), we get
[X.sub.it] - [lambda][X.sub.it-1] = [[beta].sub.0] [Z.sub.it] ...
... ... (13)
[Y.sub.it] - [lambda][Y.sub.it-1] = [[beta]'.sub.0]
[Z.sub.it], ... ... ... (14)
or
[X.sub.it] = [lambda] [X.sub.it-1] + [[beta].sub.0] [Z.sub.it] ...
... ... (15)
[Y.sub.it] = [lambda] [Y.sub.it-1] + [[beta]'.sub.0]
[Z.sub.it]. ... ... ... (16)
This is a standard distributed-lag model, with the lagged value of
the dependent variable occurring on the right-hand side of the equation.
Note that the distributed-lag model not only permits the assumption of
farmers gradually (as opposed to instantaneously) adjusting to price and
other exogenous changes, but it also controls for unobserved fixed
effects, [[alpha].sub.i]. In this sense, it is superior to the static
fixed-effects model (contained in Equations (9) and (10) [Behrman et al.
(1992); Koyck (1954)].
Functional Form
The only major question that remains is of functional form. If the
underlying profit function is of the generalised quadratic form, viz.,
[PI] = [alpha] + [b.sub.0]p + 1/2 [b.sub.1][p.sup.2] + [b.sub.2] q
+ 1/2 [b.sub.3] [q.sup.2] +
1/2 [b.sub.4] p q + [b.sub.5] A + 1/2 [b.sub.6] [A.sup.2] + 1/2
[b.sub.7] p A +
1/2 [b.sub.8] q A + 1/2 [b.sub.9] p [alpha] + 1/2 [b.sub.10] q
[alpha] + 1/2 [b.sub.11] A [alpha], ... (17)
where the subscripts i and t have been dropped, the input demand
and output supply equations can be obtained as the first derivatives of
the profit function with respect to q and p, respectively (see Equations
(5) and (6))'.This yields:
-X = [b.sub.2] + [b.sub.3]q + 1/2 [b.sub.4]p + 1/2 [b.sub.8]A + 1/2
[b.sub.10] [alpha] (18)
Y = [b.sub.0] + 1/2 [b.sub.4] q + [b.sub.1] p + 1/2 [b.sub.7]A +
1/2 [b.sub.9] [alpha]. (19)
Thus, the appealing feature of the generalised quadratic profit
function is that the resulting input demand and output supply equations
are linear in parameters.
To control for fixed effects, [alpha], the Equations in (18) and
(19) can be estimated in first-differenced form. As discussed earlier, a
dynamic adjustment model would lead essentially to the same estimating
equations, but with the lagged value of the dependent variable as an
additional right-hand side variable.
EMPIRICAL MODEL
The model developed above treats cropping pattern as a choice
variable, and enables us to analyse the demand for inputs used in all
crops and the output supply of all crops. However, for the purposes of
this exercise, we have confined the analysis to a single crop, viz.,
wheat, one of the principal agricultural outputs in Pakistan [Hapke and
Vosti (1992)]. We have used the IFPRI Pakistan panel data for three
rounds: Rabi 1986-87, Rabi 1987-88, and Rabi 1988-89. This provides us
with 720 observations over three rounds.
In all, information on one output (viz., harvested quantity of
wheat in maunds-1 maund = 40 kilograms) and thirteen inputs is available
for the three rounds. The inputs are hired labour use (in days per
season), family male labour, family female labour, tractor use (hours),
bullock use (days), farm manure use (number of carts), fertilizer use
(total as well as DAP, urea, and nitrogen) (number of 50 kilogram bags),
number of weedings, number of irrigations after planting, and number of
ploughings. Descriptive statistics and variable labels appear in Table
1.
The resulting input demand and output supply system has one output
price (viz., wheat) and three input prices (rental price of bullocks,
rental price of tractor services, and wage rate for labour) as
explanatory variables (all expressed in terms of 1986 Rupees). In
addition, fixed factors of production in the system are acres of rainfed
land, canal-irrigated and well-irrigated land in the operational
holding. Dichotomous variables for the different Rabi seasons are also
included as shift variables:
Household-level input and output prices were not used because
differences in "unit values" (amount paid or received per unit
of an input or output quantity) reported by households may reflect
quality variations rather than genuine price variation. Instead, prices
reported by farm households were averaged over the four districts and
three rounds. As a result, the price variation in the sample is somewhat
limited. In addition, data on fertilizer prices were not available at
the time this model was estimated and therefore were not included in
this demand system. This obvious shortcoming will hopefully be remedied
in subsequent versions of this paper.
EMPIRICAL RESULTS
Parameters estimates from the fixed-effects, distributed-lag model
of the input demand and output supply system are reported in Table 2.
T-ratios appear beneath each of the parameter estimates, and summary
statistics for each equation appear in the final two columns of Table 2.
Since the system is linear in parameters, the coefficients represent the
change in input use or output quantity due to a unit change in price or
land holding. The corresponding elasticities, evaluated at the sample
means of variables, are calculated and reported in Table 3.
Several points can be made about these estimates. First, a large
number of estimated effects in the demand system are significant. For
example, the majority of the 56 price effects estimated (tractor hire
rate, bullock hire rate, wheat price, and wage rate) were statistically
significantly different from zero at the 10 percent level.
Canal-irrigated land is significant in 10 of the 14 equations estimated,
while rainfed land is significant in 9 equations. The parameters are
thus estimated with a high level of precision. The explanatory power of
the regressions is also generally high; for example, the included
prices, fixed factors, and lagged dependent variable account for 77
percent of the variation in wheat output. The [R.sup.2]'s of the
other equations are also relatively high.
Second, the estimated effects of the rental price of tractor
services are very large in magnitude. The tractor price elasticity of
input demand and output supply (see Table 3, Column 1) ranges from -39
(for family female labour use) to 19 (for manure demand), suggesting
very strong links between mechanisation costs and the use of other farm
inputs.
Third, estimated wheat price effects are consistent with the a
priori predictions of the analytical framework. The profit maximisation
model predicts the impact of output price on output supply and most
input demands to be positive. The estimated model indicates a very
strong supply response (with an elasticity of harvested output with
respect to the wheat price of 3.0), and strong positive effects of wheat
price on the demand for manure and fertilizer (especially urea and
nitrogen). However, wheat prices are estimated to significantly depress the demand for family labour, especially family female labour. These
negative effects on labour demand probably reflect an income effect:
increase in wheat prices (the dominant crop for many households)
improves income and prompts the substitution of purchased inputs for
family labour.
Fourth, the bullock price elasticities are generally small in
magnitude. The own-price effect of bullock rental rates on the demand
for bullock services is estimated to be positive (although, at 0.128,
the elasticity is small). This slightly positive slope to the bullock
"demand curve" is quite plausible if bullock ownership is
common among sample households, and price variations over time are a
consequence of demand, and not supply, shifts. Increased bullock rental
rates led to increased demand for family male labour (as a consequence
of increased bullock use), but reduced demand for family female labour.
Fifth, the estimated wage rate effects on labour demand and output
supply are generally well-behaved. They are consistently estimated to be
significantly less than zero. The results suggest that a one percent
increase in the wage rate reduces harvested wheat output by about 1
percent, hired labour use by 1.9 percent, and family male labour by 3.5
percent. These results suggest that as the market wage increases, male
family members switch from own farming to other activities (including
paid, wage labour). Female members participate less frequently in wage
labour markets and do not seem to substitute for males (family or hired)
as wages rise.
The estimated effect Of the wage rate on bullock use is highly
negative (elasticity of -4.8), again-confirming the strong
complementarity between bullock and human labour. The statistically
insignificant wage elasticity of tractor services indicates that there
is a greater degree of complementarity between bullocks and labour than
between tractors and labour. Finally, the estimated effects of the wage
rate on fertilizer demand (particularly, DAP) are very strongly
negative. A one percent increase in wages is estimated to reduce the
demand for DAP by as much as 3.2 percent, indicating strong
complementarity between fertilizer and labour use.
Sixth, the effects of the quantity of land holding by access to
irrigation on input demand and output supply are .also generally in line
with a priori expectations. Of the two types of irrigation, only canal
irrigation appears to have a strong impact on input demand and output
supply; well irrigation had virtually no significant effects on farmer
behaviour, perhaps due to the limited presence of tubewells in our
sample of wheat farmers. All of the estimated land holding effects that
are significantly different from zero are positive, implying that an
increase in land holding (almost regardless of access to canal water)
increases the harvested quantity of wheat and the demand for most
inputs. However, the elasticities based on estimated parameters for
canal-irrigated areas are generally much larger than the rainfed
elasticities. For example, an increase in canal-irrigated land is
observed to have much larger effects on wheat supply than an increase in
rainfed land (elasticities of 0.31 and 0.05, respectively), suggesting
that canal-irrigated land is roughly six times as productive as rainfed
land. The elasticities of fertilizer and tractor use with respect to
canal-irrigated land are two to three times as large as those with
respect to rainfed land.
The coefficients on the lagged dependent variable (the
[lambda]'s) in the distributed-lag model indicate the speed of
farmer response over time. The smaller the value of [lambda], or the
larger the value of the "adjustment parameter" (1-[lambda],),
the smaller is the lag between the independent variables and the
dependent variables. The estimates in Table 4 imply that the speed of
responding to price and other agroeconomic changes is the longest for
tractor use, family male labour, bullock labour, and output, but that
farmers do adjust inputs, such as fertilizer, family female labour,
weeding, ploughing and irrigation practices, rapidly as prices or other
factors change. However, due to market rigidities and supply
constraints, other inputs take much longer to fully adjust to the price
and other shocks.
CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
We have found that a distributed-lag model, in which farmers are
presumed to adjust their inputs and outputs gradually over time in
response to price and other changes, offers plausible estimates for the
Pakistan panel of wheat farmers over the 1986-89 period, and highlights
the nature of farm-level resource allocation and production decisions.
The model confirms the highly interrelated nature of input use, and
the policies known to influence it. Where statistically significant,
own-price elasticities were generally in line with theoretical
predictions. More importantly, many of the cross-price elasticities were
statistically significant and quite strong, emphasising the need for
comprehensive analyses of the responses by farmers to policy shifts, For
example, the model suggests that an increase in the price of wheat will
not only increase output of wheat, but also increase the demand for key
purchased and farm-produced inputs. Therefore, an increase in the price
of wheat might more than offset any (supposed, but not estimated here)
decrease in total fertilizer use brought about by the removal of a price
control on that important input. In addition, the elasticities
associated with input changes in response to a change in wheat prices
are not equal, suggesting a change in production technology, which
policy-makers need to be aware of.
The substitutability of agricultural mechanisation for some types
of rural labour was borne out by the data, and this model. Increases in
tractor use in response to a decrease in tractor hire rates (a likely,
but not statistically demonstrable effect in these data), would lead to
a decrease in the quantity of hired and family male labour used, and an
increase in family female labour used. Therefore, areas experiencing
rapid rates of agricultural mechanisation should pay close attention to
rural unemployment, and potentially initiate programmes to increase
off-farm, and perhaps non-agricultural employment opportunities.
Input demand and output supply responses to increases in land
availability were uniformly positive, and particularly strong for
canal-irrigated areas. The output relation is well known, but the
implications of increased canal irrigation for hired labour and
fertilizer use (strong increases in demand, for all cases) is a clearly
beneficial side-effect, perhaps achievable without any additional price
policy intervention.
Changes in rural wages clearly affect farm production, as well as
input choice. Labour is a key ingredient to agricultural production, and
its sparing use in the face of increases in wage rates is likely
(according to this model) not to be fully compensated for by the use of
other inputs. Indeed, use of virtually all other inputs declines along
with labour input when wages rise. The most logical substitute for
labour, mechanical traction, does not seem to react to wage increases,
suggesting some imperfections in rental and purchase markets for
tractors.
Finally, the speed with which different output and factors of
production reacted to price and other agroecological changes differed
greatly. Farming practices, such as the number of weedings, irrigations,
and ploughings, were quickest to adjust--usually making complete
transitions in a single period or season. Adjustments to fertilizer
application rates were slightly slower, but still managed to complete
the transition in a single season, more or less. Labour use displayed a
more diverse pattern of adjustment. Family female labour adjusted
quickly, followed by hired labour, ending with family male labour, which
took several periods to make complete adjustments. Limited off-farm
labour opportunities for females, functioning daily hired and other
labour markets for males, and fairly rigid on-farm responsibilities for
family males are likely explanations for differences in speed of
adjustment across labour groups. Improvements in rural labour markets
could speed transitions for some of these groups.
There are several ways in which the research reported in this paper
will be extended. First, an attempt will be made to include fertilizer
prices paid by farmers in the sampled provinces. This will enable
estimation of fertilizer price elasticities. Second, multi-crop input
demand and output supply systems could be estimated with data on several
alternative crops during the Rabi season. Third, analysis will be
extended to include a separate input/output demand system for the Kharif
season. Fourth, we will attempt to control for differences across
villages as regards key agroecological characteristics known to affect
crop choice and production technology decisions. Fifth, we will attempt
to decompose the "fixed effects" into farmer and farm-specific
components relevant for policy and future research. Finally, the very
large elasticities generated by this model suggest that the O.L.S.
estimator may be inappropriate. Given the large number of
"zeros" in the input/output matrix, we intend to experiment
with a Tobit estimator designed for such circumstances.
Comments on "The Demand for Inputs and the Supply of Output in
Pakistan : Estimating a Fixed-effects, Distributed-lag Model for Wheat
Farmers"
The empirical results from various field surveys on Pakistan's
agriculture bear ample testimony to the vast scope for raising
productivity through removing various economic, technical and
institutional constraints which are hindering the path of agricultural
development. The yields of the "progressive farmers" are
substantially higher than those of the average yields obtaining in the
country. In some cases the gap is 2-3 times. The timely provision of
inputs by minimising supply constraints, provision of credit, if lack of
resources constrain optimum use of modem inputs and technology and or
solving marketing problems if it applies brakes on the progress and,
above all, providing a conducive economic environment for farm
production may provide some of the missing links in this direction.
The scope for increasing agricultural production through horizontal
expansion of the cropped/cultivated area is limited especially in the
short run, and is quite capital-intensive, even if possible, in the long
run. Therefore, the bulk of the increase in farm production has to come
from increasing the productivity of the land and other resources
committed to agriculture. An analysis of the micro data which provides
the empirical estimates for resource productivity is an important way to
gain useful insights. It is in this context that the paper needs to be
examined. In the introduction, the authors pose an important question
about the continued success of the agriculture sector in meeting the
food and employment needs of the expanding population in Pakistan and
about the potential and sources for increasing its growth rate in the
future. In this context, they emphasise the need for identifying the
sources of agricultural growth, technology, policies and institutional
arrangements necessary to achieve the desired results.
Based on the panel data, relating to 1986-89, the paper has
estimated the impact of various factors on the supply of wheat as well
as the demand for various inputs. Here it may be noted that given the
considerable variation and diversity in the production relations in
various regions of the country, it may have been useful, to the readers,
if the authors had provided some details about their panel farmers, the
basis for their selection, and the details of data collection, as it
would help in appreciating the extent to which one can generalise from
these results.
The data provided in Table 1 reveal tremendous variations in the
use level of various inputs, as reflected by very high values of the
standard deviations. It may be advisable to report these data on per
acre or per hectare basis. At the same time, some of the values in this
table are ridiculous. For instance, the mean value of irrigated land by
wells is reported as zero while its standard deviation is 50.4.
Similarly, the information about the use of bullocks and the custom rate
for their service as reported is confusing. The use of bullocks should
be in terms of pair of bullocks and not in terms of a single bullock and
the custom rate reported for a team of bullocks, if at all there is a
market for bullock services in the countryside.
Disaggregating the data in view of the heterogeneity in production
relations and cultural practices, i.e., separating the results for
rainfed/barani and Canal irrigated regions, would have been helpful.
The profit function is an elegant tool for analysing production
behaviour of the farmers but it is highly demanding in terms of its data
requirements which sometimes may not be fully met. For example,
estimating input elasticities from cross-section data may be constrained by the lack of sufficient variability in prices to allow a meaningful
estimation. The explanation that household level input and output prices
were not used because differences in unit value reported by households
may reflect quality variations rather than genuine price variation does
not seem very convincing. If accepted as such, then the very estimation
of demand functions may be an exercise in futility. The real problem, I
feel, is the lack of sufficient variation in the input price data. The
authors' inability to include prices of fertilizer in their
estimation because of the nonavailability of requisite data is rather
surprising as these are the most readily available data.
Now let us discuss some of the results in Table 2: The wheat
harvested equation. In this equation a noteworthy omission is that of
fertilizers. Fertilizer is known to have played an important role in
expanding wheat production. It is also a strategic input in various
plans. Here we are trying to identify the sources of increase in wheat
production and do not include fertilizers. The same can be said about
seed.
It is interesting to find a strong relationship between wheat
output and its prices. However, it is difficult to find an explanation
for the positive impact of the increase in the tractor hiring rate on
wheat output. The estimated effect of the wage rate on fertilizer demand
is strongly negative, indicating a strong complementarity between
fertilizer and labour use, according to the authors. Here it is worth
mentioning that one of the arguments advanced in favour of the
elimination of subsidy on fertilizer has been to reduce wasteful and
inefficient use of fertilizers which were being substituted for
practices involving labour 'use. The use of fertilizers by
increasing production should provide for more labour use--a
complementary relationship but how and why a higher wage rate should
induce the use of less fertilizer seems rather odd, especially, when the
analysis does not incorporate the impact of changing fertilizer prices.
The negative relationship between tubewell and inputs demand is
rather strange. Given the kind of arguments to incorporate the impact of
some farm-specific variable in the intercept, I find it difficult to
explain its negative coefficient in several of the equations estimated
and reported in Table 2.
The finding that an increase in land holding increases the
harvested quantity of Wheat and the demand for most inputs is not
surprising at all. Similarly, the students of Pakistani agriculture know
quite well that an increase in canal-irrigated land would have a much
larger effect on wheat supply than an increase in rainfed land.
Before concluding my observations, I would like to thank the
organisers of the meeting for providing me the opportunity to
participate in their annual meeting and to discuss an interesting paper.
I am also grateful to the Chairman of this session and other
participants for bearing with me.
Abdul Salam
APCOM, Islamabad.
Authors' Note: Sincere thanks go to Dipa Nag-Chowdhury, Holly
M. Hapke, Jafar Raza, Sumiter Broca, and the many efficient and
dedicated assistants in the IFPRI-Pakistan office for their work in
organising thousands of computer records into useful data. Without their
efforts, this research could never have been undertaken. Special thanks
also go to Lourdes Hinayon and Julie Witcover for manuscript preparation
and review, respectively. Important insights were provided by Sohail J.
Malik and Zakir Hussain. All errors are ours. This research was
completed under USAID to Pakistan Grant Number 391-0492-G-001791-00 for
the Ministry of Food and Agriculture, Government of Pakistan.
REFERENCES
Behrman, J. R., Anil B. Deolalikar and Victory Lavy (1992) Child
Growth in Rural South India: Economic and Biological Determinants.
Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Hapke, Holly M., and Stephen A. Vosti (1992) The Role of Farm-level
Output Diversification on Technical Change in Agriculture: Evidence from
the IFPRI Panel. Background paper prepared in conjunction with the ARD portion of the USAID/Pakistan Research Programme. Washington, D.C.:
IFPRI.
Koyck, L. M. (1954) Distributed Lags and Investment Analysis.
Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Company.
Lau, L. J. (1969) Applications of Profit Functions. Stanford:
Center for Research in Economic Growth. (Memos No. 86 A and 86B.
Mimeographed.)
McFadden, D. L. (1970) Cost, Revenue and Profit Functions.
Berkeley: University of California, Department of Economics.
(Mimeographed).
Pakistan, Government of (1991) National Agricultural Policy.
Islamabad: Ministry of Food, Agriculture, and Cooperatives.
Pakistan, Government of (1991a) The Estimates of Fertilizer Demand
and Import Requirements: Fertilizer Forecast 1991-92. Islamabad:
National Fertilizer Development Centre, Planning and Development
Division.
Nag-Chowdhury, Dipa, and Stephen A. Vosti (1992) Patterns and
Trends in Agricultural Labour Use: Evidence from the IFPRI Panel.
Background paper prepared in conjunction with the ARD portion of the
USAID/Pakistan Research Programme. Washington, D.C.: IFPRI.
Raza, Jafar, and Stephen A. Vosti (1992) Examination of the 1991-92
National Input-Output Survey of Major Crops. Background paper prepared
in conjunction with the ARD portion of the USAID/Pakistan Research
Programme. Washington, D.C.: IFPRI.
Reardon, Thomas, and Stephen A. Vosti (1992) Issues in the Analysis
of the Effects of Policy on Conservation and Productivity at the
Household Level in Developing Countries. Quarterly Journal of
International Agriculture. (Forthcoming.)
World Development Report (1992) Development and the Environment.
World Bank: Oxford University Press.
(1) Although this assumption can be tested, given availability of
appropriate data.
(2) While this is possible in principle, the derivation may not
always be tractable, depending upon the functional form assumed for the
production or profit functions.
(3) These relations are proven in McFadden (1970) and Lau (1969).
(4) The assumption of the fixed effect, [[alpha].sub.i], entering
linearly in the input demand and output supply equations is critical to
the estimation.
Anil B. Deolalikar is Professor at the Department of Economics,
University of Washington and Stephen A. Vosti is Research Fellow at the
Environment and Production Technology Division of the International Food
Policy Research Institute (IFPRI).
Table 1
Descriptive Statistics and Variable Labels
Descriptive Statistics--Wheat
Production
Variable Units of Mean Standard
Description Measure Deviation
Bullock Hire Rate 1986 Rupees per Day 147.9 268.1
Bullock Days Days 11.9 1.3
Canal-irrigated Land Acres 8.4 11.8
DAP 50 Kg Sacks 2.1 5.0
Female Family Labour Days 3.2 87.2
Hired Labour Days 19.6 84.9
Male Family Labour Days 63.4 11.3
Manure Carts 3.7 8.0
Nitrogen 50 Kg Sacks 1.0 3.0
Number of Irrigation Number 2.4 2.8
Number of Ploughings Number 4.0 2.6
Number of Weedings Number 0.2 0.7
Rainfed Land Acres 2.3 6.4
Rural Wage 1986 Rupees per Day 38.7 12.0
Total Family Labour Days 66.7 13.1
Total Fertilizer Sacks 7.0 7.2
Tractor Hire Rate 1986 Rupees per Hour 65.3 5.7
Tractor Hours Hours 6.8 20.1
UREA 50 Kg Sacks 3.4 4.7
Well-irrigated Land Acres 0.0 50.4
Wheat Harvested Maunds 64.0 86.2
Wheat Price 1986 Rupees per Maund 90.4 13.1
Table 2
Input Demand Equations, Dynamic Model Estimates, Pakistan Panel,
1986-87 to 1988-89
Independent Variables
Lagged
Dependent Dependent Rabi
Variable Estimate Intercept Variable 1987-88
Wheat Parameter -564.353 0.603 -41.511
Harvested T-ratio -5.3 24.5 -3.2
Hired Labour Parameter -184.987 0.482 -13.051
T-ratio -1.7 9.0 -1.0
Family Male Parameter 396.406 0.698 -73.744
Labour T-ratio 3.3 13.1 -4.8
Family Parameter 254.586 0.201 30.378
Female Labour T-ratio 10.6 6.8 10.2
Tractor Parameter 3.116 0.747 -7.475
Hours T-ratio 0.1 18.8 -2.4
Bullock Days Parameter 68.852 0.631 -18.979
T-ratio 1.8 10.3 -4.0
Manure Parameter -56.487 0.048 -4.633
T-ratio -2.9 1.5 -2.0
Total Parameter -65.324 0.435 11.378
Fertilizer T-ratio -3.0 7.3 -4.3
DAP Parameter -12.092 0.090 -3.347
T-ratio -1.l 1.3 -2.4
Urea Parameter -38.948 0.208 -5.503
T-ratio -3.7 3.7 -4.2
Nitrogen Parameter -16.747 0.123 -1.380
T-ratio -2.4 2.3 -1.6
No. of Parameter 2.845 0.002 0.042
Weedings T-ratio 1.7 0.2 0.2
No. of Parameter -18.342 0.117 -3.143
Irrigations T-ratio -3.5 1.9 -4.7
No. of Parameter -21.705 0.083 -2.758
Ploughings T-ratio -4.8 1.7 -5.0
Independent Variables
Dependent Rabi Tractor Bullock
Variable Estimate 1988-89 Hire Rate Hire Rate
Wheat Parameter -32.360 7.273 -0.01
Harvested T-ratio -1.9 6.9 -1.0
Hired Labour Parameter -20.566 2.656 0.007
T-ratio -1.1 2.6 0.7
Family Male Parameter -36.226 2.224 0.036
Labour T-ratio -1.8 2.0 3.1
Family Parameter 34.569 -2.266 -0.019
Female Labour T-ratio 8.7 -10.0 -8.2
Tractor Parameter -5.857 0.180 -0.004
Hours T-ratio -1.4 0.8 -1.6
Bullock Days Parameter -7.466 0.816 0.009
T-ratio -1.2 2.3 2.5
Manure Parameter -3.844 0.911 -0.001
T-ratio -1.2 5.0 -0.3
Total Parameter 8.797 1.010 0.001
Fertilizer T-ratio -2.5 4.9 0.3
DAP Parameter -0.945 0.280 -0.002
T-ratio -0.5 2.6 -1.4
Urea Parameter -4.708 0.540 0.000
T-ratio -2.7 5.4 0.2
Nitrogen Parameter -1.698 0.189 0.000
T-ratio -1.4 2.8 0.3
No. of Parameter 0.678 -0.027 -0.001
Weedings T-ratio 2.4 -1.6 -3.7
No. of Parameter -2.404 0.367 0.001
Irrigations T-ratio -2.8 7.3 2.5
No. of Parameter -2.363 0.478 0.000
Ploughings T-ratio -3.3 10.7 1.1
Independent Variables
Dependent Wheat Wage
Variable Estimate Price Rate
Wheat Parameter 1.945 -1.391
Harvested T-ratio 3.4 -4.4
Hired Labour Parameter 0.659 -0.845
T-ratio 1.1 -2.7
Family Male Parameter -2.962 -5.391
Labour T-ratio -4.3 -15.1
Family Parameter -1.385 -0.108
Female Labour T-ratio -10.4 -1.6
Tractor Parameter -0.044 -0.090
Hours T-ratio -0.3 -1.3
Bullock Days Parameter -0.625 -1.327
T-ratio -3.0 -12.2
Manure Parameter 0.143 -0.227
T-ratio 1.4 -4.3
Total Parameter 0.260 -0.355
Fertilizer T-ratio 2.2 -5.8
DAP Parameter 0.023 -0.150
T-ratio 0.4 -4.6
Urea Parameter 0.164 -0.138
T-ratio 2.8 -4.6
Nitrogen Parameter 0.086 -0.037
T-ratio 2.2 -1.8
No. of Parameter -0.010 -4.008
Weedings T-ratio -1.1 -1.5
No. of Parameter 0.012 -0.069
Irrigations T-ratio 0.4 -4.7
No. of Parameter 0.016 -0.14
Ploughings T-ratio 0.7 -11.2
Independent Variables
Operational Holding (Acres)
Dependent Canal- Well-
Variable Rainfed irrigated irrigated
Wheat Parameter 1.446 2.094 2.334
Harvested T-ratio 4.8 11.8 0.3
Hired Labour Parameter 1.627 0.970 -3.528
T-ratio 5.4 5.7 -0.4
Family Male Parameter 0.641 0.073 1.797
Labour T-ratio 1.9 0.4 0.2
Family Parameter -0.001 0.062 0.031
Female Labour T-ratio 0.0 1.7 0.0
Tractor Parameter 0.252 0.112 0.436
Hours T-ratio 3.7 2.9 0.2
Bullock Days Parameter 0.034 0.068 0.257
T-ratio 0.3 1.2 0.1
Manure Parameter -0.031 -0.033 -0.608
T-ratio -0.6 -1.2 -0.5
Total Parameter 0.192 0.198 -0.597
Fertilizer T-ratio 3.1 5.7 -0.4
DAP Parameter 0.119 0.088 0.186
T-ratio 3.7 4.9 0.2
Urea Parameter 0.094 0.096 -0.299
T-ratio 3.3 5.7 -0.4
Nitrogen Parameter 0.068 0.025 -0.368
T-ratio 3.4 2.4 -0.7
No. of Parameter 0.002 -0.001 -0.097
Weedings T-ratio 0.5 -0.6 -0.8
No. of Parameter -0.011 0.014 -0.135
Irrigations T-ratio -0.8 1.8 -0.4
No. of Parameter 0.022 0.011 -0.198
Ploughings T-ratio 1.9 1.7 -0.6
Independent Variables
Dependent F- R-
Variable Ratio Square
Wheat Parameter 235.540 0.769
Harvested T-ratio
Hired Labour Parameter 21.890 0.236
T-ratio
Family Male Parameter 148.020 0.676
Labour T-ratio
Family Parameter 26.470 0.272
Female Labour T-ratio
Tractor Parameter 54.570 0.435
Hours T-ratio
Bullock Days Parameter 63.650 0.473
T-ratio
Manure Parameter 12.430 0.149
T-ratio
Total Parameter 31.120 0.305
Fertilizer T-ratio
DAP Parameter 12.020 0.145
T-ratio
Urea Parameter 19.600 0.217
T-ratio
Nitrogen Parameter 6.530 0.084
T-ratio
No. of Parameter 7.000 0.090
Weedings T-ratio
No. of Parameter 59.800 0.458
Irrigations T-ratio
No. of Parameter 82.510 0.538
Ploughings T-ratio
Table 3
Elasticities of Input Demand, Dynamic Model Estimates, Pakistan Panel,
1986-87 to 1988-89
With Respect to
Tractor Bullock Wheat Wage
Elasticity of Hire Rate Hire Rate Price Rate
Wheat Harvested 8.094# -0.026 2.960# -0.935#
Hired Labour 9.735# 0.062 3.302 -1.869#
Family Male Labour 2.392# 0.090# -4.355# -3.501#
Family Female Labour -38.571# -0.755# -32.247# -1.107#
Tractor Hours 1.855# -0.088# -0.627 -0.559
Bullock Days 4.867# 0.128# -5.100# -4.783#
Manure 18.353# -0.026 3.946 -2.761#
Total Fertilizer 10.509# 0.014 3.697# -2.230#
DAP 9.828# -0.129 1.092 -3.191#
Urea 11.485# 0.008 4.762# -1.767#
Nitrogen 13.868# 0.031 8.607# -1.665#
No. of Weedings -9.135# -0.481# -4.822 -1.562
No. of Irrigations 10.252# 0.083# 0.470 -1.173#
No. of Ploughings 8.194# 0.019 0.384 -1.453#
With Respect to
Operational Holding (Acres)
Rainfed Canal- Well-
Elasticity of irrigated irrigated
Wheat Harvested 0.051# 0.308# 0.001
Hired Labour 0.189# 0.469# -0.003
Family Male Labour 0.022# 0.010 0.000
Family Female Labour 0.000 0.139# 0.000
Tractor Hours 0.083# 0.153# 0.001
Bullock Days 0.007 0.054 0.000
Manure -0.020 -0.088 -0.003
Total Fertilizer 0.063# 0.273# -0.002
DAP 0.132# 0.407# 0.002
Urea 0.064# 0.269# -0.002
Nitrogen 0.158# 0.247# -0.007
No. of Weedings 0.024 -0.065 -0.008
No. of Irrigations -0.010 0.053# -0.001
No. of Ploughings 0.012# 0.025# -0.001
Notes: Figures in bold indicate statistical significance at the
10 percent level.
Notes: Figures in bold indicate statistical significance at the 10
percent level indicated with #.
Table 4
Estimates of [lambda] and the Speed of Adjustment
Adjustment
Estimate Parameter
Variable of [lambda] (1 - [lamda])
Wheat Harvested 0.603# 0.397#
Hired Labour 0.482# 0.518#
Family Male Labour 0.698# 0.302#
Family Female Labour 0.201# 0.799#
Tractor Hours 0.747# 0.253#
Bullock Days 0.631# 0.369#
Manure 0.048 0.952
Total Fertilizer 0.435# 0.565#
DAP 0.090 0.910
Urea 0.208# 0.792#
Nitrogen 0.123# 0.877#
No. of Weedings 0.002# 0.998#
No. of Irrigations 0.117# 0.883#
No. of Ploughings 0.083# 0.917#
Notes: Figures in bold indicate statistical significance at the
10 percent level.
Notes: Figures in bold indicate statistical significance at the
10 percent level indicated with #.