The systematic risk and leverage effect in the corporate sector of Pakistan.
Nishat, Mohammed
I. INTRODUCTION
Poor corporate financing policies, non-competitive role of
institutional development, a tendency towards the underpricing of
initial offering resulted in high levered stocks in Karachi stock market
(KSE). The KSE is termed as high risk high return emerging market where
investors seek high risk premium Nishat (1999). The leverage is the most
important factor which determines the firms risk premium [Zimmer
(1990)]. Hamada (1969) and Bowman (1979) have demonstrated the
theoretical relationship between leverage and systematic risk.
Systematic risk of the leverage firm is equal to the without leverage
systematic risk of the firm times one plus the leverage ratio (debt
equity). Bowman (1979) established that systematic risk is directly
related to leverage and the accounting beta (covariability of a
firms' accounting earnings with the accounting earnings of the
market portfolio). One explanation of time-varying stock volatility is
that leverage changes as the relative price of stocks and bonds change.
Schwert (1989) demonstrated how a change in the leverage of the firm
causes a change in the volatility of stock returns. Haugen and Wichern
(1975) analysed the relationship between leverage and relative stability
of stock value based on actuarial science (1) and found that the
duration of the debt is an important attribute in assessing the effect
of leverage on stock volatility. If the leverage is persistent, or
changing over time due to the issuance of additional debt, or if the
firms are trying to return back the debt, this will change the risk of
holding common stock. Kane, Marcus, and McDonald (1985) argued that a
well defined metric for the advantage of debt financing is the
difference in rates of return earned by optimally levered and unlevered
firms, net of a return premium to compensate for potential bankruptcy costs.
After the experience of excessive controls and rigid financial
regulation before 1987 in Pakistan, restrained market forces in the
allocation of resources, and growing competition at both the national
and international level, motivated the deregulation and financial
reforms observed after 1987. In addition to several private investment
boosting and deregulating policies in the corporate sector during mid
eighties, the strategy of corporate financing has also been changed
gradually to reduce debt-equity ratio from 80:20 and 60:40 to 50:50 over
time. The mandatory quotas of institutional investors before offerings
to the public curtailed and now the prices of new shares are determined
in the market. The purpose of this policy was to boost private
investment participation on competitive basis and reduce the leverage in
corporate sector of Pakistan over time.
The objective of the this study is to determine the relationship
between leverage and systematic risk in the corporate sector of Pakistan
during the non-reform (January 1980 to June (1988) and reform period
(July 1988 to December 1994). The rest of the paper is organised as
follows: the second section describes the theoretical framework. The
econometric methodology is given in section three followed by empirical
results in section four. The concluding remarks are provided in section
five.
2. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND ECONOMETRIC MODEL
The firm-wise analysis indicates that stock return volatility rises
after prices fall [Black (1976); Christie (1982) and Cheung and Ng
(1992)]. Two possible explanations are given leverage and time-varying
risk premia. The leverage effect posits that a firm's stock price
decline raises the firm's financial leverage, resulting in an
increase in the volatility of equity [Black (1976); Christie (1982)].
The leverage hypothesis assumes that the volatility of log changes in
firm's net asset value (debt plus equity) is constant over time and
concludes that the volatility of log changes in the firm's equity
varies over time with the firm's debt/equity ratio. A decline in
the value of the firm's assets will fall (almost) entirely on the
value of equity, thereby raising the firm's debt/equity ratio and
raising the future volatility of stock returns [Christie (1982)]. The
theory underlying the leverage effect shows that highly levered firms
should exhibit a stronger negative relation between stock returns and
volatility than should less highly levered firms. Cheung and Ng (1992)
find an inverse relation between period t firm stock returns and changes
in firm stock return volatility from period t to t+l. They also find
that this inverse relation is stronger for firms with large debt/equity
ratios. Cheung and Ng (1992) note that this inverse relation is also
stronger for smaller firms.
Black (1976), and others [French, Schwert and Stambaugh (1987);
Schwert (1989)], however, argued that the response of stock volatility
to the direction of returns is too large to be explained by leverage
alone. According to the leverage effect, a reduction in the equity value
would raise the debt to equity ratio, hence raising the riskiness of the
firm as manifested in an increase in future volatility. As a result, the
future volatility will be negatively related to the current return on
the stock.
In the literature leverage is described as one of the explanations
for the time varying stock return volatility. If the leverage of a firm
changes relative to stock and bond prices, the volatility of the firm
also changes. In particular, the variance of the return to the assets of
a firm is a function of the variances of the returns to the stocks and
bonds and the covariance of returns. For a firm with riskless debt,
where the variance of the assets of the firm is constant over time, the
standard deviation of the stock return is related to the standard
deviation of last year's leverage. This shows a change in the
leverage of the firm causes a change in the volatility of stock returns.
[[??].sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [beta][DELTA][[delta].sub.it]) +
[[micro].sub.it] ... ... ... ... ... (1)
where [[??].sub.it] is the weekly return on industry i in period t
and [DELTA]([delta].sub.it]) is the change in weekly return volatility
of the industry i in period t.
3. DATA
The firm level weekly share prices, dividend, capital issues, and
paid-up capital data on KSE is collected and computerised by the author
using the original "Daily List" and "List of Daily
Trading Documents" published by the KSE during January 1980 to
December 1994. The data consists of weekly share prices of 14 industries
for which the leverage data is available for the entire period of the
study published in Balance Sheet Analysis published by SBP. The data
consists of weekly share prices adjusted for dividend and capital
issues. The value-weighted returns are calculated and industry
portfolios are formulated. The value-weighted industry portfolios are
made for non-reform sub-periods (January 1980 to June 1985 and July 1985
to June 1988) and reform sub-periods (July 1988 to June 1991 and July
1991 to December 1994). For further details see [Nishat (1999)].
4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS AND INTERPRETATION
Leverage data on selected industries registered with the KSE are
given in Table 1. (2) In all sub-periods of non-reform and reform we
observed a significant variation in the extent of leverage across
industries. In most cases the debt-equity ratios across industries are
higher throughout the study period, except for a few industries like
tobacco and vanaspati and allied. (3) During the overall period, the
average leverage is 0.809. Cotton, paper and paper board, fuel and
energy, and transport and communications, indicated above average
leverage. The average leverage increased during the first sub-period of
non-reform. However, the pattern of leverage across industries does not
change much over time. The extent of leverage is comparatively lower
during the reform period.
A notable change is observed in cotton, engineering and sugar and
allied where the leverage magnitudes are higher during the reform
sub-periods than the non-reform sub-periods. Other industries do have
variations in their leverage magnitudes, but the pattern has been almost
the same across non-reform and reform sub-periods. Paper and paper board
has the highest level of leverage in most cases, whereas vanaspati and
allied have the lowest level of leverage throughout all the subperiods
of non-reform and reform. The following model is estimated to test the
hypothesis that highly levered industries in Pakistan should exhibit a
stronger negative relation between stock returns and change in
volatility than should less levered industries:
[[??].sub.it] = [[alpha].sub.0] + [beta][DELTA]([[delta].sub.it]) +
[[micro].sub.it] ... ... ... ... ... (1)
where [[??].sub.it] is the weekly return on industry i in period t
and [DELTA]([[delta].sub.it]) is the change in weekly return volatility
of the industry i in period t.
We estimate the returns and risk relationship with the hypothesis
that leverage causes a change in the volatility of stock returns
[Christie (1982) French, Schwert and Stambaugh (1987); Schwert (1989)
and Cheung and Ng (1992)]. The regression results for industry returns
and change in industry return volatility relationships are presented in
Tables 2 to 7. The relationship between returns and change in return
volatility during the overall period generalise the strong negative
relation for highly levered industry as described in other studies. Few
of the less levered industries also indicate a negative and significant
relationship between return and change in volatility. Less levered
industries either have an insignificant relation between returns and
change in volatility (vanaspati and allied) or weaker negative
relationship than levered industries.
During the first sub-period of non-reform most of the industries
have a negative and significant relationship between return and changes
in return volatility except vanaspati and allied which has positive and
insignificant coefficient. Higher levered industries have a strong
negative relationship between returns and change in return volatility
compared to less levered industries. During the second sub-period of
non-reform, most of the industries have a negative and significant
relation between return and changes in return volatility except
vanaspati and allied. However, higher levered industries have stronger
negative relation between return and change in return volatility during
this sub-period. The average leverage magnitudes during reform
sub-periods are less than the average leverage magnitude during
non-reform sub-periods. The negative and significant relationships
between return and change in return volatility are consistent in most
cases. The higher levered industries have a stronger negative
relationship between return and change in return volatility during both
sub-periods of reform. A similar pattern is observed during the overall
reform period. The more highly levered industries have a negative and in
most cases significant relationship between returns and changes in
return volatility. However, some variations in the strength of this
negative relationship between return and change in return volatility has
been observed in all sub-periods. The leverage level in Pakistan has
been relatively high, hence the consistent negative and significant
relationships between return and change in volatility are observed
during both non-reform and reform sub-periods. In most cases higher
levered industries indicated stronger negative relationships between
return and change in volatility than the less levered industries. The
leverage effect is better explained during the nonreform than the reform
period.
5. CONCLUDING REMARKS
The above findings indicate that leverage at industry level has
been historically high in Pakistan, hence the consistent negative and
significant relationships between return and volatility change are
observed. In most cases, highly levered industries had a stronger
negative relationship between return and volatility change than the less
levered industries. The leverage effect was better explained during the
non-reform than the reform period.
REFERENCES
Black, F. (1976) Studies of Stock Market Volatility Changes.
Proceedings of the American Statistical, Association, Business and
Economic Statistics Section. 177-81.
Bowman, R. G. (1979) The Theoretical Relationship Between
Systematic Risk and Financial (Accounting) Variables. Journal of Finance
34:3, 617-630.
Cheung, Yin-Wong, and L. K. Ng (1992) Intersections Between the U.
S. and Japan Stock Market Indices. Journal of International Financial
Management, Institutions and Markets 21 : 1, 93-108.
Christie, A. A. (1982) The Stochastic Behaviour of Common Stock
Variance Value, Leverage and Interest Rate Effects. Journal of Financial
Economics 10, 407-32.
French, K. R., G. W. Schwert, and R. F. Stambaugh (1987) Expected
Stock Returns and Volatility. Journal of Financial Economics 19, 3-29.
Hamada, K. (1969) Optimal Capital Accumulation by an Economy Pacing
an International Capital Market. Journal of Financial Research 17:2,
175-186.
Haugen, R. A., and D. W. Wichem (1974) The Elasticity of Financial
Assets, Journal of Finance 29, 1229-40.
Hicks, J. R. (1939) Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Kane, E. J., A. J. Marcus, and R. L. McDonald (1985) Debt Policy
and the Rate of Return Premium to Leverage. Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis 28:2, 479-500.
Malkiel, B. G. (1962) Expectations, Bond Prices and the Term
Structure of Interest Rate. Quarterly Journal of Economics 76: 2,
197-218.
Malkiel, B. G. (1963) Equity Yields Growth and the Structure of
Share Prices. American Economic Review 53: 5, 1004-1031.
Nishat, M. (1999) The Impact of Institutional Development on Stock
Prices in Pakistan, Unpublished Dissertation, Auckland Business School,
University of Auckland, Auckland.
Schwert, G. W. (1989) Why Does Stock Market Volatility Change Over
Time? Journal of Finance 44:5, 1115-1154.
State Bank of Pakistan (1980-1995) Balance Sheet Analysis of
Companies Listed with Karachi Stock Exchange.
Zimmer, S. A. (1990) Event Risk Premia and Bond Market Incentives
for Corporate Leverage. FRB New York Quarterly Review 15:1, 15-30.
(1) Hicks (1939); Haugen and Wincher (1974); Malkiel (1962, 1963)
who have attempted to isolate the theoretical determinants of risk of
equity capital.
(2) The SBP publishes the firm-wise Balance Sheet Analysis for the
KSE companies, but data on leverage is not readily available for entire
study period.
(3) The corporate sector in Pakistan have comparatively easy access
to debt and have higher debtequity ratios. During 1992 government
announced plans to limit the debt-equity ratio to 50:50 by 1994.
Traditionally the debt-equity ratio has fluctuated between 80:20 to
60:40 depending on extent of concessional loans and sectoral priorities
for fiscal concessions.
Comments
Although a number of initiatives have been taken in research on
stock market behaviour in Pakistan, it appears that economists in
Pakistan still consider this area of research outside their domain. In
today's global financial market the role of stock markets in the
economy, both in the short run and long run, cannot be understated.
Perhaps the day-to-day fluctuations in stock prices that do not coincide
with current economic conditions leave an impression that stock markets
do not really serve as the so-called 'barometer' of the state
of economy. Another reason could be that despite a remarkable growth in
its size and sensitivity, the stock market in Pakistan still remains
small and ups and downs in the market do not always serve as important
signals for what lies ahead for the economy. But if the past trends and
the current global financial market conditions have any relevance to
future, one can predict with a high level of confidence that the stock
market's sole in Pakistan will rise. Research on stock market, in
particular the one that links finance with economics is important not
only to understand the complex nature of the subject but also to lay
foundations for future work.
The paper by Mohammad Nishat is a useful contribution to the
subject and it can serve as a foundation work for future research. The
study estimates the effects of changes in weekly volatility on the
average weekly returns for the overall Karachi Stock market and its 12
industrial sectors. This relationship is then analysed in the light of
leverage position of each industry, defined as the ratio of equity to
fixed liabilities. The main finding of the study is that weekly returns
are inversely related to weekly changes in volatility and the
relationship is stronger in the high-leverage industries. The analysis
is repeated for various sub-periods from January 1980 to December 1994
and it is found that the relationship holds for each sub-period. Thus
the study provides reasonably strong and consistent evidence to conclude
that leverage effect is present in Karachi Stock Exchange.
Leverage effect is a well-tested proposition in developed markets,
in an emerging market like Pakistan thin trading and rent-seeking
speculations can distort the leverage effect. It is indeed a revelation
that the evidence on the presence of leverage effect is so strong and
consistent. The author can take this result as a stepping stone to
further analyse the implications of leverage effect. If the required
data are available the analysis can be repeated at firm level, because
the leverage effect estimated at the aggregate industry level is likely
to have suppressed some useful information. Furthermore, the author can
analyse the consequences of leverage effect for asymmetry in the
risk-return relationship. This analysis is quite useful to understand
the dynamics of the markets, especially in the presence of negative
return shocks that are no common in case of Pakistan.
The author has done a remarkable job in compiling all the detailed
data required for the analysis. It is quit well known that stock market
data are not entirely available in ready-to-use form and it needs a
great deal of persistent hard work and dedication to complete the task.
The author also deserves appreciation for professional approach. In
spite of huge data work, the presentation of the research is precise and
to the point. The paper is well organised and there is no indication of
contamination of results by preconception.
There are a few typing errors, misplaced footnotes at the tables of
results and missing pieces of information, such as the computation of
volatility. It is expected that the author will revise his presentation
for the final submission.
Eatzaz Ahmad
Quaid-i-Azam University, Islamabad.
Mohammad Nishat is Professor at the Institute of Business
Administration, Karachi, and at the Applied Economics Research Centre,
University of Karachi.
Table 1
Extent of Leverage for Selected Industries Listed with Karachi
Stock E.echange
This table provides the extent of leverage for the selected industries
during the overall and sub-periods of non-reform and reform. Leverage
is defined as a ratio of total shareholder's equity to total fixed
liabilities (book value). The data used to calculate the leverage is
provided in Balance Sheet Analysis of State Bank of Pakistan on annual
basis.
Non- Non
reform reform Reform
Overall Sub-period Sub-period Period
period Jan Jan 1980 II.July July 1988
1980 to to June 1985 to to Dec
Industry 12/01/1994 1985 June 1988 1994
Cotton 1.295 ** 1.547 1.837 1.044
Chemical 0.436 0.470 0.238 0.467
Engineering 0.583 * 0.408 0.570 0.748
Sugar and All 0.532 * 0.349 0.408 0.736
Paper and Paper Board 2.025 ** 2.877 1.603 1.549
Cement 0.748 0.849 0.568 0.739
Fuel and Energy 1.073 1.093 0.995 1.084
Transport and Commun. 1.337 * 1.649 1.500 1.038
Tobacco 0.270 0.309 0.215 0.254
Jute (a) 0.460 * 0.358 0.534 0.539
Vanaspati and Allied -0.068 0.081 0.076 -0.238
Misc. 0.530 0.477 0.704 0.532
Overall 0.809 0.924 0.854 0.733
Reform Reform
Sub-period Sub-period
I July II July
1988 to 1991 to
Industry June 1991 12/01/1994
Cotton 1.099 0.987
Chemical 0.278 0.639
Engineering 0784 0.763
Sugar and All 0.576 0.875
Paper and Paper Board 2.191 0.741
Cement 0.675 0.818
Fuel and Energy 1.067 1.137
Transport and Commun. 1.033 0.945
Tobacco 0.204 0.328
Jute (a) 0.572 0.492
Vanaspati and Allied 0.300 -0.472
Misc. 0.612 0.455
Overall 0.806 0.669
(a) Indicates difference in the extent of leverage during no-reform and
reform period.
(b) Indicates diference in the extent of leverage during non-reform and
the second sub-period of reforms.
* Significant at 0.05 level.**Significant at 0.10 level.
Table 2
The Leverage Effect for the overall period (January /980 to December
1994). Model estimated: [??];t =[alpha.sub.o] + [beta][DELTA]
([delta.sub.it],) + [mu].sub.it], where [??].sub.it is the return on
industry in time period t, [DELTA]([ohm.sub.it]) is the change in
volatility of return on industry in time period t
Industry [alpha] t([alpha]) ([btea]) t([beta])
Cotton 0.536 5.777 -0.035 -6.535
Chemical 0.356 2.571 -0.029 -3.537
Engineering 0.554 2.453 -0.026 -12.221
Sugar and All. 0.415 3.134 -0.054 -10.901
Paper and Paper Board 0.501 2.325 -0.015 -9.853
Cement 0.419 1.721 -0.016 -8.809
Fuel and Energy 0.304 2.459 -0.046 -6.485
Transport and Commun. 0.384 1.856 -0.029 -8.613
Tobacco 0.243 1.339 -0.034 -7.222
Jute 0.314 2.251 -0.049 -6.832
Vanaspati and Allied 0.534 2.451 0.000 0.418
Misc. 0.262 1.754 -0.018 -15.101
Industry [??]2 s.e.
Cotton 0.133 1.741
Chemical 0.043 2.323
Engineering 0.349 3.779
Sugar and All. 0.268 2.215
Paper and Paper Board 0.259 3.606
Cement 0.218 4.085
Fuel and Energy 0.131 2.074
Transport and Commun. 0.211 3.465
Tobacco 0.158 3.048
Jute 0.143 2.336
Vanaspati and Allied 0.001 3.649
Misc. 0.451 2.503
Table 3
The Leverage Effect.for tlae non-reform sub-period I (January 1980 to
Jume 1985). Model estimated:[??.sub.it] = [alpha.sub.o] + [beta][DELTA]
[delta.sub.it]) + [mu.sub.it], where [??.sub.it] is the return on
industry in time period t, [DELTA]([sigma.sub.it],) is the change in
volatility of return on indarshy in time period t
Industry [alpha] t([alpha]) [beta] t([beta])
Cotton 0.241 2.308 -0.053 -6.535
Chemical 0.356 2.571 -0.029 -3.537
Engineering 0.554 2.453 -0.026 -12.221
Sugar and All 0.415 3.134 -0.054 -10.901
Paper and Paper Board 0.501 2.325 -0.015 -9.853
Cement 0.419 1.721 -0.016 -8.809
Fuel and Energy 0.304 2.459 -0.046 -6.485
Transport and Commun. 0.384 1.856 -0.029 -8.613
Tobacco 0.243 1.339 -0.034 -7.222
Jute 0.314 2.251 -0.049 -6.832
Vanaspati and Allied 0.534 2.451 0.000 0.418
Misc. 0.262 1.754 -0.018 -15.101
Industry [??]2 s.e.
Cotton 0.133 1.741
Chemical 0.043 2.323
Engineering 0.349 3.779
Sugar and All 0.268 2.215
Paper and Paper Board 0.259 3.606
Cement 0.218 4.085
Fuel and Energy 0.131 2.074
Transport and Commun. 0.211 3.465
Tobacco 0.158 3.048
Jute 0.143 2.336
Vanaspati and Allied 0.001 3.649
Misc. 0.451 2.503
Table 4
The Leverage Effect for the non-reform sub-period 11 (July 1985 to
June 1988). Model estimated.[??.sub.it] = [alpha.sub.o] + ([beta][DELTA]
([delta.sub.it] [DELTA][sigma.sub.it] , where + [mu.sub.it] is the
return on industry in time period t, [DELTA](sigma.sub.it] is the
change in volatility of return on industry in time period t
Industry [alpha] t([alpha]) [beta] t([beta])
Cotton 1.069 4.446 -0.027 -5.189
Chemical 0.466 2.753 -0.045 -6.281
Engineering 0.465 1.692 -0.014 -7.521
Sugar and All 0.574 3.164 -0.027 -14.421
Paper and Paper Board 0.234 0.976 -0.031 -4.249
Cement 0.668 3.023 -0.044 -6.902
Fuel and Energy 0.409 2.522 -0.062 -4.235
Transport and Commun. 0.656 1.093 -0.006 -2.112
Tobacco 0.267 0.955 -0.023 -4.981
Jute 0.201 0.968 -0.027 -6.257
Vanaspati and Allied 0.321 1.178 0.001 0.334
Misc. 0.443 1.888 -0.028 -7.114
Industry [??]2 s.e.
Cotton 0.149 2.995
Chemical 0.205 2.108
Engineering 0.269 3.426
Sugar and All 0.576 2.259
Paper and Paper Board 0.106 2.987
Cement 0.237 2.754
Fuel and Energy 0.105 2.021
Transport and Commun. 0.028 7.477
Tobacco 0.139 3.491
Jute 0.203 2.584
Vanaspati and Allied 0.001 3.397
Misc. 0.248 2.922
Table 5
The Leverage Effect for the reform period (July 1988 to December 1994).
Model estimated: [??.sub.it] = [alpha.sub.o] + ([beta][DELTA]
([delta.sub.it]) + [mu.sub.it], where [??.sub.it]is the retarrn on
industry in time period t,[DELTA] [sigma.sub.it] is the change in
volatility of retcrrn on industry in time period t.
Industry [alpha] t[alpha]) [beta] t([beta])
Cotton 0.535 3.396 -0.045 -7.509
Chemical 0.629 3.298 -0.022 -5.637
Engineering 0.669 3.009 -0.012 -10.311
Sugar and All 0.251 2.066 -0.046 -8.553
Paper and Paper Board 0.532 2.937 -0.036 -15.121
Cement 0.812 3.811 -0.021 -8.945
Fuel and Energy 0.792 3.882 -0.022 -12.021
Transport and Commun. 0.586 1.572 -0.012 -9.042
Tobacco 0.545 2.196 -0.019 -13.231
Jute 0.009 0.047 -0.021 -10.181
Vanaspati and Allied 0.435 2.339 0.000 0.171
Misc. 0.717 4.646 -0.042 -8.135
Industry [??]2 s.e.
Cotton 0.147 2.857
Chemical 0.089 3.454
Engineering 0.246 4.032
Sugar and All 0.183 2.198
Paper and Paper Board 0.412 3.282
Cement 0.197 3.861
Fuel and Energy 0.307 3.699
Transport and Commun. 0.201 6.761
Tobacco 0.349 4.494
Jute 0.241 3.472
Vanaspati and Allied 0.009 3.367
Misc. 0.179 2.796
Table 6
The Leverage Effect for the reform stab-period l (July 1988 to June
1991). Model estimated: [??.sub.it] = [alpha.sub.o]+[beta][DELTA]
[delta.sub.it])+[mu.sub.it] , where [??.sub.it] is the return on
industry in time period t, [DELTA]([sigma.sub.it]] is the change in
volatility of return on industry in time period t.
Industry [alpha] t([alpha]) [beta] t([beta])
Cotton 0.454 2.781 -0.067 -5.468
Chemical 0.535 2.842 -0.071 -6.435
Engineering 0.448 2.136 -0.054 -6.551
Sugar and All 0.277 1.711 -0.053 -5.695
Paper and Paper Board 0.279 1.419 -0.041 -17.951
Cement 0.154 0.648 0.009 1.547
Fuel and Energy 0.506 3.025 -0.081 -11.051
Transport and Commun. 0.006 0.321 -0.025 -2.721
Tobacco 0.339 1.059 -0.018 -4.848
Jute 0.125 1.568 -0.047 -10.421
Vanaspati and Allied 0.434 2.159 0.000 -0.281
Misc. 0.418 2.829 -0.094 -8.651
Industry [??]2 s.e.
Cotton 0.166 2.014
Chemical 0.216 2.323
Engineering 0.222 2.589
Sugar and All 0.178 1.996
Paper and Paper Board 0.682 2.427
Cement 0.015 2.929
Fuel and Energy 0.448 2.058
Transport and Commun. 0.047 3.949
Tobacco 0.135 3.952
Jute 0.419 2.717
Vanaspati and Allied 0.000 2.482
Misc. 0.333 1.822
Table 7
The Leverage Effect for the reform sub period II (July 1988 to December
1994). Model estimated: [??.sub.it] = [alpha.sub.o] + [beta][DELTA]
([sigma.sub.it]) + [mu.sub.it] where [??.sub.it], is the return on
industry in. time period [DELTA], (sigma.sub.it]is the change in
volatility of return on industry in time period t
Industry [alpha] t([alpha]) [beta] t([beta])
Cotton 0.605 2.351 -0.043 -5.564
Chemical 0.708 2.264 -0.018 -3.719
Engineering 0.856 2.321 -0.012 -8.051
Sugar and All 0.227 1.283 -0.047 -6.537
Paper and Paper Board 0.748 2.552 -0.028 -5.965
Cement 1.378 4.311 -0.026 -9.086
Fuel and Energy 0.937 2.753 -0.021 -9.188
Transport and Commun. 1.079 1.679 -0.012 -6.846
Tobacco 0.722 1.944 -0.021 -11.421
Jute -0.158 -0.553 -0.016 -7.089
Vanaspati and Allied 0.435 1.449 0.001 0.798
Misc. 0.976 3.843 -0.034 -5.611
Industry [??]2 s.e.
Cotton 0.151 3.414
Chemical 0.073 4.149
Engineering 0.271 4.894
Sugar and All 0.197 2.354
Paper and Paper Board 0.169 3.891
Cement 0.322 4.243
Fuel and Energy 0.326 4.519
Transport and Commun. 0.212 8.535
Tobacco 0.428 4.931
Jute 0.224 3.811
Vanaspati and Allied 0.004 3.984
Misc. 0.153 3.369