The search for a stable money demand function for Pakistan: an application of the method of cointegration.
Hossain, Akhtar
I. INTRODUCTION
Despite an impressive number of studies on money demand in Pakistan
since the early 1970s, the question of stability of the money demand
function did not receive much attention. This paper examines the
question of whether there exists a stable money demand function in
Pakistan. The novelty of the study comes from the application of the
method of cointegration to Pakistani annual data over 1951-91. (1) The
empirical findings of this study are somewhat different from those of
earlier studies on money demand in Pakistan and have monetary policy
implications. However, besides some inherent shortcomings of the method
of cointegration, one possible weakness of the paper is the use of data
which extend over the 1950s and 1960s when Bangladesh was a part of
Pakistan. It creates an unavoidable problem of data conformability. It
induced me to take the risk of being somewhat complacent about the
sample size as I report empirical results for a shorter sample period
1972-91. One consolation is that empirical findings for this sub-sample
appear qualitatively better than those obtained for the full sample
period.
II. TESTS FOR UNIT ROOTS
A long run money demand function for a developing country can be
specified as: ln [m.sub.t] = [alpha]0 + [alpha]1 ln y, + [alpha]2 ln
[int.sub.t] + [alpha]3 [[pi].sup.e], where ln is natural logarithmic operator, in is real (narrow or broad) money balances, y is real
income/output (measured or permanent), int is a representative interest
rate, [[pi].sup.e] is expected inflation and [alpha]s are structural
parameters with the expected signs: [alpha]1> 0 and [alpha]2,
[alpha]3 < 0. Based on this specification the following variables
have been subjected to unit root testing to determine their eligibility
to form a long run equilibrium relationship.
Definitions of Real Money Balances
ln(M1/CPI) = natural log of real narrow money balances (the stock
of narrow money (M1), Millions of Rupees, deflated by the consumer price
index (CPI), 1985 = 1.00).
ln(M2/CPI) = natural log of real broad money balances (the stock of
narrow money plus quasi-money (M2), Millions of Rupees, deflated by the
consumer price index (CPI), 1985 = 1.00).
Definition of Scale Variable
ln RGDP = natural log of gross domestic product, Millions of
Rupees, at 1985 prices.
Definitions of Opportunity Cost Variables
ln GBY = natural log of yield on government bonds (percent).
ln MR = natural log of the market call rate of interest (percent).
[pi] = natural logarithmic difference of the consumer price index
(1985 = 100) multiplied by 100.
Unit Root Tests Results
Appendix Table 1 reports the test results for a unit root in each
of the variables in the money demand function. It shows that the null
hypothesis that real money balances (narrow or broad), real output, the
yield on government bonds and the market call rate of interest have a
unit root cannot be rejected at the 1 percent level. (2) However, the
hypothesis that inflation has a unit root can be rejected by the DF and
ADF(1) tests at the 10 percent level. (3) For both real money balances
(narrow or broad) and real output, even though the hypothesis that
[beta]0 = [beta]1 = [beta]2 = 0 is rejected at the 5 percent level, the
hypothesis that [beta]1 = [beta]2 = 0 cannot be rejected. It suggests
that the log of real money balances (narrow or broad) and the log of
real output follow a random walk with a drift. In the cases of yield on
government bonds and the market call rate of interest, the hypothesis
that [beta]0 = [beta]l = [beta]2 = 0 cannot be rejected at the 5 percent
level. It suggests that the log of yield on government bonds and the log
of the market call rate of interest follow a random walk with no drift.
III. TESTS FOR COINTEGRATION
The presence of a unit root in each of real narrow and broad money
balances, real output and the interest rate suggests that they are
eligible to form a cointegrating set or long run equilibrium
relationship. The inflation rate is not however eligible to form a
cointegral relationship with any of the above variables because it
appears to be integrated of order zero I(0).
Besides the DF and ADF tests, the Cointegrating Regression Durbin-Watson (CRDW) test has been conducted to determine the presence
of cointegration between each of real narrow and broad money balances
and real output (with or without the interest rate). Appendix Table 2
reports the cointegration tests results. For the two variable case the
CRDW and ADF tests results for 1951-91 suggest that there is a
cointegral relationship between the log of real narrow money balances
and the log of real output. However, such a relationship does not exist
between the log of real broad money balances and the log of real output.
The coefficient of the interest rate bears a positive sign in each of
real narrow and broad money balances cointegrating regressions for
1951-91, which indicates that the interest rate perhaps does not form a
cointegral relationship with each of real narrow and broad money
balances. Even though the practice of including dummy variables in a
cointegrating regression to capture extraordinary events has come under
criticism [Engle and Granger (1991); Muscatelli and Hurn (1992)], in the
cointegrating regression for 1951-91 a dummy variable has been used to
capture the break-up of the country in 1971. The inclusion of such a
dummy did not give any better results in rejecting the null hypothesis
of non-cointegration. (4)
For the sub-sample 1972-91 the cointegration tests results are
qualitatively better. All the tests results indicate a cointegral
relationship among real money balances (narrow or broad), real output
and the interest rate. Importantly, the coefficient of the interest rate
bears a negative sign in the cointegrating regression. However, because
of small sample size, the cointegral relationship among these variables
cannot be formally tested.
The Johansen Cointegration Tests
The Engle-Granger procedure of testing for cointegration has a
number of shortcomings. One major shortcoming of the Engle-Granger
approach is that it tests for the presence of a unique cointegrating
relationship even though in the case of more than two variables there is
always a possibility of multiple cointegration relationships [Muscatelli
and Hurn (1992)]. The possibility of multiple cointegration
relationships can be examined within a multivariate framework proposed
by Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990). Johansen and
Juselius (1990) propose two likelihood ratio tests for the number of
cointegrating vectors: the trace test and the maximum eigenvalue test.
The trace test evaluates the null hypothesis that there are at most r
cointegrating vectors against the general alternative, while the maximum
eigenvalue test evaluates the null hypothesis that there are r
cointegrating vectors against the alternative of r + 1. Johansen and
Juselius (1990) also provide a methodology for testing hypotheses about
estimated coefficients of cointegrating vectors based on likelihood
ratio tests with standard chi-squared distributions.
Appendix Table 3 reports the Johansen cointegration tests results
among real narrow or broad money balances, real output and the market
call rate of interest. Both the trace and maximum eigenvalue tests are
reported to determine the number of cointegrating vectors.
The trace test results reject the null hypothesis of r = 0. The
null hypothesis that r [less than or equal to] 1 however cannot be
rejected. The maximum eigenvalue test provides an alternative check for
the number of cointegrating vectors. The results of the maximum
eigenvalue test accord well with those of the trace test and suggest
that there is one cointegrating vector. The fact that the maximum
eigenvalue test rejects the null is noteworthy because Johansen and
Juselius (1990) note that the power of the trace test is relatively low.
Appendix Table 5 reports the implied long run income and interest
elasticities of demand for real money balances (obtained after
normalising the cointegrating vectors). It shows that the interest
elasticity of demand for each of real narrow and broad money balances is
positive for 1953-91. Because this finding is theoretically
inconsistent, the Johansen cointegration tests have been conducted
between the log of real narrow or broad money balances and the log of
real output. Appendix Table 4 reports the tests results. Both the trace
and maximum eigenvalue tests results suggest that there is one
cointegrating vector between the log of real narrow or broad money
balances and the log of real output.
From the unrestrained cointegrating vectors for 1953-91 the
following two normalised equations can be selected as long run money
demand equations because they are consistent with economic theory and
the implied income elasticities make economic sense. For example, the
value of income elasticity of demand for real narrow money balances is
1.17, while the value of income elasticity of demand for real broad
money balances is 1.30. A likelihood ratio test has been conducted for
the parameter restriction that the value of income elasticity of demand
for each of real narrow and broad money balances is one. This
restriction is rejected for each of real narrow and broad money
balances.
Sample: 1953-91
In(M1/CPI) = constant +1.17 ln RGDP
In(M2/CPI) = constant +1.30 ln RGDP
Sample: 1972-91
Two Cointegrating Vectors
The Johansen cointegration tests results for 1972-91 in Appendix
Table 4 suggest that there are two cointegrating vectors. As indicated
earlier, the strength of the Johansen cointegration testing methodology
over the Engle-Granger one is its ability to detect multiple
cointegration when there are more than two variables in the
cointegrating set. This strength of the Johansen methodology is
associated with one of its weaknesses that there is no satisfactory way
of interpreting multiple cointegrated vectors in economic terms
[Muscatelli and Hurn (1992)].
From the unrestrained cointegrating vectors for 1972-91 the
following two normalised equations can be selected as long run money
demand functions because they are consistent with economic theory and
the implied income and interest elasticities make economic sense. The
value of income elasticity of demand for real narrow money balances is
lower than one, while the value of income elasticity of demand for real
broad money balances is around one. The absolute value of interest
elasticity of demand for real narrow money balances is found higher than
that for real broad money balances. Such a difference in the values of
interest elasticities of demand for real narrow and broad money balances
has been found in studies, such as Hafer and Jansen (1991), for other
countries.
Sample: 1972-91
In (M1/CPI) = constant +0.86 ln RGDP -0.54 ln MR
In (M2/CPI) = constant +1.07 ln RGDP -0.05 ln MR
IV. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
This paper has examined the question of whether there exists a
stable money demand function in Pakistan for 1951-91 by applying the
method of cointegration. Tests for unit roots suggest that each of real
narrow and broad money balances, real output and a representative
interest rate (the market call rate of interest or the yield on
government bonds), but not inflation, appear to have a unit root. Based
on these unit root tests results, the Engle-Granger procedure has been
adopted initially to test for cointegration among real narrow or broad
money balances, real output and a measure of the interest rate. As the
CRDW, DF and ADF tests results have given conflicting results about the
presence of a cointegral relationship among real narrow or broad money
balances, real output and the interest rate, the Johansen multivariate
cointegration tests have been conducted to resolve the issue. The latter
tests have shown that there is a cointegral relationship between the log
of real narrow or board money balances and the log of real output for
1953-91. The likelihood ratio test results suggest that the value of
income elasticity of demand for each of real narrow and broad money
balances is greater than one. However, for the sub-sample 1972-91, the
Johansen cointegration tests results among real narrow or broad money
balances, real output and the market call rate of interest suggest the
presence of two cointegrating vectors. From the two unconstrained
cointegrating vectors one normalised equation has been derived and
interpreted as the long run money demand function as it is consistent
with economic theory and the implied income and interest elasticities of
demand for money make economic sense. However, because of small sample
size, the tests results for 1972-91, although qualitatively superior to
those obtained for the full sample period, are to be used cautiously.
The presence of a cointegral relationship between each of real
narrow and broad money balances and real output is consistent with the
notion of a stable long run money demand relationship, albeit in a
limited sense. (5) An implication of a stable money demand function is
that there is potential for achieving price stability by controlling the
growth rate of the money supply. The overall empirical results suggest
that the narrow money demand function is more stable than the broad
money demand function and hence a narrow monetary aggregate may be used
for monetary targeting in Pakistan. (6) It would however require the
monetary authority in Pakistan to consider price stability, instead of a
multitude of objectives, as the main objective of monetary policy and to
adopt a more flexible exchange rate system in order to ensure control
over the stock of money supply.
Comments on "The Search for a Stable Money Demand Function for
Pakistan: An Application of the Method of Cointegration"
This paper by Dr Hossain identifies the stability of the money
demand function for Pakistan by using the cointegration technique.
Conventional econometric techniques can only be applied to stationary
variables, therefore, it poses certain problems when applied to
variables which are non-stationary in nature. However, recent
econometric development in the area of time-series analysis has dealt
with such problems in a quite simple but interesting fashion. Now it has
been realised that the determination of the long-run relationship in
variables being studied, is the primary objective of any economic
research, and Dr Hossain has provided an excellent application of the
method of cointegration to identify the long-run stable relationship of
the money demand function. There are a few comments to be made.
First, Dr Hossain has used yield on government bonds and market
call rate of interest as opportunity cost variables in this study and he
came up with theoretically inconsistent interest elasticity parameters
as the coefficient of the rate of interest bears a positive sign. Also,
he does not find any cointegral relationship of the interest rate with
each of the real narrow and broad money balances for the full sample
period covering the period 1951-91. This perhaps may by due to the
choice of the rate of interest variables used in this study i.e., yield
on government bonds and the market call rate of interest, which are not
found to be true representatives of the market conditions in Pakistan.
Many of the earlier studies, for example by Khan and Ahmed (1990), have
termed the rate of return on time deposits of different maturity periods
as a better opportunity cost variable to be used in the money demand
specification. Moreover, cointegral relationships of the rate of return
on time deposits of different maturity periods have been found with real
money balances in the case of Pakistan see Ali (1994). In this
situation, by taking rate of return on time deposits of one year as the
short-term rate and the interest rate on time deposits of more than
three years maturity period as the long-term interest rate, the results
of the study can be improved.
Second, the use of the sample period which extends over decades
when Bangladesh was a part of Pakistan, makes this an exercise for
illustrative purposes only. On the other hand, the estimation for the
sub-sample period, 1972-91, makes the sample size too small to employ
this technique. In this circumstance, the use of quarterly data can
resolve some of the problems relating to sample size. Of course, the use
of the quarterly data would not affect the long-run relationship between
the variables, but it will increase the sample size sufficiently large so as to improve the validity of the results achieved. Quarterly data is
easily available for all variables of money demand specification except
for GDP. However, quarterly series of GDP can be generated by using
standard techniques as has been done by Khan (1994).
Finally, this paper identifies a stable long run money demand
relationship. This finding is important because during the 1980s
Pakistan has experienced various reforms, especially exchange rate
reforms, debt management reforms and interest rate liberalisation. These
changes in the financial sector do not have any significant impact on
the long-run behaviour of the money demand. It may, however, be the case
that the changes in the financial environment have not affected the
long-run relationship of money demand but might have rendered somewhat
unpredictable short-run deviations from the long-run equilibrium. Such
deviations obviously have their implications for policy purposes. There
are standard tests like CUSUM or CUSUMSQ which can be employed to
ascertain whether the money demand relationship exhibits predictable
short-run behaviour or not.
Syed Sajid Ali
H. 76-R Block 2, PECH Society, Karachi.
REFERENCES
Khan, Ashfaque H. (1994) Financial Liberalisation and the Demand
for Money in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 33:4 Part II.
Khan, Ashfaque H., and Mushtaq Ahmed (1990) A Re-examination of the
Stability of the Demand for Money in Pakistan. Journal of the
Macroeconomics 12:2 307-321.
Ali, Syed Sajid (1994) Financial Liberalisation, Money Demand and
Monetary Policy in Pakistan. An Unpublished M. Phil dissertation.
Islamabad.
Appendix Table 1
The Time Series Properties of Variables in the Money Demand Function
Sample Series DF ADF(1) ADF(2) [PHI]2 [PHI]3
1952-91 In (M1/CPI) -2.6 -2.8 -2.0 5.6 2.5
1952-91 In (M2/CPI) -3.0 -3.7 -2.7 7.6 3.5
1951-91 In RGDP -0.6 -0.6 -0.2 6.3 1.9
1952-91 In GBY -1.0 -0.9 -1.0 1.3 0.9
1952-91 In MR -2.4 -1.3 -1.2 3.5 3.3
1952-91 [pi] -3.4 -3.5 -2.6 2.2 3.3
1953-91 A In (M1/CPI) -5.9
1953-91 A In (M2/CPI) -5.9
1952-91 A In RGDP -5.6
1953-91 A In GBY -6.1
1953-91 A In MR -9.0
1953-91 A [pi] -6.7
Source : Fuller (1976:373); Dickey and Fuller (1981, Tables V and
VL 1063). Critical values in parentheses for the DF/ADF statistics
are for cases where the regression equations are estimated with a
constant, but no time trend.
Notes: + The test for a unit root in the level form is based on the
regression equation: [DELTA][z.sub.r] = [beta]0 + [beta]1t +
[beta]2 [z.sub.t-1] + [summation][delta]i [z.sub.t-1] + error term,
where z is the generic term for the variable used for unit root
testing; [DELTA][z.sub.t] = [z.sub.t] - [z.sub.t-1; t is a linear
time trend; [beta]0 is a column of ones, and i = 1, 2, ... 1. The
Dickey-Fuller (DF) test in the level form is based on the above
regression with restriction that Edi = 0. The test of the random
walk hypothesis is the test of the zero restriction on [beta]2.
When the null hypothesis of unit root was not rejected, a
regression of the form, [[DELTA].sup.2][z.sub.t], = [gamma]0 +
[gamma]1 [DELTA][z.sub.t-1] + error term, was run and then the null
hypothesis [gamma]1 = 0 was tested against the alternative
[gamma]1<0.
++ ADF(1) is the augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with
a lag length of 1 = 1, 2.
+++ The statistics [PHI] and [PHI] are for testing the hypotheses
([beta]0 = [beta]1 = [beta]2 = 0) and ([beta]1 = [beta]2 = 0) in the
ADF specification with the lag length of 1 = 2.
! The reported sample period is for the DF test statistic. For the
ADF(1) or ADF(2) test statistic, the sample period of estimation
is reduced by 1 or 2 because of the inclusion of lagged dependent
variable(s) in the estimating equation.
!!Critical Values DF/ADF [PHI]2 [PHI]3
Probability of
a Smaller Value
Sample
Size 1% 5% 10% 0.95 0.95
25 -4.38(-3.75) -3.60(-3.00) -3.24(-2.63) 5.68 7.24
50 -4.15(-3.58) -3.50(-2.93) -3.18(-2.60) 5.13 6.73
Appendix Table 2-A
Cointegration Regressions of Real Money Balances on
Real Output and the Interest Rate
Dependent Coefficient on
Variable ln RGDP ln GBY [R.sup.2] CRDW
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M1/CPI) 1.09 0.03 0.97 0.81
ln (M1/CPI) 1.11 0.97 0.82
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M1/CPI) 1.08 -0.13 0.91 1.00
ln (M1/CPI) 1.05 0.91 0.82
Dependent
Variable DF ADF(1) ADF(2)
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M1/CPI) -3.1 -4.7 -3.4
ln (M1/CPI) -3.2 -4.8 -3.5
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M1/CPI) -3.9 -5.4 -2.9
ln (M1/CPI) -4.0 -5.2 -2.3
Coefficient on
ln RGDP ln MR
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M1/CPI) 1.11 0.003 0.97 0.83
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M1/CPI) 0.95 -0.46 0.97 1.03
Critical Values
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M1/CPI) -3.2 -4.8 -3.5
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M1/CPI) -2.5 -3.3 -3.0
Critical Values
2 Variable Case 3 Variable Case
Statistic Sample Size (5 Percent Level) (5 Percent Level)
CRDW 50 0.78 0.99
DF 50 -3.67 -4.11
ADF 50 -3.29 -3.75
Source: Engle and Yoo (1987).
Appendix Table 2-B
Cointegration Regressions of Real Broad Money Balances on
Real Output and the Interest Rate
Dependent Coefficient on
Variable ln RGDP ln GBY [R.sup.2] CRDW
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M2/CPI) 1.07 0.29 0.97 0.47
ln (M2/CPI) 1.29 0.96 0.43
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M2/CPI) 1.03 0.03 0.91 0.90
ln (M2/CPI) 1.03 0.92 0.92
Dependent
Variable DF ADF(1) ADF(2)
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M2/CPI) -2.3 -3.4 -2.3
ln (M2/CPI) -2.0 -3.1 -1.9
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M2/CPI) -3.7 -5.5 -2.3
ln (M2/CPI) -3.6 -5.4 -2.3
Coefficient on
ln RGDP ln MR
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M2/CPI) 1.14 0.15 0.97 0.88
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M2/CPI) 0.95 -0.39 0.96 0.81
Sample: 1951-91
ln (M2/CPI) -3.3 -4.0 -3.1
Sample: 1972-91
ln (M2/CPI) -2.2 -3.9 -2.3
Notes: Critical values areas for Table 2-A.
Appendix Table 3
The Johansen Cointegration Tests Results
A. In (M1/CPI), In RGDP and In MR were used for cointegration tests;
Maximum Lag in VAR = 2.
Maximal Eigenvalue Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r = 1 29.09 25.54 21.07
r [less than or
equal to] 1 r = 2 4.65 15.95 14.90
r [less than or
equal to] 2 r = 3 1.33 0.83 8.17
Trace Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r [greater 35.07 42.31 31.53
than or
equal to] 1
r [less than or r [greater
equal to] 1 than or
equal to] 2 5.98 16.77 17.95
r [less than or
equal to] 2 r = 3 1.33 0.83 8.18
B. In (M2/CPI), In RGDP and In MR were used for cointegratin tests;
Maximum Lag in VAR = 2.
Maximum Eigenvalue Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r = 1 29.91 30.27 21.07
r [less than or
equal to] 1 r = 2 5.16 21.90 14.90
r [less than or
equal to] 2 r = 3 1.14 0.01 8.18
Trace Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r [greatest
than or
equal to] 1 36.21 52.19 31.53
r [less than or r [greatest
equal to] 1 than or
equal to] 2 6.31 21.92 17.95
r [less than or
equal to] 2 r = 3 1.14 0.01 8.18
Notes: r denotes the number of cointegrating vectors.
Appendix Table 4
The Johansen Cointegration Tests Results
A. In (M1/CPI), In RGDP and In RGDP were used for cointegration tests;
Maximum Lag in VAR = 2.
Maximal Eigenvalue Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r = 1 29.16 23.08 14.19
r [less than r = 2 3.42 1.22 8.18
or equal to] 1
Trace Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r [greater
than or
equal to] 1 32.57 24.29 17.95
r [less than r [greater
or equal to] 1 than or
equal to] 2 3.42 1.22 8.18
B. In (M2/CPI) and In RGDP were used for cointegrating tests; Maximum
Lag in VAR = 2.
Maximum Eigenvalue Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r [greater
than or
equal to] 1 16.48 19.14 14.90
r [less than r [greater
or equal to] 1 than or
equal to] 2 3.81 1.37 8.18
Trace Test
Null Alternative Test Statistic 95% Critical
Hypothesis Hypothesis 1953-91 1972-91 Value
r = 0 r [greater
than or
equal to] 1 20.29 20.51 17.95
r [less than r [greater
or equal to] 1 than or
equal to] 2 3.81 1.37 8.18
Notes: r denotes the number of cointegrating vectors.
Appendix Table 5
Cointegrating Vectors and the Implied Long Run Elasticities
A. Cointegrating Vectors
Sample Vector ln (M1/CPI) ln RGDP ln MR
1953-91 1 1.84 -2.13 -0.01
1953-91 1 -1.82 2.14
1972-91 1 0.77 -1.38 -0.77
2 -4.48 3.86 -2.43
Sample Vector ln (M2/CPI) ln RGDP ln MR
1953-91 1 1.59 -1.86 -0.28
1953-91 1 1.30 1.81
1972-91 1 -2.54 2.74 -0.13
2 2.84 -2.16 2.07
B. Implied Long Run Elasticities
LR Test
([chi
Interest square]
Sample Income Rate (1))
ln (M1/CPI)
1953-91 1.16 0.007
1953-91 * 1.17 15.5 (a)
1972-91 1.79 0.99
1972-91 * 0.86 -0.54
ln (M2/CPI)
1953-91 1.16 0.17
1953-91 * 1.38 9.8 (a)
1972-91 * 1.07 -0.05
1972-91 0.76 -0.73
Notes. * Represents a cointegrating vector that gives theoretically
consistent elasticities.
+ The Likelihood ratio test rejects the parameter restriction that the
income elasticity of demand for each of real narrow and broad money
balances is one ([[micro].sub.y]).
(a) Denotes statistical significance at the 1 percent level.
Author's Note: This is an abridged version of a long and
expanded paper on this topic. I sincerely thank Professor Colin Kearney
and Dr Tony Webber for their substantive comments on an earlier draft of
the paper. I acknowledge the receipt of a travel grant from the Research
Management Committee of the University of Newcastle for attending the
conference and thank both the Pakistan Society of Development Economists
and the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics for their
hospitality during the conference.
REFERENCES
Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller (1981) Likelihood Ratio Statistics
for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Econometrica 50:
1057-72.
Engle, R. F., and B. S. Yoo (1987) Forecasting and Testing in
Cointegrated Systems. Journal of Econometrics 35: 143-59.
Engle, R. F., and C. W. J. Granger (1991) Long Run Economic
Relationships. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Fuller, W. A. (1976) Introduction to Statistical Time Series. New
York: John Wiley.
Hafer, R. W., and D.W. Jansen, (1991) The Demand for Money in the
United States: Evidence from Cointegration Tests. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 23: 155-68.
Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 12: 232-54.
Johansen, S., and K. Juselius (1990) Maximum Likelihood Estimation
and Inference on Cointegration with Applications to the Demand for
Money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 52: 169-209.
Khan, T. M., and A. Bergan (1966) Measurement of Structural Change
in the Pakistan Economy: A Review of the National Income Estimates,
1949-50-1963-64. The Pakistan Development Review 6: 163-208.
Miller, S. (1991) Monetary Dynamics: An Application of
Cointegration and Error-correction Modelling. Journal of Money, Credit,
and Banking 23: 139-54.
Muscatelli, V. A., and S. Hum (1992) Cointegration and Dynamic Time
Series Models. Journal of Economic Surveys 6: 1-43.
(1) The basic data are taken from various issues of both
International Financial Statistics Yearbook and the State Bank of
Pakistan Bulletin and also from Khan and Bergan (1966). The data set
used for the study and their detailed sources may be available from the
author upon request.
(2) By the ADF(1) test, the hypothesis that real broad money
balances have a unit root is rejected at the 5 percent level.
(3) Note that the [PHI]2 and [PHI]3 tests do not reject the null
hypothesis that inflation has a unit root with a drift. When the
inflation rate is calculated from the wholesale price index, the
following values are obtained for the DF, ADF(1), ADF(2), [PHI]2 and
[PHI]3 test statistics: DF = -4.5, ADF(1) = -5.8, ADF(2) = -3.3, [PHI]2
= 4.4 and [PHI]3 = 6.3. From these results it appears that inflation
probably does not have a unit root
(4) Engle and Granger (1991) suggest that when the individual
series are 1(1) with a drift, one may include a time trend in the
cointegrating regression which is equivalent to detrending the series
first. In the case of Pakistan, each of real narrow and broad money
balances and real output are found to be I(1) with a drift. A trend was
therefore included in the cointegrating regression, but the overall
cointegration tests results did not change in qualitative sense.
(5) Long term structural change in the money demand function is
sometimes examined by estimating cointegration regressions for two or
more sub-samples. Looking at the normalised cointegration vectors for
1953-91 and 1972-91, one would find that the income elasticity of demand
for each of real narrow and broad money balances has declined over time
that the interest rate has become significant in the money demand
function during 1972-91. If the small sample bias is assumed small, then
such a result would imply that the long run money demand function in
Pakistan has undergone structural change over time. The idea that there
exists a stable money demand function should therefore be interpreted in
such a way that can accommodate any gradual structural change in
parameter values in response to a structural (and institutional) change
in the economy. Miller (1991) reports results for the United States
which show that the values of income and interest elasticities of demand
for real money balances have changed in recent years, possibly because
of financial innovation and deregulation.
(6) The presence of any cointegral relationship between money and
output would indicate that the velocity of money is stationary. The
Dickey-Fuller tests for a unit root in the velocity of money in Pakistan
give the following results:
Sample Series DF ADF(1) ADF(2)
1952-91 Velocity of M1 -3.2 -4.7 -3.5
1952-91 Velocity of M2 -2.2 -3.3 -2.0
The above unit root tests results provide further evidence that the
narrow money demand function in Pakistan is more stable than the broad
money demand function. One area of further research is to examine the
question of whether the velocity of money in Pakistan has any cointegral
relationship with the interest rate.
Akhtar Hossain is a Lecturer in Economics at the University of
Newcastle, Australia.