Fiscal adjustment: trade-offs of macro-economic goals and recent policy reforms in Pakistan.
Ahmad, Mushtaq
The paper attempts to show how the interaction of macro economic
policies in Pakistan has moved over the years in past and attempts to
assess the ultimate impact on fiscal adjustment of economic policies
initiated under the structural adjustment and stabilisation (SASS)
reforms. Its discussion centres around the basic hypothesis that the
fiscal stabilisation mainly depends on interaction between public
finances and other macro economic indicators of the economy which are
differently influenced by different policies. It reveals that the
conflicting goals have made the task of the policy mix under SAAS difficult in reducing the fiscal gap. The paper is presented in four
parts. The first part describes macro economic scenario, albeit briefly,
prevailing at the turn of the 1980s, a time period when a departure from
the old development strategy was conceived and a new agenda of
structural reforms was put in place. The performance of the economy
during the first four decades ending by the close of the 80s when
assessed in terms of growth, equity and stability was found a mixed one.
GDP growth averaged at 6 percent a year. But the fiscal and BOP gaps had
widened and given the persistent savings-investment imbalance, the debt
liability had reached an alarming level. This provides background for
the second part of the paper which presents a short account of reforms
launched since the close of the 80s. The reforms mainly covered market
orientation of the monetary policy and exchange rate, liberalisation of
the economy and its integration into globalisation, privatisation,
reprioritising development programmes, shifting the emphasis of fiscal
policy from taxing foreign trade to domestic broad based consumption
taxes etc. The third part provides an analysis of how the implementation
of different policy reforms in different sectors has impacted on the
public finances. The disaggregated analysis of the fiscal and non fiscal
factors initiated by the reforms programme of the government to put the
economy back on tract of fiscal adjustment is also provided in this
part. Most of the non-fiscal initiatives taken under SAAS in different
areas had serious consequences for fiscal policy in reducing fiscal gap.
Towards the end in the last part the paper concludes that the
experience of almost 10 years of implementing SASS reforms reveals that
non-fiscal policies have mostly conflicted with fiscal policy in
achieving fiscal discipline. At the cost of painful trade-offs the
fiscal deficit has come down from 7 percent of GDP in the 80s to 5.4
percent GDP in 1997-98. Reduction in fiscal deficit has caused the
growth tempo to slow which has ultimately reduced the revenue raising
potentials of the economy.
The paper has explored alternative possibilities for effecting
improvements in the existing national development strategy so that it
succeeds in achieving fiscal discipline while pursuing other goals.
I. INTRODUCTION
Fiscal policy, being an embodiment of government measures to raise
resources through taxes, tariffs of utilities, user charges and pricing
of public sector goods, diverts resources from private sector to the
government which rechannels these resource into socially preferred
activities. The resource diversion and their rechannelisation helps
achieve certain economic goals, and for this reason, the fiscal policy
has strong interactive linkages with other macro economic policies. By
virtue of this strong bond, the fiscal indicators have a close
interactive association with other macro economic indicators. For this
reason, the role of fiscal policy is inevitably vulnerable to influences
of other economic policies and fiscal discipline and general economic
health of the country become interlinked. This linkage results in
generating trade offs between different macroeconomic policy goals.
The aim of this paper is to demonstrate how interaction of macro
economic policies in Pakistan has moved over the years in past and to
assess the ultimate impact on fiscal adjustment of economic policies
initiated under the structural adjustment and stabilisation (SAAS)
reforms. This presentation centres around the basic hypothesis that the
fiscal stability chiefly depends on interaction between public finances
and other macro indicators of the economy which are differently
influenced by different policies. The objective is to demonstrate how
conflicting goals made the task of the policy mix under SAAS reforms
difficult in reducing the fiscal gap.
The presentation in the paper has been ordered in four parts. The
first part describes macro economic scenario, albeit briefly, prevailing
at the turn of the 1980s, a time period when a departure from the old
development strategy was conceived and a new agenda of structural
reforms was put in place. This provides a background for the second part
which presents a short account of the reforms launched since the close
of the 80s. The third part provides an analysis of how the
implementation of different policy reforms in different sectors has
impacted on the public finances. The disaggregated analysis of the
fiscal and non fiscal factors initiated by the reform programme of the
government to put the economy back on a track of fiscal adjustment is
also provided in this part. The concluding section explores alternative
possibilities for forging improvements in the existing national
development strategy so that it succeeds in achieving fiscal discipline
while pursuing other goals.
II. MACRO-ECONOMIC SITUATION IN 1980s
During the first four decades since independence, different
development strategies were pursued. By the end of that period, the
performance of the economy in terms of growth, equity and stability is a
mixed one. On the bright side, there was high and sustained economic
growth of around 6 percent per annum. There was also marked
diversification in the production edifice as the manufacturing sector
grew from a negligible base to a substantial base. The tertiary sectors
also grew in importance. The external sector considerably expanded. It
had generated an appreciable growth in exportable surplus. To meet the
country's growing requirements of capital and raw material, imports
were financed by continued aid inflow and Pakistan's hard earned
foreign exchange. These developments were accompanied by moderate
expansion in social services and physical infrastructure like energy,
electricity, telecommunications and roads. The dismal side of the story
is that the economy remained persistently in fiscal and BoP deficits.
These deficits primarily reflected the national resource gap: national
savings hovered around 15 percent of GDP while investment was maintained
at over 20 percent of GDP. Pursuing goal of high GDP growth could have
pushed macro-economic stability into a jeopardy. Fiscal indiscipline had
persisted, taxation had disappointedly settled at a low level of 14
percent of GDP while budgetary expenditure had continued to rise.
Government's borrowing had reached an alarming level. Subsidies and
debt servicing had pre-empted resources from the routine functions of
the Government; the whole development budget was being financed for a
long time through borrowing. Since the early 80s the government's
non-inflationary resources fell short of current expenditure and as a
result the deficit in the current budget was also met through
borrowings.
Exports had for years in a row fell short of imports; and the
current account of BoP had stubbornly remained in the red. The
country's dependence on foreign borrowings had increased and even
most of the borrowings were consumed for debt servicing, causing
ultimately a steep fall in foreign aid inflow. Heavy recourse was made
to borrowing from the banking system for meeting the budgetary
requirement; this crowded out the private sector and in fact the
monetary policy has rightly been criticised as having been made a
hostage to the fiscal policy. Bank credit was rationed through annual
credit plan, and it was over regulated. Interest rate for many
activities was zero and in many cases negative in real terms. Social
sectors considerably lagged behind the real sectors and the country has
been ranked very low among other developing countries of the region when
judged by social indicators like literacy rate, infant mortality, access
to potable water, sanitation and housing facilities. Some sections of
the society did not adequately benefit from the past growth. Research
studies indicate some improvement in poverty incidence from 1979 to 1988
but the incidence of poverty has gone up in the 1990s. There was a large
number of people living below poverty line. The growth had also
engendered many disparities among the people in their access to
education and social amenities. The disparities hit hard the rural
masses, women and children. Unemployment has remained persistently a
structural problem. The open unemployment, estimated by using broad
definition of employment as taking a person employed who worked for one
hour or longer in a week, was estimated at 5-6 percent and yet when
adjusted for underemployment it could be no less than one fifth of the
total labour force. Its incidence was high among the educated youth and
the women. Demand-supply gap in physical infrastructure had widened;
road network, telecommunication facilities, electricity etc. were
assessed inadequate to support the existing 6 percent per annum in
future.
The weaknesses and problems assessed in the late 80s could be
capsuled as: (a) mismanagement of the economy displayed by persistent
fiscal imbalance, heavy reliance on borrowings, low savings rate,
structural deficit in balance of payments, domination of public sector
in the economy, excessive regulatory system and continued inflation; (b)
low productivity of the real sectors and inefficient production edifice;
(c) high population growth and neglect of social sectors reflected in
indicators like low literacy rate, high unemployment, skewed income
distribution and high poverty incidence, inadequate health facilities,
regional and gender disparities in sharing the benefits of growth; and
(d) weak physical infrastructure, manifested into qualitative and
quantitative inadequacies in transport and communication network, and
sluggish growth in energy resources.
A diagnostic review of lopsided development over the first four
decades helps in the identification of many a factors which the past
policies have either failed to recognise or the policy-makers had
consciously ignored them as these were considered to be incongruous to
their vested interests. The other most probable reason, could also be
that soft options, based on political grounds, were preferred over long
term decisions, which initially appeared to be painful and politically
tough, but would have ultimately steered the economy out of the
difficulties and would have served the national interest.
III. SYNOPSIS OF RECENT REFORMS
The government has adopted a comprehensive agenda of structural
adjustment and stabilisation (SAAS) reforms to attend to structural
problems and to put the economy back on the track of growth recovery
with economic stability, a key element of which is the goal of improving
fiscal discipline, mainly by reducing budgetary gap. [for details of
reforms see Ahmad (1997), Economic Survey (199293) and Qureshi (1995)].
To maintain a cohesion in discussion, the synopsis of reforms is
presented under four groups by virtue of the ultimate goals these
reforms are envisaged to achieve. First, on top of the agenda was (and
is still) the goal of Macroeconomic Stability consisting of three
ingredients of budgetary balance, BoP improvement and reduction in
inflation. Fiscal and monetary policy reforms and devaluation have been
mainly aimed to achieve this. Second, the goal of promoting efficiency
and fostering growth was intended to be achieved through deregulations
and decontrols, privatisation, market liberalisation, institutional
reforms and improvement in public sector efficiency. Third, the goal of
Human Resource Development is to be attained through population control,
improvement in social services, reduction in personal and regional
disparities in access to social services and strengthening the social
safety-nets. Fourth, the goal of expansion in physical infrastructure
and development of energy resources was to be achieved through improved
pricing system and encouraging the private sector, especially the
foreign investors. We have selected those policies which had directly or
indirectly impacted on public finances although these have been
primarily targeted at some other specific goals.
IV. IMPLEMENTATION OF SELECTED POLICY REFORMS
Monetary Policy's Fallout for Public Finances Monetary Policy
has been used as a supportive plank for the fiscal policy for a fairly
long time in Pakistan. The central bank which is its executing agency,
as is the case elsewhere in the world, was kept until recently as an
appendix to Ministry of Finance. The monetary policy was excessively
regulated and was used to provide support to fiscal policies. Interest
rates were arbitrarily fixed by the central bank under the direction of
the Government. Distorted structure of interest rates was pursued to
favour lending to government for financing budgetary gap and meeting
requirements of certain priority sectors like small farmers, locally
manufactured machinery and some specified exports. General lending to
the private sector was made at a high interest rate. (See Annex Tables
1, 2 and 3). In fact there was a wide dispersion in interest rate
starting from minimum zero to a maximum of 9-10 percent and over time
the cap on the maximum rate has undergone changes. The general lending
rate for a considerably long time remained below the prevailing
inflation rate, implying that real interest rate was negative. The bank
credit to the Government for financing budgetary requirements was
advanced at a very low rate; even most of the credit was at around one
percent and besides that, the Government had a direct access to the
surplus deposits of some public sector agencies at a low rate, though
higher than one percent, and yet certainly much less than the inflation
rate. The average inflation rate in the country has been around 7
percent per annum in the first four decades. The low nominal interest
rate adjusted for inflation assured negative real interest rate on
government borrowing from the banking system and thus the government
borrowing from the banking system was substantially subsidised.
The central bank has been regulating bank credit through annual
credit plans, implying direct control on total money supply as well as
on its further allocation to different sectors of the economy. Monetary
policy management was more or less on the pattern of centrally planned
economies. The credit plan first reserved the credit for the government
and the residual in the total annual credit ceiling was allowed to the
private sector. The Government requirements for credit were essentially
to meet budgetary gap and to finance commodity operations: the interest
on the latter was higher than that on the former but that too enjoyed a
concessional margin of 2-3 percent point over the general interest rate.
They carried high weight in the annual credit plan as could be seen from
the figures given below for selected years. (Table 1.)
Within the country, the government taps three types of borrowings
i.e. permanent debt, floating debt and unfunded debt. Of these the
floating debt is the one obtained from the banking system as mentioned
above. The other two categories of debt have been raised from the open
market, the chief source of which is general public, but occasionally
public sector financial institutions were also allowed to purchase
government bonds and securities. Since the direct government borrowings
from the central bank i.e. floating debt was done at a low nominal
interest rate and such loans had a large element of subsidy. The
government made frequently heavy reliance on this type of borrowing for
meeting the budgetary gap. Until the early 80s floating debt was less
than half of the total government debt. Government reliance on this
source of borrowing starting tapering off in subsequent period in the
80s but its share had declined to the lowest level in 1991-92. As the
process of the implementation of reforms continued the Central bank
started gradually shifting from this source of borrowing to the open
market operations. The Treasury bills and Government securities issued
to borrow from the banking institutions were progressively auctioned in
the market and the government has started offering a competitive
interest rate in the open market. This interest rate has remained in the
vicinity of 14-15 percent. These rates showed not only substantial
increase over the nominal interest rates charged in the pre-reforms
period but the real interest rates also turned out to be positive as the
nominal rate exceeded inflation rate. Reforms had progressively exposed
the government borrowing from the banking system to the open market
forces. As a result the two developments of far reaching fiscal
consequences have taken place. First, the government was, in a large
measure, deprived of real subsidy on borrowing from the banking system
and government had now to pay much higher nominal interest rate, making
on the other hand real interest rate positive. Second, raising resources
through open market operations by the government, created a competition
with the private sector and as a result the general level of interest
rates in the country went up and this also pulled up the cost of
borrowings in the form of permanent debt and unfunded debt. This
situation caused a double pressure on debt liability and consequently
the overall cost of government borrowing shot up and the debt servicing
liability also increased. This has had a snow ball effect on the
internal outstanding debt profile. The share of debt servicing in the
current budget has substantially increased. The debt servicing coupled
with defence alone eat up most of the government revenue. The government
is now in a debt trap; it has to borrow not only to meet the primary
fiscal deficit but also to service its past loans. How the debt trap has
emerged over time could be gauged from the trends in the selected debt
related indicators given in Table 2.
Repayment of principal in the case of all types of loans is
adjusted against new loans each year but interest payment is adjusted
only against unfunded loans. Thus debt servicing shown in the budget
documents includes only interest payments for floating and permanent
debts while it is repayment of principal and interest in the case of
foreign loans. As the government has moved away from cheaper source of
credit borrowing from the banking system, the growth of interest
payments, on domestic debt has accelerated and outpaced the other
components of debt servicing. (See Table 3).
Fiscal Implications of External Trade Policy Reforms
Pakistan has a long history of excessively regulated foreign trade
regime. The foreign trade has been considered a main source of revenues
and the trade, particularly imports, was subject to high tariffs, which
had simultaneously provided protection to the local industry. The tariff
structure maintained wide dispersion of rates accompanied by enormous
exemptions. Duty drawbacks and export rebates were allowed for promoting
certain exports and some exports related industries. Besides tariffs,
quantitative restrictions were also used to discourage some imports as
well as exports: thereby checking imports was to shelter some local
industries while restricting exports was considered necessary to
maintain adequate domestic availability of some commodities at low
prices to the consumers. Pakistan has all along been dependent on
foreign capital inflow to meet domestic resource gap, and this has
provided leverage to donors to exert pressure in influencing the
direction of the development strategy of the country. They have never
been happy with regulated trade regime but in the 80s, donors, IMF and
World Bank have largely succeeded in convincing the authorities in
Pakistan to negotiate an agenda of reforms for trade liberalisation.
Since then the country has been steadily progressing in reducing the
tariff and non tariff barriers. The agenda of reduction in non tariff
barriers has been speedily completed but the tariff reforms were
interruptedly implemented. The punctuation in implementing the tariff
reforms was necessitated purely on the ground of revenue loss, albeit
there was wide spread agitation from local industry. Nevertheless the
pace of trade reforms has been quite encouraging since 1988-89.
In March 1997, the largest step taken for reducing protection
related to slashing the maximum tariff rate to 45 percent from 65
percent and minimising the multiple tariff rates to only 4 with
cascadence on the basis of value addition, implying maximum rate on the
import of the finished goods while minimum on the imports of raw
material and machinery used in the high value added local industry but
not locally manufactured. The ultimate goal of the reforms is to bring
maximum tariff rate to 35 percent as agreed by way of conditionalities
with IMF (which coordinates on this with World Bank, ADB and Pakistan
Economic Forum, a successor of Aid to Pakistan Consortium) and also as a
requirement of WTO Charter already signed by Pakistan. The existing
situation characterised by only 45 percent maximum tariff with four
tariff rates, completely eliminated all non tariff barriers, only a few
items on the negative/restricted lists (and that too on very genuine
grounds of security, religion etc.) demonstrates great efforts on the
part of the government to move the economy towards liberalisation as
especially contrasted with the situation prevailing ten years ago, when
in 1987-88 there existed a huge negative and restricted list of items,
maximum tariff rate was as high as 225 percent, coupled with 5 percent
import surcharge, 5 percent Iqra surcharge and 4 percent licence fee,
super imposed with an institutional cap in the form of Office of the
Chief Controller, Imports and Exports to issue licences. Sequenced
removal of restrictions on foreign trade over time could be seen in
Annex Table 4. In the process of liberalisation, there has also been
marked progress in removing certain exemptions and improving the system
of duty draw backs.
The ultimate aim of liberalisation was not only to improve
efficiency of the local industries by exposing them to international
competition (in fact this stipulated gradual elimination of inefficient
industries which have grown under high protection and promoting
efficient industries which could expectedly cope with the changing
global system) and it was also meant to integrate the economy into
global economy. By removing distortions the authorities contemplated
that the economy can grow on its intrinsic strength and find its place
in the global economy on the basis of comparative advantages in trade
and production.
During the last ten years while there was good progress on the
front of implementation of reforms the balance of trade had remained
under continued pressure. The reforms have exerted both direct and
indirect adverse effects on the public finances of the country. At the
start of the reforms the custom duties stood the largest source of
government revenues and that claimed 40.7 percent of total tax revenues
in 1987-88 and their share has declined to 21.7 percent in 1997-98. Now
only imports fetch revenues while the exports which also used to fetch
handsome revenues earlier to the government are now totally exempted
from tariffs. The effective import duty has declined from 33.8 percent
to 18.0 percent over this period. The indirect effect of trade reforms
is that some local industries which were running under protection have
heavily suffered and some of them have come to a standstill and the
recessionary growth trends in manufacturing sector, even negative in
recent years, has reduced revenue potentials to be tapped through sales
tax and excise duty. This provides a glaring unfavourable contrast with
the period immediately preceding the launching of reforms when
manufacturing growth was around 8 percent per annum.
Budgetary Impact of Foreign Exchange Policy Reforms
Under the exchange rate system prior to 7th January 1982, Pak Rupee was linked with the US dollar and infact the fixed exchange rate system
continued since 1947 although the Rupee had been devalued on two
occasions till 7th January, 1982. Since the new exchange rate policy
brought about a switch over from fixed parity with US dollar to a
managed floating system under which the Rupee was linked with a basket
of currencies of country's major trade partners. The Rupee had
remained subjected to periodic depreciation/devaluation. During January
1982 to 1987 the Rupee was devalued by 43 percent and under the current
exchange reforms the Rupee came under great pressure and there was
persistent pressure by the donors for devaluation. There were also a
genuine ground because the domestic prices recorded higher increases
over the preceding period and higher inflation, therefore, justified
correction in the exchange rate through devaluation with a view to
protect competitiveness of exports in international market.
During the period, 1987-88 to 1997-98, the Rupee recorded against
the US dollar a depreciation/devaluation of 59 percent. The rupee:
dollar parity changed from Rs 17.6/dollar to Rs 43.2/dollar. This
directly impacted the Rupee debt servicing liability in the case of
foreign debt. As demonstrated in an earlier table, repayment of foreign
debt as percent of GDP has gone up from 2 percent of GDP in 1987-89 to 4
percent of GDP in 1997-98 and is estimated at 4.1 percent of GDP in
1998-99. The repayments/amortisation of foreign debt stood at Rs 13.5
billion in 1987-88. The positive impact of devaluation expected to come
through higher rupee value of imports leading to higher yield of
advalorem import duties was neutralised by negative impact of falling
imports and scaling down of tariffs. The exchange rate policy reforms
pushed the expenditure to rise more in the process of reforms than in
the earlier period. The Rupee valued debt servicfng of foreign loans has
directly increased and thus built pressure on government budget.
Privatising and Divesting Policies' Impact on Budget
The tradition of direct involvement of the public sector in
economic activities started in the early history of the country when the
government established Industrial Development Corporation of Pakistan to
undertake industrial projects. In fact that was necessitated due to the
fact that the private sector was shy to undertake capital intensive
industries because that did not have the experience and expertise in the
field. Nevertheless these projects were ultimately to be sold to the
private sector on completion. However a radical change occurred in the
national economic philosophy in the 70s, and an equity-oriented
development strategy was pursued under which large scale nationalisation
took place in the fields of major industries, banking, insurance,
shipping and trade. As a result public corporate sector emerged in
tandem with general government and that started maintaining its own
parallel budget. There was a fiscal linkage between the general
government and the public corporate sector. The pricing policies were
controlled by the government which kept prices below cost and
consequently the public sector enterprises were meeting their deficit by
borrowing funds from central government, banking sector and private
sector but in certain cases the Federal Government gave subsidy on some
operations undertaken under specific government directives.
The public corporate sector as a whole has remained for a long time
in net deficit and such persistent deficit has pushed it into a debt
trap. This has thus created problems for monetary and fiscal policies.
The fixed investment in the corporate sector was mostly owned by the
government and its profitability soon turned into loss which had direct
bearing on the public finances. Under the reforms around the turn of the
80s the government has off loaded a big chunk of the public corporate
sector and so far 105 units falling in manufacturing, banking, PTC vouchers, and power sectors have been divested against Rs 60.67 billion
and an amount of Rs 57.23 billion plus mark up of Rs 1288.3 million has
been received. Of this an amount Rs. 37.66 billion has been used by
Government/ WAPDA during 1994-95 to 1997-98 in routine operations and
about Rs 5 billion has been used for retirement of public debt.
Administered Pricing Policy
The prices of agricultural inputs, gas and public utilities were
controlled by the Government and these were invariably kept below their
actual cost. In most cases the public sector was directly involved in
the production and distribution of these commodities and utilities, and
the price-cost differential was met either by way of subsidies or
through borrowings. Maintaining such differential persistently over a
long period caused the debt liability of some public sector agencies
like WAPDA and KESC to skyrocket. Under the price reforms the subsidies
on agricultural inputs like fertiliser and pesticides has been almost
eliminated and there has been some increase in the prices of
agricultural non traded inputs like irrigation water, credit and
electricity but even the revised prices did not cover total cost. Some
progress has been made in implementing economic pricing but still sale
prices of electricity and gas are much less than the cost which also
continued to increase due to rising wages, rents and interests. The
subsidy bill on fertilisers has sharply declined from Rs 1.4 billion in
1990-91 to Rs. 47 million in 1995-96 and was then completely eliminated
in subsequent years. In the recent years only in 1994-95 and 1995-96 a
subsidy of Rs 1 billion per annum was given on agricultural loans.
These reforms have two positive effects: one is a clear move in the
direction of reduction in the burden of subsidies on budget and the
second is that economic pricing policy has been recognised as a cardinal
principle of the national development strategy for achieving fiscal
discipline.
Budgetary Implications of Social Safety Net and Provision of Social
Services
In the process of reforms two important developments took place.
First, it was recognised that in the transition phase of reforms income
disparities at personal as well as regional (rural viz. urban) level
have widened and poverty incidence risen. This was to be mitigated by
having adequate social safety-net. In recognition of the need for
improving the quality and coverage of social services like education,
health etc. for upgrading low ranked human development indicators, the
government had to increase social spending. The government had to
subsidise wheat distribution network. Its budgetary impact has earlier
declined from Rs 5.9 billion in 1991-92 to Rs 2.9 billion but has
subsequently increased to Rs 11.7 billion in 1997-98. To assist the poor
financially the government has to run Bait-ul Mal which entailed an
endowment of Rs 2 billion. In February 1997 Poverty Alleviation Fund has
been established with a Government-contributed endowment of Rs 2
billion. Loans of SBFC and HBFC are also subsidised. Expenditure on
education and health sectors has been increased in parallel to overall
expenditure under budget but a gigantic SAP stipulates huge expenditure
which has put a heavy impact on the budget.
Direct Role of Fiscal Policy Reforms
The focus of the fiscal policy reforms was on reduction in fiscal
deficit by mobilising more revenues and curtailing public expenditure.
The measures aimed at mobilising additional resources envisaged
fundamental changes in the taxation system in the form of shifting
emphasis from the taxes on foreign trade to generalised income and
consumption taxes, broadening tax base, reducing tax rate, curtailing
numbers of tax slabs, switching over from quantum to advalorem basis in
the case of taxes on foreign trade, excise duty and sales tax. In the
case of taxes on international trade sharp reduction has been made in
the maximum tariff which has been brought down to 45 percent and their
structure is simplified to only four cascadence tax rates. The coverage
of excise duty and sales tax has also been increased and their structure
has been reformed in terms of reduction in the number of tax slabs and
switch over from quantum to advalorem basis. Direct taxes have also
undergone similar reforms as the tax rates has been reduced and many
services and agriculture have been brought into their tax net.
Government has succeeded in curtailing the level of public
development expenditure in relation to GDP and in current expenditure
some selected expenditure categories like transfer payments particularly
subsidies have been reduced. Nevertheless the propensity to reduce the
current expenditure is limited as most of the items like interest
payments and expenditure on essential services like law and order,
general administration cannot be reduced beyond a certain level.
Moreover with a time lag, the expenditure on projects and economic
activities undertaken under development programmes are shifted, on their
completion, to the current expenditure and this is a continuous inflow
into the current expenditure. Notwithstanding the inflexibility in the
current expenditure, the reduction in public expenditure had become
possible through reduction in the development expenditure. The reforms
did not show satisfactory results in tax realisation and in fact the tax
receipts pace has rather slackened. In the second half of the 80s the
tax revenues were on average slightly higher than 14 percent of GDP
while this average has slightly slipped to little over 13 percent. The
non tax revenues had shown a slight improvement in the early 90s as
these were on average 4.3 percent of GDP but these declined to less than
3 percent of GDP in the last three years through 1997-98. The overall
expenditure had touched a peak at 26.7 percent of GDP in 1997-98 but in
subsequent years the level started tapering off and it has declined to
21.8 percent of GDP in 1997-98. Relatively some decline has been
recorded in both current and development expenditures but as already
mentioned the development expenditure became the main victim of this
reduction [See Annex Table 5].
Many fiscal specific factors have stood in the way of efficient
implementation of fiscal reforms. The provincial government and local
bodies did not actively participate in resource mobilisation and have
thus failed to meet the mandate of the National Finance Commission
awards which reflect the plan for intergovernmental fiscal relations.
The other principal factors include a continued exclusion of potential
tax handles, large scale tax evasion, anomalies in tariff policies,
heavy tilt towards indirect taxes (inspite the reforms), lags in tax
policy, lack of documentation, vague language of tax amendment rules,
thriving black economy, and lack of compatibility of the taxation system
with the requirements of the ensuing regional blocks and international
trade system. Tightening the taxation system led to an under-invoicing
of imports and over-invoicing of exports which is also feared to have
caused capital flight [Commerce Minister's Speech (1998)]. Frequent
changes in the taxation policy and allowing a large number of tax
exemptions on one or the pretext have further compounded the fiscal
problem.
Secondary Effect of Reforms on Public Finances
Reduction in the relative size of annual development programme in
the budget made growth oriented projects, like those on water logging
and anti salinity to starve. Dismantling protection tariff wall took a
heavy toll on many industries. Withdrawal of subsidies on agricultural
inputs inflicted heavy below to agriculture. As a result the growth of
real sectors suffered in the 90s. Secondly under the reforms despite the
government started tightening of the tax administration, tax evasion
increased. Frequent devaluations prompted resort to foreign currency
business which is mostly out of tax net. Similarly under-invoicing of
imports became attractive. As a result under ground or black economy has
considerably expanded. A recent research study has found that its annual
growth has increased from 14 percent in the 80s to 26 percent in the 90s
[Iqbal et al. (1998)]. This trend combined with the depressed GDP growth
has inhibited the pace of resource mobilisation under the existing
taxation system.
V. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The experience of almost 10 years of implementing SAAS reforms
reveals that non-fiscal policies have mostly conflicted with fiscal
policy in achieving fiscal discipline. At the cost of painful tradeoffs
the fiscal policy deficit has come down from 7 percent of GDP in the 80s
to 5.4 percent of GDP in 1997-98. This reduction in fiscal deficit seems
to have slowed pinched the growth tempo which in turn has reduced the
revenue potentials [See Annex Table 5]. Whether the partial success of
the reforms in limited areas outweighs the loss in the growth momentum
is debatable. Certainly reduction in fiscal deficit does not fully
explain the fiscal discipline because that could be a necessary
condition but not a sufficient condition for fiscal discipline. Some
what subdued deficit is accompanied with mounting debt liability,
sluggish resource mobilisation and stubborn current expenditure place
the public finances far away from the planned fiscal discipline.
In fact the agenda of SAAS reforms was too big to be efficiently
'managed when the country did not have the expertise to steer it
through the vast restructuring of the economy. The basic principle of
economics that economic policies option conflict in their goals has been
over looked. The authorities have not been allowed sufficient time to
appraise the reforms before these came under implementation because the
donors pressed them to accept these as conditionalities for loans which
were badly needed to cover the resource gap. Secondly the public,
particularly business community, industry, and farmers have not been
taken into confidence in formulating SAAS reforms. The press has always
been hostile to them. The reforms were not debated at national forums,
and thus no consensus was developed on the context of reforms. In short,
the reforms got poor receptivity within the country.
The reforms lacked proper sequencing in their implementation.
Monetary policy reforms were front loaded with adverse fiscal fall out.
Similarly by effecting reduction in tariffs on foreign trade before
ensuring compensatory domestic taxes was ill timed.
Absorption capacity was reduced by launching tight monetary and
fiscal policy but that adversely affected domestic production. Moreover
these policies failed to give support to stabilise the Rupee exchange
rate. Excepting temporary slow down in 1997-98 the domestic prices
remained under persistent pressure, keeping inflation in double digit.
This distorted other policy objectives as well.
Defaulted and non performing bank loans have totalled about Rs 184
billion by 31st March, 1998 (reported by Finance Minister to the
National Assembly on 26th August, 1998--Business Recorder, 26th August,
1998) but their recovery is slow. This is the greatest hurdle in
reforming the banking system. Lack of political will is considered a
main cause of this malaise.
There is urgent need for corrections both in the policy mix and
their sequencing. Consensus both at public and political level has to be
developed on the reforms. A strong team at technical level in all
relevant fields has to be put together so that a meaningful dialogue
could be made on conditionalities with the donors. Legal framework for
implementation of the reforms should be speedily developed. Taxation
system should contain minimum exemptions and concessions which often
cause tax leakages. Tax/tariff collection and administration needs to be
strengthened and to be made immune to political influences. In no case,
fiscal policy should be anti-growth. With a view to accelerate resource
mobilisation as wall as to check fiscal leakage, fiscal devolution needs
to be fostered. Transparency should be encouraged in revenue collections
and public spending to avoid corruption and to minimise tax evasion.
The existing situation provides sound ground to conclude that the
progress in reducing the deficit is not yet deeply entrenched in the
economic structure and the fundamentals to support its continued
downward trend in the long run are still fragile. Continued effort on
the part of the authorities with support of the public is required to
strengthen the process of reforms on lines indicated in the previous
analysis.
Author's Note: I am grateful to Dr Sarfraz K. Qureshi for some
useful suggestions towards refining this paper.
Annex Table 1
Scheduled Banks' Rates of Return on Advances
* (Percent per Annum)
Ceiling Rates
Conventional Fixed Fixed
Effective Advances Industrial Agricultural
From Investments Investments
12-05-1972 10.00
31-10-1972 10.00
27-02-1973 10.00
16-08-1973 11.00
03-09-1974 13.00 13.00 13.00
07-06-1977 14.00 14.00 14.00
07-07-1977 14.00 14.00 14.00
05-09-1977 14.00 12.50 14.00
03-03-1978 14.00 12.50 14.00
01-07-1978 14.00 11.00 11.00
Ceiling Rates
** Export Locally
Finance Manufacture
Effective Scheme Machinery
From (Export Sales)
12-05-1972
31-10-1972 6.00
27-02-1973 7.00 6.00
16-08-1973 9.00 8.00
03-09-1974 10.00 9.00
07-06-1977 10.10 9.00
07-07-1977 8.00 7.00
05-09-1977 8.00 7.00
03-03-1978 6.00 5.00
01-07-1978 3.00 2.00
Ceiling Rates
Government Commodity
Operation @ Minimum Rates #
If Refinanced From Own Finished Other
by SBP Sources Goods Advances
Except
Effective Capital
From Goods
12-05-1972 6.25 6.25
31-10-1972 6.25 6.25
27-02-1973 6.25 6.25
16-08-1973 6.25 6.25
03-09-1974 8.25 8.25
07-06-1977 9.25 9.25 12.00 11.00
07-07-1977 10.25 11.50 13.00 11.00
05-09-1977 10.25 11.50 13.00 11.00
03-03-1978 10.25 11.50 13.00 11.00
01-07-1978 10.25 11.50 13.00 11.00
# No bank other than ADBP and IDBP may charge return on any loan or
advance or credit facility of any nature, which is less than 10.0
percent per annum or more than 13.0 percent per annum, except to
the extent that in case of advances against finished goods
(excluding capital goods) the minimum return rate shall be 12.0
percent per annum and maximum 13.0 percent per annum.
** As a part of first phase of interest free banking the financing
of the entire trading operations Rice-Export Corporation of
Pakistan. Cotton Export Corporation under part-I of the Export
Finance Scheme of the State Bank has also been changed to the
mark-up basis at 0.75 percent for 90 days. @ The financing of
Government commodity operations has been shifted from interest to
mark-up basis at the rate:
(i) if counter finance is obtained from SBP 2.563 percent for 90
days shared between the bank and SBP as 1:40 and
(ii) if financed from banks funds 2.875 percent for 90 days.
* On mark-up basis as from July, 1985.
* Table 2: Adjustment Lending in Pakistan (US$ million).
* Source: State Bank of Pakistan, Annual Reports 1990 and 1995,
Karachi.
Annex Table 2
Weighted Average Rates of Return on Advances by Scheduled Banks
(All Banks)
(Percent per Annum)
Interest-Bearing 7
Islamic Modes Interest Islamic Modes
of Financing Bearing of Financing
As at the End of
1993 June 13.32 13.09 13.36
December 13.52 12.46 13.68
1994 June 13.66 12.78 13.78
December 13.53 13.43 13.54
1995 June 13.74 13.19 13.80
December 13.91 13.39 13.97
1996 June 14.36 13.04 14.48
December 14.26 13.70 14.32
1997 June 14.55 13.53 14.65
December 14.71 13.72 14.79
Source: State Bank of Pakistan, Annual Reports 1990 and 1995, Karachi.
Annex Table 3
Sate Bank Rates of Return
(Percent per Annum)
Export Locally Manufactured Machinery Export Sales
Effective Finance
from Scheme Local Sales Pre-shipment Post-shipment
26-05-1985 3.00 5.62 3.00 4.50
31-08-1985 3.00 5.50 3.00 4.50
01-07-1987 3.00 1.00 3.00 4.50
27-06-1988 3.00 4.00 3.00 4.50
01-07-1989 3.00 4.00 3.00 4.50
10-07-1990 3.00 5.00 5.00 4.50
11-07-1990 4.00 5.00 5.00 4.50
01-08-1991 4.00 6.00 6.00 5.50
01-03-1992 5.00 6.00 6.00 5.50
16-08-1993 8.00 9.00 9.00 8.50
02-03-1994 9.00 10.00 10.00 9.50
11-11-1994 9.00 11.00 11.00 10.50
13-11-1994 10.00 11.00 11.00 10.50
29-10-1995 10.00 12.00 11.00 10.50
28-07-1997 9.00 12.00 9.00 9.00
01-07-1998 6.00 12.00 6.00 6.00
Agricultural
Effective Development Federal Bank for
from Bank of Pakistan Cooperatives
26-05-1985 4.00 0.50
31-08-1985 4.00 0.50
01-07-1987 5.00 0.50
27-06-1988 5.00 0.50
01-07-1989 6.00 0.50
10-07-1990 6.00 0.50
11-07-1990 6.00 0.50
01-08-1991 6.00 0.50
01-03-1992 6.00 0.50
16-08-1993 6.00 0.50
02-03-1994 6.00 0.50
11-11-1994 6.00 0.50
13-11-1994 6.00 0.50
29-10-1995 6.00 0.50
28-07-1997 6.00 0.50
01-07-1998 6.00 0.50
Source: State Bank of Pakistan, Annual Reports 1990 and 1995,
Karachi.
SBP refinance rate to the Federal Bank for Co-operatives
at 7.00 percent up to 31-12-1982 and at 6.00 percent from
01-01-1983-85 and at 0.50 percent services charges basis
from 01-04-1985.
Annex Table 4
Changes in Trade Policy: 1987-88 to 1998-99
Items Removed Items Removed Maximum
Fiscal from from Tariff
Year Negative List Restricted List (%)
1987-88 136 10 225
1988-89 169 51 125
1989-90 70 20 125
1990-91 97 43 95
1991-92 23 17 90
1992-93 21 11 90
1993-94 2 7 80
1994-95 1 0 70
1995-96 11 0 65
1996-97 0 0 65
1997-98 0 0 45
1998-99 0 2 45
Import Igra Licence
Fiscal Surcharge Surcharge Fee
Year (%) (%) (%)
1987-88 5 5 4
1988-89 6 5 5
1989-90 7 5 5
1990-91 10 5 6
1991-92 10 5 6
1992-93 0 5 6
1993-94 0 5 6
1994-95 0 0 0
1995-96 0 0 0
1996-97 0 0 0
1997-98 0 0 0
1998-99 0 0 0
1. Items removed are a mixture of numbers and categories and,
therefore, are only a broad indication.
2. Automobiles and alcohol continue to carry tariffs up to 425
percent.
Annex Table 5
Selected Fiscal and Economic Indicators
1980-81 1985-86 1992-93
1. Fiscal Indicators
as % of GDP
--Total Revenues 16.9 17.5 18.0
--Tax Revenue 14.0 12.3 13.3
--Non Tax Revenue 2.9 5.2 4.6
--Current Expenditure 13.6 18.4 20.3
--Development Expenditure 9.3 7.7 5.7
--Total Expenditure 22.9 26.1 26.0
--Overall Fiscal Deficit 5.3 8.1 8.0
2. Growth Rates
--GDP 6.40 6.36 2.27
--Agriculture 3.66 5.95 -5.29
--Manufacturing 10.63 7.55 5.35
1997-98 1980s 1990-98
1. Fiscal Indicators
as % of GDP
--Total Revenues 16.5 17.2 17.3
--Tax Revenue 13.2 13.4 13.4
--Non Tax Revenue 3.2 3.8 3.6
--Current Expenditure 0.8 17.6 19.0
--Development Expenditure 3.2 7.3 4.9
--Total Expenditure 21.8 24.8 23.9
--Overall Fiscal Deficit 5.4 7.0 6.7
2. Growth Rates
--GDP 5.44 6.14 6.66
--Agriculture 5.90 4.07 4.09
--Manufacturing 7.00 8.21 5.21
REFERENCES
Ahmad, Mushtaq (1993) Taxation Policy in Pakistan: Grey Areas and
Need for Reforms. Paper presented at seminar organised by the Pakistan
Economic Forum, 20-21 February.
Ahmad, Mushtaq (1997) Experience of Developing Countries in Growth,
Price Stability and Income Distribution. Presented at PIDE's
Course, 28-29th August.
Commerce Minister of Pakistan (1998) Various Policy
Statements/Speeches Made in September to December.
Pakistan, Government of (1992-93) Economic Survey of Pakistan,
1992-93. Islamabad: Ministry of Finance.
Pakistan, Government of (n.d.) CBR Year Book 1995-96. Islamabad.
Iqbal, Zafar et al. (1998) The Underground Economy and Tax Evasion
in Pakistan: A Fresh Assessment. Pakistan Institute of Development
Economics, Islamabad. (Research Report No. 159.)
State Bank of Pakistan (1998) Statistical Bulletins of Selected
Months. Karachi.
State Bank of Pakistan (Various Issues) Annual Report of Selected
Years. Karachi.
Mushtaq Ahmad is Member, National Tariff Commission, Islamabad.
Table 1
Government Access to Bank Credit
(Rs Billion)
1974-75 1982-83
Annual Cumulative Annual Cumulative
Years Sector Addition Stock Addition Stock
Government Sector 3.06 17.50 9.20 71.37
--Budgetary Financing 1.52 13.83 5.63 55.44
--Commodity Operations 1.54 3.67 3.57 15.93
Total Domestic Credit 5.07 33.07 29.52 146.03
1992-993 1997-98
Annual Cumulative Annual Cumulative
Years Sector Addition Stock Addition Stock
Government Sector 78.94 359.76 57.63 653.49
--Budgetary Financing 65.70 322.77 48.46 554.98
--Commodity Operations 7.34 30.20 10.59 63.66
Total Domestic Credit 89.82 595.39 149.11 1202.35
Table 2
Outstanding Domestic Debt
(Rs Billion)
Years Debt-related
Indicators 1980-81 1985-86 1992-93 1997-98
Total Domestic Outstanding 58.09 203.12 615.31 1279.75
Debt (% of GDP) (20.9) (39.5) (45.9) (42.1)
--Floating Debt 31.69 57.63 215.82 549.71
--Permanent Debt 13.76 58.23 245.49 265.69
--Unfunded Debt Adjusted 12.64 57.63 154.00 464.35
for Debt Servicing
Interest Payment on Floating 4.70 (1) 19.02 62.73 164.52
and Permanent Debt
Note: The figure has been extracted from a long series of data.
Table 3
Debt Servicing as % of GDP
1979-80 1985-86 1992-93 1997-98
Interest Payment on Domestic
Debt 1.1 2.5 4.7 5.6
Interest Payment on Foreign
Debt 1.0 1.2 1.3 1.0
Repayment of Principal on
Foreign Debt 2.4 2.1 2.2 3.2
Total Debt Servicing 4.5 5.9 8.3 10.1