Determinants of rural poverty in Pakistan: a micro study.
Malik, Shahnawaz
Using micro survey data obtained from a Punjab village we study a
large number of rural-specific and household-specific variables besides
landholding, in an attempt to determine their role in raising levels of
living of rural masses. We investigated the reasons as to how some of
the landless households managed to escape poverty whereas some
cultivating households failed to do so. (1) The main factors responsible
for this outcome were found to be favourable/unfavourable distribution
by size of landholding, household size, educational attainment,
dependency ratio, participation rates, female-male ratio, and age of the
household head. The landless households escaping poverty, however,
remained in a low-income category. Whereas our analysis highlighted the
importance of institutional setting for a better distribution of assets
and access to resources, at the same time it pointed to the fact that
numerous non-farm activities also enable the rural households to
generate incomes and thus avoid poverty.
1. INTRODUCTION
As the experience of a large number of LDCs in general and that of
Pakistan in particular shows, the substantial advances in agricultural
production on account of the Green Revolution failed to benefit the
lower sections of rural society especially in relative terms [Naseem
(1973), p. 317; Guisinger and Hicks (1978), p. 1274]. Although
considerable interest was generated to study the possible
'trickle-down' effect that might have resulted from increased
productivity in the agricultural sector, yet the conclusions were rather
of a mixed nature. In this regard, it seems appropriate to mention
Griffin (1981), who provides a persuasive account of the relationship
between high agricultural growth and absolute/relative condition of a
significant proportion of rural population in Asia. According to Griffin,
it seems safe to assume that except in countries which have had a
radical redistribution of land, the degree of inequality in rural
Asia has not diminished significantly and in most countries has
increased. Indeed there is evidence supporting the even stronger
proposition that in many areas the absolute standard of living of a
significant minority of the rural population has declined. That is,
despite the growth of per capita income and per capita agricultural
output, large numbers of people in Asia have experienced absolute
impoverishment (p. 289).
Griffin points out three main causes behind this phenomenon, what
he calls 'immiserising growth': (i) concentration of
productive wealth, especially land, in a few hands; (ii) resultant high
degree of inequality in income distribution; and (iii) the control by a
small segment of the population of the instruments of the state and the
use of these to further their own economic interests.
There is little to disagree with in the above explanation. The
experience of Pakistan since the seventies--e.g., undiminished
inequality in land distribution and high growth leading to increased
inequality and diminished absolute poverty seem to be consistent with
that view. As it is generally believed, such a trend may have been due
to the influence of some non-farm factors. One can further add that the
poverty of rural masses may not be completely eradicated through the
redistribution of land alone because there simply is not enough land to
go round. However, redistribution of land must provide a major component
of any such attempt [Chaudhuri (1979); Lipton (1991)].
With these observations in mind, we study a large number of
rural-specific and household-specific variables besides landholding, in
an attempt to determine their role in raising levels of living of rural
masses. In Section 2 below we outline, briefly, the data and methodology
used. Section 3 provides the framework for evaluation, while results are
reported in Section 4. Lastly, in Section 5, we offer concluding remarks
and policy implications.
2. DATA AND METHODOLOGY
The present study shifts the locus from the indices of
rural-specific variables at an aggregative level [This study is a part
of the larger work as reported in Malik (1992)] to various
village-specific and household-specific variables at a disaggregative
level. The study is based on a village survey conducted in Pakistani
Punjab containing I00 households. The village 'Wanda'
(District Bhakkar, Punjab), situated at a distance of 4 miles from the
river Indus, which forms the boundary with the North West Frontier
Province, could be taken as a fair representative of the characteristics
of the two provinces. The survey, carried out in March/April, 1990,
makes no claim to being completely representative of rural Pakistan. We
do feel, however, that the findings based on this sample, when broadly
interpreted, can serve as useful generalisations. This view is based on
the data given in Table 1, which summarises and compares the main
features of the present survey with that of the Federal Bureau of
Statistics, 1986-87 (a summarised description of the survey is given in
Appendix 1).
The survey was a 'one-shot' exercise and repeated surveys
were not possible. Within the community, the objective was the total
enumeration of households. The village had 100 households and 100
percent enumeration was obtained. In general, households tended to have
multiple attributes in terms of sectoral and organisational
involvements. Data on production activities, income, and employment were
obtained.
Per capita rural income is considered to be an important measure of
the level of living and, hence, is used as the key/dependent variable
here. The hypotheses as outlined in the next section are tested mainly
by means of decomposition of FGT index for [alpha]=2 [Foster et al.
(1984)] in terms of various characteristics/determinants of the rural
households' level of living. In the end, regression analyses are
also carried out to confirm the above results.
3. HYPOTHESES AND SELECTION OF EXPLANATORY VARIABLES
The explanatory variables are described as follows:
Landholding (LHO)
The ownership/holding of agricultural land is considered to be the
main factor capable of pulling a household/individual out of poverty.
The variable used here is the extent of landholding per household in
acres. This incorporates owner-cure-share-croppers as well as
share-croppers. On the basis of the role it plays in a rural economy, we
hypothesise that landholding has an income-enhancing
(poverty-mitigating) role.
Other Assets (AST)
Apart from landholding, other assets such as draught cattle,
tractor, tube-well, etc., also contribute in raising the earnings of the
households owning them. In the present survey, we have obtained detailed
information on such assets. These are measured in terms of rupee value
of total assets. We hypothesise that other assets have an
income-enhancing role.
Household Size (HSZ)
The evidence shows that the proportion of poor households in the
total number of households of a given size rises with an increase in
household size upto 7-8 persons, and then gradually declines [Anand
(1977); Gaiha and Kazmi (1981)]. One reason may be that the proportion
of children ([less than or equal to] 14 years) tends to be high over
this range. In other words, the number of potential earners in a
household increases beyond this range. As the average number of members
per household in our survey happens to be slightly over 6, i.e., less
than the range after which earnings start picking up, we hypothesise
that a higher household size has a poverty-increasing role.
Education (EDU)
It is generally believed that the best investment of all is the one
made in people. According to human capital models, education is an
important dimension of nonhomogeneity of labour. Hence, high educational
attainment may imply a larger set of employment opportunities, and
specifically in a rural context a better awareness of the full potential
of the new agricultural technology and associated agricultural
practices. The education data in our survey is obtained according to the
following procedure:
No education by a household member ... ... ... 0 points
Education upto secondary level ... ... ... 5 points
Education upto college/university ... ... ... 10 points
It would be proper to note that there was greater differentiation
to any education upto secondary level. Indeed it would be desirable to
measure the variable continuously by equating points with numbers of
years of schooling. However, the above procedure is followed to keep the
analysis within manageable limit.
The required level is arrived at by dividing total of educational
points by the household size. In view of its potential role we
hypothesise that the higher the educational attainment, the higher the
per capita income.
Dependency Ratio (DEP)
For a given household size, a larger number of children and old age
members would imply a smaller number of earners in the household. In the
present analysis, the dependency ratio is defined as the ratio of number
of members ([less than or equal to] 14 years and [greater than or not
equal to] 65 years) to household size. We hypothesise that the higher
the dependency burden, the lower the per capita income.
Participation Rate (PAR)
The participation rate is the first of the two employment variables
used in the analysis. According to Lipton (1983), the higher is illness,
disability, income per capita, intensity in customs and religious
beliefs, status, and the general welfare level and asset holding, the
lower are the participation rates in the LDCs. In other words, comparing
the non-poor and the poor, the positive incentive given by poverty to
participation outweighs the negative effect on it of the higher
unemployment rates normally prevailing amongst the poor. Hence, they
participate more than the non-poor.
A comparison of the poor and the extremely poor, however, suggests
that the damage that extreme poverty does to the ability to participate
(due to illness, disability, etc.) often tends to push the extremely
poor's participation rates below those of the poor. This implies
that the extremely poor's ability to participate would be less than
the poor's but more than that of the non-poor. In the present
analysis, the participation rate is defined as the ratio of number of
workers to number of adults in a household. In accordance with the above
arguments, the participation rates are expected to give results.
Female-Male Ratio (FMR)
Female-male ratio is the second of the two employment variables
used in the analysis. In view of the fact that female members in a
household in rural Pakistan are mostly constrained by their customs and
religious norms from work outside the household, their attitude to
participation is rather discouraging. This suggests that a high
female-male ratio may be poverty-enhancing.
Age of Household Head (AGE)
The age and sex composition is important in a household in the
determination of the attitude towards work. The age of the household
head has a similar role as the sex composition, discussed above, in
determining income per capita in an LDC like Pakistan. Income per capita
and age of household head can be assumed to have a positive relationship
over the age bracket of 25 to 45 years, and a negative relationship
beyond this bracket. However, since the sample household heads tend
towards the upper age bracket (40 years and above), we assume a negative
relationship between these two variables.
4. ESTIMATES AND RESULTS
A summary of the survey data is given in Table 1. For purposes of
comparison we have also reported a summary of comparable country level
data, based on the HIES, 1986-87. The representative nature of the
survey can be seen by comparing the data on members per household,
earners per household, landholding Gini coefficients, and income per
household as well as per capita income in real terms. As we can see,
these figures are reasonably comparable. The decrease in percentage
poverty over the period also makes sense keeping in view the declining
trend witnessed over the last two decades. However, one slight variation
is observable. The range of poverty estimates based on two poverty lines
is far narrower in our survey. This may well be due to the small sample
size of the present survey. Another possibility is that gradually the
range of poverty estimates based on different poverty lines is narrowing
down.
The data on distribution of landholding is given in Table 2. The
present survey and the Government of Pakistan Census, 1980 give roughly
similar distributions. The figures suggest that the distribution of
landholding is highly skewed as shown by the value of Gini coefficient,
which is 0.56 in 1989-90 and 0.55 in 1980. The detailed disaggregated survey data provides us with some interesting information. We find that
19 out of 100 households are landless but not all of these are in
poverty. In fact, a 10 of the 19 landless households are found to be
poor; which means about 50 percent of the total landless households are
in poverty. We have carried out FGT decomposition of poverty based on
the size of landholding (Table 3). The results suggests that the
intensity of poverty is most severe among the landless population, with
FGT measure equal to 0.089. This sub-group also contributes most
prominently to total poverty: 65.8 percent of total population in
poverty is accounted for by this sub-group. Both intensity and
contribution to total poverty decline as the size of landholding
increases, which is in line with our hypothesis.
As noted above, 9 landless households (out of 19) have, somehow,
managed to escape poverty. Let us follow these 9 households in some
detail. One household consisting of four members has been able to
acquire a tractor (through some loans and a retirement gratuity) which
is run on a commercial basis. Two households, each containing four
members, run their own small businesses. We find one of these 9
households as the only member of the household, a blacksmith by
profession. The remaining five households are government employees. One
can infer a lot from this tiny bit of information. For instance, small
household size together with favourable earner's ratio is enough to
avoid poverty. This has already been illustrated by this author using
aggregated HIES data [Malik (1992)]. Presently, we cross-check it with
the help of micro survey data. The results are given in Table 4.
The estimates of the decomposed FGT measure show that the intensity
of poverty gradually increases with household size upto 7
members/household. This subgroup with 0.033 FGT measure also contributes
most prominently to total poverty: 31.66 percent of total population in
poverty is accounted for by this sub group. As already noted, the
household size found most prone to rural poverty was one with 7-8
members/household. Furthermore, the household size considered to be the
optimal one (with 4 members) experiences a far lower intensity of
poverty--i.e., an FGT measure of just 0.003. Here, once again, our
hypothesis is not falsified.
A further perusal of the data suggests that 7 out of 9 households
(landless households who managed to escape poverty) have reasonable
educational levels. According to human capital models, education is an
important dimension of non-homogeneity of labour. To look into this more
explicitly, we decomposed the FGT index of poverty in terms of levels of
educational attainment. The results are given in Table 5. The results
suggest that the intensity of poverty is most severe among the
population with no educational attainment. The FGT measure for this
sub-group is equal to 0.057. This sub-group also contributes most to
total poverty: 61.4 percent of total population in poverty is accounted
for by this sub-group. Both intensity and contribution to total poverty
decline as the level of educational attainment increases. Hence, a high
educational level may imply a larger set of employment opportunities and
higher wages. This fact is further verified from Table 6, which suggests
that in 1984-85 an educated employee (with education upto secondary
level) earned far higher wages, Rs 1337/month, as compared to an
illiterate's Rs 714/month.
It was, therefore, not surprising to see these households avoiding
poverty. All these 9 households are, however, placed in a low-income
group. This brief discussion leads to the conclusion that small
household size, own businesses, and reasonable education level and
employment are the factors that help in escaping poverty but cannot
ensure reasonable income levels.
Now a few words about the 10 households which are cultivators but
unable to escape poverty. These households have small landholdings
ranging from 2 acres to 4 acres and, at the same time, large household
sizes ranging from 4 members to 9 members per household. Further, with
negligible educational levels, the employment opportunities are
non-existent. Some of the members work as casual labourers but this
status does not guarantee regular earnings to avoid poverty. A closer
look at the economic situation of these households reveals that their
poverty can be best explained in terms of unfavourable setting of one or
more of dependency ratio, participation rates, and female-male ratio.
To get a closer view of the above three aspects, we have decomposed
the FGT index of poverty in terms of each of these. We start with the
dependency ratio which may be regarded as having a significant impact on
a household's well-being. The estimates, given in Table 7, show an
increase in the intensity of poverty with an increase in the dependency
ratio. The sub-group with the highest dependency ratio encounters the
highest FGT measure (0.053). This sub-group also contributes
substantially more to total poverty: 81.42 percent of total population
in poverty is accounted for by this subgroup.
Next, we have decomposed the FGT index of poverty in terms of the
participation rates. The participation rate is the first of the two
employment variables used in the analysis. As may be recalled, we noted
previously that the extremely poor's ability to participate would
be less than the poor's but more than that of the non-poor
(Lipton's proposition), which forms a useful hypothesis. The
estimates of the decomposed FGT index, given in Table 8, show that the
extremely poor sub-groups with FGT measures of 0.009 and 0.026 have
participation rates in the range of 0-0.50. The less poor sub-group with
an FGT measure of 0.001, on the other hand, has participation rates in
the range of 0.51-1.00, which is higher than those of the extremely
poor. These estimates give some indication in favour of the proposed
hypothesis.
Last poverty group to be decomposed is in terms of the female-male
ratio. The results are given in Table 9. The estimates show an increase
in the intensity of poverty with an increase in female-male ratio. The
sub-group with the highest female-male ratio experiences the highest FGT
measure (0.040). This sub-group also contributes significantly more to
total poverty: 35.75 percent of total population in poverty is accounted
for by this sub-group. This suggests that a household with high
female-male ratio may be more prone to poverty in rural Pakistan.
This discussion leads us to an important dimension of rural
poverty--poverty among female-headed households. In rural Pakistan,
female-headed households form a highly heterogeneous group. There could
be many factors leading to female-headed households, including not only
widowhood but also male migration and divorce, amongst others. Little
can be inferred about the proportion of a particular sub-group from
aggregative observations but one fact remains clear that female heads in
rural Pakistan are often found to include a very large proportion of
widows.
The empirical links between female-headedness and rural poverty in
Pakistan remain to be investigated in some detail. For example, there is
no evidence that female-, headed households in rural Pakistan are in
fact 'poorer' than male-headed households. While remaining
within the limitations of our small sample survey, we attempt to
establish that female-headed households (especially widows) are a group
more prone to deprivation and poverty.
Our sample of 100 households contains just two cases of
female-headedness. Incidentally, both belong to the widow's
sub-group and both failed to cross the poverty-line. This gives rise to
the following comments. First, these female-headed households are on
average smaller than male-headed ones. We know from our earlier findings
that the proportion of poor households in the total number of households
of a given size rises with an increase in the household size up to 7-8
persons and then the proportion gradually declines due to the increase
of potential earners beyond this range.
Secondly, the dependency ratio among these households is high which
simultaneously suggests that the households have a low earners'
ratio. The relationship between a low earners' ratio and poverty is
evident, a fact that this author has shown in detail elsewhere [Malik
(1992)]. Thirdly, the household earners in the above two households lack
any regular wage-employment. This is yet another common reason behind
rural poverty. Albeit the sample is small, the evidence suggests that
female-headed households characterised by these features are likely to
end up in poverty.
In addition to the above, these hypotheses may also be tested using
the cross-section survey data on 100 households. Here we have also
included the remaining two variables--AST and AGE--which were not
analysed above due to some data problems. In order to carry out
estimation, we propose the following general formulation of multivariate
log-linear relationship:
Y = BX + U
where 'Y' stands for vector of 'n' observations
on dependent variable, 'B' is the coefficient vector,
'X' stands for matrix of observations on explanatory variables
and 'U' represents the error vector. The variables (all in
logs) used here are defined as follows:
(i) the dependent variable is measured as income per capita;
(ii) the explanatory variables such as LHO, AST, HSZ, EDU, DEP,
PAR, FMR, and AGE as defined above; and
(iii) The error term is as usually defined.
In order to have an optimal use of the survey data, the regression
analysis has been carried out at three different levels, as described
below:
(i) analysis of the complete sample of 100 households to infer into
the totality;
(ii) analysis on the basis of higher income households (43
households with per capita income greater than Rs 300 per month); and
(iii) analysis on the basis of lower income households (57
households with per capita income less than Rs 300 per month).
The results are reported in Table 10. As we can see, the
explanatory power of regression Equation 1, as measured by [R.sup.2] is
significantly high. The joint test of significance, F-test, is accepted
at 1 percent level. The results suggest that the coefficients on LHO,
HSZ, AST, EDU, and DEP are significant at 1 percent to 5 percent level
and have signs in accordance with our hypotheses. The coefficients of
FMR and AGE have the correct signs with the Tatter significant at 10
percent whereas the former gives insignificant result. Just as we
anticipated in the previous section, the PAR has given inconclusive results.
Equation 2 reports estimates on 43 higher income households. The
[R.sup.2] is moderately high whereas the F-test is significant at 1
percent level. The results derived here are not much different from
those of Equation 1 above. There are, however, some minor variations.
The coefficients on LHO and EDU variables are found to be slightly
larger than those arrived at on the basis of complete sample estimates.
This is to be expected as the higher income households derive a larger
part of their income from those sources. An interesting picture is
presented by the coefficient of PAR which is large and significantly
negative. This suggests, in line with our hypothesis, that the higher
the income the lower the participation.
Equation 3 gives estimates based on 57 lower-income household. The
[R.sup.2] is moderately high and F-test significant at 1 percent level.
As the results suggest, almost all the coefficients have
'correct' signs. The coefficients on LHO and EDU are smaller
than those obtained from previous equations. This is to be expected. DEP
and FMR have a strong negative effect on the dependent variable which
highlights the vulnerability of low-income households to a high level of
dependency and female-male ratio. Another important result is in terms
of AST, which turns out to be highly insignificant. This implies that
other assets do not contribute much to the incomes of the lower-income
households. Once again, the coefficient on PAR presents a variation.
This time it turns out to be positive with significance level at 10
percent. This means the lower-income households tend to participate more
as compared to the higher-income households--just as Lipton proposed.
As end-result of the above analyses, the extremely poor are
likeliest to be in the most unemployment-prone group, casual labour, due
to their extremely unskilled status. The role of education, (being
skilled) and thus proper employment, in combating rural poverty has been
noted by us previously. This has been emphasised by Michael Lipton as
follows:
As education raises skill levels so that some jobs once done by
unskilled labourers are done (better) by those whose parents could
afford the direct and the opportunity costs of their
education--unemployment shifts even further towards the unskilled,
undereducated poor and poorest [Lipton (1983), p. 66].
This highlights the point that not only is unemployment probably a
more important determinant of poverty than is generally believed; its
relative importance is probably increasing.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
The main findings of the analysis are summarised below:
(i) The primary analysis of data reveals that our sample village
turned out to be a fairly representative sample in terms of basic
indicators of rural economy. The percentage rural poverty is found to be
in line with the declining trend of rural poverty in Pakistan.
(ii) The disaggregated nature of data has enabled us to pursue the
problem of rural poverty in some detail. For instance, investigation of
the reasons as to how some of the landless households managed to escape
poverty whereas some cultivating households failed to do so gave us some
useful information. To explain this phenomenon we attempted to see the
relationship between poverty and certain household-specific
characteristics, mostly by undertaking FGT decomposition. The main
factors responsible for this outcome were found to be
favourable/unfavourable distribution by size of landholding, household
size, educational attainment, dependency ratio, participation rates and
female-male ratio. Those households escaping poverty, however, remained
in a low-income category.
(iii) Another problem discussed was poverty among female-headed
households. The evidence showed that female-headedness characterised
mainly by widowhood has a possibility of ending up in poverty. However,
given that there were just two such cases, this conclusion needs to be
viewed with caution.
(iv) The analyses were carried out at three different levels: on
the basis of complete sample, low-income level, and higher-income level.
We found some of the explanatory variables behaving differently at
different levels of analysis, which is as expected. Landholding,
household size, household educational level, and dependency ratio were
found to influence the dependent variable (rural income per capita) in a
significant way. Other assets and household educational level were found
to enhance the per capita income of the high-income households as
compared to that of the low-income households. The rationale behind this
is well-understood.
(v) The two variables, female-male ratio and age of the household
head, gave correct signs but did not perform well. Participation rate, a
measure of rural employment, however, gave some useful results. The
hypothesis that the extremely poor participate less than the poor but
more than the non-poor was confirmed by our analysis.
In sum, the possibility of falling below the poverty-line is lower
for a household with a larger area to cultivate for its own, access to
other productive assets, a smaller number of dependents, greater
participation in non-farm work, and a higher education level. Whereas
our analysis highlights the importance of an institutional setting with
a better distribution of assets and access to resources it points, at
the same time, it points to the fact that numerous non-farm activities
also enable the rural households to generate incomes and thus avoid
poverty.
Appendix 1
VILLAGE SURVEY, 1990
Background to Village Survey
The village (called 'Wanda' located in Punjab Province)
survey was conducted in March/April, 1990, for six continuous weeks. The
survey was mainly based on a household questionnaire largely concerned
with quantitative economic analysis. The format of the questionnaire was
such that the information could easily be transformed on an individual
basis. The modes of data collection were the following:
(i) direct questioning of household head and other members;
(ii) extracting data from participant observation; and
(iii) interviewing of selected informants.
The survey was a 'one-shot' exercise, and repeated
surveys were not possible. The events of the recent past (agriculture
data, etc.) had to be based on memory recall of respondents with
cross-checking from co-residents.
Within the community, the objective was the total enumeration of
households. The village had 100 households and 100 percent enumeration
was obtained. In general, households tended to have multiple attributes
in terms of sectoral and organisational involvements. Data on production
activities, income, and employment were obtained.
The village consisting of 100 households is connected to the
nearest town (called 'Darya Khan' at a distance of 8 miles) by
a single metalled road. It was electrified only two years ago and has
educational facility up to the primary level. The primary health centre
is located at a distance of 3 miles.
The village agricultural land is plain and mostly cultivable. The
land tenure system consists of both owner-cropping as well as
share-cropping. The main crops of the area are wheat, sugar-cane, maize,
sorghum, and cotton.
Author's Note: This article is based on my Ph.D. thesis
submitted to the University of Sussex, U.K. I am thankful to my
supervisor Professor Pramit Chaudhuri for guidance and encouragement,
and to an anonymous referee for making useful suggestions.
REFERENCES
Anand, S. (1977) Aspects of Poverty in Malaysia. Review of Income
and Wealth Series 23:1 1-15.
Chaudhuri, P. (1979) The Indian Economy: Poverty and Development.
New York: St. Martin Press.
Foster, J. et al. (1984) A Class of Decomposable Poverty Measures.
Econometrica 52: 761-766.
Gaiha, R., and N. Kazmi (1981) Aspects of Poverty in Rural India.
Economics of Planning 17:74-112.
Griffin, K. B. (1981) Land Concentration and Rural Poverty (2nd
Ed.). New York: MacMillan.
Guisinger, S., and N. Hicks (1978) Long-term Trends in Income
Distribution in Pakistan. Worm Development 6:1271-1280.
Lipton, M. (1983) Labour and Poverty. World Bank. (World Bank Staff
Working Paper 616).
Lipton, M. (1991) Land Reform as Commenced Business: The Evidence
Against Stopping. (Mimeographed.)
Malik, S. (1992) A Study of Rural Poverty in Pakistan w.s.r, to
Agricultural Price Policy. Ph.D. Dissertation submitted to the
University of Sussex, U.K.
Naseem, S. M. (1973) Mass Poverty in Pakistan: Some Preliminary
Findings. The Pakistan Development Review 12:4 317-360.
Shahnawaz Mahk is Associate Professor of Economics, Bahauddin
Zakariya University, Multan.
Table 1
Primary Survey Data Summarised
1989-90 1986-87
Indicators (Present Survey) (FBS Survey)
Total Household 100 9459
Total Population 625 59781
Members/HH 6.25 6.32
Earners/HH 1.62 1.70
Total LHO (Acres) 8.30 --
LHO/HH 8.30 --
LHO (Gini) 0.56 0.55 (+)
Income/HH (Rs) * 2794.00 1774.83
Income/per Capita 446.04 282.00
Pov Line I 192.65 170.56
II 215.62 190.70
HCR (Pop) I 18.56 21.42
II 20.32 27.01
LHO = Landholding; HCR = Headcount Ratio.
(+) Based on 1980 Census data; * Income/month.
Table 2
Distribution of Landholding, Survey Data, 1989-90
HH % Cumu- Area %
Size(in Acres) (No.) of Total lative (in Acres) of Total
Landless 19 19 19 -- --
1-2.5 10 10 29 20 2.3
2.6-5.0 19 19 48 70 8.2
5.1-6.5 15 15 63 94 11.0
6.6-12.5 23 23 86 225 26.3
12.6-25.0 6 6 92 109 12.8
25.1-50.0 6 6 98 204 23.9
50.0 & + 2 2 100 132 15.5
Cumu-
Size(in Acres) lative
Landless --
1-2.5 2.3
2.6-5.0 10.5
5.1-6.5 21.5
6.6-12.5 46.8
12.6-25.0 60.0
25.1-50.0 84.5
50.0 & + 100.0
Gini Coefficient = 0.56
Table 3
Decomposition of Poverty (FGT Index, [alpha]=2) by Size of
Landholding Based on Micro Survey Data, 1989-90
Average % % Share
Size Number Popu- Income Group in Total
(in Acres) of HH lation of Poor Poverty Poverty
Landless 19 19 121.11 65.00 65.8
1-2.5 10 54 154.00 61.00 18.3
2.6-5.0 19 126 155.32 17.00 11.5
5.1-6.5 15 76 145.83 11.00 4.4
6.6-12.5 23 162 -- -- --
12.6-25.0 6 49 -- -- --
25.1-50.0 6 43 -- -- --
50.0&+ 2 16 -- -- --
Total 100 625 137.14 20.32 100.0
Size FGT
(in Acres) ([alpha]=2)
Landless 0.089
1-2.5 0.025
2.6-5.0 0.006
5.1-6.5 0.006
6.6-12.5 --
12.6-25.0 --
25.1-50.0 --
50.0&+ --
Total 0.016
Table 4
Decomposition of Poverty (FGT Index, ([alpha]=2), HH Size by
Members, Micro Survey Data, 1989-90
Average % Share
HH Number Income %G Group in Total FGT
Size of HH of Poor Poverty Poverty ([alpha]-2)
1 1 -- -- -- --
2 1 -- -- -- --
3 6 -- -- -- --
4 11 166.63 18.18 4.74 0.003
5 16 133.33 18.75 17.00 0.018
6 24 136.58 25.00 30.21 0.021
7 17 133.88 35.29 31.66 0.033
8 9 145.88 11.11 5.99 0.007
9 9 134.28 22.22 10.40 0.019
10&+ 6 -- -- -- --
Table 5
Decomposition of Poverty (FGT Index, ([alpha]=2), b), Educational
Attainment Based on Micro Survey Data, 1989-90
Average % Share
Education Popu- Income % Group in Total FGT
Codes lation of Poor Poverty Poverty ([alpha]=2)
000 123 132.50 59.00 61.40 0.057
0.01-1.00 101 114.31 37.30 36.70 0.056
1.01-3.00 349 175.92 4.40 1.90 0.0003
3.01&+ 52 -- -- -- --
Total 625 137.14 20.32 100.0 0.016
Table 6
Average Monthly Wages of Employees by Level of Education
and Industry in Rural Pakistan, 1984-85 (Rs/Month)
Illiterate Matric
& Less than Less than and
Primary Primary Matric Above
Agriculture 558 739 -- 1080
Manufacturing 750 638 1004 3890
Construction 611 762 1016 1333
Trade 642 931 979 970
Transport 811 1038 997 2139
Social Services 839 1019 1077 2754
All 714 889 992 1337
Household Income and Expenditure Survey, 1984-85.
Table 7
Decomposition of Poverty (FGT Index, ([alpha]=2), by Dependency
Ratio Based on Micro Survey Data, 1989-90
Average % Share
Dependency Popu- Income % Group in Total FGT
Ratio lation of Poor Poverty Poverty ([alpha]=2)
0.00-0.33 255 150.00 3.92 6.33 0.002
0.34-0.50 193 155.78 11.92 12.25 0.004
0.51-1.00 177 131.64 53.11 81.42 0.053
Total 625 137.14 20.32 100.00 0.016
Table 8
Decomposition of Poverty (FGT Index, ([alpha]=2), by Participation
Rates Based on Micro Survey Data, 1989-90
Average % Share
Participation Popu- Income % Group in Total FGT
Ratio lation of Poor Poverty Poverty ([alpha]=2)
0.00-0.33 155 146.64 16.23 16.40 0.009
0.34-0.50 363 131.27 25.62 81.11 0.026
0.51-1.00 108 175.92 8.33 2.49 0.001
Total 625 137.14 20.32 100.00 0.016
Table 9
Decomposition of Poverty (FGT Index, ([alpha]=2), by Female-Male
Ratio Based on Micro Survey Data, 1989-90
Average % Share
Female-Male Popu- Income % Group in Total FGT
Ratio lation of Poor Poverty Poverty ([alpha]=2)
0.00-0.67 283 139.86 14.84 32.50 0.009
0.68-1.50 283 147.96 17.31 31.75 0.011
1.51 & + 59 143.50 61.02 35.75 0.040
Total 625 137.14 20.32 100.00 0.016
Table 10
The Determinants of Rural Income/Capita
Log-linear Regression Results, 1989-90
Estimated Estimated Estimated
Explanatory Coeff. Coeff. Coeff.
Variables (Eq. 1) (Eq. 2) (Eq. 3)
Intercept 7.08 7.13 6.21
(8.67) (4.74) (9.68)
LHO 0.061 0.095 -0.034
(3.96) (2.40) (2.89)
HSZ -0.412 -0.478 -0.340
(2.90) (1.91) (2.66)
AST 0.074 0.041 0.004
(6.36) (2.03) (0.24)
EDU 0.089 0.106 0.062
(3.67) (1.73) (3.66)
DEP -0.184 -0.18 -0.226
(1.97) (1.16) (2.36)
PAR -0.011 -0.688 0.156
(0.06) (1.93) (1.10)
FMR -0.036 -0.036 -0.149
(0.53) (0.28) (2.83)
AGE -0.263 -0.304 -0.057
(1.27) (0.79) (0.36)
[R.sup.2] 0.62 0.46 0.58
F-test 18.63 3.58 7.26
Note: Equation 1 is based on the complete sample of 100 households.
Equation 2 is based on 43 higher-income households.
Equation 3 is based on 57 lower-income households.
The dependent variable is rural income/capita.
The figures in parentheses are t-ratios.
LHO = Landholding (area in acres).
AST = Other assets.
DEP = Dependency ratio.
FMR = Female male ratio.
HSZ = Household size.
EDU = Household education level.
PAR = Participation rate.
AGE = Age of the household head.