Importance of a population policy in Pakistan.
Siddiqui, Fakhari A.
INTRODUCTION
This paper is a modest attempt at understanding the importance of
population growth and its relationship to economic development in
Pakistan. A summary of the recent approaches to economic development is
provided at the outset. Population growth is discussed with a view to
understanding the economic and socio-cultural determinants of fertility
behaviour. This is based on the experience of other developing
countries. The issues of unwanted fertility, demand for large family
size and population momentum are discussed in the context of
Pakistan's past population growth and the potential demographic
changes in the future.
The basic message here is a simple one: Pakistan's experience
with population issues and economic development has been a case of many
missed opportunities and its deteriorating economic performance in the
1990s poses serious impediments for the future outlook and a daunting challenge to the leadership. It is argued that an integrated population
policy is critical in its own right but is also essential for maximising
the positive outcome of whatever development efforts are contemplated.
This is work in progress. It is presented here to stimulate further
discussion and debate.
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
"In the midst of this age of plenty, the standard of living
for much of the world is declining, their poverty and economic
backwardness are increasing, and their share of the world's
population is growing. In the world community of nations, the rich are
getting richer while the poor are getting poorer... First among causes
is the rapid, over whelming and utterly unprecedented world population
explosion".
The above statement was made by John F. Kennedy in 1958 when he was
a junior senator [Facing the Future (1908), p. 1]. At that time, world
population was less than 3 billion, the income gap between rich and poor
nations was about 30 to l. Now the population has doubled and so has
this gap moved to 60 to 1. More than 40 years later, the following quote
sums up the current situation [Earth Summit (2002), p. 6].
"Despite decades of developrnent efforts, both the gap between
rich and poor nations and the inequalities within nations have widened.
Serious econotnic, social, gender and other inequities persist and
hamper eftbrts to improve the quality of life for hundreds of millions
of people. The number of people living in poverty stands at
approximately 1 billion and continues to mount".
The early post World War II view of development primarily in terms
of economic growth and increase in per capita income was gradually
replaced over the last few decades with a broader view of development.
This view in its simplest form places greater emphasis on the reduction
or elimination of poverty, inequality, and unemployment within the
context of a growing economy. Dudley Seers saw the meaning of
development as [Seers (1969), p. 3]:
"The questions to ask about a country's development are
therefore: What has been happening to poverty? What has been happening
to unemployment? What has been happening to inequality? If all three
have declined from high levels, then beyond doubt this has been a period
of development for the country concerned. If one or two of these central
problems have been growing worse, especially if all three have, it would
be strange to call the result 'development' even if per capita
income doubled".
The experience of many developing countries in the 1960s and 1970s,
including Pakistan, proved Seers correct. High growth rates and rising
per capita income did not show much improvement in other measures. In
some cases there was an actual decline in employment, equality and the
real incomes of the lower 40 percent of the population.
In the 1990s the momentum towards this broader view continued and
was also recognised by the World Bank whose policies in 1980s were
clearly focused on economic growth as the goal of development. This new
found broader perspective of the World Bank is illustrated in their
statement in 1991 World Development Report (p. 4).
"The Challenge of development ... is to improve the quality of
life. Especially in the world's poor countries, a better quality of
life generally calls for higher incomes--but it involves much more. It
encompasses as ends in themselves better education, higher standards of
health and nutrition, less poverty, a cleaner environment, more equality
of opportunity, greater individual freedom, and a richer cultural
life".
In these terms economic growth is a necessary condition for
development but not sufficient unless one incorporates the human
development factors. It is argued that improvements in education, for
example, would also contribute towards growth through increase in human
capital [Klasen (1999) and Jones (1999)].
Pakistan's experience with economic growth and almost all
development indicators, particularly over the last fifteen years, has
been disappointing. From the 1960s to 1985, Pakistan experienced
respectable economic growth rates averaging above 6 percent with a
reduction in poverty. Since the early 1990s, the growth rate declined to
less than 4 percent and population growth continued at a rate of over
2.5 percent, resulting in a per capita income increase of just over 1
percent. The positive and high economic growth of the 1960s, 1970s and
early 1980s was driven primarily by external factors of aid, remittances and green revolution technology without due attention paid to reforming
the domestic climate for growth. As the inward inflow of aid and
remittances began to dry up since the late 1980s along with the
maturation of the green revolution, growth also declined [Stern (2001)].
Failure to undertake the necessary reform in the socio-economic and
political arena led not only to slowing economic growth, but aggravated the human development indicators such as poverty, literacy rate, school
enrollment, and gender equality, as well as continued high fertility.
The lesson from this experience is that economic growth is not
sustainable without due regard to education, gender equality, poverty
reduction, good governance and other social development indicators.
These factors are important in and of themselves for economic
development but they are equally important for a positive investment
climate which drives economic growth. A comparison of Pakistan and India
during the 1990s provides a good example.
In the 1980s Pakistan's growth rate was higher than
India's. Since the 1990s India's growth rate has been almost
twice (6 percent) that of Pakistan (3.7 percent).
"What made India's rapid growth possible was a reform
programme that increased openness and competitiveness while improving
major elements of its investment climate. India also took steps to
increase the inclusiveness of growth, by expanding education, including
education of girls. As a result, India's literacy rate has risen
over the past decade, with significant increase in the female literacy
rate ... and yet Pakistan has failed to take similar steps to overcome
those problems". [Stem (2001)].
Unlike the policies of the past, explicit integration of
populations into economic and development policies is a necessary
prerequisite for development and poverty alleviation. These further
reinforce achievement of population objectives as well as the improved
quality of life of the population.
POPULATION GROWTH
The debate on population growth is not new. It was the Malthusian
population trap that gave economics its name as a "dismal
science". Malthus' dismal outlook for the future of mankind
was based on the basic principle of diminishing returns when one
considers the land-labour ratios where increasing population to fixed
land would eventually result in a chronic low level standard of living.
His contention was that the only way to avoid such a fate was to
practice "moral restraint" thereby limiting the number of
births. Some might, therefore, consider Malthus as the father of the
birth control movement.
The Malthusian population trap model is a simple and crude theory
of the relationship between economic progress and population growth. As
a theory it is subject to serious criticism on analytic and empirical
grounds. Analytically, its failure to account for technical change over
time and the assumption of the relationship of increased population
growth and national income are unacceptable given the long run
historical experience of advanced economies and in light of the more
recent cases of many developing countries.
The evidence on the relationship between the fertility rate and per
capita income in aggregate in developing countries is not supportive of
this model. Fertility rates varied between 2.5 and over 7.0 with an
average per capita income of under $1000. This demonstrates that per
capita income fails to explain variations in population growth.
Household income, or the distribution of income may be better predictors
of population growth [Todaro (2001)]. See Fig.1.
A microeconomic approach by economists uses the application of
standard consumer behaviour models (utility maximisation) by explicitly
recognising desired number of children as a rational economic response
relative to other goods. Such utility maximising economic models of
fertility explain fertility behaviour in advanced economies and with
some modifications can provide a good guide for developing countries
too. The issue can be simplified by asking whether the people in the
developing countries respond to changes in price or cost of children in
the same manner as in advanced countries. For example, when these costs
rise (opportunity costs) as a result of increased educational and
employment opportunities for women or rise in school fees etc., and if
parents respond by reducing their desire for more children, then one
would accept such a model. Empirical evidence, though not conclusive,
from a number of international studies support the basic premise of such
models. The works of Schultz (1974); Birdsall (1988) and Dasgupta (1995)
among others, are some of the examples of such an approach providing
empirical evidence. Lant Pritchett (1994) offers strong empirical
evidence that low fertility is determined mostly by economic, social,
cultural, and educational improvements in a population and less so from
the availability of family planning programmes.
[FIGURE 1 OMITTED]
The above is a brief account of the possible explanations or
determinants of population growth. Like anything else in development
economics, the relative importance of each of these many factors may
vary from country to country. Nevertheless it offers a good guide for a
country specific analysis and some implications for development and
fertility. A simple implication is that family planning programmes
(supply side) would be effective only when the population at large has
the desire or motivation (demand side) for smaller families. This
demand-side is determined by a host of economic, social, cultural,
educational and other factors. It is important to note that many of
these factors are not only important in understanding fertility
behaviour (population growth) but are equally significant determinants
of economic development. Thus the linkage between population growth and
development.
The existence of this linkage is generally accepted, but the
precise nature or causal direction between the two is a subject of
continuing debate. The questions such as, 'Does population growth
cause poverty?' or 'Does poverty cause population
growth?' must be addressed in formulating effective population
policy as well as development programme strategies. One aspect of this
debate involves the opposing views of the North and South particularly
when the population growth and environmental concerns are added to the
equation. An excellent survey of this debate is provided by Najam (2001)
in a recent paper. Important and interesting as some dimension of this
broader debate may be, it is beyond the scope and the main purpose of
this paper. The questions that are relevant for this paper, deal with
the impact and importance of population growth to economic development
in Pakistan, where population growth has been and continues to pose a
serious problem along with other adverse development indicators
Population Growth in Pakistan. (See Table 4.)
The overall record of Pakistan in terms of the usual population
issues, both in absolute and relative terms, is a matter that deserves
serious attention and analysis. Since Pakistan's inception, it has
distinguished itself by a rapid rate of growth of its population. In
1950 it ranked the 13th largest country by population size but graduated
to the 7th ranked country by 1996 and according to one UN projection
will become the 3rd most populated country (after India and China) by
the middle of this century if the recent growth is maintained (Table 1).
Among the projected top ten contributors to world population growth
during 1995-2000, Pakistan stood third in absolute numbers and number
one in rate of growth (Table 2). It is important to note that statistics
provided here, and the projections derived from these numbers indicate a
rate of growth of population in Pakistan to be 300 percent faster than
China and 170 percent faster than India. Some would argue that in light
of Pakistan's 1998 census, my numbers are over estimates.
Regardless of statistical discrepancy, the point is that whatever set of
numbers, are used, in both absolute and relative terms, Pakistan's
population growth rate is still higher than desired by any definition.
This is not to say that no progress has been made towards reducing the
growth rate. What is significant is the fact that the current population
growth rate is high (shown in Table 3), and so is the average total
fertility rate per woman of 5.2 in Pakistan compared to 2.4 in
Indonesia, 2.9 in Iran and 3.1 in India. [Population Reports (1996), p.
1]. This necessitates urgent attention for a comprehensive population
policy.
An effective policy formulation has to be based on a thorough
understanding of key determinants of population growth. Here one can
draw on the experience of other countries, as well as to see if there
are some special factors peculiar to the situation in Pakistan. Recent
empirical evidence clearly shows that it is a combination of economic,
social cultural (religious) and institutional factors which are
important determinants of desired family size. Equally important are the
related factors such as level of poverty, educational levels, gender
equality and health services which interact in a complex manner to
influence family size and population growth. [Todaro (2000).]
The idea that fertility decline must be viewed beyond the narrow
vision of family planning services and in conjunction with improvements
in social and economic development has received wide acceptance since
the 1994 ICPD at Cairo. The south Commission in its report, stressed
similar views, well before ICPD, as stated in the following quote [South
Commission (1990)]:
"While family planning measures are vitally necessary, they
are more effective as security and living standards improve. Poverty
must be eradicated, for only then will it be possible to create the
conditions in which people are more likely to see virtue in smaller
families".
Pakistan's renowned development economist, late Mahbub-ul-Haq
vigorously expressed this view that the solution to the problem of
population is to be found in the solution to the problem of poverty. In
his view,
"Population growth is a developmental issue, not a clinical
problem. No one denies today that top priority must be given to reducing
high rates of population growth in the developing world. The differences
are on strategies, not on objectives. Family planning must be regarded
as an integral part of new models of sustainable human development.
Divorced from such development models, and pursued as
condom-distribution programmes with single-minded zeal to meet
'unmet demand' they will fail ... We cannot slip a condom on
poverty." (1994.)
The implications of this broader view of population growth and
economic development are indeed far reaching. In terms of policy
formulation it is imperative to interpret this carefully and precisely.
Otherwise the temptation might be to ignore the population problem
until, for example, the poverty question is resolved. It is true that
the experience of advanced countries clearly demonstrates that economic
improvement took care of the population growth problem and now in many
western countries the problem is too low birth rates. Similarly there is
clear evidence that despite continuing poverty, India and Bangladesh
have experienced a much lower population growth rate than Pakistan.
It is, therefore, a question of an appropriate population policy
that would also help simultaneously economic development objectives.
This requires a closer look at the demographic dynamics by decomposing
aggregate population growth rates.
POPULATION DYNAMICS
The overall population growth rate can be decomposed into three
components: (a) unwanted fertility (unmet need), (b) high desired family
size, and (c) population momentum. Population momentum refers to the
tendency of population to continue growing after the
replacement-level-fertility has been achieved due to a large proportion
of young persons in the population.
A recent Population Council and Overseas Development Council
Conference report provides an excellent source of material on this
issue. In addressing global population growth, they report that,
"Disaggregated projections of global population growth show
that population momentum alone will account for an increase in less
developed countries from 4.5 billion (1995 level) to 7.3 billion, by the
year 2100; high desired fertility will raise the total an additional one
billion to 8.3 billion; and unwanted fertility will increase it to 10.2
billion. By the year 2040, virtually all of the global population growth
could be due to momentum alone." [Population Council (1998), p. 3]
Such a disaggregation exercise is important for better
understanding of population growth issues. To the degree that the
composition of population growth can vary substantially across countries
and overtime for a given country, specific evaluation of different
components is of vital importance. For example, in India, the
Philippines, and Kenya the population momentum alone will account for 61
percent, 66 percent and 68 percent of the future growth respectively. In
the case of Sub-Sahara Africa, this factor's contribution to the
future growth is less than 50 percent and the most significant factor
remains high desired family size. Thus a given policy for India will not
be appropriate for Sub-Sahara Africa. One must therefore avoid
"one-size fits all" approaches in dealing with population
growth issues.
The following discussion examines each of the three components with
respect to their relative importance and some suggested policy responses
for Pakistan.
Unwanted Fertility
A measure of unwanted fertility is an important dimension of
population growth in many developing countries. It is a good indicator
of the gap between desired family size and the actual size. The size of
the gap equals unmet need and is determined by a host of socio-economic
factors and is usually estimated through surveys of women of
childbearing age. For example, in Population Report (1996), the total
for the developing countries was estimated to be 100 million women who
had unmet needs. According to this source, the unmet need for Pakistan
was 5.7 million, 31 million for India, 4.4 million for Bangladesh and
Indonesia and 3.9 for Nigeria [Population Reports (1996), p. 1]:
If 5.7 million women had an unmet need for contraception in the
1990s, and assuming this number has been reduced considerably since
then, to say 4 million, it is still a very significant indicator for the
potential to reduce this component of fertility. Even if 50 percent of
this group ends up with one unwanted child born it would add 2 million
more to the population.
An appropriate policy response to deal with this problem must be
based on the reasons for not using contraception, despite expressed
desire. Table 5, lists the relative importance of some of the factors.
It is worth noting that neither availability nor expense were prominent
reasons. Husband's preferences, religious reasons and lack of
knowledge were the main motives. In light of this, it is obvious that
the simple supply side response (i.e. family planning services) would
prove ineffective in absence of increased education and improvement in
other development indicators.
This task is neither easy nor simple as ultimately it would require
reducing the impact of all such forces which in their totality act as a
wall of resistance toward adopting reproductive behaviour conducive to
lowering fertility. For lack of a better term, we can denote all these
forces taken together as the knowledge factor which may be conceived as
an index. (1) These three factors: husband's preferences, religious
reasons, and lack of contraception knowledge can be measured in terms of
this index. In these terms, education defined in broad terms, is the
answer as it would raise the numerical value of this index. The impact
of religion and the role of religious leaders are discussed in the next
section.
High Desired Family Size
High desired family size still remains an important component of
the population growth in Pakistan. It too is determined by
socio-economic factors. Conceptually, and based on the historic
experience of advanced countries, this can be completely eliminated over
time. Developing Islamic countries, like Bangladesh, Iran and Indonesia
have successfully reduced their total fertility rates to 3.l, 2.8 and
2.6 respectively, compared to Pakistan where it is still about 5. How
can this be explained? In addition to the generally accepted
socio-economic determinants of high fertility, it can be argued that in
the case of Pakistan the high desired family size might be explained in
terms of lack of effective action to enhance the knowledge factor.
The knowledge factor in Pakistan manifests itself as a result of
the complex interacting forces of strong conservative traditions, the
role of woman, the level of poverty, the level of education and the
perceived notions of religious dictates regarding reproductive
behaviour. The relative sustained strength of these factors in Pakistan,
in contrast to say Iran, is partly a reflection of a failure of
effective population policy due to the lack of strong commitment on the
part of (i) political leadership, (ii) religious leadership, (iii)
intellectual leadership, and (iv) neglect of women's education.
These four factors alone stand out in Iranian experience as instruments
of significant fertility reduction and offer a good example for Pakistan
to follow [Aghajanian (1995)].
In the western media, Iran has been viewed as an Islamic extremist
state where the government itself is dominated by religious leaders. It
offers an excellent example of the power of state in both increasing and
reducing fertility. After the 1979 revolution, Iran's rulers urged
Iranians to produce more children and they lowered the legal age of
marriage to nine. The response was an unprecedented natural increase in
population growth of 3.9 percent, the highest ever recorded. Then in
1989, there was a complete turn around and new population stabilisation
efforts and promotion of reproductive health received top priority with
the blessings of the religious leaders. The policies were so successful
that population growth rates declined to 1.4 percent and Iran was the
proud recipient of the UN Population Award in 1999.
Aghajanian and Mehryar (1999) provide an interesting and useful
analysis of the fertility transition experience of Iran. The statistics
in Table 6 are indicative of an impressive decline in the population
growth rate, total fertility rate and age at marriage. The positive
improvements were particularity significant in the 1990s when the
population stabilisation policies were actively pursued with full
support of religious leadership and a strong and sustained commitment of
government leaders. Additional factors which were also significant
include expansion of the network of rural health workers (behvars),
dramatic increase in school enrollment of the female population (from
54.7 percent to 83.2 percent for 10-14 age from 1976 to 1995), and
substantial progress in the female literacy rate (by 1996, over 80
percent of woman age 15-29 were literate).
The Iranian experience of unprecedented decline in total fertility
from 8.4 children to 4.6 children per woman (a 45 percent decline)
during a period of only 10 years is explained by two group of factors
[Aghajanian and Mehryar (1999), p. 12]
"One group includes all the changes which led to the
socio-structural precursors for fertility decline and motivation for a
smaller family size. The other group of factors include direct policy
changes by the government regarding population and birth control during
this period".
The first group of these factors were mainly reduced infant
mortality (through a better network of health workers), increased female
enrollment in schools with the accompanying prevalence of working
outside the home and economic factors such as the increased costs of
raising children and increased costs of marriage (which led to a higher
age of marriage). The importance of the governmental and the religious
leadership role is best summed up by the authors (p. 11).
"It is clear that family planning within a sound reproductive
health policy can be acceptable and supported and encouraged by
religious and political leaders in a Muslim country ... Once the
educated technocrats described the issue of rapid population growth and
the problems faced by the government, the religious leaders gave their
complete support. In any Muslim country, interaction between religious
leaders and government technocrats must be considered a vital part of
programme implementation. Such interaction brings about political
expressions by the clergy and religious politicians and creates an
environment of acceptability among the common people with respect to the
issues of birth control and family size limitations. Such a supportive
environment makes the idea of smaller family size legitimate and
acceptable for couples of all classes and all areas".
Population Momentum
This component of population growth is very significant for
Pakistan as it has a very large (over 40 percent) proportion of its
population under age 15. Even if the country achieves a fertility rate
equaling replacement level, the population will continue to grow because
of the large size of these young age cohorts. A look at the population
pyramid, shown in Figure 2, clearly illustrates the scope and magnitude
of this component for potential population growth. Since the size of
this group is known, simple extrapolation into the future, holding the
current socio-economic determinants constant, provides a scary scenario
of population growth. By the same token, it points to the urgency to
devise an appropriate set of population and development policies to
minimise this potential growth.
[FIGURE 2 OMITTED]
Addressing the population momentum problem may require delaying the
age at marriage and childbearing and promoting birth spacing through
expanding education and improving women's socio-economic
opportunities. Here again, Iran's example is a good model. Delay in
age at marriage is a powerful instrument. For example, in the case of
Bangladesh it is estimated that by year 2100 its population will be 253
million. Momentum alone will produce a population of 244 million, but
his number will be 223 million and 206 million if the median age of
marriage is delayed by 2.5 year and 5 years respectively [Population
Council (1998), p. 5].
The age at marriage in Pakistan is considerably lower in comparison
to other countries with similar socio-economic indicators. In a recent
study [Mahmood (2001)], it is shown that (i) the median age at marriage
is 18.3, (ii) education of women is the only factor contributing to an
increase in age at marriage (age at marriage with secondary education is
22 years vs. 17.7 with no education) and (iii) the socioeconomic norm of
marrying early is still strong and prevalent in Pakistan. Commenting on
teenage mothers the authors state, "A substantial proportion of
women get married during adolescence (13-20 years) and are under social
pressure to produce an offspring"... over 10 percent of the
teenaged females have begun childbearing (p. 7).
This rather high incidence of marriage at a younger age, combined
with the reality that 12.9 million females are aged 15-49 (46 percent of
the total 28 million females), creates a need for serious attention to
the population momentum problem.
POPULATION POLICY FRAMEWORK
Despite the onset of demographic transition since the late 1990s,
Pakistan still faces serious population problems, as the previous
discussion has outlined. The adverse consequences of population effects
on other development efforts (i.e. poverty, education, gender
inequality, health and nutrition standards etc.) are obvious. Equally
obvious is, therefore, the need for an effective population policy. It
is suggested here that such a policy must be assigned a top priority in
the overall development plans of the country. The point that a rapidly
growing population is both a challenge and a constraint to development
prospects in Pakistan was addressed in an earlier paper and a plea was
made for action on the policy front [Siddiqui (1998)].
Based on the policy experiences of other developing countries and
the recent demographic realities in Pakistan, an effective population
policy must address the following three objectives:
1. Reduction in the rate and incidence of unwanted fertility.
2. Reduction in demand for large size families.
3. Greater investment in adolescents.
The issue of unwanted fertility and low level usage of
contraception in Pakistan is well known and documented [Bongaart Bruce
(1995); Casterline, et al. (2001); Mahmood (1992, 1996); Hashmi, et al.
(1993); Robey, et al. (1996)]. These studies provide evidence of a
considerable gap between stated fertility preference and reported
contraception behaviour. The size of the gap indicates latent demand for
contraception use. The larger the gap (unmet need) the greater is the
potential positive benefits from programme improvements for any given
set of socio-cultural determinants. The real increase in contraceptive use would require changes in the socio-cultural determinants. For
example, women with expressed desire for fewer children might be
prevented to achieve this desire due to husbands' preferences,
religious reasons, lack of knowledge, or health reasons rather than
access to family planning services. Thus, policy and programme
initiatives, which reduce these barriers to contraceptive use are vital.
In other words the specific objective of increased contraceptive usage
requires increasing the knowledge factor. To increase the knowledge
factor requires broader policy approaches dealing with formal education
as well as advocacy.
The second goal, of reducing demand for high family size is still
very important in the Pakistani context. If the goal is two surviving
children, policy options would require creation of conditions for small
families. The population policy component may deal with advocacy issues,
but the greatest long term success will be the result of better
education, improving the status of women and general economic
improvement of the poor. Here again, the importance of the knowledge
factor is obvious, particularly when we consider the population growth,
economic growth and human development linkages. [Ranis, et al. (2000)].
The third goal of investment in adolescents is an essential
component of any policy formulation considering the impact of population
momentum problem faced by Pakistan with over 40 percent of its current
population being so young. Not only does this group impose tremendous
dependency costs today, but failure to invest in their education or
knowledge factor would make the problem worse in the future.
Consequences of a successful policy would result in: (i) delay in age at
marriage, (ii) reduction in size of family, and (iii) increased
contraception usage.
Despite the existence of a family planning programme since 1965,
Pakistan has never really had an effective population policy. As a
result, this small country now has a population of over 140 million of
whom over 40 million live in utter poverty. Even under the most
optimistic future population growth scenario it will end up with a
population of over 213 million by year 2025 (assuming a growth rate of
1.5 percent during 2010-2020 and only 1 percent from 2020 onwards).
A meaningful policy starts with a sound concept and is based on
recognition of the problem. Most importantly, its success demands strong
leadership, commitment and courage, widespread support and adequate
resources. Experience of countries like Iran, India, Egypt and Kenya
indicate that political commitment resulted after a prolonged period of
national debate. A national debate has yet to occur in Pakistan, which
would provide the necessary strength to the leadership at all levels and
would also be an important source of information to the people. Only
through strong political commitment, strategies necessary for widespread
support become feasible and the adequate flow of resource availability
is ensured.
Solid commitment by the leadership involves their thorough (i)
understanding of the rationale for reducing population growth, and (ii)
the legitimacy of the programmes used to reduce fertility. The
contentious nature of the second issue may, at least, partially explain
the lack of leadership as it arises from the particular socioeconomic
and religious factors in Pakistan (i.e. low level of knowledge factor
index).
The value of the knowledge factor index will rise over time through
improvements in education, particularly female education. But, in the
short run, a good population policy can be a catalyst in its direct
effect on increasing this index when religious leadership is part of the
commitment. The role of religious leadership must be reevaluated so that
instead of being a problem in reproductive behaviour it is an important
part of the solution. The experience of Iran provides ample evidence of
the importance of this issue and serves as a model for Pakistan. A
well-conceived and implemented strategy of education and communication
(IEC) must have religious leadership as a full and active partner to
achieve the desired results in altering reproductive behaviour. The role
and status of women and husbands' preferences are two important
determinants of contraceptive usages. Both are subject to religious
beliefs. The positive attitude of religious leadership can and must play
a significant role in this regard.
The development agenda of Pakistan, according to the Planning
Commission includes a ten point programme of poverty elimination. By
year 2025, it aims to eliminate poverty, increase per capita income from
Rs 24000 to Rs 69,000, male and female adult literacy rate of 100
percent, and to provide clean water, air and universal health care for
all its citizens. It also mentions population growth rate of 1 percent
by year 2025. Of course many of these goals would positively impact
fertility reduction. As a policy statement there is not even a mention
of the need or role of population policy. Even under the most optimistic
scenario, attainment of these goals would be problematic. Without an
explicit and effective population policy, success on other fronts would
indeed be extremely difficult.
In conclusion, Pakistan still has a population problem that it must
deal with by a comprehensive and effective population programme. Failure
to do this would magnify the current problems which are a result of
previous policy neglect. Some modest decline of recent fertility rates
should not lull the leadership into complacency because the underlying
population momentum continues to pose a real and significant problem.
REFERENCES
Aghajanian, Akbar (1995) A New Direction is Population Policy and
Family Planning in the Islamic Republic of Iran. Asia Pacific Population
Journal 10:1, 3-20. March.
Aghajanian, and Mehryar Amir (1999) Fertility Transition in the
Islamic Republic of Iran: 1976-1996. Asia Pacific Population Journal
14:1, 21-12.
Asian Development Bank (2001) Country Strategy and Programme Update
(2002-2004). Pakistan, July.
Birdsoll, Nancy (1988) Economic Approaches to Population Growth. In
Hollis B. Chenery and T. N. Shinwasah (eds.) Handbook of Development
Economics Vol. 1. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Casterline J.. Sathar, Z.. and Hague H. (2001) Obstacles to
Contraceptive Use in Pakistan: A Study in Punjab. Population Council.
Population Council Web Site. (Policy Research Dirlsim Working Paper No.
145.)
Chaudry, Shahid A. (2000) Pakistan's Economy: Potential and
Challenges. The Pakistan Development Review 39:4, 287-292.
Dasgupta, P. (1995) The Population Problem: Theory of Evidence.
Journal of Economic Literature 33, 1879-1902.
Facing the Future, Economic and Social Impacts of Population Growth
(1998). Website: www.l'acingthcfuture.org/econ.html
Hakim, Abdul (2000) Are Status of Women and Contraceptive
Prevalence Correlated in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 39:4,
1057-1073.
Jones, Gavin W. (1999) Population and Human Resources Development.
Asia-Pacific Population Journal 7:2, 23-49.
Klaser, Stephan (1999) Does Gender Inequality Reduce Growth and
Development? Evidence from Cross Country Regressions. (World Bank PRP Working Paper Series, No. 7.)
Mahmood, Naushin and Durr-e-Nayab (2000) An Analysis of
Reproductive Health Issues in Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review
39:4, 675-693.
Mahbub-ul-Haq (1994) We Cannot Slip A Condom on Global Poverty. The
Earth Times 1:29.
Najam, Adil (n.d.) A Developing Country Perspective on Population
and Environment, and Development. Population Research and Policy Review
15:1. Website: www.mit:edu/people/anaiam/pop2.html
Population Council (1998) What Can be Done to Foster Multisectoral
Population Policies: A Summary Report of a Seminar. Population Council.
Population Information Programme (1996) Population Report 24:1.
John Hopkins, Baltimore. Website: wwvv.Thucco.oriz/pr/i43edsum.stm.
Siddiqui, F. A. (1998) Population Growth and Development Prospects
for Pakistan. The Pakistan Development Review 37:4, 557-574.
Todaro, Michael P. (2000) Economic Development, 7th Edition. New
York: Addison Wesley.
UN Population Summit (2002) Tool Kit for Women. Website:
www.earthsummit2002.org/toolkits/woiTien/un
World Bank (2001) Engendering Development Through Gender Equality
in Rights, Resources, and Voice. Washington, D.C.: World Bank, Website.
World Bank (1991) World Development Report, 1991. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Comments
1.
Having been associated with the population field for over three
decades and having seen the heyday of the issue in the 1960s and the
1970s, and the fatigue with which the subject is being dealt with in the
1980s and 1990s, does my heart good to see the subject put in
perspective, in its relationship with human progress and development. Dr
Fakhari's paper highlights the need for strong inconsistent
population policy in the context of elastic development in the country
to get it out of debt trap the slowing economic growth and the
escalating poverty. He has succinctly examined the determinants of high
population growth and its linkages with poverty, inequality as well as
social in economic engender inequality. His comments on the fact that
increase in per capita income does not lead to a better quality of life
in the majority of the people unless other social indicators such as
health, literacy, gender inequalities and high fertility are addressed.
It takes the case of economic growth of 4 percent of Pakistan almost
negated by the 2.5 percent population growth rate in the decades of
1990s. Drawing home the point that an inexplicit integration of
population in the economic development policies is necessary for
development and poverty elevation. He comments that population problem
cannot be addressed only by the supply side of the population programme
but must be a companied by a demand generation strategies by addressing
the concerns of non-users such as perceived spousal disapproval, lack of
the adequate knowledge regarding how and where of contraceptive delivery
and perceived religious opposition. He sites success stories from
Bangladesh, Indonesia and above all Iran, where they have a strong
pronetalistic culture. The states sponsored a complete turn around
toward population stabilisation and reproductive health lowering the
growth rate from 3.92 to 1.4. Above all Imam Khomani's
'faatwa' in support of family planning followed by enrolling
the involvement of religious leaders and an element did we in Pakistan
continued to sweep under the carpet except for some very successful NGOs
initiatives. These are the examples for Pakistan to illuminate. Dr
Fakhari's demographic figures are not up to date as the rest of his
presentation presumably because he is being out of the country for so
long. He estimates TFR and PGR 5.2 and 2.7 respectively against the
latest NIPS study figures of 4.8 and 2.1. However, he is right on the
mark when he points out that there is room for addressing the population
momentum in Pakistan. Where approximately 60 percent of our population
is below 25 and likely to really rock the demographic boat in the next
20 years. Even if we succeed insignificantly lowing birth rate. Summing
up the complex nature of the factors to confront debt growth and poverty
alleviation, he stresses the need for an effective and consistent
population policy by reducing unwanted fertility through culturally
acceptable quality services reducing demand for large families by
reducing IMR, CMR and MMR. And investment in adolescent through in
attitudes formation in supports for the small family norms. The
significant points brought out in his paper is the need for the strong
and inconsistent population policy back by political commitment at the
highest level. Factors which have frequently absent from our national
agenda. A case in point being his reference to the Planning
Commission's 10 point programme of poverty elimination which does
not include the population related issues. However, it is nice to be
able to re-assure him that now at last there is an attempt to address
development in holistic manner and the President his setup a task force
for human development which focuses on basic health including
reproductive health in family planning, basic education and income
generation. Hopefully, as a result of this new inclusive development
paradigm Pakistan will be able to successfully confront the issues of
debt growth poverty and population exposure.
Begum Surryia Jabeen
President Task Force on Human Development, Islamabad.
2.
First of all, I would like to appreciate Prof. Siddiqui's
motivation to write about Pakistan's development concerns with a
particular focus on population as an issue of special significance in
the whole scenario. The debates and deliberations done on poverty,
growth and development on this forum have rarely emphasised population
growth as a frontline cause of the problem. In fact, population which
lies at the core of all planning procedures and policy formulation is
not given its due place in the national reform agenda.
Turning my attention to the contents of the paper, I could not
agree more with Prof. Siddiqui's basic stance that Pakistan's
population growth needs to be reduced to maximise its development
outcome. In this context, the paper addresses a whole spectrum of issues
pertaining to population growth, economic development, poverty and their
interlinkages. While making the argument for the importance of
population policy in Pakistan's development context, Prof. Siddiqui
himself acknowledges the fact that the two have a cause and effect
relationship and it is hard to determine whether population growth
causes poverty or vice versa. He clearly contends that while family
planning measures are necessary, poverty must be eradicated to create
the conditions in which people are more likely to see virtue in having
small families. Hence, with the limited financial resources that the
country has at hand, the choice to prioritise poverty reduction
strategies versus population growth reduction strategies remains a
policy question. On the one hand, it is argued that social and economic
conditions which constrain the use of family planning must be changed to
generate more than a marginal decline in fertility. On the other hand,
the emphasis on the provision and improvement of supplies of
contraceptives is considered important for an increased and sustained
use of family planning even with low levels of socioeconomic
development. It is not clearly spelled out in the paper which strategy
would be more rewarding to have a stronger impact on reducing population
growth and improving the quality of life of the people, because both
affect and reinforce each other.
While reading through the paper, one tends to lose track of the
argument made in the beginning that Pakistan's population growth is
the fore runner of social and economic problems, including poverty,
unemployment, low education etc. The issue becomes more challenging when
we consider that other countries with lower socioeconomic conditions and
sustained poverty such as Bangladesh, Indonesia and India have
successfully achieved high levels of contraceptive prevalence and
decline in fertility. Given this, it is crucial to determine what policy
prescriptions would be more effective in changing the fertility
behaviour of Pakistani couples. The paper's contents lack this
analysis and the case made for a strong population policy for Pakistan
remains inconclusive in this context.
Moving away from the arguments of population and development
interlinkages, the author then highlights population growth problem in
Pakistan in terms of unwanted fertility, high-unmet need, high desired
number of children and population momentum built in the age structure.
There is no dispute that all these issues merit due attention from
population policy perspective. Looking at the high unmet need in
Pakistan, the demand for family planning services does not appear to be
a problem. This demand needs to be simply matched with the supply side
factors--an efficient service delivery system. Based on the situation
analysis of these demographic issues, a case is made in the paper for an
integrated and effective population policy for Pakistan. Yet the paper
remains silent on interpreting what an effective and integrated policy
would be? What have been the successes and failures in programme
interventions and what effective approach would be more viable to have
the desired outcome?
If the thrust of the paper is on the importance of an effective
population policy, there is a need to review the policy options and then
link it with the situation at hand and the ground realities to justify
the argument made in the beginning. In this context, I would like to
mention that a paper on policy shifts and problems of their
implementation was presented in another session on demographic issues
which could provide some input for linking the population policy and
programme performance issues. However, the basic message of the paper is
clear and quite relevant for Pakistan's population policy concerns.
However, I feel that population issues and the illustration cited for
other countries need to be reorganised in a systematic way to make a
strong case for an effective population policy and programme for
Pakistan.
Naushin Mahmood
Pakistan Institute of Development Economics, Islamabad.
(1) Conceptually, such an index can be viewed as similar to the
Human Development Index.
Fakhari A. Siddiqui is Professor of Economics, Williams School of
Business and Economics, Bishop's University, Canada.
Author's note: Financial support from Bishop's University
Research Committee and SEED Foundation is gratefully acknowledged.
Table 1
The 13 Largest Countries Ranked Accounting
to Population Size *
1950
Population
Rank Country (Million)
1 China 555
2 India 358
3 U.S.A. 158
4 Russian 102
Federation
5 Japan 84
6 Indonesia 80
7 Germany 68
8 Brazil 54
9 United 51
Kingdom
10 Italy 47
11 France 42
12 Bangladesh 42
13 Pakistan 40
1996
Population
Rank Country (Million)
1 China 1,232
2 India 945
3 U.S.A. 269
4 Indonesia 200
5 Brazil 161
6 Russian 148
Federation
7 Pakistan 140
8 Japan 125
9 Bangladesh 120
10 Nigeria 115
11 Mexico 93
12 Germany 82
13 Viet Nam 75
2050
Population
Rank Country (Million)
1 India 1,533
2 China 1,517
3 Pakistan 357
4 U.S.A. 348
5 Nigeria 339
6 Indonesia 318
7 Brazil 243
8 Bangladesh 218
9 Ethiopia 213
10 Iran 170
11 Zaire 165
12 Mexico 154
13 Philippines 131
Source: United Nations, Population Division.
Popin Web Site, p 1, 1998.
Table 2
Top Terra Contributors to World Population Growth, 1995-2000
Percent of
Net Addition World Pop. Cumulative
No. Country (in Thousands) Growth Percent
1 India 15,999 20.6 20.6
2 China 11,408 14.7 35.3
3 Pakistan 4,048 5.2 40.5
4 Indonesia 2,929 3.8 44.2
5 Nigeria 2,511 3.2 47.5
6 U.S.A. 2,267 2.9 50.4
7 Brazi1 2,154 2.8 53.1
8 Bangladesh 2,108 2.7 55.9
9 Mexico 1,547 2.0 57.9
10 Philippines 1,522 2.0 59.8
Sub-total 46,494 59.8 59.8
World total 77,738 100 100
Source: United Nations, Population Division, World
Population Prospects: The 1998 Revision, (forthcoming).
Table 3
Demographic Indicators for Selected Asian Countries, 2001
Population
Mid-2001 Annual Projected
Population Growth to 2025
Country (Thousands) Rate (Thousands)
1. Indonesia 214,840 1.3 272,911
2. Malaysia 23,639 2.0 31,326
3. Bangladesh 140,369 2.1 210,823
4. India 1,025,096 1.6 1,351,801
5. Iran 66,475 1.5 99,343
6. Pakistan 142,326 2.4 250,981
Crude Crude Total
Birth Rate Death Rate Fertility Rate
Country per 1000 per 1000 per Women
1. Indonesia 20.8 7.2 2.4
2. Malaysia 24.4 4.4 3.1
3. Bangladesh 26.8 8.9 3.7
4. India 24.5 8.6 3.1
5. Iran 22.5 5.1 2.9
6. Pakistan 36.8 10.0 5.2
Taken from UN Web Site: http://www.unescap.org/pop/
data_sheet/2001/table2.htm.
Table 4
Key Demographic Indicators, 10 Selected Asian Countries *
Annual Crude Birth
Population Population Rate per
Country (Thousands) Growth Rate 1000
China 1,253,567 0.9 16.0
Japan 126,380 0.2 9.6
South Korea 46,444 0.8 14.9
Indonesia 204,336 1.4 21.8
Malaysia 22,174 2.3 25.8
Bangladesh 124,178 1.6 26.8
India 974,912 1.6 25.0
Iran 63,471 1.5 21.0
Pakistan 141,680 2.7 (a) 35.8
Turkey 64,747 1.5 21.7
Avg. for
the group 302,189 1.5 21.8
Crude Death Total Population
Rate per Fertility Under 14
Country 1000 per Woman (%)
China 7.1 1.8 25
Japan 7.1 1.4 15
South Korea 6.4 1.7 22
Indonesia 7.8 2.5 31
Malaysia 4.5 3.3 36
Bangladesh 9.6 3.1 38
India 9.0 3.0 34
Iran 6.0 3.1 40
Pakistan 7.7 5.0 42
Turkey 6.5 2.5 29
Avg. for
the group 7.2 2.7 30.7
Infant Per Per Capita
Mortality Capita GN P Real GDP **
Country (per 1000) (US$) (PPP$)
China 37 620 2,604
Japan 4 39,640 21,581
South Korea 9 9,700 10,656
Indonesia 49 980 3,740
Malaysia 11 3,890 8,865
Bangladesh 77 240 1,331
India 71 340 1,348
Iran 39 1,648 5,768
Pakistan 73 460 2,154
Turkey 43 2,780 5,193
Avg. for
the group 45.7 6,030 6,324
Source: * UN, ESCAP DATASHEET (1998). UNDP. Popin Website.
(a) This is the figure quoted, Actual difference between
crude birth and death rates gives a higher rate of 2.8
** UNDP, Human Development Index, 1997.
Table 5
Distribution of Ever Married Women Who Are Non-users of Contraception *
by Reason for Never Using Contraception by Expenditure Quintile
First Second Fifth
Quintile Quintile Quintile Overall
Husbands Prefer Not to 38.9 38.8 30.9 35.6
Bad Side Effects 4.5 9.6 8.5 7.0
Expensive 5.9 6.0 1.7 4.3
Not Available 0.6 4.6 3.1 3.1
Did not Know Enough 18.7 10.3 9.8 12.6
Ineffective Methods 4.3 0.5 3.6 2.3
Religious Reasons 18.9 17.0 16.9 17.7
Husband III or Away 2.1 4.1 2.7 2.3
Other 5.9 8.2 22.8 14.9
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: World Bank tabulations from PIHS (1991). (Reproduced
from Pakistan 2010, 1997).
* Excluding those who state they wanted more children.
Table 6
Fertility Transition in Iran, 1966-1996
Average
Annual Urban Crude Rural Crude
Population Growth Rate Birth Rate Rate per
Year in Millions Percent per 1000 1000
1966 25-7 3.1 45.0 52.0
1976 33.7 2.7 32.7 49.1
1986 49.4 (a) 3.8 (b) 37.5 50.7
1991 55.8 2.5 34.8 45.2
1996 60.1 1.5 25.1 33.1
Total
Percent Ever Fertility
Married Rates
15-19 Children
Year 20-24 per Women
1966 46.5 86.6
1976 78.6 78.6 63
1986 33.5 76.6 7.0
1991 25.5 67.1 5.5
1996 18.6 66.7 3.4
* Derived from Aghajanian Mehryar (1999).
(a) Includes 1.8 million Afghan refugees.
(b) Excluding Afghan refugees.