The economics profession in Pakistan: a historical analysis.
Ul Haque, Nadeem ; Khan, Mahmood Hasan
The development of professions has contributed significantly to our
understanding of how economies, societies, and polities function, and
what works and what does not. The rise of the economics profession--a
critical mass of influential people with specialised knowledge--can be
traced to the emergence of modern industrial economy in the 19th
century. Economists found their place not only in the academia teaching
and doing research but also advising private businesses engaged in
finance and manufacturing and governments in their central hanks,
treasury, colonial, and war offices. They established professional
associations to exchange and publicise their ideas and results of
researches through conferences, journals, pamphlets, and books. Peer
recognition and institutional support became important to economists for
their reputation and influence in the professional circle and society.
In Pakistan, the stock of knowledge was limited at the time of
Independence. While the stock of professionals in several fields has
increased quite significantly, we have not taken stock of professional
development in Pakistan. The study attempts to develop a history of the
economics profession in Pakistan. The survey shows that the young
professionals of today have "'no professional contact"
with their senior counterparts. There was no skill transfer taking
place. In addition, the avalanche of consultancy, in the 1980s, has
aggravated the situation. The advent of ideas from the donor development
expert and the NGO industry did not help to develop academic profession
and academic institutions in Pakistan. If all Pakistani professionals
will seek to develop deep and broad professions in their own respective
fields, only than any meaningful development can and will occur.
Consequently, the economic development will be the sum total of the
development of these professions.
**********
The development of professions has contributed significantly to our
understanding of how economies, societies, and polities function, and
what works and what does not. The rise of the economics profession--a
critical mass of influential people with specialised knowledge--can be
traced to the emergence of modern industrial economy in the 19th
century. Economists found their place not only in the academia teaching
and doing research but also advising private businesses engaged in
finance and manufacturing and governments in their central hanks,
treasury, colonial, and war offices. They established professional
associations to exchange and publicise their ideas and results of
researches through conferences, journals, pamphlets, and books. Peer
recognition and institutional support became important to economists for
their reputation and influence in the professional circle and society.
In Pakistan, the stock of knowledge was limited at the time of
Independence. While the stock of professionals in several fields has
increased quite significantly, we have not taken stock of professional
development in Pakistan. The study attempts to develop a history of the
economics profession in Pakistan. The survey shows that the young
professionals of today have "'no professional contact"
with their senior counterparts. There was no skill transfer taking
place. In addition, the avalanche of consultancy, in the 1980s, has
aggravated the situation. The advent of ideas from the donor development
expert and the NGO industry did not help to develop academic profession
and academic institutions in Pakistan. If all Pakistani professionals
will seek to develop deep and broad professions in their own respective
fields, only than any meaningful development can and will occur.
Consequently, the economic development will be the sum total of the
development of these professions.
I. INSTITUTIONS, ORGANISATIONS, AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
Economics is a policy science: its claim is to describe policies
that can improve peoples' lives. Its usefulness for policymaking,
therefore, depends on how well economists understand and interpret
economic behaviour. In other words, successful economic policy entails a
good understanding of the dynamics of economic change. In turn, a model
of economic change requires analysis of institutions and organisations
in the society. Institutions are the informal conventions (customs) and
formal rules by which the members of a society organise the production
and distribution of goods and services. Organisations are the players in
the economy, including the state (executive, legislature and judiciary),
private businesses (profit-seeking individuals and corporate entities),
and private non-profit associationS (NGOs, professional groups and
bodies). Both institutions and organisations change with the evolution
of each society and economy. Much as economists disagree on the
underlying assumptions and interpretation of "facts" about
economic change, they have a broad agreement that the discipline of
economics must be embedded in the study of interactions between
institutions and organisations.
A major factor in the development of Western Europe (including
North America) since at least the seventeenth century was the
realisation that knowledge, based on rational thought and empiricism,
was valuable hence to be pursued to empower the self and society. It is
with the application of this knowledge to natural resources that much
capital has been accumulated and incomes increased. It is also true that
the accumulation of knowledge and expansion of markets were accomplished
by changes in institutions and organisations of the society. Both of
these changes reinforced each other. The relative failures of the
Chinese and Islamic societies can also be explained within this
perspective. Modern colonial empires were sustained by the strength of
capitalist institutions and the associated technology used in commerce
and war. A vast majority of underdeveloped countries as colonial
societies--devastated though their people and resources were in many
respects--have inherited institutions and organisations implanted by the
colonialists.
The literature on economic development since the end of World War
II has made significant contribution to the economics discipline as the
discipline itself has contributed to our understanding of how economies
change and how do institutions and organisations play their roles in
this process. A society first needs a legitimate state that the populace
generally supports: it has achieved a consensus for governance to
promote peace. It establishes a legal framework that clearly defines
property rights, enacts laws and rules for contracts and maintains a
rule of law. The judicial and administrative structure should have the
capacity to enforce the laws and rules. The roles of organisations--the
state, private businesses and non-profit entities (NGOs)--should
dovetail their function without doctrinal rigidity. The state should (i)
maintain a facilitating environment--including expansion of property
rights and stable macroeconomic policies--for the other two
organisations and (ii) invest in public and merit goods that the private
sector may not produce or provide in optimum measure. Businesses (farms
and firms) must play by the rules in the marketplace without reliance on
public subsidy, open to competitive forces both internal and external.
NGOs should help expand the base of civil society to ensure that the
state and businesses do not injure the public interest. Of course, these
roles evolve through time as experience accumulates, reflecting clearly
the dynamics of economic development embedded in changes in technology
and institutions.
II. THE ECONOMICS PROFESSION AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
For our purpose a profession can be defined as a group (body) of
persons practising an occupation requiring intellectual abilities and
training. Contemporary intellectual and professional specialisation is
the result of the growth of accumulated knowledge in natural, physical
and social sciences in the last four centuries. In addition, and perhaps
more importantly, the growth and evolution of modern (complex)
industrial society and economy have fostered the development of
professions. The development of professions has in turn contributed to
our understanding of how economies, societies and polities function and
what works and what does not. The rise of the economics profession--a
critical mass of influential people with specialised knowledge--can be
traced to the emergence of modern industrial economy in the 19th
century. Economists found their place not only in the academia teaching
and doing research but advising private businesses engaged in finance
and manufacturing and governments in their central banks, treasury,
colonial and war offices. They established professional associations to
exchange and publicise their ideas and results of researches through
conferences, journals, pamphlets, and books. Peer recognition and
institutional support became important to economists for their
reputation and influence in the professional circle and society.
Universities became the competitive reservoir of professionals--teachers
and researchers--producing knowledge and young professionals carrying
that knowledge to the rest of the society. The deepening of the
economics profession, as of other professions, has been an integral part
of the development and evolution of a corporate culture and civil
society in the industrially advanced countries.
The economics profession has developed its strength and influence
on public policy in the industrially advanced countries because of
several factors. For one thing, it has generally been allowed an
environment of free inquiry and public support through investment in the
infrastructure necessary for acquiring and disseminating knowledge.
Seekers and distributors of knowledge and ideas have been respected,
recognised and adequately rewarded. Intellectual competition has induced
creative ideas and use of the scientific method. Competing
paradigms--classical, neoclassical, Marxist, Keynesian, Monetarist--have
developed according to differences in ideology and interpretation of
events (facts). Economists have borrowed methods of inquiry from
physical and natural sciences and adapted the language of logic and
mathematics to test their hypotheses and theories. All of this allows
the professionals to describe, explain, analyse and propose policy
prescriptions: what works or does not work. Of course, given the
complexity of issues related to human behaviour, there is much in
economics that is controversial. Public sector investment in and support
for education and research in economics and the growth of private sector
institutions--financial and corporate sectors--have also been important
factors in the development of the economics profession.
We cannot make similar generalisations for the economics profession
in underdeveloped countries. For one thing, with some exceptions in
Latin America, there was almost no economics profession in these
countries before they achieved political independence as nation states
after end of World War II. Almost all economists were employed in a
limited number of colleges and universities--engaged almost exclusively
in undergraduate teaching--without any influence on policy-making since
government policies were established by the Centre's political
elite and private interest groups and carried out by colonial
administrators. The demand for economists in the colonies was limited
and met by the expatriate professionals and bureaucrats. A second
problem was that training in economics did not equip individuals with
concepts and methods necessary to make critical analyses of the received
economic theory and interpretation of economic facts. Similarly,
resources were not available to establish the infrastructure necessary
to conduct economics research. Finally, the institutional environment
was dominated by feudal and tribal social structures with a limited role
of competitive markets for ideas, resources and products. The colonial
governments did not much encourage (intellectual) competition in the
colonies since it was thought to be potentially subversive. In fact, for
most of the educated elite in underdeveloped countries--a vast majority
of them belonged to the well-connected feudal, merchant or tribal
families--the two professions with the highest pay-off were the
government's administrative services and practice of law or
politics.
The structural conditions in most underdeveloped countries after
World War II were quite similar in that their economies were dominated
by feudal (tribal) and mercantilist institutions. These countries also
inherited a colonial political structure in which the only dominant
player was a non-representative and highly centralised state with little
or no accountability to the people it ruled. What is even more important
is that the new political elite--to whom the colonial masters
transferred power at independence--were deeply impressed by the idea
that the state had a major (if not a central) role to promote economic
development. In some cases it was ideological, but for many it was
simply expedient. Their positions were greatly strengthened by the
dominant development paradigm and competing sources of foreign economic
assistance. The development paradigm most popular and influential at
that time had at its core the idea that economic growth--capital
accumulation and technological progress--required an activist state
since private markets were weak, fragmented and unreliable. Foreign
economic assistance--both from multilateral and bilateral sources--was
likewise premised on the assumption that the state must take the lead in
directing the development process. Also, the economics profession was
dominated by this idea due to the writings of John Maynard Keynes,
Marxist ideology and the "socialist" experiment in the former
Soviet Union, and a particular interpretation of historical growth in
Japan and Western Europe. In many countries, a major consequence of all
this was an uncritical reliance on the beneficent power of the state and
foreign economic assistance.
III. THE ECONOMICS PROFESSION IN PAKISTAN: BACKGROUND
This case study offers us a unique perspective to understand the
issue of the development of a profession, because at independence
Pakistan inherited very few trained economists. Since independence
numerous government and donor inspired efforts have been made to develop
professional economists and the profession of economics. Our analysis
focuses primarily on these efforts to see how a broad-based profession
of economics can be developed in Pakistan. This study also has
implications for governments, foreign donors and other groups that seek
to catalyse such developments in other underdeveloped countries. It is
common knowledge that at independence in 1947 we did not inherit a large
stock of professionals in any field. While the stock of professionals in
several fields has increased quite significantly, we have not taken
stock of professional development in Pakistan. There are no analyses
available of any profession to see how we have developed from what we
inherited. Such analysis is important to see whether the development of
professions has been relatively healthy or not. It is in this spirit
that we attempt to develop a history of the economics profession in
Pakistan.
It is necessary first to layout the major institutional and
structural conditions that Pakistan inherited at independence in 1947.
First, Pakistan's economy was based mainly on agriculture with
little industrial production: this region of the Indian economy was
exporting food and raw material in exchange for manufactured
(industrial) goods from other regions or abroad. Further, most of the
commercial and industrial activities were controlled by non-Muslim
entrepreneurs who left Pakistan after the partition of India. Second,
Pakistan's society was (a) dominated by primordial (feudal, tribal
and caste) relations and (b) divided between the rich few and rural
masses. Third, the political elite--who came mainly from the feudal
families--exercised power through the state machinery in which the civil
administration played a dominant role. Finally, the professional class
was very small and without much influence: there were almost no
professional societies or entities. Most of the professionals were
working in the public sector organisations, including colleges and
universities. The small educational system--with limited number of
institutions, enrolments and faculty--was based on curricula that
emphasised disciplines and skills needed to assist the colonial
administration.
There were few economists in Pakistan, working in universities and
colleges and the State Bank of Pakistan (SBP). There was no institution
involved in applied economics research, except for the Punjab Board of
Economic Inquiry and the Agriculture College in Lyallpur. It should,
however, be added that the academic economists (from East and West
Pakistan) established the Pakistan Economic Association in 1950, which
started to publish its journal, Pakistan Economic Journal (PEJ), in the
same year and held annual meetings until 1968. Many of the contributors
to PEJ were well-known international economists and others were
Pakistani academics (mainly from East Pakistan).
IV. THE FIRST TWENTY-FIVE YEARS: FROM INDEPENDENCE TO
DISMEMBERMENT(1947-1971)
In the first five to six years after independence, the federal
government initiated two programmes for the development of professional
economists to work mainly in the public sector. The State Bank of
Pakistan initiated a programme whereby economists were attracted to the
Bank as it offered a reasonably attractive professional career. Some of
them were sent overseas for a PhD in economics. As Haq and Baqai (1988)
note, "the first generation of economists in Pakistan was trained
in the remarkable tradition of the State Bank of Pakistan". At the
same time, the government established overseas training scholarships for
young economists working in universities and the government. While some
of the trained economists returned to Pakistan, but others joined
international organisations to pursue their individual careers. No
attempt was, however, made to encourage the college and university
faculty to improve their knowledge or education. In fact, a high
proportion of the university and college teachers were attracted to join
the civil service of Pakistan to improve their well-being and social
status in view of the growing influence and status of bureaucracy.
In the early to mid-1950s, two important developments initiated the
growth of the economics profession Pakistan. First, there was rapid
expansion of teaching institutions (universities and colleges) and
government departments (e.g., State Bank of Pakistan, Central
Statistical Office, and Planning Commission) that required trained
economists. Second, foreign economic assistance started to provide the
necessary resources to support local and foreign education and training.
The Commonwealth and Colombo Plan were the first major multilateral
sources of assistance, including scholarships for foreign education.
However, in the second half of the 1950s, the United States official
bilateral assistance--with additional support from the Asia Foundation,
Ford Foundation, and U.S. Educational Foundation--became the more
important source of institutional support and individual training and
educational scholarships. In fact, the first major crop of economists
was harvested with the advent of American aid--under the Point-4
programme--and involvement of the Harvard Advisory Group (HAG) from
Harvard University Centre for International Affairs in the affairs of
Pakistan's economy in the mid-1950s. (1)
The active involvement of the United States in Pakistan's
economic affairs was part of the Cold War alliances in which Pakistan
became an active regional partner in the mid-1950s. With the rise of
General Ayub Khan into power in 1958, the U.S.-Pakistan alliance was
cemented and bilateral economic aid from the United States became a very
important source of foreign resources for the "planned"
development of Pakistan's economy. In fact, the First Five-Year
Plan (1955-60)--which was launched in 1957--became the foundation
document articulating the official development strategy later endorsed
and reinforced by Ayub Khan. The policy framework of the time envisioned
an activist government to be led by the modernising elite with
benevolent sentiments for the well being of the population. All that was
needed was to graft and develop economic expertise. It is in this
context that the HAG advisors became influential in designing
Pakistan's economic policy in the Ayub era (1958-68). In this they
had strong support of the international aid community. Their vision for
Pakistan also included a large infrastructure for the development of
economics and economists in Pakistan. Primed by the desire to promote
and catalyse rapid economic growth in Pakistan, the HAG thinking
(perspective) underlying these institutions was to quickly develop some
policy analysis units appended mainly to the government.
In line with this thinking, the HAG advisors strengthened the
Planning Commission and, with assistance from the Ford Foundation,
established the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (PIDE) in
1957. In the following year, PIDE started publishing its journal,
Economic Digest, which was replaced by The Pakistan Development Review
(PDR) in early 1961. The Directors of PIDE and Editors of PDR were
Americans until the end of 1965. The first Pakistani Director of PIDE
was appointed in early 1966--supported by HAG advisors--who remained in
that position until the PIDE ended its work in Dhaka with the
dismemberment of Pakistan in December 1971. Economic aid from the United
States and the HAG advisors helped to equip the Planning Commission,
State Bank of Pakistan and PIDE with some of our most economists--who
have continued to loom large on the economics profession in Pakistan--in
the 1950s and 1960s.
This trend culminated in the establishment of the fields of
development studies and public administration that in any case were
closely associated with the generalist education offered to the civil
servants in the Civil Service Academy. Edward Mason at Harvard
University, who had considerable influence on development studies and
the U.S. aid programme, encouraged young Pakistani civil servants and
others to acquire training in Public Administration from U.S.
universities. The famous Edward Mason programme was set up in Harvard
University--to award a Master in Public Administration (MPA) degree--to
which senior and influential bureaucrats were sent and came back to
dominate the economics profession. Because of their bureaucratic
associations and the backing by donors these holders of MPA degree were
quite important in the economics profession in Pakistan. In fact, this
programme further margnalised the role of the academic institutions.
It is worth noting that very few economists were added to the
academic institutions because of the relatively low economic and social
status of universities and inadequate infrastructure for serious
research. The academic economists in Pakistan started to appear in small
number in the 1950s. However, the colleges and universities did not
receive large-scale financial and institutional support to create a
research-friendly environment. Further, the internal administrative
structure in the Departments of Economics was highly hierarchical,
giving almost uncontested power to the senior faculty who had not been
exposed to economics research or inquiry. A few who returned from abroad
in the late 1950s to mid-1960s did not survive and others resigned
themselves to routine teaching. Consequently, there was no economist
engaged in serious research in the academia. But that is not surprising
given that academia was ignored and its management structure was almost
feudal. Perhaps the only exception to this model was the Department of
Economics at the Quaid-i-Azam University created in the late 1960s. But
this too did not last for too long, thanks largely to the infighting among the faculty, and came to a sad end towards the end of the 1970s.
Since then its record has been no better than other Departments of
Economics in the country.
The HAG vision was flawed in three major respects and sowed the
seeds of distorted development of economics profession in Pakistan.
First, it did not attempt to develop an economics profession that was
rooted in the country. The HAG economists left the universities and
colleges in a state of neglect, using most of the domestic and foreign
resources to build the largely non-academic, semi-bureaucratic
institutions, and attempted to give these institutions the role of
leadership in the profession. Without the seed of the profession being
nurtured and jealously guarded in academia, the profession was bound to
have distorted growth. Second, the HAG-trained economists were very
deferent from the mainstream economists of the time in the West. The
HAG-sponsored training was development-oriented and specific to
Pakistan. They were not encouraged to do any theoretical or pioneering
research. They were instead trained to assist policy-makers design plans
and projects within the overall development vision of the time. Third,
given the influence of HAG and the new institutions, and the symbiotic
relationship between these institutions and the bureaucratic and
political structure of the time in Pakistan, the HAG-trained economists
acquired a large and visible role in the economy. These visible
economists have not only played an important role in Pakistan's
history, but also by and large distorted the perception of economist,
the economics profession and economic policy in Pakistan.
To drive all these ideas home, let us contrast the Pakistani
economists with the Indian economists of the time. First, all major
Indian economists are rooted in their academic institutions, having
taught at home and in major universities overseas. Second, they have
engaged in theoretical and fundamental research, and not just
development economics, and have published widely in major academic
journals and not just on Indian economy. Third, they have had limited
visibility in the corridors of power in India, other than through their
international prominence. Interestingly, the Indian economics profession
matured in the 1970s in the sense that the domestic teaching and
research institutions reached a level of self-perpetuation where its
products are internationally recognised. The implicit proposition here
is that had the HAG vision been based on rooting the profession on sound
academic lines in academic institutions in the country, perhaps Pakistan
would have seen a wholesome development of the profession.
Let us now turn to the dominant economic ideas planted by the HAG
advisors in Pakistan. By design and reflecting the development thinking
of the time, the HAG group was interventionist and oriented to plan and
budgetary allocations. (2) They largely mistrusted the market and
arrogantly assumed (even claimed) that planners and bureaucrats had
better (more) information than the market and the rest of society. (3)
Interestingly enough, the HAG training of development economics was
collapsing on itself by the early 1970s. Because these people had no
behavioural relationships in mind and no faith in markets, they did not
merely push policy levers and study response lags and dynamics. Instead,
they developed lengthy plans or wish lists and used the bureaucratic
structures to control the environment to make these plans happen. The
control-oriented and market-mistrusting civil service loved this new
intellectual force given to their view.
A second element in the thinking of the HAG economist was the
increasing concern with poverty and inequality. Haq and Baqai (1986)
note with concern that "early writing on economics in Pakistan
surprisingly did not contain much reference to poverty related
themes." It is interesting that most of the early econometric or
behavioural research is done mainly by the HAG advisors, whereas the
work on measuring poverty, productivity is done by the Pakistani
economists. Before anything about the economy was understood, poverty
and regional inequality indices, and decline in real wages (when the
wage data were hardly available) were the main areas of concern as is
reflected by articles in PDR.
The manner in which the first-generation economists were trained
itself created a certain perception of economists in Pakistan. They were
trained to be policy-oriented development economists. A sharp
distinction was made between such economists and those who studied more
theoretical and academic economics. The erroneous impression was
unintendedly cultivated that the study of theory or more rigorous
economics was of limited use to the country. Such pursuit was considered
a luxury that the country could ill-afford. This view has persisted and
developed over time and reinforced the perception that to be a good
economist for Pakistan a grounding in economic theory is not only not
required but perhaps may even be a hindrance. The result is that there
is a tremendous disrespect for academic and theoretical economics. The
term "ivory tower" intellectual has been used to describe
anyone who attempts to read and keep abreast of academic economics.
Instead, an amalgam of general knowledge and mild development verbiage has been established as sound Pakistani development economics.
V. THE POST-BANGLADESH PERIOD (1972-1997)
By the late 1960s and early 1970s, the HAG era was ending and
fragmentation in the nascent economics profession was already visible.
In the late 1960s, Bengali economists started to take lead in the
academic field, but their major interest was to highlight the so-called
interregional inequality and resource transfer. The West Pakistani
economists were following the HAG design and were totally enmeshed with
the civil service and the political scene in developing the annual
budgets and five-year plans. The Bengalis felt marginalised from this
and were heading off in the direction of laying the ideological and
economic foundation for the emerging state of Bangladesh. The separate
reports of the Bengali and West Pakistani economists for the Fourth
Five-Year Plan (1970-75) remain perhaps the most important evidence of
the contradictory visions of development in Pakistan. The State Bank
group was frustrated by the relative lack of importance of the Bank and
monetary policy and the domination of the Bank by the civil service. The
possibility of an independent and professional Bank had apparently
become more remote. Indeed the State Bank of Pakistan never developed a
core economists given to serious research.
The academic and research environment for the economics profession
in Pakistan started to change in the 1970s in several ways. First,
Pakistan's dismemberment in 1971--splitting into what are Pakistan
and Bangladesh now--had profound implications for the profession. The
main institution for economic research, PIDE, was moved from Karachi to
Dhaka in 1969 and the main economists who were running it were Bengalis.
The result was that the Institute was virtually moribund. Second, even
the Pakistani economists who remained were induced overseas by a
combination of better incentives in international agencies. To this a
feeling of devaluation of professional skills was added in the Bhutto
era (1972-1977) which was dominated by the rhetoric of socialism
accompanied by large-scale nationalisation of banks and industries. The
visibility that professional economists had acquired in the Ayub era was
lost by now. They had little to contribute to public policy during the
1970s and the Planning Commission lost its earlier importance.
By the early 1970s, the HAG-trained economists had been
marginalised by the political movement led by Zulfikar Ali Bhutto,
dominated by the ideas of nationalisation and socialism. Politicisation
of the civil service further weakened the influence of professional
economists in government services. However, after the imposition of
Martial Law in 1977, the civil service was rehabilitated to its former
dominance in policy-making. The political rhetoric of the militrat
regime led by General Zia ul Haque shifted to a full-steam programme of
"Islamisation" with a large doze of foreign aid. These changes
fragmented the economics profession further. Some economists used their
international development contacts to retreat to the international
agencies where, as we all know, they have had sterling careers. At this
stage, the first Pakistani academic economists also emerged not through
the government or donor inspired scholarship schemes but through
individual career choices. Some of them started publishing in overseas
journals and occupied prestigious positions in universities and
international organisations. However, given the dearth of academic
institutions, incentives and academic respectability in Pakistan, all of
them have stayed abroad. Attempts were made to compensate for these
losses by means of some institution building.
1. Building Research Institutions
The PIDE was re-established in Islamabad in mid-1972, followed by
the creation of Applied Economics Research Centre (AERC) as a
"centre of excellence" in the University of Karachi. This
eventually paved the way for several institutions for ostensible economic research. These institutions as they were formed received
substantial financial assistance from the federal government, USAID and
the Ford Foundation. A large number of young professionals from these
institutions were sent overseas, particularly to the United State, for
the Master and PhD degree programmes with financial assistance from one
or another donor agency. Some economists from universities were also
sponsored to complete M.A. and PhD degrees under different scholarship
programmes. These institution-building efforts during the 1970s and
1980s have not borne fruit as they were plagued by at least four major
difficulties.
First, universities were not able to attract or keep the newly
foreign trained economists for lack of favourable work
environment--feudal management structure, poor research infrastructure
(books, journals, computing facilities, etc.) and low material
incentives. Some of these academics moved to public sector organisations
or international organisations. There is not one Department of Economics
in Pakistan today with a credible programme in economics. The academic
quality of graduates at the M.A. level is by and large low and uneven
between universities, and quite inferior to a middling B.A. in any
international university. However, this reflects the larger national
crisis in Pakistan's post-secondary education system.
Second, the PIDE--which was the supposed leader and a model of
economic research--was also unable to attract and hold a core group of
competent economists. The AERC, which has made a significant reputation
for itself largely through its entrepreneurial leadership, too was
unable to develop a significant grouping of economists. Both of these
institutions had access to scholarships for several young economists to
study mainly in the U.S. throughout the 1980s. It is important to note
that PIDE and AERC, for more or less similar reasons, have lost several
well-trained economists to public sector institutions and international
agencies in the last decade.
Third, interestingly enough, throughout this period, the
fragmentation of the profession mentioned earlier has persisted,
reflecting the poor institutional development in Pakistan. Whether the
HAG-trained economists, who went overseas, took no interest or were not
allowed to work does not matter since the result is the same. The new
professionals who never really worked in Pakistan attempted to do so,
but have found that they cannot contribute or are used for purpose of
internal institutional politics rather than professional or
institutional development.
Finally, the visible fragmentation and institutional decline are
further evidence in that the State Bank of Pakistan has stopped
virtually all in-house research and its publications since the
mid-1970s. Moreover, all of the research centres and institutes,
including PIDE and AERC, have largely excluded from their programmes and
studies the involvement of faculty from the Departments of Economics in
universities in Karachi, Islamabad, Lahore, Peshawar, and Hyderabad.
There is almost no formal joint study and research programme at any of
these places. On the contrary, there is unhealthy competition for scarce
resources and skills and even mutual resentment and hostility.
Considering the migration of skilled economists to overseas
positions, the supply of quality economists in Pakistan has remained
quite limited. Notwithstanding the limited skilled resources, the push
for creating new "research" centres and institutes accelerated
through the 1980s. Several new centres (institutes) were established
during this period: the Centre for Applied Economics Studies in the
University of Peshawar, Economics Research Centre in the University of
Sindh, Punjab Economics Research Institute (formerly the Punjab Board of
Economic Inquiry) in the (Government of) Punjab Planning Board,
Institute of Development Studies in the Agriculture University in
Peshawar, and Islamic Economics Research Centre in the International
Islamic University in Islamabad. The available resources were spread too
thin so that no core grouping of professionals has been formed anywhere.
It seems that there are two major reasons for this mushroom-like
growth of the so-called research institutions: (i) build new regional or
specialised capabilities for economic research as competing empires vis
a vis Departments of Economics in universities and (ii) use them as
institutional vehicles to attract projects and studies funded by
governments and foreign donors. The proliferation of institutions was
also accompanied by an increase in the number of universities in
Pakistan. The traditional centres of learning in Pakistan, such as the
Punjab University or Government College in Lahore, meanwhile were
denuded of funding. The case of the Islamic Economics Research Centre is
somewhat special in that the establishment of the International Islamic
University coincided with the policy of Islamisation in the Zia era.
Several relatively young economists were drawn into the teaching of and
research on "Islamic Economics" in the International Islamic
University. It is fair to say that most of the research centres and
institutes have so far neither created a favourable environment for
academic research nor published any research output. The result of all
this has been to reinforce the notion established in the earlier period
that the profession of economics was to be nurtured outside the
university centres.
2. Developing Professional Associations
At the meta-institutional level, an effort was made to revive the
Pakistan Economic Association (PEA) in mid-1972, which held its
16th--and as it turns out the last--Annual Meeting in Islamabad in early
1973. As stated earlier, PEA had held its annual conference from 1950 to
1968 and maintained its quarterly journal, PEJ, to which papers were
contributed by some well known international scholars and academics that
enjoyed respectability within academia. However, after its meeting in
1973, PEA went into a state of inaction from which it has not recovered
to this day. The moribund state of PEA and its revival were discussed in
several public fora in the late 1970s (University of Karachi) and early
1980s (University of Punjab), but without results. PEA was effectively
controlled by a small number of senior (academic) economists, and its
last president did not hold the usual annual meeting for a number of
years.
As an alternative to the defunct PEA, PIDE established the Pakistan
Society of Development Economists (PSDE) in 1983. PSDE was established
as an instrument of PIDE for its own purposes and not necessarily for
the development of the profession. Its membership was not open.
Professional associations normally select the president on the basis of
intellectual stature and for a limited tenure, usually a year. An
important function of the president is to conduct some key proceedings
of the association to further his/her scholarly agenda. That is how a
professional association remains alive and gets invigorated. Contrary to
this standard professional practice, the Director of PIDE is also
appointed the president of PSDE under its charter. PSDE activities have,
therefore, highlighted the personal agenda of the Director of PIDE. The
annual meetings of PSDE have usually attracted some international
economists (funded by foreign assistance from Germany and the Ford
Foundation endowment fund) and some Pakistani economists from outside
PIDE. But these PSDE annual meetings are perhaps more distinguished by
the prominent Pakistani economists that were often excluded from
participation.
Considering the checkered life of the PEA and activities of PSDE so
far, it is clear that Pakistani economists have been unable to create a
forum that would disseminate economic thought and ideas and subject all
shades and hierarchies of the profession to peer opinion and discussion.
Indeed this failure has been an important reason for the stunted
development of the profession. The key question for future is to lay the
foundation of a professional association in the environment where
hierarchies and titles are less important then exchange of ideas through
open debate and discussion under the critical scrutiny of one's
peers in the profession.
3. Research and Professional Journals
A detailed evaluation of research output from PIDE and AERC--the
only relatively active research institutions in the country--in the last
15 years is hard to make, thanks to lack of detailed information about
their research programmes and research output. However, some meaningful
comments can be made on the basis of published articles in PDR and PJAE
and occasional papers and reports issued by PIDE and AERC. (4)
The PIDE research programme seems to cover a variety of issues or
themes, driven mainly by their "relevance" to Pakistan,
availability of funds and research staff. The research areas range from
demography (population and migration) to industry (productivity and
protection), agriculture (terms of trade, use of inputs, farm
productivity), and monetary and fiscal economics (money demand,
government spending, inflation). Articles published in PDR are
contributed both by the research staff of PIDE and outside contributors.
Some of these articles are products of project or programme-based
reports prepared by the PIDE staff for the government and/or
international donor organisations. Other articles are of some academic
standing, based on doctoral dissertations of the PIDE staff and other
contributors. A large volume of the papers published in PDR are
presented at the annual meeting of PSDE, for which they are not even
internally screened much less refereed. It is worth noting that a high
proportion of the PIDE papers are co-authored, reflecting "team
work", but usually carrying the name of a senior economist in PIDE.
In 1982, AERC started its own biannual journal, Pakistan Journal of
Applied Economics (PJAE), to publish the results of in-house research
and contributions by outsiders. Looking at the issues of PJAE and AERC
occasional reports, it seems that much of the in-house research has been
driven by contractual project studies completed for governments, public
sector agencies and international donors. The contractual
"research" studies completed by the AERC staff reflect a
limited number of areas: crop production, farm credit, local
administration, urban growth, education and employment, and fiscal
federalism. It is worth noting that the PJAE editorial staff are unable
to publish the journal regularly even two times in the year: the
time-lag has increased from one to two years.
Both PIDE and AERC seem to have very little to offer in their
research programmes on the topical issues since Pakistan, like so many
underdeveloped countries, has been slipping in or out of structural
adjustment programmes since the early 1980s. For example, they have not
examined the micro and macro aspects of the structural adjustment
programmes, e.g., distorted markets for products and resources (land,
labour and capital); effects of taxes and subsides on private sector
efficiency, consumption and savings; financial repression; trade
liberalisation; privatisation, etc. Despite the exhibited vulnerability
of the country to repeated supply shocks to its main export, cotton and
its products, none of these two institutions has had anything to say on
the issue. It seems that expensive projects with dubious payoffs or
esoteric value have received extensive patronage without any input from
external referees or peer review. Also, there are very few examinations
of the important social and economic questions of the time: quality of
governance, fiscal federalism, regional resource transfer and income
disparities, and the declining quality of life in the country.
4. Academic Management and Incentive Structure
The major factors affecting" the volume and quality of
academic research in economics include: the internal management
structure, work environment, and the reward system in academia and
research institutes. Reflecting the pathology of the larger
feudal-bureaucratic social order in Pakistan, the senior management
generally follows the national model of centralised power without
consultation and participation. A high proportion of the junior research
and teaching staff finds itself in a patron-client relationship, in
which the patron has considerable power to punish and reward
individuals. The personalised nature of power breeds mediocrity since
salary, scholarship, and promotion are rarely based on merit and
personal achievement. Some of the senior research staff and faculty have
achieved their positions through this system and suffer from a sense of
insecurity.
Rather than publication and the development of academic ideas,
status and title are considered worthy if merit. For example, a PhD
certificate has been regarded by many seniors academics and
professionals as the end of their scholarship and research. They,
therefore, set an example that young professionals are expected not to
transgress if they want to build their careers. (5) Often, in the
academic and teaching institutions, one finds that the volume and
quality of research published by the senior research staff are indeed
very limited. In addition, it is rare to see the names of Pakistani
economists in local universities and research institutes as authors of
paper in journals outside Pakistan.
It is worth noting that universities, including Departments of
Economics and Centres of Excellence (like AERC), have enjoyed a large
degree of autonomy in their management since they are not governed
directly by federal or provincial governments. They receive their
funding through the Universities Grants Commission (UGC). This, however,
does not mean that are entirely free from government interference since
public sector representative carry substantial weight in the Board of
Governors, etc. As stated earlier, the internal management structures
are by large non-participatory, based on hierarchy by seniority. The
reward system follows the national model of patronage. Finally, in the
early 1970s, academics and professionals misguidedly fought for and
received the national grade (and salary) structure followed in the civil
service. However, they have not enjoyed the perks and rent-seeking
opportunities available to civil servants. Salaries for most academic
and professional economists are quite unrelated to one's work and
needs, leading to increased dependence on "moonlighting" or
the more lucrative private consultancy work.
It terms of management, the case of PIDE is special since it was
established as an "autonomous" entity in the federal
government. Its Board of Directors is chaired by the Federal Finance
Minister and includes secretaries of the Ministries of Finance, Economic
Affairs, Planning, and Education. Other members of the Board are
Governor of the State Bank, Chairmen of UGS, five members of the Council
of Senior Fellows of PIDE. The Director of PIDE is ex-officio member of
the Board. The Board Chairman enjoys substantial power because of
his/her official position. The Council of Senior Fellows, with 15
members includes representatives from regional universities and
professionals selected by the Director of PIDE. In theory, the Council
supervises the research, training, publication, and professional
functions of PIDE. In reality, the Council members act as
"friends" of PIDE and often rubber stamp the Director's
programme or agenda.
5. Resources for Research: Aid and Consultancy
There is little funding for economic research in the country,
reflecting the general lack of investment in education and research in
Pakistan. An academic has no way of finding funds for what he/she or
his/her peer group might consider interesting or necessary for research.
The only funding available is that which donors consider necessary for
their operations. But then this funding is available to meet the
priorities of lenders or donors and not to conform to the needs of the
local community of economists. The donor agenda in Pakistan, as in many
other countries, has not been consistent over time, since it has changed
according to the shifting development perspectives of the political
elite in the donor countries and senior managers of donor agencies.
Similarly, donor funding has been unreliable, dependent largely on the
changing priorities and moods of those in power in the donor countries
and agencies.
A new and somewhat ominous phenomenon started to emerge in the
early 1980s: careers in the consultancy industry. It has affected the
economics profession in a disastrous way in Pakistan. Consulting on
economic issues at the individual and institutional level is clearly
associated with the growth of project and programme-based foreign
"aid" from multilateral (e.g., World Bank and Asian
Development Bank) and bilateral (e.g., United States, Japan, the
European Union countries, Switzerland, and Canada) donors.
Pakistan's dependence on foreign aid and its foreign debt liability
have increased significantly in the last 15 years or so, hence increased
involvement of the multilateral and bilateral donors. A major effect of
donor involvement and inflow of resources for projects and programmes,
mainly in the public sector, has been the growth of demand for local
consultants (individual and institutional) as partners with foreign
consultants or as independents to produce (feasibility and evaluation)
reports on projects and programmes.
Consultancy has become a profitable industry for professional
economists inside and outside universities and research institutes.
Given the largely unfavourable environment for academic research in
economics and the lucrative monetary gain and social status from
consulting services, this industry has drawn the energy and time of
almost every academic economist in the country. In fact, most of the
so-called research agenda and output in almost all of the academia and
institutes is driven by the demand for studies and reports by donor
agencies and government departments or organisations. Coincidentally
there has been impressive growth of Non-Governmental Organisations
(NGOs) throughout the country, again based largely on foreign resources.
(6) The NGOs, working in the economic and social sectors, have been able
to attract many economists to work for them. Almost all of this work has
no serious academic or research content--in fact it is anti-intellectual
since it wants immediate answers to self-serving propositions or
questions--but its pecuniary benefits are generally much higher than in
academia and provides greater exposure to the wheels of power. The
economists involved in consulting--and all of them are--have found a
symbiotic relationship with the civil bureaucracy in Pakistan and
officials of donor agencies. They need each other for their survival and
growth. It seems that the economics profession is too well caught in
this privately profitable but non-academic enterprise. Can it be saved
from this malaise? It is hard to say at this stage.
VI. CONCLUSION
Today there are very few Pakistani economists who have really
seriously published and achieved a modicum of respectability in the
academic world. They are to be contrasted with the HAG tradition in
Pakistan of acquiring a doctorate and then doing high profile and catchy
things in newspapers and magazines in Pakistan. Sadly enough some
younger economists are continuing that tradition and they use every
means at their disposal to decry the profession that they practice by
making claims like "much of it may not be applicable," and
"theory is only for advanced societies". Suffice to say that
the old HAG divide continues!
To gauge the extent of the fragmentation in the profession, we
recently conducted two simple investigations in Pakistan.
First, we surveyed the younger professionals to find out what sort
of contact they had had with their more senior counterparts, especially
the first crop of Pakistani economists. The answer was uniformly
"no professional contact". In addition, many of them also said
that, if ever they met, the first crop either patronised them or found
some innuendo to deride them (e.g., "when are you going to get off
your ivory tower and do some real work"). None of them felt
comfortable with the contact noting that the first crop claimed
hierarchical privilege and felt very uncomfortable with an equal debate
of issues. The culture of Pakistan too does not help here, for age can
often interpret a genuine difference of opinion as rudeness. This claim
has often prevented dialogue.
Second, in looking at the development of professions and
professionals in more advanced societies, we see that much of skill
transfer takes place through mentoring by senior professionals of junior
professionals (apprentices). All the younger economists denied that they
had received any mentoring from their more senior professionals. In
fact, many of them found the first crop to be unapproachable. More
interestingly, upon searching, we could not find any professionals that
the first crop had mentored.
The avalanche of economics consultancy since the early 1980s has
exacerbated the plight of the young professional in Pakistan. Pakistani
economists, instead of attempting to create their own professional
associations, develop peer review and evaluation, and set their own
research and policy priorities, are investing their major efforts into
finding ways to please donors and to compete not often and only on the
basis of professional competence but for the favour of the donor.
The building of an edifice on weak foundations is extremely
difficult. Unfortunately, Pakistan did not inherit a tradition of
learning and research. That in itself was a difficult obstacle to
overcome. But it was capped by the advent of ideas from the donor
development expert that did not root the academic profession in the
cradle--the academic institutions--that would regenerate it. Instead,
they created the visible, development economist of Pakistan. These
development economists have been seeking a political role and have
contributed nothing to the development of the economics profession in
Pakistan. They have always displayed and impatience for growth and
development. It is not surprising that they have missed out on the
fundamental truth in theoretical economics that economic development is
not mere "plan allocations" but human skill development. After
all they have no respect for the "ivory tower" intellectual.
The problem of academic study of economics and the development of
professionals in Pakistan has become even more serious in recent years
in light of the decline in the standard of education in the academia and
the growth of consultancy and NGO industry. If only all Pakistani
professionals will seek to develop deep and broad professions in their
own respective fields, meaningful development can and will occur.
Economic development will be the sum total (and may be even more) of the
development of these professions.
Comments
The study analyses the development of economic profession over time
and comes out with the conclusion that Pakistani economists have
contributed very little to economic literature and to policy formulation
in Pakistan. The study examines the role of universities, academic
institutions, bureaucracy and the professional bodies in pre-and post
1971 period. The paper argues that lack of free inquiry and public
support through investment in the infrastructure necessary for acquiring
and disseminating knowledge on the one hand and the low research funds
and the low reward structure for the economists have been responsible
for that.
It needs to be underscored that a country needs three types of
economists, viz. academics in the universities, professionals in the
applied economic research institutes, and those in the government
helping in the policy formulation. The major thrust of the study has
been only on the first category. Times and again the study points out to
relatively little contribution made by economists to the theoretical
constructs while the Indian economists have been able to do so. Needless
to add that most of the contribution made by the Indian economists is by
those residing outside the country. Why celebrated Pakistani economists,
both the authors are residing outside the country, have not been able to
make similar contribution. After all expatriate Pakistanis enjoy the
same facilities as their counterparts from other countries have. This
has not been analysed in the paper.
The authors examine the role of Harvard Advisory Group in the
training of Pakistani economists. The author points out that the
training was imparted to bureaucracy but they do not seem to be happy
over that. But if such training did result in better policy formulation
what is the worry. When the group was not mandated to train the
academicians why blame them. It is odd to note that the authors suggest
that the Harvard group and the economists working in the government at
that time did not believe in the market forces. One may look at the
articles published in The Pakistan Development Review, the books
published by those in the Harvard group and those in the Planning
Commission and that should be sufficient to contradict the impression
created by the authors. It needs to be noted that under their influence
Pakistan abandoned the policy of controls and relied on price mechanism.
The author gives an impression as if Harvard Advisory Group and the
economists at that time were concerned with poverty. One wished they
were. Unfortunately at that time the policy prescription favoured growth
rather than income distribution leading to various problems by the end
of the 70s. No doubt the economists trained at that time believed in the
government intervention in the market. When there are distortions in the
market the policy still merits consideration.
The authors argue that government did not make any effort to
upgrade the faculty of the universities and the academic institutes
notwithstanding the fact that government did launch various programmes
to do so. Unfortunately the influential persons got the fellowship but
opted to stay abroad rather than serving the country. That they stayed
away because in Pakistan they did not have the research grant and salary
structure was poor may have some merit but considering that the Indian
salary structure and the research grants have been no better than
Pakistan the argument is not very valid. However, the observation that
there has been no tradition to carry out research in the universities is
probably right though recently even that is changing.
Why the economist in the government could not make contribution to
the policies of the government? The economists are generally subservient to the bureaucrats in the government and their impact on policy-making
is, therefore, limited. Over the passage of time they tend to forget the
hard core economics and become bureaucrat in their own right. Their
policy suggestions are not much different form an ordinary bureaucrat.
The Planning Commission was an effective institution in the
pre-1971 period but in the post-197 period it has lost the significance.
We may note that 1971-77 period was non-plan period and the Planning
Commission did not have any Deputy Chairman. The Commission became only
an institution to appraise the projects. The policy advice was neither
sought nor planning commission volunteered. With increasing role of IMF and with their focus on short term issues like budgetary deficit and
stabilisation the ministry of finance has taken up the role assigned to
Planning Commission.
The authors examine the professional institutes like PIDE and AERC
in detail. The Governing Board and Council of Senior Fellows of these
institutions are examined. It is unfortunate that the authors come out
with assertions without substantiating them. While in the earlier part
of the paper the low salary structure is lamented at a later stage
supplementing the salaries with consultancies is criticised. While too
much of consultancy resulting into poor performance of the institutions
is bad, the consultancies that help individuals and the organisation
need to be encouraged.
The authors start with that it is a case study and as such one
expected that it would come out with the suggestions for improvements in
the profession. Unfortunately the study is completely silent on policy
recommendations. Therefore the study at best is an analysis of the past
experience relating to the economic profession in Pakistan but without
leading us anywhere.
A. R. Kemal
The Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan, Islamabad.
REFERENCES
Ben-Ner, Avner, and Louis Putterman (eds) (1998) Economics, Values,
and Organisation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Haq, Mahbubul, and Menadione Baqai (eds) (1986) Employment,
Distribution and Basic Needs in Pakistan: Essays in Honour of Jawaid
Azfar. Lahore: Progressive Publishers.
Haque, Nadeem U1 (1992) Economists and the Role of Government.
Pakistan and Gulf Economist.
Hussain, Akmal (1988) Strategic Issues in Pakistan's Economic
Policy. Lahore: Progressive Publishers.
Islam, Nurul (1981) Foreign Trade and Economic Controls in
Development: The Case of United Pakistan. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Kardar, Shahid (1987) Political Economy of Pakistan. Lahore:
Pakistan Progressive Publishers.
Naqvi, Zafar J. (1993) Directory of Pakistani Economists and
Demographers. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
North, Douglas C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change and
Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglas C. (1994) Economic Performance Through Time.
American Economic Review 84:3.
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (1993) Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics: An Introduction. Islamabad: Pakistan
Institute of Development Economics.
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics (1993) PIDE's
Research Programme for 1993-1996. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of
Development Economics.
Robinson, E. A. G. (1967) The Problems of Teaching Economics in
Pakistan. Karachi: Pakistan Institute of Development Economics.
Samad, Abdus (1993) Governance, Economic Policy and Reform in
Pakistan. Lahore: Vanguard Books.
Siddiqui, Akhtar H. (Various Issues) The Economy of Pakistan: A
Select Bibliography. Islamabad: Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1994) The Institutions and Governance of
Economic Development and Reform. World Bank Economic Review, Proceedings
of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics.
Nadeem Ul Haque is Adviser, Research Department, International
Monetary Fund, Washington, D. C., Mahmood Hasan Khan is Professor in the
Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University, Burnaby, B.C., Canada.
(1) The term Harvard Advisory Group (HAG) has been used loosely in
view of the fact that this group came to dominate economic policy and
thinking in the country. In the early period, there were a number of U.S
universities and funding agencies (Ford Foundation in particular)
seeking to work with Pakistani institutions.
(2) It is interesting to note that Haq and Baqai (1988) point to
the "widening in the choice of subjects in research" in the
1960s and 1970s. Their choices include. "analysis of planning
expertise"; "powerful question of regional disparity";
"question of dual exchange rate"; "effective
protection"; type of industrialisation"; and the "effect
of the tube wells on agriculture". They also note, somewhat
disparagingly, that the "focus of economic literature in the
fifties was on monetary analysis, fiscal policy, deficit financing and
inflation". These statements illustrate our point that the issues
of concern to the development economist in the 1960s and 1970s were
interventionist and distributional and not those dealing with
macroeconomic stability backed by a market-oriented regime.
(3) See Hussain (1988), who argues that "the logic of planning
is that the existing set of world prices is not an appropriate indicator
of resource allocation," and concludes that the "sixth five
year plan constitutes an abandonment of ... planning in the strictest
sense of the term ... since it adopts world prices and comparative
advantage as a basis for the abandonment of national economic
planning".
(4) PJAE and PDR are the main economic journals in Pakistan. Like
the proliferation of "research" centres or institutes, a
number of in-house journals, periodicals and magazines of uneven quality
are issued by small colleges and departments of economics. They usually
reflect vanity publication efforts. Also, it may be added that economic
journalism in Pakistan has also increased, but it is still weak and
uneven in quality. Perhaps only one weekly magazine, Pakistan and Gulf
Economist, has achieved a respectable status in recent years.
(5) In fact, a larger social problem in Pakistan. especially among
the "intellectual" (technocratic) elite, is that the PhD.
degree grants the individual the right to add "Dr" as a prefix
to his/her name, it simply acts as a status symbol and gives membership
to the exclusive club.
(6) The question, whether an appropriate domestic research or
policy agenda can be formulated when the local academics and
professionals depend so much on donor funds, is open to investigation.
See Samad (1993).